Portfolio Optimisation under Transaction Costs

Similar documents
An Explicit Example of a Shadow Price Process with Stochastic Investment Opportunity Set

Duality Theory for Portfolio Optimisation under Transaction Costs

Shadow prices, fractional Brownian motion, and portfolio optimisation under transaction costs

The super-replication theorem under proportional transaction costs revisited

On the existence of shadow prices for optimal investment with random endowment

Portfolio optimization for an exponential Ornstein-Uhlenbeck model with proportional transaction costs

Portfolio optimization with transaction costs

hal , version 1-28 Nov 2011

ON THE EXISTENCE OF SHADOW PRICES

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

Shadow prices, fractional Brownian motion, and portfolio optimisation under transaction costs

Christoph Czichowsky, Walter Schachermayer Duality theory for portfolio optimisation under transaction costs

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.mf] 12 Oct 2017

Convex duality in optimal investment under illiquidity

Utility maximization in the large markets

Option Pricing and Hedging with Small Transaction Costs

On Utility Based Pricing of Contingent Claims in Incomplete Markets

Option Pricing and Hedging with Small Transaction Costs

Markets with convex transaction costs

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging

Martingale Transport, Skorokhod Embedding and Peacocks

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure

5 The local duality theory

The Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing under Proportional Transaction Costs in Finite Discrete Time

DO ARBITRAGE FREE PRICES COME FROM UTILITY MAXIMIZATION?

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets

MASTERARBEIT. Titel der Masterarbeit. Verfasser. Stefan BACHNER, BSc. angestrebter akademischer Grad. Master of Science (MSc.)

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

The dual optimizer for the growth-optimal portfolio under transaction costs

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

Optimal investment and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Finance

Kim Weston (Carnegie Mellon University) Market Stability and Indifference Prices. 1st Eastern Conference on Mathematical Finance.

The Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing under Transaction Costs

The value of foresight

Yuri Kabanov, Constantinos Kardaras and Shiqi Song No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

ON USING SHADOW PRICES IN PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION WITH TRANSACTION COSTS

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

Short-time asymptotics for ATM option prices under tempered stable processes

ON UTILITY-BASED PRICING OF CONTINGENT CLAIMS IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS

Lecture Notes on The Core

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach

Lecture 5: Iterative Combinatorial Auctions

Umut Çetin and L. C. G. Rogers Modelling liquidity effects in discrete time

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

UTILITY MAXIMIZATION, RISK AVERSION, AND STOCHASTIC DOMINANCE

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Derivative Pricing and Logarithmic Portfolio Optimization in Incomplete Markets

arxiv: v4 [q-fin.pr] 10 Aug 2009

Equilibrium Models with Transaction Costs I

No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires

Follow links for Class Use and other Permissions. For more information send to:

Risk Neutral Pricing. to government bonds (provided that the government is reliable).

Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach

A Robust Option Pricing Problem

E cient trading strategies with transaction costs

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Optimal martingale transport in general dimensions

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.cp] 21 Oct 2010

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Prospect Theory, Partial Liquidation and the Disposition Effect

Robust hedging with tradable options under price impact

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Pricing and hedging in the presence of extraneous risks

A Portfolio Optimization Problem with Stochastic Interest Rate and a Defaultable Bond

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

Optimal Order Placement

ECOLE POLYTECHNIQUE CENTRE DE MATHÉMATIQUES APPLIQUÉES UMR CNRS PALAISEAU CEDEX (FRANCE). Tél: Fax:

Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Hedging

On the law of one price

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 19 Jun 2015

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

The minimal entropy martingale measure

Mean-Variance Hedging under Additional Market Information

Forward Dynamic Utility

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

Price functionals with bid ask spreads: an axiomatic approach

Expected utility models. and optimal investments. Lecture III

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

Continuous time Asset Pricing

Arbitrage Theory. The research of this paper was partially supported by the NATO Grant CRG

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Transcription:

Portfolio Optimisation under Transaction Costs W. Schachermayer University of Vienna Faculty of Mathematics joint work with Ch. Czichowsky (Univ. Vienna), J. Muhle-Karbe (ETH Zürich) June 2012

We fix a strictly positive càdlàg stock price process S = (S t ) 0 t T. For 0 < λ < 1 we consider the bid-ask spread [(1 λ)s, S]. A self-financing trading strategy is a càglàd finite variation process ϕ = (ϕ 0 t, ϕ 1 t ) 0 t T such that dϕ 0 t S t (dϕ 1 t ) + + (1 λ)s t (dϕ 1 t ) ϕ is called admissible if, for some M > 0, ϕ 0 t + (1 λ)s t (ϕ 1 t ) + S t (ϕ 1 t ) M

We fix a strictly positive càdlàg stock price process S = (S t ) 0 t T. For 0 < λ < 1 we consider the bid-ask spread [(1 λ)s, S]. A self-financing trading strategy is a càglàd finite variation process ϕ = (ϕ 0 t, ϕ 1 t ) 0 t T such that dϕ 0 t S t (dϕ 1 t ) + + (1 λ)s t (dϕ 1 t ) ϕ is called admissible if, for some M > 0, ϕ 0 t + (1 λ)s t (ϕ 1 t ) + S t (ϕ 1 t ) M

Definition [Jouini-Kallal ( 95), Cvitanic-Karatzas ( 96), Kabanov-Stricker ( 02),...] A consistent-price system is a pair ( S, Q) such that Q P, the process S takes its value in [(1 λ)s, S], and S is a Q-martingale. Identifying Q with its density process Z 0 t = E [ dq dp F t], 0 t T we may identify ( S, Q) with the R 2 -valued martingale Z = (Z 0 t, Z 1 t ) 0 t T such that S := Z 1 Z 0 [(1 λ)s, S]. For 0 < λ < 1, we say that S satisfies (CPS λ ) if there is a consistent price system for transaction costs λ.

Definition [Jouini-Kallal ( 95), Cvitanic-Karatzas ( 96), Kabanov-Stricker ( 02),...] A consistent-price system is a pair ( S, Q) such that Q P, the process S takes its value in [(1 λ)s, S], and S is a Q-martingale. Identifying Q with its density process Z 0 t = E [ dq dp F t], 0 t T we may identify ( S, Q) with the R 2 -valued martingale Z = (Z 0 t, Z 1 t ) 0 t T such that S := Z 1 Z 0 [(1 λ)s, S]. For 0 < λ < 1, we say that S satisfies (CPS λ ) if there is a consistent price system for transaction costs λ.

Portfolio optimisation The set of non-negative claims attainable at price x is X T L 0 + : there is an admissible ϕ = (ϕ 0 t, ϕ 1 t ) 0 t T C(x) = starting at (ϕ 0 0, ϕ1 0 ) = (x, 0) and ending at (ϕ 0 T, ϕ1 T ) = (X T, 0) Given a utility function U : R + R define u(x) = sup{e[u(x T ) : X T C(x)}. Cvitanic-Karatzas ( 96), Deelstra-Pham-Touzi ( 01), Cvitanic-Wang ( 01), Bouchard ( 02),...

Question 1 What are conditions ensuring that C(x) is closed in L 0 +(P). (w.r. to convergence in measure)? Theorem [Cvitanic-Karatzas ( 96), Campi-S. ( 06)]: Suppose that (CPS µ ) is satisfied, for all µ > 0, and fix λ > 0. Then C(x) = C λ (x) is closed in L 0. Remark [Guasoni, Rasonyi, S. ( 08)] If the process S = (S t ) 0 t T is continuous and has conditional full support, then (CPS µ ) is satisfied, for all µ > 0. For example, exponential fractional Brownian motion verifies this property.

Question 1 What are conditions ensuring that C(x) is closed in L 0 +(P). (w.r. to convergence in measure)? Theorem [Cvitanic-Karatzas ( 96), Campi-S. ( 06)]: Suppose that (CPS µ ) is satisfied, for all µ > 0, and fix λ > 0. Then C(x) = C λ (x) is closed in L 0. Remark [Guasoni, Rasonyi, S. ( 08)] If the process S = (S t ) 0 t T is continuous and has conditional full support, then (CPS µ ) is satisfied, for all µ > 0. For example, exponential fractional Brownian motion verifies this property.

Question 1 What are conditions ensuring that C(x) is closed in L 0 +(P). (w.r. to convergence in measure)? Theorem [Cvitanic-Karatzas ( 96), Campi-S. ( 06)]: Suppose that (CPS µ ) is satisfied, for all µ > 0, and fix λ > 0. Then C(x) = C λ (x) is closed in L 0. Remark [Guasoni, Rasonyi, S. ( 08)] If the process S = (S t ) 0 t T is continuous and has conditional full support, then (CPS µ ) is satisfied, for all µ > 0. For example, exponential fractional Brownian motion verifies this property.

The dual objects Definition We denote by D(y) the convex subset of L 0 +(P) D(y) = {yz 0 T = y dq dp, for some consistent price system ( S, Q)} and D(y) = sol (D(y)) the closure of the solid hull of D(y) taken with respect to convergence in measure.

Definition [Kramkov-S. ( 99), Karatzas-Kardaras ( 06), Campi-Owen ( 11),...] We call a process Z = (Zt 0, Zt 1 ) 0 t T a super-martingale deflator if Z0 0 = 1, Z 1 [(1 λ)s, S], and for each x-admissible, Z 0 self-financing ϕ the value process is a super-martingale. Proposition (ϕ 0 t + x)z 0 t + ϕ 1 t Z 1 t = Z 0 t (ϕ 0 t + x + ϕ 1 t Zt 1 ) Zt 0 D(y) = {yz 0 T : Z = (Z 0 t, Z 1 t ) 0 t T a super martingale deflator}

Definition [Kramkov-S. ( 99), Karatzas-Kardaras ( 06), Campi-Owen ( 11),...] We call a process Z = (Zt 0, Zt 1 ) 0 t T a super-martingale deflator if Z0 0 = 1, Z 1 [(1 λ)s, S], and for each x-admissible, Z 0 self-financing ϕ the value process is a super-martingale. Proposition (ϕ 0 t + x)z 0 t + ϕ 1 t Z 1 t = Z 0 t (ϕ 0 t + x + ϕ 1 t Zt 1 ) Zt 0 D(y) = {yz 0 T : Z = (Z 0 t, Z 1 t ) 0 t T a super martingale deflator}

Theorem (Czichowsky, Muhle-Karbe, S. ( 12)) Let S be a càdlàg process, 0 < λ < 1, suppose that (CPS µ ) holds true, for each µ > 0, suppose that U has reasonable asymptotic elasticity and u(x) < U( ), for x <. Then C(x) and D(y) are polar sets: X T C(x) iff X T, Y T xy, for Y T D(y) Y T D(y) iff X T, Y T xy, for X T C(y) Therefore by the abstract results from [Kramkov-S. ( 99)] the duality theory for the portfolio optimisation problem works as nicely as in the frictionless case: for x > 0 and y = u (x) we have

(i) There is a unique primal optimiser ˆX T (x) = ˆϕ 0 T which is the terminal value of an optimal ( ˆϕ 0 t, ˆϕ 1 t ) 0 t T. (i ) There is a unique dual optimiser Ŷ T (y) = Ẑ 0 T which is the terminal value of an optimal super-martingale deflator (Ẑ 0 t, Ẑ 1 t ) 0 t T. (ii) U ( ˆX T (x)) = Ẑ 0 t (y), V (ẐT (y)) = ˆX T (x) (iii) The process ( ˆϕ 0 t Ẑ t 0 + ˆϕ 1 t Ẑ t 1 ) 0 t T is a martingale, and therefore {d ˆϕ 0 t > 0} { Ẑ t 1 = (1 λ)s Ẑt 0 t }, {d ˆϕ 0 t < 0} { Ẑ t 1 Ẑt 0 etc. etc. = S t },

Theorem [Cvitanic-Karatzas ( 96)] In the setting of the above theorem suppose that (Ẑt) 0 t T is a local martingale. Then Ŝ = Ẑ 1 is a shadow price, i.e. the optimal portfolio for the Ẑ 0 frictionless market Ŝ and for the market S under transaction costs λ coincide. Sketch of Proof Suppose (w.l.g.) that (Ẑt) 0 t T is a true martingale. Then d ˆQ dp = Ẑ T 0 defines a probability measure under which the process Ŝ = Ẑ 1 is a martingale. Hence we may apply the frictionless theory to (Ŝ, ˆQ). Ẑ 0 T is (a fortiori) the dual optimizer for Ŝ. As ˆX T and Ẑ 0 T satisfy the first order condition U ( ˆX T ) = Ẑ 0 T, Ẑ 0 ˆX T must be the optimizer for the frictionless market Ŝ too.

Theorem [Cvitanic-Karatzas ( 96)] In the setting of the above theorem suppose that (Ẑt) 0 t T is a local martingale. Then Ŝ = Ẑ 1 is a shadow price, i.e. the optimal portfolio for the Ẑ 0 frictionless market Ŝ and for the market S under transaction costs λ coincide. Sketch of Proof Suppose (w.l.g.) that (Ẑt) 0 t T is a true martingale. Then d ˆQ dp = Ẑ T 0 defines a probability measure under which the process Ŝ = Ẑ 1 is a martingale. Hence we may apply the frictionless theory to (Ŝ, ˆQ). Ẑ 0 T is (a fortiori) the dual optimizer for Ŝ. As ˆX T and Ẑ 0 T satisfy the first order condition U ( ˆX T ) = Ẑ 0 T, Ẑ 0 ˆX T must be the optimizer for the frictionless market Ŝ too.

Question When is the dual optimizer Ẑ a local martingale? Are there cases when it only is a super-martingale?

Theorem [Czichowsky-S. ( 12)] Suppose that S is continuous and satisfies (NFLVR), and suppose that U has reasonable asymptotic elasticity. Fix 0 < λ < 1 and suppose that u(x) < U( ), for x <. Ẑ 1 Then the dual optimizer Ẑ is a local martingale. Therefore Ŝ = Ẑ is a shadow price. 0 Remark The condition (NFLVR) cannot be replaced by requiring (CPS λ ), for each λ > 0.

Theorem [Czichowsky-S. ( 12)] Suppose that S is continuous and satisfies (NFLVR), and suppose that U has reasonable asymptotic elasticity. Fix 0 < λ < 1 and suppose that u(x) < U( ), for x <. Ẑ 1 Then the dual optimizer Ẑ is a local martingale. Therefore Ŝ = Ẑ is a shadow price. 0 Remark The condition (NFLVR) cannot be replaced by requiring (CPS λ ), for each λ > 0.

Examples Frictionless Example [Kramkov-S. ( 99)] Let U(x) = log(x). The stock price S = (S t ) t=0,1 is given by p 2 1 ε 1 ε n 1. 1 n.

Here ε n = 1 p 1. n=1 For x = 1 the optimal strategy is to buy one stock at time 0 i.e. ˆϕ 1 1 = 1. Let A n = {S 1 = 1 n } and consider A = {S 1 = 0} so that P[A n ] = ε n > 0, for n N, while P[A ] = 0. Intuitively speaking, the constraint ˆϕ 1 1 1 comes from the null-set A rather than from any of the A n s. It turns out that the dual optimizer Ẑ verifies E[Ẑ 1 ] < 1, i.e. only is a super-martingale. Intuitively speaking, the optimal measure ˆQ gives positive mass to the P-null set A (compare Cvitanic-Schachermayer-Wang ( 01), Campi-Owen ( 11)).

Discontinuous Example under transaction costs λ (Czichowsky, Muhle-Karbe, S. ( 12), compare also Benedetti, Campi, Kallsen, Muhle-Karbe ( 11)). 2 ε2 1 ε2 n 3 1 + 1 1. 1 + 1 n. ε 0,1 1 ε 1,1 1 ε 1 ε 0,1 1 ε n,1 ε 1,1 ε n,1 4 1 λ 3 1 λ 2 1+ 1 1+1 1+ 1 n+1 1 For x = 1 it is optimal to buy 1+λ many stocks at time 0. Again, the constraint comes from the P-null set A = {S 1 = 1}. There is no shadow-price. The intuitive reason is again that the binding constraint on the optimal strategy comes from the P-null set A = {S 1 = 1}.

Continuous Example under Transaction Costs [Czichowsky-S. ( 12)] Let (W t ) t 0 be a Brownian motion, starting at W 0 = w > 0, and Define the stock price process τ = inf{t : W t t 0} S t = e t τ, t 0. S does not satisfy (NFLVR), but it does satisfy (CPS λ ), for all λ > 0. Fix U(x) = log(x), transaction costs 0 < λ < 1, and the initial endowment (ϕ 0 0, ϕ1 0 ) = (1, 0). For the trade at time t = 0, we find three regimes determined by thresholds 0 < w < w <.

(i) if w w we have ( ˆϕ 0 0 +, ˆϕ 1 0 + ) = (1, 0), i.e. no trade. (ii) if w < w < w we have ( ˆϕ 0 0 +, ˆϕ 1 0 + ) = (1 a, a), for some 0 < a < 1 λ. (iii) if w w, we have ( ˆϕ 0 0 +, ˆϕ 1 0 + ) = (1 1 λ, 1 λ ), so that the liquidation value is zero (maximal leverage).

We now choose W 0 = w with w > w. Note that the optimal strategy ˆϕ continues to increase the position in stock, as long as W t t w. If there were a shadow price Ŝ, we therefore necessarily would have Ŝ t = e t, for 0 t inf{u : W u u w}. But this is absurd, as Ŝ clearly does not allow for an e.m.m.

Problem Let (B H t ) 0 t T be a fractional Brownian motion with Hurst index H ]0, 1[\{ 1 2 }. Let S = exp(bh t ), and fix λ > 0 and U(x) = log(x). Is the dual optimiser a local martingale or only a super-martingale? Equivalently, is there a shadow price Ŝ?

Agaphtè Giˆnnh, Se euqarist gia th filða sou kai sou eôqomai Qrìnia Pollˆ gia ta Genèjliˆ sou! RVR