Grexit : Who would pay for it?

Similar documents
How to avoid a double-dip recession in the eurozone

A Copernican Turn for Banking Union

over No. 267, April bubble The Spanish housing What with adjusted, but soared and the (Reinhart, 2008). The any the immigration

GREEK ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

The Greek. Hans-Werner Sinn

IS A DEBT TARGET FOR THE EMU FEASIBLE?

Global Economic Outlook John Hawksworth Chief Economist, PwC September 2012

Communication on the future of the CAP

Ranking Country Page. Category 1: Countries with positive CEP Default Index and positive NTE. 1 Estonia 1. 2 Luxembourg 2.

Eurozone Focus The Ongoing Saga Of Sovereign Debt

Panel Discussion: Europe at the Crossroads

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast Summer edition June 2011

Fragmentation of the European financial market and the cost of bank financing

In search of symmetry in the eurozone

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast September 2013

External debt statistics of the euro area

Falling Short of Expectations? Stress-Testing the European Banking System

Modelling the sovereign debt crisis in Europe

Macroeconomic Imbalances in the Euro Area: Symptom or cause of the crisis?

EU BUDGET AND NATIONAL BUDGETS

Central Banks in Times of Crisis: The FED vs. the ECB

FINANCIAL MARKETS IN EARLY AUGUST 2011 AND THE ECB S MONETARY POLICY MEASURES

European Sovereign Crisis, what s the Outcome? Gonzalo Rengifo June 2012 Mexico

Fiscal rules in Lithuania

Discussion of Marcel Fratzscher s book Die Deutschland-Illusion

ECONOMIC AND MONETARY DEVELOPMENTS

Consumer credit market in Europe 2013 overview

DG TAXUD. STAT/11/100 1 July 2011

Challenges to the single monetary policy and the ECB s response. Benoît Cœuré Member of the Executive Board European Central Bank

Overcoming the crisis

Auditor s involvement in the contributions to the Single Resolution Fund. Providing assurance for 2014 and 2015 SURVEY

The Trend Reversal of the Private Credit Market in the EU

Quarterly Financial Accounts Household net worth reaches new peak in Q Irish Household Net Worth

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast March 2015

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast Autumn edition September 2011

Governor of the Bank of Latvia

The currency market just got a lot bigger!

European Advertising Business Climate Index Q4 2016/Q #AdIndex2017

Unemployment is the scourge, not youth unemployment per se The misguided policy preoccupation with youth

NOTE. for the Interparliamentary Meeting of the Committee on Budgets

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast June 2013

ECB LTRO Dec Greece program

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast Spring edition March 2012

Is the Euro Crisis Over?

The International Monetary System

EBA REPORT ON ASSET ENCUMBRANCE JULY 2017

Macroeconomic overview SEE and Macedonia

BRIEFING ON THE FUND FOR EUROPEAN AID FOR THE MOST DEPRIVED ( FEAD )

Trends in European Household Credit

Preliminary results of International Trade in 2014: in nominal terms exports increased by 1.8% and imports increased by 3.

March 2005 Euro-zone external trade surplus 4.2 bn euro 6.5 bn euro deficit for EU25

The EU Craft and SME Barometer 2018/H2

46 ECB FISCAL CHALLENGES FROM POPULATION AGEING: NEW EVIDENCE FOR THE EURO AREA

Where is the European household sector in the deleveraging cycle?

State aid: Overview of national rescue measures and deposit guarantee schemes

WP4: 2030 (RES) targets & effort sharing

Market Commentary May 2015

Pan-European opinion poll on occupational safety and health

Gains for all: A proposal for a common euro bond Paul De Grauwe Wim Moesen. University of Leuven

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast March 2014

Survey on the access to finance of enterprises in the euro area. October 2014 to March 2015

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast September 2013

The Euro Crisis through the Lens of Capital Flow Reversals

CREDIT REPORTING: THE FUTURE

Economic and Financial Affairs Committee. The EMU: challenges and the way forward

Live Long and Prosper? Demographic Change and Europe s Pensions Crisis. Dr. Jochen Pimpertz Brussels, 10 November 2015

January 2005 Euro-zone external trade deficit 2.2 bn euro 14.0 bn euro deficit for EU25

Overcoming the crisis

74 ECB THE 2012 MACROECONOMIC IMBALANCE PROCEDURE

cepstudy cepdefault-index 2018 Creditworthiness Trends of Eurozone Countries Lüder Gerken, Matthias Kullas and Till Brombach

On the Structure of EU Financial System. by S. E. G. Lolos. Contents 1

Measuring household wealth in Switzerland

PUBLIC PROCUREMENT INDICATORS 2011, Brussels, 5 December 2012

The regional analyses

Summary of Conclusions of the. Brussels, 14 th February ) The agenda was adopted without any additional suggestions.

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast June 2014

New Member States Climate Protection and Economic Growth. Macroeconomic implications of a burden sharing non-ets GHG target in Bulgaria and Romania

EUROPA - Press Releases - Taxation trends in the European Union EU27 tax...of GDP in 2008 Steady decline in top corporate income tax rate since 2000

Financial institutions and enterprises issue less debt securities in 2010

August 2005 Euro-zone external trade deficit 2.6 bn euro 14.2 bn euro deficit for EU25

Composition of capital IT044 IT044 POWSZECHNAIT044 UNIONE DI BANCHE ITALIANE SCPA (UBI BANCA)

International financial crises

Can the Euro Survive?

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast September 2014

PUBLIC SPENDING ON CULTURE IN EUROPE

Morgan Stanley European Financials Conference, London 27 March Jan Erik Back CFO SEB

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast March 2014

Courthouse News Service

ILO World of Work Report 2013: EU Snapshot

GREEK ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

Annual Report Statistical Appendix. Rome, 31 May nd. Financial Year nd financial year

DEVELOPMENTS IN THE COST COMPETITIVENESS OF THE EUROPEAN UNION, THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN MAIN FEATURES

Eurozone Ernst & Young Eurozone Forecast Winter edition December 2012

1. IMF Article IV interim mission to the euro area. Eurogroup The President. Brussels, 13 December To the members of the Eurogroup

ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT FOUNDATION IKV BRIEF 2010 THE DEBT CRISIS IN GREECE AND THE EURO ZONE

PORTUGUESE BANKING SECTOR OVERVIEW

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast March 2015

CFA Institute Member Poll: Euro zone Stability Bonds

GENERAL GOVERNMENT DATA

Europe s Response to the Sovereign Debt Crisis. Christophe Frankel, CFO of EFSF ICMA Conference, Milan 24 May 2012

Transcription:

Grexit : Who would pay for it? Cinzia Alcidi, Alessandro Giovannini and Daniel Gros No. 272, 23 May 2012 W hat would be the cost if Greece were to exit from the eurozone? This much-debated question cannot be answered with a single number. The consequences of Greece s exit would depend decisively on the exact circumstances of events in the country itself as well as the general state of financial markets in the eurozone. The intangible costs of a Greek exit cannot be quantified into a figure. In the short run, they consist of contagion in the form of even higher risk premia for countries like Spain and Italy and the risk of bank runs throughout the peripheral countries. The tangible cost would come in the form of a likely default of Greece on its remaining foreign debt. After the PSI (private sector involvement), Greece owes relatively little to foreign private creditors, but a lot to official creditors (principally the EFSF and the ECB). Why would an exit from the eurozone precipitate Greece s default on its foreign debt? At present Greek GDP amounts to about 200 billion per annum. If Greece were to reintroduce the drachma, the new currency is likely to depreciate by about 50% (even more if the Argentine experience is of any guide), which would probably cause the Greek GDP to fall proportionally or below 100 billion. The revenues of the Greek government would also fall in a similar proportion, from about 85 billion today to around 40 billion. These meagre resources should be compared to a total of over 300 billion that the Greek government owes to its foreign creditors. At first sight it appears that the foreign official creditors would have to write off most of their claims on the country. (We leave aside here the current 22 billion of claims the IMF has on Greece, which are indisputably senior and likely to be serviced in full.) This is the outlook in the short run. A longerrun view, however, leads to somewhat different conclusions. After the initial overshooting, the exchange rate is likely to return to a longer-run equilibrium and growth would slowly resume closing the output gap. Experience with similar cases of emerging markets suggests that after ten years nominal GDP should return to at least its previous level, say about 200 billion. Moreover, exports are likely to grow by more than GDP, thus increasing over time the capacity of the country to service foreign debt. Exports (in hard currency ) might well double over a decade, bringing them from 52 billion (goods plus services) today to about 100 billion. At that point, the country will have a much higher debt service capacity. Whether or not it is sufficient to service the existing mountain of debt will depend decisively on the interest rate. However, before addressing this question, we start asking why euro exit has so suddenly become a real prospect. Cinzia Alcidi is LUISS Research Fellow at CEPS, Alessandro Giovannini is a Research Assistant at CEPS and Daniel Gros is Director of CEPS. CEPS Policy Briefs present concise, policy-oriented analyses of topical issues in European affairs, with the aim of interjecting the views of CEPS researchers and associates into the policy-making process in a timely fashion. Unless otherwise indicated, the views expressed are attributable only to the authors in a personal capacity and not to any institution with which they are associated. Available for free downloading from the CEPS website (http://www.ceps.eu) CEPS 2012

2 ALCIDI, GIOVANNINI & GROS How did we get to this point? At the official level, nobody seems to want a eurozone without Greece: neither the Greeks (opinion polls suggest three-quarters of the population want to remain in the eurozone) nor the European policy-makers who continue to affirm that the European Union s main objective is to keep the eurozone s membership intact. What has thus led to talk about a Grexit? The main reason is that as of early May, the ongoing deposit flight has apparently accelerated so much that it could turn into a real bank run. There is the very real possibility that Greece could have no more fresh money in its banking system. Figure 1. Greek deposits and repos: 12-month percentage changes 10.0 5.0 0.0-5.0-10.0-15.0-20.0-25.0-30.0-35.0 Non-financial corporations Households Source: Bank of Greece, 2012. The classic form of a bank run occurs when savers withdraw their deposits in the form of cash (as happened e.g. with Northern Rock), but this does not seem to have occurred in Greece so far at least. Until late April, as Figure 1 depicts, deposits fell rather continuously at a rate of about 20% per annum. However, the total loss of deposits of over 50 billion has not shown up in a corresponding increase in cash in circulation. An alternative route for Greeks to try to protect their money is to open a bank account abroad (preferably in Germany) and transfer funds from Greece to the German account with a simple transfer order. However, this route has to overcome several administrative hurdles, including the hassle of opening a bank account in Germany, which is difficult without being able to show a German address. This does not seem to have happened on a large scale. A much simpler way of insuring oneself against the return of the drachma, however, is to buy German government bonds with the money parked in Greek savings accounts. This involves few costs, no administrative hurdles and seems now to have become the preferred vehicle of capital flight. However, this option is feasible only to the extent that the ECB provides Greek banks with the funds to make these operations (by transferring money to a German bank or buying German bonds). So far, the ECB has continued to allow the Greek banking system to have access to its normal refinancing windows. However, the quality of the securities that Greek banks have been able to provide as collateral has continuously declined and since the PSI has cut the value of the 50 billion in Greek government bonds held by Greek banks, the banks themselves are technically close to bankruptcy (their equity is negative or very close to zero). However, the ECB cannot lend to insolvent banks. This is why the Greek banks will soon be shut off from the normal repo operations and the only way the Greek banking system can be kept afloat is through the emergency

GREXIT : WHO WOULD PAY FOR IT? 3 liquidity assistance (ELA), which is channelled via the Greek central bank. Even this move, however, will require the release of the EFSF bonds to Greek banks, which are needed as a recapitalisation instrument (agreed in the second bail-out plan). The tangible cost: The risk transfer from private to public sector One aspect of the cost of a Greek exit that can be quantified is the loss that European banks, the ECB and the EFSF/ESM can expect to suffer from a disorderly exit, followed by a large currency devaluation. Indeed, the latter would reduce significantly the capacity of the Greek government to service debt in euro. Given that Greece is, despite its collapsing economy, still running a current account deficit of 7% of GDP, most observers believe that any new drachma will have to depreciate by 50%. As this will cut the debt service capacity of both the Greek private and public sectors in half, one can assume roughly a loss rate of onehalf as well. (We neglect here the new Greek government bonds that were created under PSI and which have a face value of over 70 billion, but which trade in the market at less than 20% of their face value.) Table 1 shows the outstanding claims on Greece as of end 2011, which amounted then to the equivalent of about $90.5 billion ( 65 billion). With a loss rate of 50%, this should be bearable for the European banking system (except perhaps for Portugal s system whose exposure to Greece represents close to 5% of the country s GDP). Table 1 also clearly shows how European banks have progressively and drastically cut their exposure to Greece by around $103 billion ( 74 billion) since the crisis broke (more than 50% in two years). Between them, French and German banks hold the largest exposures, with that of French banks now more than three times that of German banks. This is probably due to the fact that some French banks have taken majority shares in some banks in Greece. For example, Crédit Agricole controls Emporiki and Société Générale Group owns a majority of the shares of Geniki Bank. This might also be the reason why German banks cut their total exposure by over 70%, while French banks cut theirs by only 40%. As a result, the claims of German banks on Greece have dropped from representing around 25% of total European banking exposure in 2009 to 15% at end of 2011; conversely, the share of French banks has risen from 40% to 50%. Table 1. Exposure of BIS-reporting banks in selected EU countries ($ million) December 2009 Dec 09/ Dec 11 December 2011 % European Absolute Total % change claims change claims Total claims 193,521-103,048-53.2 90,473 % European claims France 78,818 40.7-34,465-43.7 44,353 49 Germany 45,003 23.3-31,648-70.3 13,355 14.8 United Kingdom 15,352 7.9-4,815-31.4 10,537 11.6 Netherlands 12,209 6.3-8,724-71.5 3,485 3.9 Portugal 9,800 5.1-1,679-17.1 8,121 9 Ireland 8,574 4.4-8,382-97.8 192 0.2 Italy 6,858 3.5-4,672-68.1 2,186 2.4 Austria 4,767 2.5-2,446-51.3 2,321 2.6 Belgium 4,207 2.2-3,485-82.8 722 0.8 Spain 1,206 0.6-237 -19.7 969 1.1 Sweden 681 0.4-388 -57 293 0.3 Source: Authors elaboration based on BIS Banking Statistics, Table 9D: Consolidated foreign claims of reporting banks - ultimate risk basis, European banks claims vis-à-vis Greece.

4 ALCIDI, GIOVANNINI & GROS We now turn our attention to an analysis of the evolution of (banks ) foreign claims vis-àvis Greece by sector (see figures in the Annex). While the cutting vis-à-vis the public sector has been fairly constant at around 20% in each quarter between 2010 and 2011 (roughly 3 billion per quarter, considering only France and Germany) there was a sudden quickening in the exit process in the banking sector between June 2011 and September 2011, especially by German banks (-50% over the previous period) and French banks (-60%). Finally, it is interesting to observe that the exposure of eurozone banks towards the nonbank private sector has remained in the last two years more or less stable: French banks (which account for around 80% of the eurozone exposure in this sector) have cut only 5% of their exposure (around 1.5 billion), while German banks have reduced their exposure by one and a half times this amount, cutting around 35% of their exposure. 1 How can such a drastic cut in the exposure of European banks vis-à-vis Greece be reconciled with its persistent current account deficit? This has been possible only because of the funding that Greece has received from the official sector. As a result, most of the reduction in the exposure of the banks has been transferred to the balance sheet of the public sector, mainly through the EFSF and the ECB involvement. There has thus been a massive indirect bail-out of eurozone banks, which started even before the EFSF intervention, during the debt restructuring process. A stiff bill for the eurozone? This leads to the next question: what is the exposure of the euro area official sector? The total is staggering: over 300 billion if one tallies up the various channels through which Greece has received support. At the moment, the eurozone member states have already committed about 160 billion in official assistance to Greece, through the first 1 Note that BIS data on German banks exposure are marked as estimates and may underestimate the real size of the claims. package of bilateral loans ( GLF, 53 billion) and the EFSF (total so far: 108 billion). 2 To this one has to add the exposure of the ECB, which amounts to a similar amount, as the Eurosystem has a direct exposure through its lending to Greek banks ( 103 billion) 3 and the Securities Markets Programme (SMP), under which the ECB bought Greek bonds worth about 50 billion. 4 Any losses on these different forms of official support would have to be split among euro area member countries. The distribution of losses among the share-holders of the ECB would be very similar to the losses from EFSF lending. But with one difference: under the EFSF assistance programme to Greece, neither Ireland nor Portugal have to provide official guarantees due to their step-out creditor position. Thus, all the EFSF potential losses in this programme would be split only among the remaining member states. Table 2 shows the exposure for each member country, separately taking into account the exact distribution keys. 2 In recent months, the EFSF has disbursed several loans to Greece as a contribution to the PSI operation ( 70 billion) and as part of the second assistance programme to the public finances ( 13 billion) and to banking sector recapitalisation ( 25 billion). 3 The Eurosystem (i.e. the National Central Banks of the eurozone) is connected to the Greek system by the TARGET2 system: the balance sheet of the Bank of Greece shows a liability of 103 billion towards the Eurosystem. 4 The portfolio composition of the SMP has not been revealed, but a plausible assumption is to consider that after August 2011 (that is, when the ECB also started to buy Spanish and Italian bonds), the ECB did not buy other Greek bonds and that two-thirds of the existing stock at that time was represented by Greek government securities. Under this assumption, 50 billion (face value) of Greek bonds are still on the ECB s balance sheet.

GREXIT : WHO WOULD PAY FOR IT? 5 Table 2. Exposure of official sector by country vis-à-vis Greece: National central banks and sovereigns ( million) GLF EFSF SMP TARGET2 Total Germany 14,719 31,217 13,912 28,749 88,598 France 11,054 23,443 10,448 21,589 66,534 Italy 9,713 20,600 9,181 18,971 58,465 Spain 6,454 13,689 6,101 12,606 38,850 Netherlands 3,100 6,574 2,930 6,055 18,659 Belgium 1,885 3,998 1,782 3,682 11,348 Austria 1,509 3,201 1,426 2,948 9,084 Finland 975 2,067 921 1,904 5,866 Portugal 1,361 0 1,286 2,657 5,304 Ireland 863 0 816 1,686 3,365 Slovak Republic 539 1,143 509 1,053 3,244 Slovenia 256 542 242 499 1,538 Estonia 139 295 132 272 837 Luxembourg 136 288 128 265 817 Cyprus 106 226 101 208 640 Malta 49 104 46 96 296 TOTAL 52,858 108,387 49,961 103,240 313,445 Note: The computation of each country s exposure via the EFSF is based on their share of the total ECB paidup capital, excluding Greece, Portugal and Ireland. Similarly the losses to the Eurosystem through Target2 are distributed among the countries on the basis of their share of the ECB paid-up capital, excluding Greece. Source: Authors calculations on ECB, European Commission and EFSF data. Given that most banks depend on government support in the event of the worst-case scenario materialising, it makes sense, especially for some countries, to aggregate the exposure of banks and that of the official sector. The official exposure is distributed essentially proportional to GDP (the shares both in the ECB and EFSF are similar to GDP weights). Given the large differences in private sector exposure, a somewhat differentiated picture emerges. Germany and France, for example, record about the same total exposure (close to 100 billion in each case), but Germany s exposure is considerably smaller (4 vs 5) as a % of GDP. The country with the highest total exposure is the one that can least afford it: Portugal. This is mainly due to the surprisingly high exposure of Portuguese banks to Greece (a classic case of a gamble for resurrection that went awry?). Table 3. Total (private plus official) exposure by country vis-à-vis Greece ( billion) Official Private Total As % GDP France 66,534 34,757 101,290 5% Germany 88,598 10,465 99,063 4% Italy 58,465 1,713 60,178 4% Spain 38,850 759 39,609 4% Netherlands 18,659 2,731 21,390 4% Belgium 11,348 566 11,914 3% Portugal 5,304 6,364 11,668 7% Austria 9,084 1,819 10,903 4% Finland 5,866 20 5,887 3% Ireland Euro area 3,365 313,000 150 59,000 3,516 372,000 2% 4% Note: The computation of each country s exposure is based on their share of the total ECB paidup capital, excluding Greece. Note also that data for the private sector are as of end of 2011, while data for the official sector are as of May 2012.

6 ALCIDI, GIOVANNINI & GROS Conclusion At present the eurozone countries are sitting on an aggregate exposure to Greece exceeding 300 billion. If the country exits the eurozone, it would certainly not be able to service its debt in the short run when the exchange rate overshoots. Over the longer run, the debt service capacity of the country should improve again (this would also be the case if the country remains in the euro zone). Given that an exit is likely to be followed by a U-type pattern in debt service capacity, it might be best to look at the present value over a longer period. Greece is starting with an export base (of goods and services) of about 52 billion per annum. In ten years, this figure might well double in current euro terms, helped by an explicit devaluation (drachma) or an internal devaluation (if it remained in the eurozone). After that, exports should grow in line with nominal GDP, i.e. around 4% per annum. Over 30 years the present value of this time path of exports would be considerable, but would vary strongly with the interest rate. Using the current rate on German government debt (1.5%) per annum, the present value of Greek export revenues would be close to 3 trillion, implying that debt service would, on average, amount to about 10% of exports, which should be feasible even for Greece. However, at the interest rate the Spanish and Italian governments pay at present, i.e. around 6.5%, the present value of Greek export revenues would be much lower around 1.4 trillion), implying a debt service burden of around 25%, which might be more than Greek society is willing to transfer resources to foreigners. Whether or not an exit from the eurozone is followed by default on the official debt depends decisively on the willingness (and ability) of Greece s euro partners to wait and finance the bridge between the short and the long run.

GREXIT : WHO WOULD PAY FOR IT? 7 Annex 1. Evolution of exposure of selected eurozone countries Figure A.1 Total banking foreign claims on Greece ($ million) Belgian banks French banks German banks Italian banks Spanish banks 100,000 80,000 60,000 40,000 20,000 0 Dec.2010 Mar.2011 Jun.2011 Sep.2011 Dec.2011 Figure A.2 Banking foreign claims on Greek public sector ($ million) 40,000 30,000 20,000 10,000 0 Dec.2010 Mar.2011 Jun.2011 Sep.2011 Dec.2011 Figure A.3 Banking foreign claims on Greek banking sector ($ million) 5,000 4,000 3,000 2,000 1,000 0 Dec.2010 Mar.2011 Jun.2011 Sep.2011 Dec.2011 Figure A.4 Banking foreign claims on Greek private-non banking sector ($ million) 60,000 50,000 40,000 30,000 20,000 10,000 0 Dec.2010 Mar.2011 Jun.2011 Sep.2011 Dec.2011 Source: Authors elaboration based on BIS data, 2012.

ABOUT CEPS Founded in Brussels in 1983, the Centre for European Policy Studies (CEPS) is widely recognised as the most experienced and authoritative think tank operating in the European Union today. CEPS acts as a leading forum for debate on EU affairs, distinguished by its strong in-house research capacity, complemented by an extensive network of partner institutes throughout the world. Goals Carry out state-of-the-art policy research leading to innovative solutions to the challenges facing Europe today, Maintain the highest standards of academic excellence and unqualified independence Act as a forum for discussion among all stakeholders in the European policy process, and Provide a regular flow of authoritative publications offering policy analysis and recommendations, Assets Multidisciplinary, multinational & multicultural research team of knowledgeable analysts, Participation in several research networks, comprising other highly reputable research institutes from throughout Europe, to complement and consolidate CEPS research expertise and to extend its outreach, An extensive membership base of some 132 Corporate Members and 118 Institutional Members, which provide expertise and practical experience and act as a sounding board for the feasibility of CEPS policy proposals. Programme Structure In-house Research Programmes Economic and Social Welfare Policies Financial Institutions and Markets Energy and Climate Change EU Foreign, Security and Neighbourhood Policy Justice and Home Affairs Politics and Institutions Regulatory Affairs Agricultural and Rural Policy Independent Research Institutes managed by CEPS European Capital Markets Institute (ECMI) European Credit Research Institute (ECRI) Research Networks organised by CEPS European Climate Platform (ECP) European Network for Better Regulation (ENBR) European Network of Economic Policy Research Institutes (ENEPRI) European Policy Institutes Network (EPIN) CENTRE FOR EUROPEAN POLICY STUDIES, Place du Congrès 1, B 1000 Brussels, Belgium Tel: 32 (0)2 229 39 11 Fax: 32 (0)2 219 41 51 www.ceps.eu VAT: BE 0424.123.986