Government Policy Response to War-Expenditure Shocks

Similar documents
Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Optimal Monetary Policy in a Sudden Stop

Final Exam Solutions

Housing Prices and Growth

On the Optimality of Financial Repression

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Tax Smoothing, Learning and Debt Volatility

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Growth and Inclusion: Theoretical and Applied Perspectives

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Preference Shocks, Liquidity Shocks, and Price Dynamics

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis

Overborrowing, Financial Crises and Macro-prudential Policy. Macro Financial Modelling Meeting, Chicago May 2-3, 2013

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Commitment versus Discretion in a Political Economy Model of Fiscal and Monetary Policy Interaction

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Financing Government Expenditures: Some Basics

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Efficient Bailouts? Javier Bianchi. Wisconsin & NYU

Essential interest-bearing money

Professor Dr. Holger Strulik Open Economy Macro 1 / 34

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Does the Timing of the Cash-in-Advance Constraint Matter for Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy?

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Explaining the Boom-Bust Cycle in the U.S. Housing Market: A Reverse-Engineering Approach

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Elastic money, inflation and interest rate policy

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Booms and Banking Crises

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Aging, Social Security Reform and Factor Price in a Transition Economy

Liquidity and Asset Prices: A New Monetarist Approach

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income

Monetary Economics. Money in Utility. Seyed Ali Madanizadeh. February Sharif University of Technology

Discretionary Monetary and Fiscal Policy. with Endogenous Sovereign Default

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks

Classroom Etiquette. No reading the newspaper in class (this includes crossword puzzles). Limited talking. Attendance is NOT REQUIRED.

A note on testing for tax-smoothing in general equilibrium

Appendix: Net Exports, Consumption Volatility and International Business Cycle Models.

. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective. May 10, 2013

BUSINESS CYCLE ACCOUNTING

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

Real Business Cycles in Emerging Countries?

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

The Optimal Quantity of Capital and Debt 1

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

The Employment and Output Effects of Short-Time Work in Germany

Optimal Monetary Policy and Imperfect Financial Markets: A Case for Negative Nominal Interest Rates?

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Inflation & Welfare 1

Discussion of: Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations by Christiano, Motto, and Rostagno

On the new Keynesian model

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

Nominal Debt as a Burden on Monetary Policy

Money in an RBC framework

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Devaluation Risk and the Business Cycle Implications of Exchange Rate Management

The Basic New Keynesian Model

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults. June 3, 2009

Sovereign Default and the Choice of Maturity

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No Elastic Money, Inflation, and Interest Rate Policy

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

Optimal Taxation and Debt Management without Commitment

Towards a General Equilibrium Foundation for the Observed Term Structure and Design in Sovereign Bonds

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Research Summary and Statement of Research Agenda

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

The Role of Central Bank Operating Procedures in an Economy with Productive Government Spending

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

Transcription:

Government Policy Response to War-Expenditure Shocks Fernando M. Martin SFU August 12, 2011

Wartime policy in the U.S. Episodes of interest: Civil War World War I World War II Qualitative stylized facts: 1. mix of contemporaneous financing instruments: debt, inflation and taxes 2. large and persistent debt response 3. significant increase in GDP 4. large wartime deficits followed by peacetime surpluses 5. WWII: inflation is also used to finance accumulated debt

Model predictions Barro (JPE 1979) or Ramsey w/incomplete markets: explains (some aspects of) debt-behavior cannot explain wartime increase in taxation no predictions for inflation Ramsey + money (Chari-Christiano-Kehoe, JMCB 2001): no persistence in debt (and response is in wrong direction) very volatile inflation (with zero or negative autocorrelation) Limited commitment (Martin, RED 2009): matches some facts qualitatively predicts too much inflation counterfactual post-war tax behavior not a systematic study

This paper Match qualitative and quantitative facts of U.S. wartime policy, using a model of government policy with limited commitment. Complements empirical studies on wartime policy, by providing a theoretical explanation Improves confidence in limited commitment as a key friction in explaining government policy

Related Literature U.S. policy: Goldin (1980); Ohanian (AER, 1997; 1998); Bohn (QJE, 1998); McGrattan and Ohanian (2008). Limited commitment as mechanism for debt: Martin (RED, 2009; 2010; JME, 2011); Díaz-Gimenez et al. (RED, 2008); Niemann et al. (2011), Krusell, et al. (2008). Ramsey approach: Lucas & Stokey (JME, 1983); Lucas (JME, 1986); Chari, Christiano & Kehoe (JMCB, 1991); Aiyagari et al. (JPE, 2002); Marcet & Scott (JET, 2009); Aruoba & Chugh (JET, 2010). Other motives for debt: Diamond (1965), Aiyagari & McGrattan (JME, 1998), Shin (2006), Battaglini & Coate (AER, 2008). Micro founded approach to monetary economics: Wallace (IER, 2001), Lagos & Wright (JPE, 2005),...

A monetary economy Variant of Lagos-Wright (2005). Continuum of agents. Two competitive markets open in sequence: DAY and NIGHT. Day-Market: equal chance of becoming a consumer or producer banks as in Berentsen-Camera-Waller (2007) double coincidence of wants problem, anonymity and limited commitment medium of exchange is essential Night-Market: linear disutility from labor.

Government Government is benevolent and produces a public good. Instruments: money, one-period nominal bonds and labor taxes. Policy is announced at the beginning of each period before the day market opens, but after aggregate shocks are realized. Government only operates in the night market. Limited commitment: government cannot commit to policy choices beyond the current period. Wars: agent s marginal utility from public good is stochastic. Bonds are book entries : records are not accessible during the day bonds are not exchanged in day-market.

Government Budget Constraint (GBC) Normalize nominal variables by the aggregate money stock. Government budget constraint: 1 + B p + g = τn + [1 + µ][1 + qb ] p B: bond-money ratio p: (normalized) price of night-output τ: night-labor income tax rate µ: money growth rate q: price of a government bond that pays $1 next period n: night-labor

Markets Day Market: producers deposit and consumers borrow fiat money; financial intermediation is conducted by banks consumers and producers exchange day-good x for fiat money flow utility: u(x) for consumers and x for producers Night Market: all agents can produce and want to consume the night good c government supplies public good g, financed with labor taxes, money and bonds agents exchange goods, money and bonds flow utility: U(c) + ψv(g) αn

Problem of the agent Day Market: V c (m, b, B, ψ) = max u(x) + W (m + b px il, B, ψ) x,l px m V p (m, b, B, ψ) = max x + W (m + b + px + id, B, ψ) x,d m Night Market: W (m+b, B, ψ) = max c,n,m,b U(c) αn+ψv(g)+βe[v (m, b, B, ψ ) ψ] subject to: pc + [1 + µ][m + qb ] = p[1 τ]n + [m + b]

GBC in monetary equilibrium Primal approach: use equilibrium conditions to replace prices and policies with allocations. In a monetary equilibrium, GBC can be written in terms of {B, B, x, x, c, g}. equations Note: x = X (B, ψ ) is implemented by tomorrow s government. From equilibrium conditions: µ τ x c GBC in a monetary equilibrium: ε(b, x, c, g) + βe[ϑ(b, X (B, ψ ), ψ ) ψ] = 0

Problem of the government Given (B, ψ) and anticipating that future governments will implement X (B, ψ), the problem of the current government is V(B, s) = max B,x,c,g 0.5[u(x) x] + U(c) + ψv(g) α[c + g] }{{}}{{} day night + β E[V(B, ψ ) ψ] }{{} tomorrow subject to ε(b, x, c, g) + βe[ϑ(b, X (B, ψ ), ψ ) ψ] = 0 Markov-Perfect Monetary Equilibrium: fixed point in {V(B, ψ), X (B, ψ)}

Inspecting the mechanism Generalized Euler Equation: all [ E x (λ λ ) + λ X ( B u }{{}}{{} x + u xxx + }{{}}{{} 1 B ) ] ψ = 0 tax smoothing dx /db dv m/dx dv b /dx Government weights: 1. objective of smoothing distortions intertemporally 2. time consistency-problem from interaction between debt and monetary policy Debt Monetary policy: higher inherited debt, larger incentive to inflate X B < 0. Monetary policy Debt: anticipated changes in future monetary policy affect current policy trade-offs.

Monetary policy Debt Consider the effects of increasing debt: B. government tomorrow increases money growth rate: µ x. under standard assumptions on preferences, agents would prefer to have arrived with more money, V m: current demand for money increases. Relaxes GBC. future value of bonds decreases, V b : current demand for bonds decreases and thus, q. Tightens GBC. Debt increases (decreases) if the overall effect on the current demand for money and bonds relaxes (tightens) the GBC. The cost is lower intertemporal distortion smoothing.

U.S. government policy 1791 2010 Defense Goldin (1980) s Net Federal Outlays / GDP Federal Revenue / GDP 0.45 0.40 0.35 0.25 0.15 0.05 1791 1816 1841 1866 1891 1916 1941 1966 1991 0.25 0.15 0.05 1791 1816 1841 1866 1891 1916 1941 1966 1991 Debt held by the Public / GDP 1.00 0.90 0.80 0.70 0.60 0.50 0.40 1791 1816 1841 1866 1891 1916 1941 1966 1991 Annual Inflation - - 1791 1816 1841 1866 1891 1916 1941 1966 1991 Primary Deficit / GDP 0.15 Real GDP per Capita Annual Growth Rate (5-year moving average) 1791 1816 1841 1866 1891 1916 1941 1966 1991 0.05 1791 1816 1841 1866 1891 1916 1941 1966 1991-0.05 - -

Ex.1: Calibration to post-war U.S. Calibration needs to be consistent with: details primary deficit decreasing in debt (Bohn, QJE 1998) expenditure/gdp roughly constant at different debt levels Table: Target statistics, U.S. 1962 2006 Debt/GDP Inflation Interest rate Revenue/GDP Outlays/GDP 8 0.044 0.073 0.182 0.182 Marginal utility of public good: ψ L targets 1962 2006 expenditure levels; ψ M and ψ H target WWII expenditure levels. Transition probabilities target 9% unconditional probability of wartime and average war duration of 4.5 years (Martin, RED 2009).

Simulated response to a WWII-like shock Expenditure / GDP 0.45 0.40 0.35 0.25 0.15 0.05-10 0 10 20 30 40 Tax Revenue / GDP 0.35 0.25 0.15 0.05-10 0 10 20 30 40 Debt / GDP 0.60 0.50 0.40-10 0 10 20 30 40 Inflation 0.15 0.05-10 0 10 20 30 40 0.15 Primary Deficit / GDP (Normalized) Real GDP 0.25 0.05-10 0 10 20 30 40-0.05 0.15 0.05-10 0 10 20 30 40-0.05

War peak vs 5-year pre-war average Table: Averages over 1, 000, 000 simulated periods U.S. Wars * Model Outlays/GDP [8 0.322] 0.223 (0.033) Revenue/GDP [0.050 0.135] 0.132 (0.034) Deficit/GDP [0.087 0.252] 0.129 (0.024) Debt/GDP [0.292 0.579] 0.360 (0.148) Inflation [0.243 0.132] 0.156 (0.052) GDP [0.058 0.500] 0.288 (0.046) Includes wars that last at least 3 years and were preceded by at least 10 years of peace.

Ex.2: World War II calibration Idea: calibrate model to pre-wwii and simulate WWII shock. Not a straightforward exercise: economy transitions out of depression pre-war and long-run policy looks very different post-war. Option 1: recalibrate to pre-wwii economy; problematic! Option 2: keep post-war calibration; only add an extra expenditure state for pre-wwii economy and select corresponding initial debt; simulate path of outlays from 1940-1960.

World War II: data vs LW model µ Expenditure / GDP Tax Revenue / GDP 0.45 0.35 0.40 0.35 0.25 0.25 0.15 0.05 0.15 0.05 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 Debt / GDP Inflation 1.10 1.00 0.90 0.80 0.70 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.25 0.15 0.05 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960-0.05 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 Primary Deficit / GDP (Normalized) Real GDP 0.40 0.25 0.15 0.05-0.05 1940-1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960-1940 - 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960-0.15 -

Concluding remarks A theory of long-run government policy based on limited commitment helps explain wartime policy. An empirically plausible post-wwii calibration matches qualitative and quantitative facts of wartime financing. Problematic to model inflation response: price controls, velocity. Perception of a permanent increase in size of government may be an explanation for distinct policy during Korean War. Concerns for high inflation in the future: increased debt + limited commitment = higher inflation.

Goldin (1980) Return Wars are financed with a mix of policy instruments: Civil War World War I World War II Direct taxes 0.093 0.240 0.410 Debt and seigniorage 0.907 0.760 0.590

Return In a monetary equilibrium: µ = βe[u xx ψ] x τ = 1 α U c 1 GBC: U c c α(c + g) p = 2 x p = 2U c x q = 1 E[u x ψ] i = u x 1 x(1 + B) 2 + βe[x (u x 1) + x (1 + B ) ψ] 2 = 0

Return FOCs of government s problem: E [ x (λ λ ) + λ(u x + u xxx + B )X B ψ] = 0 u x 1 λ(1 + B) = 0 U c α + λ(u c + U cc c α) = 0 α + ψv g λα = 0

Return Defense Outlays / GDP 0.40 0.35 0.25 0.15 0.05 1791 1816 1841 1866 1891 1916 1941 1966 1991

Return Functional forms: u(x) = ϕ x 1 σ 1 1 σ U(c) = c1 ρ 1 1 ρ v(g) = ln g. Table: Parameters α β ρ σ ϕ 4.172 0.973 8.188 2.508 10.753 Marginal utility of public good: {ψ L, ψ M, ψ H } = {1.0, 1.5, 3.0}.

Return War peak vs 5-year pre-war average Civil War World War I World War II Policy variable Outlays / GDP 8 8 0.322 Revenue / GDP 0.050 0.057 0.135 Deficit / GDP 0.087 0.160 0.252 Debt / GDP 0.293 0.292 0.579 Inflation 0.243 0.122 0.132 Detrended GDP per capita Linear 0.075 0.060 0.500 HP-filter 0.096 0.071 0.279 HP-filter (Ravn-Uhlig) 0.063 0.058 0.137

Return Money growth rate 0.45 0.40 0.35 0.25 0.15 0.05-0.05 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960

Return Velocity 20 15 10 5 0 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960