Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations

Similar documents
Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Optional semimartingale decomposition and no arbitrage condition in enlarged ltration

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Enlargement of filtration

Hedging under Arbitrage

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

Yuri Kabanov, Constantinos Kardaras and Shiqi Song No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

Non-semimartingales in finance

arxiv: v13 [q-fin.gn] 29 Jan 2016

Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

No arbitrage of the first kind and local martingale numéraires

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

The value of foresight

Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach

Strong bubbles and strict local martingales

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

DOI: /s Springer. This version available at:

Constructive martingale representation using Functional Itô Calculus: a local martingale extension

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Hedging under arbitrage

SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS

Credit Risk with asymmetric information on the default threshold

SURE PROFITS VIA FLASH STRATEGIES AND THE IMPOSSIBILITY OF PREDICTABLE JUMPS. 1. Introduction

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

arxiv: v4 [q-fin.pr] 10 Aug 2009

Lecture 1: Lévy processes

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Weak and strong no-arbitrage conditions for continuous financial markets

Insiders Hedging in a Stochastic Volatility Model with Informed Traders of Multiple Levels

arxiv: v5 [q-fin.pm] 7 Jun 2017

Sensitivity of American Option Prices with Different Strikes, Maturities and Volatilities

Mean-Variance Hedging under Additional Market Information

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets

The stochastic calculus

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure

VALUATION OF DEFAULT SENSITIVE CLAIMS UNDER IMPERFECT INFORMATION

On Leland s strategy of option pricing with transactions costs

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach

Risk Neutral Measures

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Asset Price Bubbles in Complete Markets

Arbitrage Bounds for Volatility Derivatives as Free Boundary Problem. Bruno Dupire Bloomberg L.P. NY

Hedging Basket Credit Derivatives with CDS

Indifference fee rate 1

Asymmetric information in trading against disorderly liquidation of a large position.

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

Pricing and hedging in the presence of extraneous risks

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

Interest rate models in continuous time

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

ARBITRAGE POSSIBILITIES IN BESSEL PROCESSES AND THEIR RELATIONS TO LOCAL MARTINGALES.

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

Polynomial processes in stochastic portofolio theory

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Hedging of Contingent Claims in Incomplete Markets

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Portfolio Optimisation under Transaction Costs

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

BSDE with random terminal time under enlarged filtration and financial applications

Exponential utility maximization under partial information and sufficiency of information

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Applications of short-time asymptotics to the statistical estimation and option pricing of Lévy-driven models

A Continuity Correction under Jump-Diffusion Models with Applications in Finance

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

An Explicit Example of a Shadow Price Process with Stochastic Investment Opportunity Set

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Option Pricing with Delayed Information

On the pricing of emission allowances

RATING BASED LÉVY LIBOR MODEL

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

SURE PROFITS VIA FLASH STRATEGIES AND THE IMPOSSIBILITY OF PREDICTABLE JUMPS

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.mf] 2 Oct 2016

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

HEDGING BY SEQUENTIAL REGRESSION : AN INTRODUCTION TO THE MATHEMATICS OF OPTION TRADING

Transcription:

Insider information and arbitrage profits via enlargements of filtrations Claudio Fontana Laboratoire de Probabilités et Modèles Aléatoires Université Paris Diderot XVI Workshop on Quantitative Finance Parma, January 29-30, 2015 This work was supported by a Marie Curie IEF Fellowship within the 7th EC Framework Programme. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 1 / 14

Private information and arbitrage profits Insider trading There exist market participants who possess additional private information which is not shared with the rest of the market; this private information allows for profitable trading opportunities. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 2 / 14

Private information and arbitrage profits Insider trading There exist market participants who possess additional private information which is not shared with the rest of the market; this private information allows for profitable trading opportunities. Let the publicly available information be represented by a filtration F. (In other words, F represents the information of a typical market participant.) Let G = (G t ) t 0 be a filtration such that G t F t, for all t 0. interpretation: G represents the point of view of a better informed agent (insider trader). enlargement of filtrations (seminal papers from the 70-80s: Azéma, Barlow, Brémaud, Jacod, Jeulin, Song, Yoeurp, Yor.) Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 2 / 14

Private information and arbitrage profits Insider trading There exist market participants who possess additional private information which is not shared with the rest of the market; this private information allows for profitable trading opportunities. Let the publicly available information be represented by a filtration F. (In other words, F represents the information of a typical market participant.) Let G = (G t ) t 0 be a filtration such that G t F t, for all t 0. interpretation: G represents the point of view of a better informed agent (insider trader). enlargement of filtrations (seminal papers from the 70-80s: Azéma, Barlow, Brémaud, Jacod, Jeulin, Song, Yoeurp, Yor.) The question: Suppose that no arbitrage profits can be realized by typical market participants on the basis of the information contained in the filtration F. Does the additional knowledge of G allow for arbitrage profits? And, if yes, in what sense? Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 2 / 14

Private information and arbitrage profits Insider trading There exist market participants who possess additional private information which is not shared with the rest of the market; this private information allows for profitable trading opportunities. Let the publicly available information be represented by a filtration F. (In other words, F represents the information of a typical market participant.) Let G = (G t ) t 0 be a filtration such that G t F t, for all t 0. interpretation: G represents the point of view of a better informed agent (insider trader). enlargement of filtrations (seminal papers from the 70-80s: Azéma, Barlow, Brémaud, Jacod, Jeulin, Song, Yoeurp, Yor.) The question: Suppose that no arbitrage profits can be realized by typical market participants on the basis of the information contained in the filtration F. Does the additional knowledge of G allow for arbitrage profits? And, if yes, in what sense? Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 2 / 14

A basic example Let W = (W t ) t 0 be a standard Brownian motion on (Ω, F, F, P), with F = F W ; let S = (S t ) t 0 represent the discounted price of a risky asset, with: ds t = S t σ dw t, S 0 = s (0, ); Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 3 / 14

A basic example Let W = (W t ) t 0 be a standard Brownian motion on (Ω, F, F, P), with F = F W ; let S = (S t ) t 0 represent the discounted price of a risky asset, with: ds t = S t σ dw t, S 0 = s (0, ); define a random time τ : Ω [0, ] (with τ < P-a.s.) as follows: { τ := sup t 0 : S t = sup S u }. u 0 Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 3 / 14

A basic example Let W = (W t ) t 0 be a standard Brownian motion on (Ω, F, F, P), with F = F W ; let S = (S t ) t 0 represent the discounted price of a risky asset, with: ds t = S t σ dw t, S 0 = s (0, ); define a random time τ : Ω [0, ] (with τ < P-a.s.) as follows: { τ := sup t 0 : S t = sup S u }. u 0 τ is not an F-stopping time! Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 3 / 14

A basic example Let W = (W t ) t 0 be a standard Brownian motion on (Ω, F, F, P), with F = F W ; let S = (S t ) t 0 represent the discounted price of a risky asset, with: ds t = S t σ dw t, S 0 = s (0, ); define a random time τ : Ω [0, ] (with τ < P-a.s.) as follows: { τ := sup t 0 : S t = sup S u }. u 0 τ is not an F-stopping time! Define the progressively enlarged filtration G = (G t ) t 0 as: G t := s>t G 0 s where G 0 t := F t σ(τ t), for all t 0. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 3 / 14

A basic example Let W = (W t ) t 0 be a standard Brownian motion on (Ω, F, F, P), with F = F W ; let S = (S t ) t 0 represent the discounted price of a risky asset, with: ds t = S t σ dw t, S 0 = s (0, ); define a random time τ : Ω [0, ] (with τ < P-a.s.) as follows: { τ := sup t 0 : S t = sup S u }. u 0 τ is not an F-stopping time! Define the progressively enlarged filtration G = (G t ) t 0 as: G t := s>t G 0 s where G 0 t := F t σ(τ t), for all t 0. An arbitrage strategy in the enlarged filtration G: Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 3 / 14

A basic example Let W = (W t ) t 0 be a standard Brownian motion on (Ω, F, F, P), with F = F W ; let S = (S t ) t 0 represent the discounted price of a risky asset, with: ds t = S t σ dw t, S 0 = s (0, ); define a random time τ : Ω [0, ] (with τ < P-a.s.) as follows: { τ := sup t 0 : S t = sup S u }. u 0 τ is not an F-stopping time! Define the progressively enlarged filtration G = (G t ) t 0 as: G t := s>t G 0 s where G 0 t := F t σ(τ t), for all t 0. An arbitrage strategy in the enlarged filtration G: buy at t = 0 and sell at t = τ. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 3 / 14

A basic example: discussion The key features of the previous example: the filtration F is continuous; the financial market based on F is arbitrage-free (NFLVR) and complete; the random time τ is a honest time: for every t > 0, there exists an F t -measurable random variable ζ t such that τ = ζ t on {τ < t}. Indeed, we can take ζ t := sup { u [0, t] : S u = sup r [0,t] S r } Ft ; for all F-stopping times σ, it holds that P(τ = σ) = 0. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 4 / 14

A basic example: discussion The key features of the previous example: the filtration F is continuous; the financial market based on F is arbitrage-free (NFLVR) and complete; the random time τ is a honest time: for every t > 0, there exists an F t -measurable random variable ζ t such that τ = ζ t on {τ < t}. Indeed, we can take ζ t := sup { u [0, t] : S u = sup r [0,t] S r } Ft ; for all F-stopping times σ, it holds that P(τ = σ) = 0. Under the above assumptions, one always faces the situation of the basic example. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 4 / 14

Arbitrage opportunities arising with honest times Lemma (Nikeghbali & Yor, 2006) Let τ be an honest time such that P(τ = σ) = 0 for all F-stopping times σ. Then, (if the filtration F is continuous), there exists a (continuous) non-negative F-local martingale N = (N t ) t 0 with N 0 = 1 and lim t N t = 0 P-a.s. such that Z t = P(τ > t F t ) = N t /N t, where N t := sup u t N u. Moreover: τ = sup{t 0 : N t = N t } = sup{t 0 : N t = N } Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 5 / 14

Arbitrage opportunities arising with honest times Lemma (Nikeghbali & Yor, 2006) Let τ be an honest time such that P(τ = σ) = 0 for all F-stopping times σ. Then, (if the filtration F is continuous), there exists a (continuous) non-negative F-local martingale N = (N t ) t 0 with N 0 = 1 and lim t N t = 0 P-a.s. such that Z t = P(τ > t F t ) = N t /N t, where N t := sup u t N u. Moreover: τ = sup{t 0 : N t = N t } = sup{t 0 : N t = N } Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 5 / 14

Arbitrage opportunities arising with honest times Lemma (Nikeghbali & Yor, 2006) Let τ be an honest time such that P(τ = σ) = 0 for all F-stopping times σ. Then, (if the filtration F is continuous), there exists a (continuous) non-negative F-local martingale N = (N t ) t 0 with N 0 = 1 and lim t N t = 0 P-a.s. such that Z t = P(τ > t F t ) = N t /N t, where N t := sup u t N u. Moreover: τ = sup{t 0 : N t = N t } = sup{t 0 : N t = N } Proposition Under the assumptions on the previous slide, the stopped process S τ admits arbitrage opportunities in the filtration G (i.e., NA fails in G). Proof: replicate the local martingale N up to τ. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 5 / 14

Arbitrage opportunities arising with honest times Lemma (Nikeghbali & Yor, 2006) Let τ be an honest time such that P(τ = σ) = 0 for all F-stopping times σ. Then, (if the filtration F is continuous), there exists a (continuous) non-negative F-local martingale N = (N t ) t 0 with N 0 = 1 and lim t N t = 0 P-a.s. such that Z t = P(τ > t F t ) = N t /N t, where N t := sup u t N u. Moreover: τ = sup{t 0 : N t = N t } = sup{t 0 : N t = N } Proposition Under the assumptions on the previous slide, the stopped process S τ admits arbitrage opportunities in the filtration G (i.e., NA fails in G). Proof: replicate the local martingale N up to τ. Related works: Imkeller (2002) and Zwierz (2007) have shown the existence of immediate arbitrage opportunities by trading as soon as τ occurs. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 5 / 14

A different notion of arbitrage Arbitrage of the first kind Definition A random variable ξ L 0 +(G T ), for some T > 0, with P(ξ > 0) > 0 is said to be an arbitrage of the first kind in G if for all v > 0 there exists a strategy θ v such that V (v, θ v ) := v + θ v S 0 and V (v, θ v ) T ξ P-a.s. If such a random variable does not exist we say that NA1(G) holds. Remarks: NA1 is the minimal condition for a meaningful solution of portfolio optimization problems (Karatzas & Kardaras, 2007); NA1 NUPBR (Karatzas & Kardaras, 2007) BK (Kabanov, 1997); NA1 is also a necessary condition for the application of the Benchmark Approach (see Platen & Heath, 2006). Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 6 / 14

No Arbitrage of the First Kind Theorem (Kardaras, 2012; Takaoka & Schweizer, 2014) NA1(G) holds if and only if there exists a local martingale deflator, i.e., a G-local martingale L = (L t ) t 0 with L 0 = 1 and L t > 0 P-a.s. for all t 0 such that LS is a G-local martingale. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 7 / 14

No Arbitrage of the First Kind Theorem (Kardaras, 2012; Takaoka & Schweizer, 2014) NA1(G) holds if and only if there exists a local martingale deflator, i.e., a G-local martingale L = (L t ) t 0 with L 0 = 1 and L t > 0 P-a.s. for all t 0 such that LS is a G-local martingale. In our previous setting: does the insider information of G give rise to arbitrages of the first kind on [0, τ]? Proposition The process 1/N τ is a local martingale deflator in G for the stopped process S τ (and, hence, NA1(G) holds for S τ ). However, 1/N τ is not a u.i. G-martingale. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 7 / 14

Arbitrages arising with honest times The continuous case...summing up: Assume that: the filtration F is continuous; the financial market based on F is arbitrage-free (NFLVR) and complete; the random time τ is an honest time such that P(τ = σ) = 0, for every F-stopping time σ. Then, in the progressively enlarged filtration G, it holds that there exist arbitrage opportunities on [0, τ]; there do not exist arbitrages of the first kind on [0, τ]. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 8 / 14

...towards a general semimartingale theory for NA1 What can we say for: a general (P-a.s. finite) random time τ; a general (non-negative) semimartingale model ( Ω, F, F, P; S = (S t ) t 0 ). We shall restrict our attention to what happens in G on the time horizon [0, τ], where G is a right-continuous filtration satisfying the following properties: (i) F t G t, for all t 0; (ii) the random time τ is a G-stopping time; (iii) G t {τ > t} = F t {τ > t}, for all t 0. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 9 / 14

Canonical pair associated to a random time τ If τ is an arbitrary random time, P(τ > t F t ) = N t /Nt may not hold. However... Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 10 / 14

Canonical pair associated to a random time τ If τ is an arbitrary random time, P(τ > t F t ) = N t /Nt may not hold. However... Theorem (Itô-Watanabe, 1965; Kardaras, 2013; Penner & Reveillac, 2014) Let τ be a P-a.s. finite random time. Then it holds that where Z t = P(τ > t F t ) = N t (1 K t ), for all t 0, N = (N t ) t 0 is a non-negative F-local martingale with N 0 = 1, K = (K t ) t 0 is a non-decreasing F-optional process with 0 K 1, such that, for every non-negative F-optional process V = (V t ) t 0, [ ] E[V τ ] = E V t N t dk t. R + Moreover, it holds that N > 0 on [[0, τ]] and {K < 1} {N = 0}. (N, K) is called the canonical pair associated to the random time τ; if τ is a honest time that avoids all F-stopping times, then 1 K = 1/N. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 10 / 14

Behaviour of F-local martingales in G on [0, τ] Classical result: Jeulin & Yor (1978) decomposition formula. Let us define the following F-stopping times: ζ := inf{t 0 : Z t = 0 or Z t = 0}; η := ζ 1 Λ + 1 Λ c, where Λ := {ζ <, K ζ < 1, N ζ > 0, K ζ = 0}. Proposition Let X be a non-negative F-local martingale such that [[η, [[ {X = 0}. Then, the process X τ /N τ is a G-local martingale. The following are equivalent: (i) for every non-negative F-local martingale X, the process X τ /N τ is a G-local martingale; (ii) the process 1/N τ is a G-local martingale; (iii) P(η < ) = 0. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 11 / 14

Behaviour of F-local martingales in G on [0, τ] Classical result: Jeulin & Yor (1978) decomposition formula. Let us define the following F-stopping times: ζ := inf{t 0 : Z t = 0 or Z t = 0}; η := ζ 1 Λ + 1 Λ c, where Λ := {ζ <, K ζ < 1, N ζ > 0, K ζ = 0}. Proposition Let X be a non-negative F-local martingale such that [[η, [[ {X = 0}. Then, the process X τ /N τ is a G-local martingale. The following are equivalent: (i) for every non-negative F-local martingale X, the process X τ /N τ is a G-local martingale; (ii) the process 1/N τ is a G-local martingale; (iii) P(η < ) = 0. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 11 / 14

Behaviour of F-local martingales in G on [0, τ] Classical result: Jeulin & Yor (1978) decomposition formula. Let us define the following F-stopping times: ζ := inf{t 0 : Z t = 0 or Z t = 0}; η := ζ 1 Λ + 1 Λ c, where Λ := {ζ <, K ζ < 1, N ζ > 0, K ζ = 0}. Proposition Let X be a non-negative F-local martingale such that [[η, [[ {X = 0}. Then, the process X τ /N τ is a G-local martingale. The following are equivalent: (i) for every non-negative F-local martingale X, the process X τ /N τ is a G-local martingale; (ii) the process 1/N τ is a G-local martingale; (iii) P(η < ) = 0. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 11 / 14

Behaviour of F-local martingales in G on [0, τ] Classical result: Jeulin & Yor (1978) decomposition formula. Let us define the following F-stopping times: ζ := inf{t 0 : Z t = 0 or Z t = 0}; η := ζ 1 Λ + 1 Λ c, where Λ := {ζ <, K ζ < 1, N ζ > 0, K ζ = 0}. Proposition Let X be a non-negative F-local martingale such that [[η, [[ {X = 0}. Then, the process X τ /N τ is a G-local martingale. The following are equivalent: (i) for every non-negative F-local martingale X, the process X τ /N τ is a G-local martingale; (ii) the process 1/N τ is a G-local martingale; (iii) P(η < ) = 0. In particular, 1/N τ is always a strictly positive G-supermartingale; the behaviour of 1/N τ fully determines the behaviour of F-local martingales in G on the time horizon [0, τ]. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 11 / 14

No Arbitrage of the First Kind in G on [0, τ] Theorem Let S be an F-semimartingale satisfying NA1 in F. If P(η <, S η 0) = 0, then the stopped process S τ satisfies NA1 in G. In particular, NA1 is preserved in all continuous semimartingale models. Theorem The following are equivalent: (i) for every F-semimartingale S satisfying NA1 in F, the stopped process S τ satisfies NA1 in G; (ii) P(η < ) = 0. Remarks: idea of the proof of (ii) (i): if Y is a LMD for S in F then Y τ /N τ is a LMD for S τ in G; alternative proofs of analogous results: Aksamit et al. (2014), Song (2014). Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 12 / 14

No Arbitrage of the First Kind in G on [0, τ] Theorem Let S be an F-semimartingale satisfying NA1 in F. If P(η <, S η 0) = 0, then the stopped process S τ satisfies NA1 in G. In particular, NA1 is preserved in all continuous semimartingale models. Theorem The following are equivalent: (i) for every F-semimartingale S satisfying NA1 in F, the stopped process S τ satisfies NA1 in G; (ii) P(η < ) = 0. Remarks: idea of the proof of (ii) (i): if Y is a LMD for S in F then Y τ /N τ is a LMD for S τ in G; alternative proofs of analogous results: Aksamit et al. (2014), Song (2014). Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 12 / 14

No Arbitrage of the First Kind in G on [0, τ] Theorem Let S be an F-semimartingale satisfying NA1 in F. If P(η <, S η 0) = 0, then the stopped process S τ satisfies NA1 in G. In particular, NA1 is preserved in all continuous semimartingale models. Theorem The following are equivalent: (i) for every F-semimartingale S satisfying NA1 in F, the stopped process S τ satisfies NA1 in G; (ii) P(η < ) = 0. Remarks: idea of the proof of (ii) (i): if Y is a LMD for S in F then Y τ /N τ is a LMD for S τ in G; alternative proofs of analogous results: Aksamit et al. (2014), Song (2014). Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 12 / 14

Initially enlarged filtrations NA1 stability under Jacod s density hypothesis For some E-valued random variable J, consider the initially enlarged filtration G = (G t ) t 0 defined as the right-continuous augmentation of G 0 t := F t σ(j). Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 13 / 14

Initially enlarged filtrations NA1 stability under Jacod s density hypothesis For some E-valued random variable J, consider the initially enlarged filtration G = (G t ) t 0 defined as the right-continuous augmentation of G 0 t := F t σ(j). Assumption (Jacod, 1985) Let γ be the unconditional law of J and γ t the F t -conditional law of J, for t 0. γ t γ P-a.s. for all t 0. Under the above assumption, there exists a nicely measurable density p x such that γ t (dx) = p x t γ(dx) P-a.s. for all 0. Define η x := inf{t 0 : p x t > 0 and p x t = 0}. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 13 / 14

Initially enlarged filtrations NA1 stability under Jacod s density hypothesis For some E-valued random variable J, consider the initially enlarged filtration G = (G t ) t 0 defined as the right-continuous augmentation of G 0 t := F t σ(j). Assumption (Jacod, 1985) Let γ be the unconditional law of J and γ t the F t -conditional law of J, for t 0. γ t γ P-a.s. for all t 0. Under the above assumption, there exists a nicely measurable density p x such that γ t (dx) = p x t γ(dx) P-a.s. for all 0. Define η x := inf{t 0 : p x t > 0 and p x t = 0}. Theorem 1 Let S be an F-semimartingale satisfying NA1 in F. If P(η x <, S η x 0) = 0 holds for γ-a.e. x E, then S satisfies NA1 in G. 2 The following are equivalent: for every E-indexed family (S x ) x E of F-semimartingales S satisfying NA1 in F, the process S J satisfies NA1 in G; P(η x < ) = 0 for γ-a.e. x E. Claudio Fontana (Université Paris Diderot - LPMA) XVI WQF, Parma, January 30, 2015 13 / 14

Thank you for your attention! For more information (http://sites.google.com/site/fontanaclaud/) F., Jeanblanc & Song (2014): On arbitrages arising with honest times. Acciaio, F. & Kardaras (2014): Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models.