International Development

Similar documents
International Development and Firm Distribution

Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Welfare Consequences of Globalization

Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices

Technology Advancement and Growth

Optimal Redistribution in an Open Economy

Dynamic Selection: An Idea Flows Theory of Entry, Trade and Growth

Thomas Sampson Dynamic selection: an idea flows theory of entry, trade and growth

Firms in International Trade. Lecture 2: The Melitz Model

Dynamic Selection and the New Gains from Trade with. Heterogeneous Firms

Capital Goods Trade and Economic Development

Location, Productivity, and Trade

International Trade Gravity Model

The Aggregate Implications of Innovative Investment in the Garcia-Macia, Hsieh, and Klenow Model

Competition and Welfare Gains from Trade: A Quantitative Analysis of China Between 1995 and 2004

Dynamic Selection and the New Gains from Trade with. Heterogeneous Firms

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003)

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Global Production with Export Platforms

Innovation, Firm Dynamics, and International Trade

Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Consequences of Globalization

Capital Accumulation and Dynamic Gains from Trade

ECO2704 Lecture Notes: Melitz Model

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity

Knowledge Diffusion, Trade and Innovation across Countries and Sectors

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS

Geography, Value-Added and Gains From Trade: Theory and Empirics

The Aggregate Implications of Innovative Investment in the Garcia-Macia, Hsieh, and Klenow Model

Endogenous Trade Participation with Incomplete Exchange Rate Pass-Through

Labor Market Rigidities, Trade and Unemployment

Eaton and Kortum, Econometrica 2002

Capital Accumulation and Dynamic Gains from Trade

Melitz Model: Heterogenous Firm Model of Trade

Heterogeneous Firms. Notes for Graduate Trade Course. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. January 30, 2013

Trade Costs and Job Flows: Evidence from Establishment-Level Data

Working Paper Series. Knowledge diffusion, trade and innovation across countries and sectors. Jie Cai, Nan Li and Ana Maria Santacreu

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

Impact of Tariff under Hecksher-Ohlin Comparative Advantage Setting and Firm Heterogeneity

Inequality, Costly Redistribution and Welfare in an Open Economy

Research at Intersection of Trade and IO. Interest in heterogeneous impact of trade policy (some firms win, others lose, perhaps in same industry)

Technology, Geography and Trade J. Eaton and S. Kortum. Topics in international Trade

Zipf s Law, Pareto s Law, and the Evolution of Top Incomes in the U.S.

Trade and Labor Market: Felbermayr, Prat, Schmerer (2011)

Productivity: Theory and Evidence

International Trade and Income Differences

International Economics: Lecture 10 & 11

International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I)

WORKING PAPER NO ESTABLISHMENT HETEROGENEITY, EXPORTER DYNAMICS, AND THE EFFECTS OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION

NOT FOR PUBLICATION. Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome. Small Open Economy Model

Gravity, Trade Integration and Heterogeneity across Industries

The Extensive Margin of Trade and Monetary Policy

Financial Frictions, Multinational Firms, and Income in Developing Countries

Trade and Technology Asian Miracles and WTO Anti-Miracles

International Banks and the Cross-Border Transmission of Business Cycles 1

Working Paper Series. Capital Accumulation and Dynamic Gains from Trade. B. Ravikumar Ana Maria Santacreu and Michael Sposi

Firm-to-Firm Trade: Imports, Exports, and the Labor Market

International Trade, Technology Diffusion, and the Role of Diffusion Barriers

Econ 8401-T.Holmes. Lecture on Foreign Direct Investment. FDI is massive. As noted in Ramondo and Rodriquez-Clare, worldwide sales of multinationals

An asymmetric Melitz model of trade and growth

Economics 689 Texas A&M University

The Effect of Globalization in a Semi Endogenous Growth Model with Firm Heterogeneity, Endogenous International Spillover, and Trade

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

1 Dynamic programming

Multinational Firms, Trade, and the Trade-Comovement Puzzle

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 1: Ricardian Models (I)

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Proximity vs Comparative Advantage: A Quantitative Theory of Trade and Multinational Production

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

Firm Entry and Exit and Growth

International Trade: Lecture 4

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

FIRM DYNAMICS, JOB TURNOVER, AND WAGE DISTRIBUTIONS IN AN OPEN ECONOMY

Factor-Biased Multinational Production and the Labor. Share

Price Discrimination and Trade in Intermediate Goods (Preliminary Draft)

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Entry, Trade Costs and International Business Cycles

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 11 Misallocation and Productivity Differences across Countries

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Foreign Direct Investment I

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters

Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil

Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Demand uncertainty and the Joint Dynamics of Exporters and Multinational Firms

Diversi cation through Trade

Elementary Endogenous Growth Theory

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Equilibrium Technology Diffusion, Trade, and Growth

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Financial Development and the Effects of Trade Liberalizations

Monopolistic competition: the Dixit-Stiglitz-Spence model

Quantifying the Impact of Financial Development on Economic Development

Global Sourcing. Pol Antràs and Elhanan Helpman

Transcription:

International Development Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis February 2019

1 A. Introduction Conventional macroeconomic models employ aggregate production at national or industrial level, ignoring the interplays between firm dynamics and economic development. The modern literature on international trade and firm distribution, summarized as follows, has generated valuable insight toward understanding international differences in productivities, growth and income distribution.! Foundation: " Jovanovic (1979): firm-specific capital and turnover " Hopenhayn (1992): firm dynamics: entry and exit " Mortensen-Pissarides (1994), job creation and job destruction! Firm distribution, productivity and trade: " Basic theoretic framework: Eaton-Kortum (1999, 2002), Melitz (2003) " Basic empirical analysis: Bernard-Eaton-Jensen-Kortum (2003) " Generalization: Alvareza-Lucas (2007), Matsuyama, K. (2007), Atkeson- Burstein (2008), Lucas (2009), Adamopoulos-Restuccia (2014)

2! Firm distribution, innovation and growth " Basic theory: Klette-Kortum (2004), Ghironi-Melitz (2005) " Generalization: Luttmer (2007), Atkeson-Burstein (2009), Burstein & Monge-Naranjo (2009), Perla-Tonetti-Waugh (2015),! Gains from Trade: " Sufficient statistics: Arkolakis, Costinot & Rodríguez-Clare (2012), " Generalization: Caliendo-Lorenzo-Parro (2015), Edmond-Midrigan-Xu (2015), Melitz-Redding (2015), Hsieh-Li-Ossa-Yang (2016), Lai-Riezman- Peng-Wang (2019) " Dynamic models: - dynamic gains from trade: Hsu-Riezman-Wang (2018) - dynamic effects of trade war: Chen-Cheng-Riezman-Peng-Wang (2019)! Trade and inequality: Grossman-Helpman (2014), Antras-de Gortari-Itskhoki (2016), Grossman-Helpman-Kircher (2017), Burstein-Vogel (2017)

3 B. Firm Distribution, Productivity and Trade 1. Empirical Regularities: Bernard-Eaton-Jensen-Kortum (2003)! large plant productivity dispersion! low export intensity! low earning from exporting! higher productivity among exporters! larger size of exporters (measured by sales) 2. The Melitz (2003) Model! Key: introduce trade to the Hopenhayn (1992) firm entry-exit model under a Spence (1976) and Dixit-Stiglitz (1977) monopolistic competition framework! Effect of trade: - cutoff φ * is higher => crowd-out of domestic firms (selection effect) - total variety rises (variety effect) - revenue rises among exporting firms - profit rises for more productive exporters (low earning from export)

4

5 C. The Cross-Country Distribution of Trade Volumes: Alvarez-Lucas (2007)! Key: a GE generalization of the Eaton-Kortum (2002) model " buyers search over producers in different countries for the lowest price " trade assigns production of any good to the most efficient producers! Preference for variety:, where the inverse of TFP (i.e., unit cost) is a common density that is exponential with parameter λ: " x - exp(λ) (note: if ω - exponential, then exp(ω) - Pareto) " ςx - exp(λ/ς) for ς > 0 " x - exp(λ x ), y - exp(λ y ), z = min{x,y} => z - exp(λ x +λ y ), Pr{x#y} = λ x /(λ x +λ y )! Labor allocation to final/intermediate good production:! Intermediate good allocation:! Production technologies (α,β 0 (0,1) and θ > 0): " final: " intermediate:, where has a Frechet distribution - higher θ => higher productivity differences - these cost draws are economy-wide, with all producers facing the common stochastic intercept and having marginal cost pricing

6! Pricing (based on cost-minimization): " final: " intermediate:,, " defining z = λx and A = (integral of a gamma function Γ(ξ), integrable if > 0), we have: - - - - all prices are multiples of labor cost w and decreases with productivity distribution parameter λ! Open economy in general equilibrium: " n countries with heterogeneity only in - labor endowments in efficiency units - productivity parameters - wages w = " iceberg transport discounting κ ij o 0 & < 1 œi j, κ ii = 1, κ ij = κ ji, " joint distribution of independent draws:

7 " consumption, output and prices: - consumption/output: - intermediate aggregate pricing: - buyers search for lowest prices: - applying exponential distribution properties: # # # - exp[ψ ij ], # - exp( ) # - exp[μ], #

8 " relative spending shares of country i on tradables from country j: where ω ij = fraction of purchase by i for good in j received by j: ω ij o 0 and ω ij < 1 (due to trade frictions/barriers) " trade balance requires: - in the absence of trade frictions/barriers (ω ij = 1): # shares of tradables in final good production: # share of tradables in production of tradables: # these two shares implies: # trade balance =>, or, - in general, trade balance =>, with # labor share in final production: # fraction of country i spending reaching producers:

9 " world equilibrium requires all excess demands be zero: " existence of a unique p m (w): - homogeneous of degree one - increasing in each element of w - decreasing in κ ij and ω ij and - bounded below by and above by /(κω) 1/β " existence of a world equilibrium, which is unique if - ω ij = ω i - $ 1 - α - ω $ 1 - [θ/(α-β)]! Calibration of key parameters: " labor share in final production: α = 0.75 " labor share in intermediate production: β = 0.5 " productivity amplifier: θ = 0.15 0 [0.08, 0.28] (Eaton-Kortem) " average iceberg transport cost factor: κ = 0.75 0 [0.65, 0.96] " average trade-barrier discounting factor: ω = 0.9

! Main results: " 1994-2000 data from selected countries: trade barriers harmful for growth US GER UK JPN HKG SNG CHN IND ARG BRZ MEX GDP/World 28.0 7.4 4.3 15.7 0.52 0.29 2.9 1.3 0.94 2.3 1.4 Per Capita GDP/U.S. 1.00 0.76 0.70 0.83 0.76 0.67 0.10 0.07 0.39 0.23 0.26 IM/GDP 0.10 0.27 0.28 0.08 1.39 1.62 0.22 0.13 0.11 0.09 0.29 Tariff Rate 5.4 5.9 5.9 5.5 0.0 0.2 18.6 33.4 12.4 13.7 14.3 " % welfare gain (in consumption-equivalent) from eliminating a 10% tariff is higher for mediansmall countries when the productivity amplifier θ is not too large 10

" wage vs. size: larger countries are associated with higher wage earning and relative productivity, where the earning-size schedule is steeper if the productivity amplifier θ is not too large " volumes of trade vs. size: larger countries are associated with lower volumes of trade! Extensions: " technology diffusion " physical capital accumulation " human capital accumulation " capital/labor barriers 11

12 D. Firm Distribution, Innovation and Growth: Luttmer (2007)! Key: extends Klette-Kortum (2004) to explain growth as a result of: " firm productivity improvements " selection of successful firms " imitation by new entrants! Population:! Expected utility: (in per capita form: Millian) " Spence-Dixit-Stiglitz consumption aggregator: - u = quality index, p = trading price - cost-minimization =>, where P is aggregate price: - price elasticity of demand for c(u,p) (in absolute value): 1/(1-β) - expenditure share of c(u,p):! Along a balanced growth path (BGP), per capita consumption and real wage both growth at the common rate κ and the real interest rate is > κ

13! Firm production, revenue and value: " at age a, a firm set up at t - employs labor L t,a to produces z t,a L t,a units of good - pays workers at wage w and sell the output at price p t,a - employs additional labor λ F (fixed) to stay in business (manager) " revenue function (RF): =, where " productivity evolution (PE):, depending on an initial condition Z and driven by - a deterministic trend component (θ E = productivity growth of new entrants) - an age trend component (θ I = productivity growth of incumbents) - a Brownian motion component W t,a (Wiener process) " firm value: s.t. (RF) and (PE) " constant η and λ F => number of firm grows at rate η => : - growth rises with deterministic trend in productivity - the effect of labor on growth is larger when the price elasticity of variety demand is lower (varieties are less substitutable)

14! Firm optimization: " production decision (profit maximization): " maximized periodic profit: Π t,a =, which is increasing in its size,, where - initial condition: (size relative to fixed cost of new entrants with a detrended initial productivity Z - Ito drift-diffusion process:, with # the process features constant (μ,σ) # the drift is negative if new entrants grow faster than incumbents # the variance is amplified when the price elasticity of variety demand is high (varieties are more substitutable) " finite value: guaranteed by " Bellman: (capital gain = κ, dividend = (e s -1)/V(s)) - flow return to owning a firm: rv(s)/v(s) = capital gain + dividend - the drift of V(s): (Ito s Lemma) - boundary condition: shut down size b => V(b) = 0, DV(b) = 0 - solution: => exit for s > b

" entry decision: - new firms can be start up at cost of λ E units of labor - entry results in random draw of productivity Z from distribution J # initial productivity: # initial size: S[Z] - free entry condition: - under, the equilibrium entry is uniquely determined, featuring an initial size that is increasing in the entry cost λ E! The distribution of firms: " assumption: " measure of firm m(a,s) must satisfy: (Kolmogorov forward equation of Brownian motion) " boundary condition: m(a,b) = 0 " thus,, where - - - N(0,1) 15

16 " conditional prob. density on initial size x:, - - " solution: - weighted sum of conditional probability density - weights increasing in x - b, because more productive firms last longer " the case of Pareto density: long right tail (superstar firms)! Along a BGP, firms enter at constant rate = I => L E = I λ E " thus, L F = I and L = I " labor market clearing => L E + L F + L = H " good market clearing => C = Y

! Main results: " a BGP exists, satisfying = C/w and since zero profit pins down, the paths of C, w and Y are determined accordingly " along a BGP, a proportional reduction in (λ E,λ F ) raises output by (1-β)/β - in the case, zero profit condition does not change - neither initial size S[Z] nor size density m(s) changes - C/w remains unchanged - since S[Z]%(1-λ F )(C/w)w β/(1-β), it must be that w grows at rate (1-β)/β, as does Y " when imitation is difficult (captured by imitation barrier δ facing new entrants), entry becomes tougher: - firm dynamics features lower survival rates - in the limit, firm size follows the Zipf s law (i.e., zeta distribution, which is a a discrete counterpart of the Pareto distribution) 17

18 E. Gains from Trade: Arkolakis, Costinot & Rodríguez-Clare (2012)! With all the exciting development in modern trade theory and firm distribution, a natural question arisen is whether such development has led to new insights toward assessing the gains from trade! ACR s seminal contribution produces a negative answer: so far, not much! Key: Observational Equivalence " regardless of micro-level details of the model, the mapping between trade data and welfare is uniform across an important class of models " this class includes Krugman (1980), Eaton-Kortum (2002), Anderson-van Wincoop (2003) and Melitz (2003) and the extended literature " in these models, gains from trade are measured by two aggregate statistics: - import penetration measured by the share of country j s import from country i: - the trade elasticity ε, based on the gravity model, measuring the extent to which imports response to trade costs - Gains from trade (in income equivalence) = =! Such gains are found to be far below 1%

19 5. Generalization! Trade induced changes in productivity: Melitz-Redding (2015), Chen-Cheng- Peng-Riezman-Wang (2019)! Gains from intermediate goods/inputs trade: Caliendo-Lorenzo-Parro (2015), Halpern-Koren-Szeidl (2015), Chen-Cheng-Peng-Riezman-Wang (2019), Lai- Peng-Riezman-Wang (2019)! The role of variable markups: Hsieh-Li-Ossa-Yang (2016), Chen-Cheng-Peng- Riezman-Wang (2019)! Import substitution versus export promotion: Lai-Riezman-Wang (2016) 6. Open Issues! Are larger firms more productive and exporting firms larger/more productive?! Is the cost of entry the primary determinant of firm distribution?! What are the dynamic gains from trade with heterogenous firms and endogenous reallocation among firms?! What is the implications of firm heterogeneity for wage inequality?! How can one explain large cross-country and cross-industry variations in the life-cycles of firms?

20 F. Dynamic Gains from Trade: Hsu-Riezman-Wang (2018)! Literature: " Sampson (2016), Perla-Tonetti-Waugh (2015): endogenous growth with productivity distribution shifting rightward over time (dynamic gains 3.6%, 13.3%) " Bloom-Romer-Terry-Van Reenen (2014): trade with factor mobility frictions (dynamic gains without frictions 13-14%) " Ravikumar-Santacreu-Sposi (2018): trade with capital accumulation (dynamic gains 1.35 times larger than static)! Hsu-Riezman-Wang (2018): dynamic general equilibrium model of trade featuring: " endogenous productivity improvement driven by R&D in general purpose technology (GPT) a la Aghion-Howitt (1992; AH) " endogenous innovation in ideas drawn for producing differentiated varieties " North-South trade with Bernard-Eaton-Jensen-Kortum (2003; BEJK) trade environment " occupational choice (innovator vs worker; entrepreneur vs worker) " endogenous royalty payment

Introduction Model Balanced Growth Equilibrium Quantitative Analysis Takeaways Basic Structure Two countries of size N i (i = 1, 2): 1 = north, 2 = south Differentiated goods produced by firms engaging in Bertrand competition as in BEJK and with monopoly GPT as in AH Perfectly competitive labor market Lifetime utility: with U i = 0 0 U it e ρt dt, ( 1 ) σ U it = (q it (ω)) σ 1 σ 1 σ dω Production of each good ω requires a blueprint of production process and production workers Each production process requires use of GPT from the North. 21

Introduction Model Balanced Growth Equilibrium Quantitative Analysis Takeaways Innovations North: the GPT monopolist is selected by a random draw at time ν Then at time ν + each unit of entrepreneurial labor M i for each good ω draws an idea from the set of γ ν T i0 ideas associated with the current GPT the productivity of that idea is drawn from a Fréchet distribution, F draw i (z) = e z θ the best ideas prevail in the market the GPT monopoly and each successful entrepreneur engage in Nash bargaining with the bargaining power of the GPT firm = β (0, 1) 22 Evolution of total number of ideas: T iν = M iν γ v T i0 maximum productivity F i,ν (z) = e T i,νz θ, z 0 joint distribution of top two productivities F i,ν (z 1, z 2 ) = [1 + T i,ν (z2 θ z1 θ)]e T i,νz2 θ.

Introduction Model Balanced Growth Equilibrium Quantitative Analysis Takeaways Production and Trade I Unit cost of supplying consumers in country n by the kth most efficient producers located in i: ( ) wi C kni (ω) = τ Z ki (ω) ni, where τ ni = 1 if n = i, τ ni = τ if n = i; Z 1i (ω) and Z 2i (ω) follows F i,ν (z 1, z 2 ) Producer serving n has unit cost C 1n (ω) = min i {C 1ni (ω)} but, under Bertrand competition, charges C 2n (ω) (markup > 1) with CES utility, markup monopoly markup σ/(σ 1) for σ > 1 (for σ 1, no upper bound) σ thus, P n (ω) = min{c 2n (ω), σ 1 C 1n(ω)}. 23

Introduction Model Balanced Growth Equilibrium Quantitative Analysis Takeaways Production and Trade II The probability that country i provides a good at the lowest price in country n is (Φ n 2 k=1 T k(w k τ nk ) θ ): π ni = T i(w i τ ni ) θ Φ n Denote X ni as the total expenditure of country n on the goods from i and X n as the total expenditure: 24 X ni = π ni Y n Y n on the RHS rather than X n (BEJK) due to royalty Under θ + 1 > σ, the price index is P n = ηφ 1 θ n where η [ 1+θ σ+(σ 1)( σ 1) σ θ 1+θ σ Γ ( ) 1 θ+1 σ θ ] 1 σ depends on a gamma function A fraction θ/(1 + θ) of revenue goes to variable cost.

Introduction Model Balanced Growth Equilibrium Quantitative Analysis Takeaways Labor I North: two types of labor with N1 M = ψn 1 (either entrepreneurs or workers), N1 R = (1 ψ) N 1 (either innovators or workers) Whether to become a worker depends on occupational choice Entreperenuers (also applied to South): ability a G(a) = 1 a k (Pareto) expected payoff to become entrepreneurer av iν = a 1 β X iν 1+θ preferred to worker wage w iν for a 1 β 1+θ M iv X w iν iν a M iν, so M iv, 25 M iv = N M i a M iν adg (a) = ( kn M i k 1 ) 1 k ( 1 β 1 + θ ) k 1 X k iν. w iν

Introduction Model Balanced Growth Equilibrium Quantitative Analysis Takeaways Labor II Innovators: the GPT winner s total profit is (zero marginal cost): Π G 1ν = β 1+θ (X 1ν + X 2ν ) GPT monopoly s value: V ν+1 = ΠG ν+1 r+λ(r 1 ) (effective) R&D labor R i,ν hired for innovating a new GPT (given V ν+1 ) is by max R1,ν λ (R ν ) V ν+1 w R ν R ν occupational choice to become an innovating researcher if (1+θ)[r+λ(R a ν )] λ (R ν )β(x 1ν+1 +X 2ν+1 ) w 1ν a R 1ν, so R ( ) ν = knr 1 k 1 a R k+1 1ν FOC with λ (R) = κr ɛ : 26 κɛ ( kn R 1 k 1 ) 1 k 1 R ɛ 1 1 k 1 ν = (1 + θ) (r + κrɛ ) β (X 1ν+1 + X 2ν+1 ) w 1ν.

Introduction Model Balanced Growth Equilibrium Quantitative Analysis Takeaways Labor III South: no research type labor and hence N M 2 = N 2 Same ability distribution as North Similar occupational choice between entrepreneurs and workers Labor market clearing implies ( θ X 1ν = N1 M 1+θ w G k N1 M 1ν k-1 ( ( θ X 2ν k N = 2 N 2 G 1+θ w 2ν k-1 M 1v M 2v ) k 1 1 ( + N1 R G k ) 1 k 1 ). k-1 27 N1 R ) k 1 1 R v

Introduction Model Balanced Growth Equilibrium Quantitative Analysis Takeaways Goods Markets Goods market clearing: Y 1ν = X 1ν + β 1 + θ X 2ν = X 11,ν + X 12,ν, Y 2ν = X 2ν β 1 + θ X 2ν = X 21,ν + X 22,ν. No balanced trade: π 12 Y 1 = π 21 Y 2 + β 1 + θ X 2. Ratio of total revenues (t 0 = T 10 T 20, m ν = M 1ν M 2ν ): [ X 1ν = m ν w θ m ν t 0 wv θ + τ θ 1 + θ β ν X 2ν m ν t 0 (w v τ) θ + 1 1 + θ ] + βτθ 1 + θ 28 Output growth: X i,ν+1 X i,ν = 1 + g = 1 + λ (R ν ) ln (γ).

Introduction Model Balanced Growth Equilibrium Quantitative Analysis Takeaways Welfare χ N 1 /N 2, x X 1 /X 2, m M 1 /M 2, w w 1 /w 2 Under constant intertemporal elasticity of substitution, lifetime utility is: U n = [ Cn0 e gt] ξ 0 e ρt dt Under bounded utility ρ > gξ, the BGP welfare is measured by U n = 1 w n0 ρ g P n0 Relative change in welfare with labor in country 1 as numeraire at period zero (w 10 = w 10 = 1): U 1 U 1 = ρ g ρ λg Decomposition: 1 = T 10 T 20 + ( τ w T 10 T 20 + ) θ ( τ w ) θ 1 θ = ρ ( κrɛ ln (γ) π ) 1 θ 11 ρ κr ɛ ln (γ) π 11 }{{}}{{} ln DF ln (Total Gains) + ln ACR ln (Total Gains). 29

Introduction Model Balanced Growth Equilibrium Quantitative Analysis Takeaways Welfare Gains from Trade 30 Two scenarios: compared with autarky (τ = 2.5 vs τ ), compared with frictionless trade (τ = 1 vs τ = 2.5) Simple decomposition of welfare gains from trade g g (%) %gain DF ACR %DF τ=2.5 τ 1.957-1.879 7.48 1.07398 1.00079 98.9 τ=1 τ=2.5 1.970-1.957 2.43 1.01353 1.01062 56.0

Introduction Model Balanced Growth Equilibrium Quantitative Analysis Takeaways Counterfactual Analysis 31 The simple decomposition above does not reflect the real dynamic gains from trade because the GPT also affects output scale and wage Need counterfactual analysis shutting down the GPT driver (thus shutting down about 2% balanced growth, consistent with development studies) % gain static dynamic dynamic/static τ = 2.5 vs τ 0.059 7.48 99.2 τ = 1 vs τ = 2.5 1.081 2.43 69.2

Introduction Model Balanced Growth Equilibrium Quantitative Analysis Takeaways Takeaways With GPT driving innovations, dynamic gains from trade are sizable, amounting to 7.48% when compared with autarky, higher than 3.6% in Sampson (2016) but lower than 13 14% in Perla-Tonetti-Waugh (2015) and Bloom-Romer-Terry-Van Reenen (2014) 2.43% when compared with frictionless trade Dynamic gains account for almost all of the gains when compared with autarky, much higher than 57.4% in Ravikumar-Santacreu-Sposi (2018) about 70% of the gains when compared with frictionless trade Dynamic gains become larger without the occupational choice effect (negative reallocation effect) 32