Volatility. Roberto Renò. 2 March 2010 / Scuola Normale Superiore. Dipartimento di Economia Politica Università di Siena

Similar documents
Optimum Thresholding for Semimartingales with Lévy Jumps under the mean-square error

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models

Volume and volatility in European electricity markets

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

Short-Time Asymptotic Methods in Financial Mathematics

Central Limit Theorem for the Realized Volatility based on Tick Time Sampling. Masaaki Fukasawa. University of Tokyo

Asymptotic Methods in Financial Mathematics

Efficient multipowers

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

Asymptotic Theory for Renewal Based High-Frequency Volatility Estimation

I Preliminary Material 1

Economics 201FS: Variance Measures and Jump Testing

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Stochastic Volatility Models with Jumps

Modelling financial returns

Economics 883: The Basic Diffusive Model, Jumps, Variance Measures. George Tauchen. Economics 883FS Spring 2015

Financial Econometrics and Volatility Models Estimating Realized Variance

Estimation of High-Frequency Volatility: An Autoregressive Conditional Duration Approach

Short-Time Asymptotic Methods In Financial Mathematics

A Simulation Study of Bipower and Thresholded Realized Variations for High-Frequency Data

Short-Time Asymptotic Methods In Financial Mathematics

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Testing for non-correlation between price and volatility jumps and ramifications

The Effect of Infrequent Trading on Detecting Jumps in Realized Variance

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Torben G. Andersen

Modeling the extremes of temperature time series. Debbie J. Dupuis Department of Decision Sciences HEC Montréal

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.st] 7 Feb 2013

Large Deviations and Stochastic Volatility with Jumps: Asymptotic Implied Volatility for Affine Models

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models

Nonparametric volatility estimation in jump-diffusion models 1

Ultra High Frequency Volatility Estimation with Market Microstructure Noise. Yacine Aït-Sahalia. Per A. Mykland. Lan Zhang

Economics 883: The Basic Diffusive Model, Jumps, Variance Measures, and Noise Corrections. George Tauchen. Economics 883FS Spring 2014

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

HAR volatility modelling. with heterogeneous leverage and jumps

Jumps in Equilibrium Prices. and Market Microstructure Noise

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Nicola Fusari

Estimation methods for Levy based models of asset prices

Université de Montréal. Rapport de recherche. Empirical Analysis of Jumps Contribution to Volatility Forecasting Using High Frequency Data

Realized Measures. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. November Rossi Realized Measures University of Pavia / 64

On modelling of electricity spot price

City, University of London Institutional Repository

Modeling the dependence between a Poisson process and a continuous semimartingale

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Weierstrass Institute for Applied Analysis and Stochastics Maximum likelihood estimation for jump diffusions

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

1 The continuous time limit

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Tutorial 11: Limit Theorems. Baoxiang Wang & Yihan Zhang bxwang, April 10, 2017

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Empirical Discrimination of the SP500 and SPY: Activity, Continuity and Forecasting

Lecture on advanced volatility models

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Pricing and hedging with rough-heston models

Volatility Measurement

Conditional Density Method in the Computation of the Delta with Application to Power Market

Rounding Errors and Volatility Estimation

Dynamic Price Jumps: the Performance of High Frequency Tests and Measures, and the Robustness of Inference

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models

econstor Make Your Publications Visible.

The Relative Contribution of Jumps to Total Price Variance

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

The Self-financing Condition: Remembering the Limit Order Book

"Pricing Exotic Options using Strong Convergence Properties

Quadratic hedging in affine stochastic volatility models

The stochastic calculus

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

Spot Volatility Estimation for High-Frequency Data

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Realized Volatility When Sampling Times can be Endogenous

High Frequency data and Realized Volatility Models

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs

Non-semimartingales in finance

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics

Technical Report as Supplemental Material: Multi-scale Jump and Volatility Analysis for High-Frequency Financial Data

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Testing for Jumps When Asset Prices are Observed with Noise A Swap Variance Approach

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Exact Sampling of Jump-Diffusion Processes

Intraday and Interday Time-Zone Volatility Forecasting

Martingales & Strict Local Martingales PDE & Probability Methods INRIA, Sophia-Antipolis

Estimation of stochastic volatility models by nonparametric filtering

Volatility Jumps. December 8, 2008

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models

The discounted portfolio value of a selffinancing strategy in discrete time was given by. δ tj 1 (s tj s tj 1 ) (9.1) j=1

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Variance derivatives and estimating realised variance from high-frequency data. John Crosby

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

The University of Chicago Department of Statistics

Recent Advances in Fractional Stochastic Volatility Models

Transcription:

Dipartimento di Economia Politica Università di Siena 2 March 2010 / Scuola Normale Superiore

What is? The definition of volatility may vary wildly around the idea of the standard deviation of price movements Let X t be a stochastic process (log-price or interest rate) Representation theorem + smoothness conditions : Ito s semimartingales: (see Jacod and Shiraev, Theorem I.4.18) dx t = µ t dt + σ t dw t + dj t W t is a standard Brownian motion J t is a jump process with jump measure µ(dx, dt) and compensator ν(dt) is the stochastic process σ t

What is? The definition of volatility may vary wildly around the idea of the standard deviation of price movements Let X t be a stochastic process (log-price or interest rate) Representation theorem + smoothness conditions : Ito s semimartingales: (see Jacod and Shiraev, Theorem I.4.18) dx t = µ t dt + σ t dw t + dj t W t is a standard Brownian motion J t is a jump process with jump measure µ(dx, dt) and compensator ν(dt) is the stochastic process σ t

What is? The definition of volatility may vary wildly around the idea of the standard deviation of price movements Let X t be a stochastic process (log-price or interest rate) Representation theorem + smoothness conditions : Ito s semimartingales: (see Jacod and Shiraev, Theorem I.4.18) dx t = µ t dt + σ t dw t + dj t W t is a standard Brownian motion J t is a jump process with jump measure µ(dx, dt) and compensator ν(dt) is the stochastic process σ t

What is? The definition of volatility may vary wildly around the idea of the standard deviation of price movements Let X t be a stochastic process (log-price or interest rate) Representation theorem + smoothness conditions : Ito s semimartingales: (see Jacod and Shiraev, Theorem I.4.18) dx t = µ t dt + σ t dw t + dj t W t is a standard Brownian motion J t is a jump process with jump measure µ(dx, dt) and compensator ν(dt) is the stochastic process σ t

Financial Returns SPX500 index, 1982-2009, frequency: one minute 4 x 105 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 x 10 3

Financial Returns are not Normal 1 Number of returns analyzed: 1855177 Unconditional returns Normal distribution 0.0001 0.01 3 2 0 2 3

Standardized Financial Returns are not Normal? 1 Number of returns analyzed: 1855177 Conditional (standardized) returns Unconditional returns Normal distribution 0.0001 0.01 3 2 0 2 3

Standardized Financial Returns are not Normal? Number of returns analyzed: 1855177 Conditional (standardized) returns Unconditional returns Normal distribution 10 0 10 2 6 3 2 0 2 3 6

Evenly sampled returns Consider an interval [0, T] with T fixed. Consider a real number = T/n. We define the evenly sampled returns as: j X = X j X (j 1), j = 1,...,n The case with unevenly sampled returns is similar (even if times are stochastic, but not in the case they are not independent from price)

Evenly sampled returns Consider an interval [0, T] with T fixed. Consider a real number = T/n. We define the evenly sampled returns as: j X = X j X (j 1), j = 1,...,n The case with unevenly sampled returns is similar (even if times are stochastic, but not in the case they are not independent from price)

Evenly sampled returns Consider an interval [0, T] with T fixed. Consider a real number = T/n. We define the evenly sampled returns as: j X = X j X (j 1), j = 1,...,n The case with unevenly sampled returns is similar (even if times are stochastic, but not in the case they are not independent from price)

Which are the Difficulties in Estimating In this seminars, we show that volatility estimates can be heavily distorted by three factors: Jumps Microstructure noise Intraday effects We discuss how to get rid of this three effects

Infill Asymptotics We can estimate σ t using infill asymptotics: µ t dt is of order if J t is a Levy process, dj t is of order (stochastic continuity) σ t dw t is of order σ t is the leading order as 0. We can estimate it in a fixed time span [0, T] with observations at times sup i (t i+1 t i ) 0 We need high-frequency data

Infill Asymptotics We can estimate σ t using infill asymptotics: µ t dt is of order if J t is a Levy process, dj t is of order (stochastic continuity) σ t dw t is of order σ t is the leading order as 0. We can estimate it in a fixed time span [0, T] with observations at times sup i (t i+1 t i ) 0 We need high-frequency data

Infill Asymptotics We can estimate σ t using infill asymptotics: µ t dt is of order if J t is a Levy process, dj t is of order (stochastic continuity) σ t dw t is of order σ t is the leading order as 0. We can estimate it in a fixed time span [0, T] with observations at times sup i (t i+1 t i ) 0 We need high-frequency data

Integrated volatility From the above discussion, it is clear that estimating σ t is similar to the problem of numerical differentiation A possible solution is concentrating on integrated volatility: T 0 σ 2 sds Integrated volatility plays a fundamental role in: option pricing portfolio selection volatility forecasting

Integrated volatility From the above discussion, it is clear that estimating σ t is similar to the problem of numerical differentiation A possible solution is concentrating on integrated volatility: T 0 σ 2 sds Integrated volatility plays a fundamental role in: option pricing portfolio selection volatility forecasting

Integrated volatility From the above discussion, it is clear that estimating σ t is similar to the problem of numerical differentiation A possible solution is concentrating on integrated volatility: T 0 σ 2 sds Integrated volatility plays a fundamental role in: option pricing portfolio selection volatility forecasting

Realized Variance Realized variance is defined as: RV (X) t = [t/ ] j=1 ( j X ) 2 It is the cumulative sum of intraday returns It depends on ; the smaller the, the closer the approximation to quadratic variation For financial data, cannot be smaller than the average time between transactions.

Realized Variance Realized variance is defined as: RV (X) t = [t/ ] j=1 ( j X ) 2 It is the cumulative sum of intraday returns It depends on ; the smaller the, the closer the approximation to quadratic variation For financial data, cannot be smaller than the average time between transactions.

Convergence of Realized Variance As 0, if J = 0, we have: ( t ) 1 2 RV (X) t σsds 2 L t 2 σsdw 2 s 0 0 where W is a Brownian motion uncorrelated with W. If J 0 a different result applies (assume J is Poisson): RV (X) t t p 0 N t σsds 2 + i=1 c 2 i

Convergence of Realized Variance As 0, if J = 0, we have: ( t ) 1 2 RV (X) t σsds 2 L t 2 σsdw 2 s 0 0 where W is a Brownian motion uncorrelated with W. If J 0 a different result applies (assume J is Poisson): RV (X) t t p 0 N t σsds 2 + i=1 c 2 i

Disentangling diffusion from jumps When we observe variations in the level of any state variable, are these variations continouous or discontinuous? Two methods: Bipower Variation (Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard, 2006) Threshold method (Mancini, 2009)

Disentangling diffusion from jumps When we observe variations in the level of any state variable, are these variations continouous or discontinuous? Two methods: Bipower Variation (Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard, 2006) Threshold method (Mancini, 2009)

Power Variation The realized power variation of order γ is defined as: PV (X) γ t [t/ ] = 1 γ/2 j=1 j X γ the normalization term 1 γ/2 disappears when γ = 2, goes to infinity when γ > 2 and goes to zero when γ < 2. when γ = 2 PV coincides with RV.

Power Variation The realized power variation of order γ is defined as: PV (X) γ t [t/ ] = 1 γ/2 j=1 j X γ the normalization term 1 γ/2 disappears when γ = 2, goes to infinity when γ > 2 and goes to zero when γ < 2. when γ = 2 PV coincides with RV.

Power variation of continuous semimartingales When J = 0 and σ, µ are independent of W, power variation converges to the integrated power-volatility: (J = 0) p lim 0 PV (X) γ t = µ γ t 0 σ γ s ds where. µ γ = E( u γ ) = 2 u N(0, 1) p+1 γ/2γ( 2 ) Γ(1/2)

Power variation in the general case In the more general case, we have: p lim 0 µ 1 γ PV (X) γ t = t 0 σγ s ds if γ < 2 t 0 σ2 sds + N t i=1 c2 i if γ = 2 + if γ > 2 However, it is impossible to get an estimate of the integrated volatility using power variation.

Bipower Variation The [1, 1]-order bipower variation, when it exists, is defined as: [t/ ] BPV(X) [1,1] t = p lim j 1 X j X 0 j=2 In the case µ = 0 and σ independent from W t, we have: BPV(X) [1,1] t t p µ 2 1 σsds 2 0 where µ 1 = 2 π This result can be extended to the case µ 0

Bipower Variation The [1, 1]-order bipower variation, when it exists, is defined as: [t/ ] BPV(X) [1,1] t = p lim j 1 X j X 0 j=2 In the case µ = 0 and σ independent from W t, we have: BPV(X) [1,1] t t p µ 2 1 σsds 2 0 where µ 1 = 2 π This result can be extended to the case µ 0

The Modulus of Continuity of the Brownian Motion The second idea to disentangle diffusion from jumps is based on the modulus of continuity of the Brownian motion: r(δ) = 2δ log 1 δ which has the following property, as established by Lévy: P lim sup δ 0 max W(t) W(s) t s δ r(δ) = 1 = 1 It measures the speed at which the Brownian motion shrinks to zero.

The intuition When δ 0, diffusive variations go to zero, while jumps do not. Moreover, we know the rate at which the diffusive variations shrink to zero: the modulus of continuity. Thus, we can identify the jumps as those variations which are larger than a suitable threshold ϑ(δ) which goes to zero, as δ 0, slower than r(δ).

The intuition When δ 0, diffusive variations go to zero, while jumps do not. Moreover, we know the rate at which the diffusive variations shrink to zero: the modulus of continuity. Thus, we can identify the jumps as those variations which are larger than a suitable threshold ϑ(δ) which goes to zero, as δ 0, slower than r(δ).

The intuition When δ 0, diffusive variations go to zero, while jumps do not. Moreover, we know the rate at which the diffusive variations shrink to zero: the modulus of continuity. Thus, we can identify the jumps as those variations which are larger than a suitable threshold ϑ(δ) which goes to zero, as δ 0, slower than r(δ).

The Result of Mancini, 2009 Suppose X = Y + J Where Y is a Brownian martingale plus drift and J is a jump process with counting process N with E[N T ] < and time horizon T <. If ϑ(δ) is a real deterministic function such that δ log 1 δ lim ϑ (δ) = 0 and lim δ 0 δ 0 ϑ (δ) = 0 then for P-almost all ω, δ(ω) such that δ < δ(ω) we have i = 1,..., n, I { N=0} (ω) = I {( X) 2 ϑ(δ)} (ω).

Threshold Bipower Variation Inspired by the results of Mancini (2009), Corsi, Pirino and Renó (2008) proposed the Threshold Bipower Variation: TBPV t = 2 n 2 t,j X t,j+1 X I π { t,j X 2 I ϑ j 1 } { t,j+1 X 2 ϑ j } j=0 where ϑ t is a threshold function proportional to the local variance. It combines threshold estimation for large jumps and bipower variation for smaller jumps (twin blade). It is expected to be not too sensitive to the threshold.

CLT for TMPV in presence of jumps Theorem (Corsi, Pirino and Renò, 2008) If J 0, assume that θ t = c t Θ(δ), δ log δ where Θ(δ) is a real function satisfying Θ(δ) 0 and 0, and c t is a stochastic process on [0, T] Θ t which is a.s. bounded and with a strictly positive lower bound. Then, as δ 0: TMPV δ (X) [γ 1,...,γ M ] t 0 1 p MY Z t+t @ µ γk A k=1 t σ γ 1 +...+γ M s ds (1) where the above convergence is in probability, and δ 1 2 TMPV δ (X) t Z t+t t «σ γ 1 +...+γ M s ds c γ Z t+t t σ γ 1 +...+γ M s dw s (2) where W is a Brownian motion independent on W.

Simulation study we simulate a one-factor jump-diffusion model with stochastic volatility: SV1FJ dx t = µ dt + v t dw x,t + dj t, d log v t = (α β log v t ) dt + ηdw v,t, W x and W v are standard Brownian motions with corr(dw y, dw v ) = ρ, dj is a compound Poisson process with constant activity λ and random jump size which is Normally distributed with zero mean and standard deviation σ J. We use model parameters estimated on S&P500 by Andersen, Benzoni and Lund (2002) Results: Bias Estimator R R σs γ ds σ γ s ds jumps conditional to the presence of

Simulation Results Estimator Relative bias (%) no jumps one jump two jumps two jumps consecutive BPV -1.00 ( 0.53) 48.04 ( 1.74) 102.03 ( 3.36) 595.57 ( 21.07) stag BPV -1.20 ( 0.53) 47.60 ( 1.72) 114.77 ( 6.32) 97.07 ( 2.43) TRV -5.56 ( 0.49) -5.95 ( 0.52) -7.00 ( 0.53) -6.93 ( 0.52) CTRV -1.39 ( 0.46) 9.40 ( 0.55) 18.69 ( 0.61) 18.94 ( 0.61) TBPV -4.15 ( 0.56) -4.83 ( 0.60) -5.65 ( 0.58) -4.70 ( 0.58) CTBPV -0.58 ( 0.53) 7.87 ( 0.62) 15.26 ( 0.66) 24.57 ( 0.74) min-rv -0.89 ( 0.65) 3.65 ( 0.73) 13.53 ( 2.55) 541.23 ( 26.21) med-rv -0.88 ( 0.58) 4.25 ( 0.64) 26.34 ( 4.74) 558.73 ( 27.29) QPV -1.53 ( 1.33) 101.90 ( 5.41) 272.32 ( 22.79) 1601.81 ( 88.71) TQV -16.32 ( 0.91) -15.98 ( 0.94) -16.47 ( 1.00) -16.31 ( 1.00) CTQV -4.10 ( 1.01) 37.75 ( 1.53) 75.96 ( 2.00) 77.10 ( 2.06) TQPV -7.39 ( 1.28) -8.92 ( 1.36) -12.04 ( 1.32) -9.10 ( 1.36) CTQPV -1.18 ( 1.33) 16.52 ( 1.71) 30.44 ( 1.94) 57.50 ( 2.88) TriPV -1.66 ( 1.24) 210.32 ( 11.64) 687.56 ( 94.69) 7841.87 ( 468.15) TTriPV -7.94 ( 1.21) -8.47 ( 1.28) -10.76 ( 1.25) -8.87 ( 1.28) CTTriPV -1.41 ( 1.25) 18.12 ( 1.69) 34.42 ( 1.95) 77.61 ( 3.16)

The C Tz test (CPR, 2009) We use a correction under the null to test for jumps Then the jump test we use is: CTz = δ 1 2 (RV δ (X) T CTBPV δ (X) T ) RV δ (X) 1 T { }, θ max 1, CTTriPV δ (X) T (CTBPV δ (X) T ) 2 As c ϑ, C Tz z.

Is that a jump? 102 101 100 Day 04/12/1990, C-Tz=4.505, z=-0.254 99 0 20 40 60 80 2 1 0 1 0 20 40 60 80

Microstructure noise Financial prices are contaminated by observation noise, also known as microstructure noise. We model it as: Y t is the latent efficient true X t = Y t + ε t price ε t is the noise (rounding, bid-ask, transaction costs, volume effects) We are interested in the volatility of Y t, but we only observe X t

Financial Returns Intraday Time Series SPX500 index, 1982-2009, frequency: all data 1.5 x 10 3 1 0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000

Estimating with Microstructure Noise Consider q non-overlapping subsamples. Two scale estimator (Zhang et al., 2005): V ts = 1 q V subsamples }{{} q R σ 2 s ds+ξ q 1 all data V q }{{} Ξ q σ 2 sds The optimal rate of convergence is n 1 6. See also the kernel estimator of Barndorff-Nielsen et al (2009). Both are not robust to jumps.

Estimating with Microstructure Noise Consider q non-overlapping subsamples. Two scale estimator (Zhang et al., 2005): V ts = 1 q V subsamples }{{} q R σ 2 s ds+ξ q 1 all data V q }{{} Ξ q σ 2 sds The optimal rate of convergence is n 1 6. See also the kernel estimator of Barndorff-Nielsen et al (2009). Both are not robust to jumps.

Combining both: preaveraged estimator Preaveraging (Jacod et al., 2008) is a two-step procedure for getting rid of microstructure noise First step: compute averaged returns: r i = with k n but k n /n 0 n k n i=1 ( ) i g r i n Second step: apply bipower variation Optimal rate of convergence: n 1/4

Combining both: preaveraged estimator Preaveraging (Jacod et al., 2008) is a two-step procedure for getting rid of microstructure noise First step: compute averaged returns: r i = with k n but k n /n 0 n k n i=1 ( ) i g r i n Second step: apply bipower variation Optimal rate of convergence: n 1/4

Combining both: preaveraged estimator Preaveraging (Jacod et al., 2008) is a two-step procedure for getting rid of microstructure noise First step: compute averaged returns: r i = with k n but k n /n 0 n k n i=1 ( ) i g r i n Second step: apply bipower variation Optimal rate of convergence: n 1/4

Preaveraging SPX500 index, 1982-2009, frquency: all data 1.5 x 10 3 Original returns Preaveraged returns 1 0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000

From Integrated to Spot Numerical differentiation (Bandi and Renò, 2008): σ 2 t = φn 0 σ 2 sds φ n with φ n 0 Localization (Kristensen, 2009, Mattiussi and Renò, 2009): σ 2 t = n i=1 1 h n K ( t ti h n ) ( i X) 2 with h n 0 and nh n. It is enough that: ( ) 1 t ti K δ(t) h n h n

From Integrated to Spot Numerical differentiation (Bandi and Renò, 2008): σ 2 t = φn 0 σ 2 sds φ n with φ n 0 Localization (Kristensen, 2009, Mattiussi and Renò, 2009): σ 2 t = n i=1 1 h n K ( t ti h n ) ( i X) 2 with h n 0 and nh n. It is enough that: ( ) 1 t ti K δ(t) h n h n

Intraday Effect intraday factor 2.6 2.4 2.2 2 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 10:30 12:00 13:30 15:00 Intraday time

Intraday Spot 1.4 1.2 Trend Spot volatility 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500

Correcting for the Intraday Effect Number of returns analyzed: 1855177 Conditional (standardized) returns Unconditional returns Normal distribution 10 0 10 2 6 3 2 0 2 3 6

Correcting for the Intraday Effect 10 0 Number of returns analyzed: 1855177 Conditional (standardized) returns Unconditional returns Normal distribution Corrected for intraday effect 10 2 6 3 2 0 2 3 6

Conclusions To measure volatility, we need to take into account jumps, microstructure noise and intraday effect A complete theory of the joint contribution of the three effects is still missing Neglecting one of them can lead to wrong conclusions in the economic analysis appears to be the most important financial quantity to be modelled.