January, 1998 forthcoming in American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 88, May 1998,

Similar documents
Financial crises in Asia and Latin America: Then and now

Currency Crises: Theory and Evidence

483 Subject Index. Global Depositiory Receipts, 250 Grassman s law, 148, 160

Did a Boom in Money and Credit Precede East Asia s Recent Currency Crisis?

What is Wrong with Market-Oriented Policies?

East Asia Crisis of Econ October 8, Team 5 Bryan Darch Svend Egholm Paramdeep Singh Sarah Zullo

The current international financial crisis: how much is new?

Asian Financial Crisis. Jianing Li/Wei Ye/Jingyan Zhang 2018/11/29

The Twin Crises: The Causes of Banking and Balance-of-Payments Problems

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

The Asian Financial Crisis

Fiscal Policy and the Global Crisis

L-3: BALANCE OF PAYMENT CRISES IRINA BUNDA MACROECONOMIC POLICIES IN TIMES OF HIGH CAPITAL MOBILITY VIENNA, MARCH 21 25, 2016

Globalization and Economic Crises in the Asia-Pacific: Imperatives on Statistics Management

Governments and Exchange Rates

Volume Author/Editor: Takatoshi Ito and Anne O. Krueger, Editors. Volume URL:

Chapter Eleven. The International Monetary System

Chapter 17 Appendix B

Developing Countries Chapter 22

The Chilean economy: Institutional buildup and perspectives

Economic Dynamics and Integration in Eastern Europe and Asia Lecture Winter semester 2017/18

Ten Lessons Learned from the Korean Crisis Center for International Development, 11/19/99. Jeffrey A. Frankel, Harpel Professor, Harvard University

A Stable International Monetary System Emerges: Inflation Targeting as Bretton Woods, Reversed

Chapter 22 (11) Developing Countries: Growth, Crisis, and Reform

IV SPECIAL FEATURES PORTFOLIO FLOWS TO EMERGING MARKET ECONOMIES: DETERMINANTS AND DOMESTIC IMPACT

Economics of Money, Banking, and Fin. Markets, 10e (Mishkin) Chapter 18 The International Financial System

Rich and Poor. Indicators of Economic Welfare for 4 groups of countries, 2003 GNP per capita (1995 US$)

Global Imbalances and Latin America: A Comment on Eichengreen and Park

The East Asia Financial Crises. Yue-Chim Richard Wong

IN THE SECOND HALF OF 1997 SEVERAL EAST ASIAN CRISIS COUNTRIES. 2 Responding to the East Asian Crisis

to T5? dollar. T4 T1 to T2 but T4 to T5. rate needed to market model) 1 Problem

POLI 12D: International Relations Sections 1, 6

IV. THE BENEFITS OF FURTHER FINANCIAL INTEGRATION IN ASIA

Presentation. The Boom in Capital Flows and Financial Vulnerability in Asia

POST-CRISIS GLOBAL REBALANCING CONFERENCE ON GLOBALIZATION AND THE LAW OF THE SEA WASHINGTON DC, DEC 1-3, Barry Bosworth

Exchange Rate and Fiscal Policies in developing countries: leaning against the wind?

Globalization in the Periphery Monetary Policy: What is Gained, What is Lost. Graciela L. Kaminsky George Washington University and NBER

Some Parallels Between Currency and Banking Crises: A Comment

Working Papers in Economics. Analyzing the Present Sustainability of Turkey s Current Account Position

Currency Crises: Are They All the Same?

Economics of Money, Banking, and Fin. Markets, 10e (Mishkin) Chapter 9 Financial Crises. 9.1 What is a Financial Crisis?

This paper updates the weights for effective exchange rate calculations, using. New Rates from New Weights

The Asian Crisis: Causes and Cures IMF Staff

Threats to Financial Stability in Emerging Markets: The New (Very Active) Role of Central Banks. LILIANA ROJAS-SUAREZ Chicago, November 2011

Identifying Banking Crises

Real Estate Crashes and Bank Lending. March 2004

Volume Title: Regional and Global Capital Flows: Macroeconomic Causes and Consequences, NBER-EASE Volume 10

Financial Crises and Debt Overhangs: Some Reflections

Why Currency Mismatches Matter

When Capital Inflows Come to a Sudden Stop: Consequences and Policy Options

IMF-Related Announcements, Fundamentals, and Creditor Moral Hazard: A Case Study of Indonesia. Ayşe Y. Evrensel Portland State University.

Causes of the 1997 Asian Financial Crisis: What Can an Early Warning System Model Tell Us?

Capital Account Controls and Liberalization: Lessons for India and China

Chapter 18. The International Financial System Intervention in the Foreign Exchange Market

Open Economy AS/AD: Applications

On crises, contagion, and confusion

Emerging Markets Debt: Outlook for the Asset Class

Bond Basics July 2007

Government Intervention during the Asian Crisis

Financial crises and incomplete information

Latin American Finance

Contagious Asian Crisis: Bank Lending and Capital Inflows

WHAT CAUSED THE FINANCIAL CRISIS THAT STRUCK A NUMBER OF EAST ASIAN

The twin crises: The causes of banking and balance of payments problems

Spillovers from Dollar Appreciation

3. The international debt securities market

International Investors in Local Bond Markets: Indiscriminate Flows or Discriminating Tastes?

ARGENTINA: WHAT WENT WRONG? Guillermo Perry and Luis Servén World Bank May 2003

LATIN AMERICA: IS IT MOVING FORWARD? Ricardo Hausmann Kennedy School of Government Harvard University

Neoliberalism, Investment and Growth in Latin America

Empirical research, considers 20 countries with fixed exchange rate, crawling peg or floating within a band.

Domestic Capital Markets and Financial Integration: Issues and Challenges

Lessons From the 1990s Experience in Latin America. Hong Kong Institute for Monetary Research November 28, 2003

Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan

New Trends and Challenges in Government Debt Management

The Center and the Periphery: The Globalization of Financial Turmoil

What Can Macroeconometric Models Say About Asia-Type Crises?

POLICY BRIEF. Resurgent Capital Flows to Developing Countries: Policies to Improve Their Impact

Does Economic Growth in Emerging Markets Drive Equity Returns?

The construction of long time series on credit to the private and public sector

Investment Newsletter

KPMG s Individual Income Tax and Social Security Rate Survey 2009 TAX

CAPITAL FLOWS: EMERGING ISSUES Guillermo A. Calvo University of Maryland Bogota, October 1, 1997

THE MIRAGE OF FLOATING EXCHANGE RATES

Foreign Currency Debt, Financial Crises and Economic Growth : A Long-Run Exploration

IMES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Exchange Rate Regimes and Monetary Policy: Options for China and East Asia

Challenges for financial institutions today. Summary

Three Sisters: The Interlinkage Between Sovereign Debt, Currency and Banking Crises

Banking Crises Throughout the World

J Ö N K Ö P I N G I N T E R N A T I O N A L B U S I N E S S S C H O O L JÖNKÖPING UNIVERSITY. A study of the Asian Financial Crisis

Ten Years Later-- A Look Back at the East Asian Currency Crisis

Lessons of the Financial Crisis for the Design of the New International Financial Architecture

The challenges of financial globalization Roberto Frenkel 1

The Evolution of the International Monetary System. Professor Keith Pilbeam City University, London

A Regional Early Warning System Prototype for East Asia

COMPARING FINANCIAL SYSTEMS. Lesson 23 Financial Crises

THE THIRTY FIVE MOST TUMULTOUS YEARS IN MONETARY HISTORY: SHOCKS AND FINANCIAL TRAUMA Robert Z. Aliber. University of Chicago

Thai Financial Crisis

UP OR DOWN? 2015 Q3 NIELSEN GLOBAL SURVEY OF CONSUMER CONFIDENCE AND SPENDING INTENTIONS

Transcription:

January, 1998 forthcoming in American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 88, May 1998, 444-48. Financial Crises in Asia and Latin America: Then and Now Graciela L. Kaminsky and Carmen M. Reinhart 1 The devaluation of the Thai Baht on July 2, 1997 set off waves of turbulence in currency and equity markets that surpassed the Tequila effects in the wake of the 1994 devaluation of the Mexican peso. The crisis first spread to East Asia, where the contagion, or Tom Yum effect, set off a string of devaluations and stock market collapses in neighboring countries. As the problems intensified, the currencies of other Asian countries, including Hong Kong and South Korea, came under speculative pressure. Outside the region, Argentina, Brazil, and Russia were among the economies to suffer sharp declines in their equity markets, and periodic bouts of speculation against their currencies. After the dust settles in currency markets, many of these countries will also be left with serious banking sector problems, if not full-scale banking crises, as in Thailand and South Korea. Our earlier work on financial crises suggested that the economy behaves differently on the eve of crises. Typically, financial crises occur when the economy enters a recession, following a prolonged boom in economic activity fueled by credit creation and surges in capital inflows. The cycles of overlending are exacerbated by implicit or explicit deposit guarantees, poor supervision, and moral hazard problems in the banking sector. 2 Crises are accompanied by an overvaluation of the currency, weakening exports, and a burst of asset price bubbles. 3 In this paper, we extend that work by analyzing the extent to which past crises share common characteristics as to their severity and antecedents in Latin America versus Asia, Europe, 1

and the Middle East. We examine the recent crises in Asia and in Latin America to determine whether the considerable regional differences that we find for the earlier sample are eroding in the 1990s. The paper proceeds as follows: Section II analyzes the regional historical differences in 76 currency crises and 26 banking crises in Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Denmark, Finland, Indonesia, Israel, Malaysia, Mexico, Norway, Peru, Phillippines, Spain, Sweden, Thailand, Turkey, Uruguay, and Venezuela in the period 1970 to 1995. Section III focuses on the recent crises; the last section summarizes our conclusions and discusses areas for future research. II. Regional Differences: History Between 1970 and 1995, Latin American (LA) countries suffered, on average, 50 percent more crises (per country) than the Asian (A), European and Middle Eastern (Others) countries in our sample. We next wish to assess whether the amplitude of the boom-bust cycle, the antecedents, and the severity of the financial crises differed systematically across regions. We begin by examining the behavior of fifteen economic indicators. The indicators used to capture the overlending cycles include: the M2 multiplier, the ratio of domestic credit to nominal GDP, the real interest rate on deposits, and the ratio of lending-to-deposit interest rates. Increases in any of these indicators could be signaling possible financial sector problems. 4 Other financial indicators include: excess real M1 balances, to capture lax monetary policy; deposits at commercial banks, to assess whether there are runs in the midst of the crises, and; the ratio of M2 (in dollars) to foreign exchange reserves (in dollars), to examine to what extent the liabilities of the banking system were backed by international reserves. The current account indicators are: exports, imports, terms-of-trade, and deviations of the real exchange rate from trend. Declines in exports and the terms of trade, increases in imports, and real appreciations of the domestic 2

currency signal potential problems in the current account. The capital account indicators are: foreign exchange reserves of the central bank and domestic-foreign real interest rate differentials. Reserves losses and increasing interest rate differentials would be considered as signals of future problems in the capital account. Finally, we include output and stock prices (in dollars) in our list of indicators, with declines in output and stock market crashes signaling impending crises. Unless otherwise noted, we work with 12-month percent changes in the indicators. In an earlier paper, we concluded that the behavior of most of these indicators in the months prior to the crises departed significantly from the behavior in tranquil times, which is defined as all the months in the sample with the exception of the 36 months around the crises. For instance, there were anomalously large declines in equity prices relative to tranquil periods on the eve of the financial crises. To assess whether these pre-crises deviations in individual indicators are larger in LA than in other regions, we measure volatility by calculating the mean absolute deviation from tranquil periods for each indicator in the 18 months prior to the crisis for the three regions separately. The first column in Table 1 lists the indicators; the second column reports the mean deviation from tranquil periods for that indicator for LA; the third and fourth columns report the comparable mean absolute deviations for Asia and Others, respectively. An asterisk denotes that the regional difference from LA, which is the benchmark, is statistically significant at the five percent confidence level. If we compare Asia and LA s currency crises (columns two and three) ten of the fifteen indicators are significantly more volatile for LA, including all the financial and capital account indicators. The regional patterns for banking crises paint a similar picture, as the amplitude of the pre-crises cycles relative to tranquil times is larger in for LA than for the other regions. However, such regional differences in volatility may be diminishing. For 3

instance, the decline in Thai equity prices (in US dollars) since their 1995 peak exceeds 80 percent; the magnitude of this deviation from the norm during tranquil periods is more in line with those observed in the LA crises than in previous Asian crises. Similar anomalies are evident in other indicators, such as credit. We next assess how frail economies are in the eve of crises. While Table 1 presented evidence on the volatility of individual indicators, we now focus on their behavior as a group. As to fragility, our basic premise is that the more widespread the economic problems are, the larger the number of indicators that exhibit anomalous behavior on the eve of a crisis. 5 Thus, to construct this measure of fragility, we need to tally crisis-by-crisis what proportion of the fifteen indicators were showing aberrant behavior in the 24 months preceding the financial crisis. This information is summarized for the three regions in Table 2. For instance, in the 24-month period prior to Venezuela s currency crisis in May 1994 ten of the fifteen (sixty seven percent) of the indicators were exhibiting anomalous behavior; this crisis gets counted in the second row of Table 2, labelled 60% to79%. If, instead, only five of the fifteen (thirty-three percent) of the indicators had shown aberrant behavior, this crisis would have been counted in the fourth row of Table 2 (labelled 20% to 39%) and Venezuela s economy would have been labelled as less frail. As to regional patterns, the top row of Table 2, which provides information on what percent of the crises in our sample were preceeded by at least 80 percent of the indicators behaving abnormally, shows that LA economies were more frail on the eve of crises than economies in other regions. In 44 percent of the currency crises in LA 80 to 100 percent of the indicators were indicating problems. Only in 28 percent of the Asian crises were preceeded by so many flashing red lights. A similar regional disparity is evident in the eve of past banking crises. 4

To measure the severity of a currency crisis we focus on a composite measure which adds the 6-month changes in reserves (with a negative weight) and the real exchange rate (with a positive weight, as an increase denotes a depreciation.) For reserves, we use the 6-month change prior to the crisis month, as reserve losses typically occur prior to the devaluation (if the attack is successful). For the real exchange rate, we use the 6-month percent change following the crisis month, since large depreciations typically occur after, and if, the central bank concedes and devalues or floats the currency. This measure of severity is constructed for each currency crisis in our sample and the regional averages are reported in Table 3. For banking crises, we use the bailout costs, as a percent of GDP, as the measure of severity; regional averages are also reported. The first row of Table 3 presents evidence of the historical patterns; it is clear that the LA financial crises were far more severe than those in Asia and elsewhere. The average severity index for currency crises is more than three times larger for LA than Asia; an even larger discrepancy is evident for the banking crises, where the average cost of the bailout is about seven times larger in LA than in Asia. The second row records the readings of this index for the recent crises, Argentina and Mexicoin 1994-1995 and the ongoing crises in Indonesia, Malaysia, Phillipines, and Thailand. The bail-out costs of the banking sector are estimated to range from a low of about 7 percent of GDP for the Philillippines to over 20 percent of GDP for Malaysia. The picture that emerges is quite distinct from the historical one. Both on the currency and banking side, the severity of the recent crises is at par with those recorded for LA in the past. To illustrate the severity of the Thai case, we note that by the mid-december the baht had depreciated by about 80 percent. The percent decline in reserves is of a similar magnitude, when the forward position is included. These components of our severity index highlight why this crisis 5

is comparable to the LA crises and not to past Asian crises. The 20 percent (to date) cost of the bailout of banks has already surpassed the cost of the Mexican bailout. 6 III. Are Regional Differences Eroding? We have argued that, historically, financial crises have been more frequent and severe in LA than in other regions. Yet we conclude that the severity of the recent crises in Asia matches LA s standards more closely than Asia s historical norm. In this section we provide some speculation as to why some of the regional differences may be eroding. As Table 4 highlights, the historically poor performance of LA, particularly vis-a vis East Asia (EA), is underscored by the persistence of high inflation and relatively low rates of GDP growth. When capital began to return to emerging market economies in the early 1990s, the combination of LA s poor economic and policy track record was often cited as the reason why a dominant share of the capital flowing to the region was of a short-term nature (Table 4). At that time, countries in EA were attracting substantial amounts of foreign direct investment (FDI) and a relatively low share of their capital inflows were short-term. However, during the 1990s a number of LA countries, implemented major inflation stabilization programs and growth in the region rebounded from its bleak performance during the 1980s. Despite the setbacks associated with the Mexican crisis of December 1994 and its Tequila effects, the pattern of lower inflation and higher growth has persisted in 1996 and 1997 (Table 4). Largely owing to improved economic prospects in LA, FDI began to account for a rising share of capital flows to the region. In several Asian countries, extensive and persistent bouts of sterilized intervention kept short-term interest rates high relative to international levels and acted as a magnet for short-term capital inflows. The evidence presented in Montiel and Reinhart (1997) suggests that these policies played a key role 6

in explaining the rising volume of short-term flows that countries like Malaysia and Thailand attracted (Table 4). By 1996, the large differences between EA and LA in the composition of capital flows had all but disappeared. These short-term flows were, in turn, largely intermediated by the poorly regulated and illsupervised domestic banking sectors. Indeed, the overlending cycles in Asia of the 1990s are reminiscent of the cycles that followed financial liberalization in many Latin American countries. The choice between tight money to defend the peg and ample liquidity and low interest rates to help troubled financial institutions is also reminiscent of Chile s currency and banking crises in the 1980s. In early 1997, bankrupt Thai finance companies were receiving loans from the central bank; on July 2, the Baht was allowed to float. Hence, the combination of volatile international capital and weaknesses in the financial sector appears to at the heart of the recent crises in EA, and and may go a long way in explaining their severity. IV. Concluding Remarks Historically, there were marked differences between the fierceness of financial crises in Asia and in LA. In the 1990s, LA made progress toward stabilization--although at the time of this writing LA remains vulnerable to contagion. At the same time, the severity of the 1997 Asian currency and banking crises has escalated to magnitudes not seen earlier in that region, and are comparable in to the LA financial crises of the past. It appears regional differences are eroding. What accounts for convergence is food for future research. However, on the basis of our analysis, one may speculate that some of the past differences in the volatility of the capital account and financial sector have diminished in the world of mobile capital and more deregulated financial markets. Regional differences in the composition of capital flows to the two regions eroded 7

throughout the 1990s, as an increasing volume of short-term capital was funneled into Asia. Also, the booms in lending and asset prices that characterized the Asian economies before the bubble burst in 1997 are reminiscent of the post-financial liberalization episodes in LA. It appears that, in a deregulated world, the well-behaved Asian financial crises are a relic of the past. 8

References Bhattacharya, A., S.Claessens, and L. Hernandez, Recent Financial Market Turbulence in Southeast Asia, Mimeo, The World Bank, October 1997. Edison, H.J., and M. Miller, The Hong Kong Handover: Hidden Pitfalls?, Mimeo, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, July 1997. Kaminsky, G.L., and C.M. Reinhart, The Twin Crises: the Causes of Banking and Balance of Payments Problems, Mimeo, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, August 1996. McKinnon, R., and H. Pill, Credible Liberalizations and International Capital Flows: the Overborrowing Syndrome, Mimeo, Standford University, 1994. Montiel, P., C.M. Reinhart, The Dynamics of Capital Movements to Emerging Economies During the 1990s, forthcoming in Short-term Capital Movements and Balance of Payments Crises, S. Griffith-Jones and M. Montes eds, Helsinki: UNU/WIDER, 1997. 9

Footnotes 1. Graciela L. Kaminsky is at the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington D.C. 20551 and Carmen M. Reinhart is at the University of Maryland, College Park, Maryland 20742. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the organizations with which they are affiliated. 2. See McKinnon and Pill (1996) on the interaction of capital inflows and liberalization. 3. See Kaminsky and Reinhart (1996). 4. See Edison and Miller (1997) on credit cycles. 5. For a detailed description of the methodology used to classify what is considered anomalous behavior in an indicator and what is not, see Kaminsky and Reinhart (1996). 6. See Battacharya, Claessens, and Hernandez (1997). 10

Table 1. Regional Differences, 1970-1995: Volatility Currency Crises Banking Crises Indicators Latin America Asia Others Latin America Asia Others M2 multiplier 28.1 8.0* 11.1* 18.1 5.3* 9.5 Domestic credit/gdp 21.4 12.6* 5.6* 13.3 5.7* 7.0 Real interest rate on deposits Ratio of lending-todeposit interest rate Excess real M1 balances 4.3 0.9* 0.8* 2.1 0.7* 0.7* 16.6 8.9* *9.7 13.9 10.4 10.1 450.2 20.0* 9.3* 227.7 22.8* 10.9* Bank deposits 321.4 6.9* 20.1* 350.2 7.3 20.8 M2/foreign exchange reserves 76.4 35.0* 22.3* 61.5 15.8* 24.0 Exports 28.4 24.9 17.4* 23.1 19.2* 31.1* Imports 35.9 27.4 21.9* 25.1 16.4* 16.9* Real exchange rate 36.1 38.2 11.6 32.8 26.1 11.5* Terms-of-trade 19.6 14.3 4.7* 16.4 12.4 4.6* Foreign exchange reserves Domestic-foreign real interest rate differential 71.7 42.5* 33.6* 53.6 19.2* 31.1* 4.3 0.9* 0.9* 2.2 0.7* 0.8* Output 10.4 8.9 6.1* 5.7 14.0 5.0 Stock prices 64.7 36.1* 30.6* 80.1 34.3* 60.3 1 Volatility is measured by the mean absolute deviation from tranquil periods for each indicator in the 18 months prior to the crisis. 11

Table 2. Regional Differences, 1970-1995: Fragility Proportion of currency crises with: Proportion of banking crises with: This percent of the indicators showing anomalous behavior preceeding the crisis. Latin America Asia Others Latin America Asia Others 80% to 100% 44 28 32 46 25 38 60% to 79% 39 42 39 46 75 25 40% to 59% 8 28 18 8 0 25 20% to 39% 8 0 11 0 0 12 less than 20% 0 0 0 0 0 0 12

Table 3: Regional Differences, Then and Now: Severity 1 Currency Crises Banking Crises Severity Index Latin America Asia Others Latin America Asia Others 1970 to 1995 48.1 14.0 9.0 21.6 2.8 7.3 1995 to 1997 2 25.4 40.0 n.a. 15.0 n.a. 1 See text for the measure of severity used. 2 As to the severity of the banking crises for the Asian group, we rely on estimates of the bail-out costs as of December 1997. 13

Table 4. East Asia and Latin America: Signs of Convergence? 1 1986-1995 1996 East Asia Latin America East Asia Latin America Inflation Rate 6.3 429.2 5.6 10.9 Real GDP Growth 7.0 3.3 7.1 4.9 FDI/Short-term and 77.2 42.2 61.8 110.5 Portfolio Flows 2 1 East Asia is comprised here of the four largest capital importers in the 1990s, Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, and Thailand. Similarly, Latin America comprises Argentina, Brazil, Chile and Mexico. 2 The composition of capital flows is for 1990-92, or the early wave of the capital inflow surge. 14