Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Similar documents
Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under arbitrage

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

Non-semimartingales in finance

Risk Neutral Measures

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

On Using Shadow Prices in Portfolio optimization with Transaction Costs

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Polynomial processes in stochastic portofolio theory

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY. 4 th World Congress Tokyo, Investments and forward utilities. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

The Self-financing Condition: Remembering the Limit Order Book

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Hedging of Credit Derivatives in Models with Totally Unexpected Default

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

The stochastic calculus

Optimization Models in Financial Mathematics

On the pricing equations in local / stochastic volatility models

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

SHORT-TERM RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN VOLATILITY-STABILIZED MARKETS

A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 6

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

LYAPUNOV FUNCTIONS AS PORTFOLIO-GENERATORS

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Multi-Asset Options. A Numerical Study VILHELM NIKLASSON FRIDA TIVEDAL. Master s thesis in Engineering Mathematics and Computational Science

Option Pricing Models for European Options

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Lecture Notes for Chapter 6. 1 Prototype model: a one-step binomial tree

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

Greek parameters of nonlinear Black-Scholes equation

Ross Recovery theorem and its extension

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Completeness and Hedging. Tomas Björk

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Path Dependent British Options

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Lévy models in finance

On Asymptotic Power Utility-Based Pricing and Hedging

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

Extended Libor Models and Their Calibration

Hedging of swaptions in a Lévy driven Heath-Jarrow-Morton framework

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

Multiple Defaults and Counterparty Risks by Density Approach

EFFICIENT MONTE CARLO ALGORITHM FOR PRICING BARRIER OPTIONS

Law of the Minimal Price

Optimal asset allocation under forward performance criteria Oberwolfach, February 2007

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Stochastic Integral Representation of One Stochastically Non-smooth Wiener Functional

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

The value of foresight

Martingales & Strict Local Martingales PDE & Probability Methods INRIA, Sophia-Antipolis

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

Pricing and hedging with rough-heston models

Basic Concepts in Mathematical Finance

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes

Portfolio optimization with transaction costs

Black-Scholes Model. Chapter Black-Scholes Model

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Brownian Motion and Ito s Lemma

Asymmetric information in trading against disorderly liquidation of a large position.

Quadratic hedging in affine stochastic volatility models

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Transcription:

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics The Third Western Conference in Mathematical Finance November 14, 2009

How should an investor trade and how much capital does she need? Imagine an investor who wants to hold the stock S i with price S i (0) of a company in a year. Surely, she could just buy the stock today for a price S i (0). This might not be an optimal strategy, even under a classical no-arbitrage situation ( no free lunch with vanishing risk ). There can be other strategies which require less initial capital than S i (0) but enable her to hold the stock after one year. But how much initial capital does she need at least and how should she trade?

Two examples where the stock price does not reflect the hedging price. Reciprocal of the three-dimensional Bessel process (NFLVR): d S(t) = S 2 (t)dw (t) Three-dimensional Bessel process: ds(t) = 1 dt + dw (t) S(t)

How can a portfolio optimally been hedged? Optimality in the sense of smallest initial capital. Solved by Fernholz D. & Karatzas I. for the market portfolio. Hedging price characterized via a PDE which can allow for non-unique solutions. Change of measure to simplify computations. In Markovian framework. No martingale representation theorem used.

We assume a Markovian market model. Our time is finite: T <. Interest rates are zero. The stocks S( ) = (S 1 ( ),..., S n ( )) T follow ( ) K ds i (t) =S i (t) β i (t, S(t))dt + σ i,k (t, S(t))dW k (t) k=1 with some measurability and integrability conditions. Markovian but not necessarily complete (K > n allowed). The covariance process is defined as K α i,j (t, S(t)) := σ i,k (t, S(t))σ j,k (t, S(t)) k=1

Two important guys: the market price of risk and its close relative, the stochastic discount factor. The market price of risk is the function ν satisfying P ({β = σν t [0; T ]} { T }) ν 2 dt < = 1. 0 The market price of risk is not necessarily unique. Related is the stochastic discount factor ( t Z ν (t) := exp ν T (u, S(u))dW (u) 1 2 with dynamics 0 t dz ν (t) = ν T (t, S(t))Z ν (t)dw (t) If Z ν is a strict local martingale, arbitrage is possible. 0 ) ν(u, S(u)) 2 du

Everything an investor cares about: how and how much? We focus on Markovian trading strategies π(t, S(t)). Which percentage of the total wealth is invested in the single stocks depends on time and current market situation. The corresponding wealth process V v,π follows dv v,π (t) V v,π (t) = n i=1 π i (t, S(t)) ds i(t) S i (t) and is usually not Markovian. We are ready to define the π-specific price of risk as ν π (t, s) := ν(t, s) σ T (t, s)π(t, s). Then d(v v,π (t)z ν (t)) V v,π (t)z ν (t) K = νk π (t, S(t))dW k(t). k=1

We explicitly allow for arbitrage. It can be shown that excluding arbitrage a priori leads to market models which cannot capture important properties of the real markets very well. (diversity, behavior of market weights) We call a strategy ρ with P(V ρ (T ) V π (T )) = 1 and P(V ρ (T ) > V π (T )) > 0 relative arbitrage opportunity with respect to the strategy π. We call ρ a classical arbitrage opportunity if π invests fully in the bond, that is, if π(t, s) 0 for all (t, s) [0; T ] R n +.

But we exclude some forms of arbitrage. Remember: We have assumed that there exists some ν which maps the volatility into the drift, that is σ(, )ν(, ) = β(, ). It can be shown that this assumption excludes unbounded profit with bounded risk. Thus making (a considerable) something out of almost nothing is not possible. However, it is still possible to certainly make something more out of something.

A new candidate for a hedging price is a risk-adjusted expectation. Let us define [ U π,ν (t, s) := E T t,s V π (T )Z ν ] (T ) V π (T t)z ν. (T t) U π,ν is non-random. Not clear at this point how U π,ν depends on market price of risk ν. We assume that U π,ν satisfies the PDE U π,ν (t, s) = 1 n n s i s j α i,j (T t, s)d 2 t 2 i,ju π,ν (t, s) + i=1 j=1 n i=1 j=1 n s i α i,j (T t, s)π j (T t, s)d i U π,ν (t, s).

Theorem: How does the optimal strategy look like? For any strategy π there here exists a new strategy π ν such that the corresponding wealth process V ˆv, πν with initial wealth ˆv := U π,ν (T, S 0 ) 1 has the same value as V π at time T, that is V ˆv, πν (T ) = V π (T ). π ν takes the form π i ν (t, s) = s i D i log U π,ν (T t, s) + π i (t, s) and is optimal: There exists no strategy ρ such that V ṽ,ρ (T ) V π (T ) = V ˆv, πν (T ) for some ṽ < ˆv.

The proof relies on Itô s formula. Define the martingale N π,ν as N π,ν (t) := E s [V π (T )Z ν (T ) F(t)] and compute its dynamics as dn π,ν (t) K ( N π,ν (t) = n D i U π,ν S i (t)σ i,k U π,ν k=1 i=1 ν π k ) dw k (t) + C π,ν dt, where C π,ν (t, s) disappears because of the assumption that U π,ν satisfies a PDE. But thus, dn π,ν (t) K N π,ν (t) = ν πν k (t, S(t))dW k(t), k=1 which are the dynamics of V ˆv, πν (t)z ν (t).

We can change the measure to compute U π,ν There exists not always an equivalent local martingale measure. However, after making some technical assumptions on the probability space and the filtration we can construct a new measure Q ν which corresponds to a removal of the stock price drift. Based on the work of Föllmer and Meyer and along the lines of Delbaen and Schachermayer.

Theorem: Under a new measure Q ν the drifts disappear. There exists a measure Q ν such that P Q ν. More precisely, for all nonnegative F(T )-measurable random variables Y we have ] E P [Z ν (T )Y ] = E [Y Qν 1 { } 1. Z ν (T ) >0 Under this measure Q ν, the stock price processes follow ds i (t) = S i (t) K σ i,k (t, S(t)) d W k (t) k=1 up to time τ ν := inf{t [0; T ] : 1/Z ν (t) = 0}. Here, t τ ν W k (t τ ν ) := W k (t τ ν ) + ν k (u, S(u))du 0 is a K-dimensional Q ν -Brownian motion stopped at time τ ν.

What happens in between time 0 and time T : Bayes rule. For all nonnegative F(T )-measurable random variables Y the representation [ E Qν Y 1{1/Z ν (T )>0} F(t) ] = E P [Z ν 1 (T )Y F(t)] Z ν (t) 1 {1/Z ν (t)>0} holds Q ν -almost surely (and thus P-almost surely) for all t [0; T ].

The class of Bessel processes with drift provides interesting arbitrage opportunities. We begin with defining an auxiliary stochastic process X as ( ) 1 dx (t) = X (t) c dt + dw (t) with W denoting a Brownian motion and c 0 a constant. X (t) is for all t 0 strictly positive since X is a Bessel process under an equivalent measure. The stock price process is now defined via ds(t) = 1 ( 1 dt + dw (t) = S(t) X (t) S 2 (t) S(t)ct dt + 1 ) dw (t) S(t) with S(0) = X (0) > 0.

After a change of measure, the Bessel process becomes Brownian motion. As a reminder: ds(t) = 1 dt + dw (t). S(t) ct We have S(t) X (t) > 0 for all t 0. The market price of risk is ν(t, s) = 1/(s ct). Thus, the inverse stochastic discount factor 1/Z ν becomes zero exactly when S(t) hits ct. Removing the drift with a change of measure as before makes S a Brownian motion (up to the first hitting time of zero by 1/Z ν ) under Q.

The optimal strategy for getting one dollar at time T can be explicitly computed. For π 1 (t, s) 0 we get ( ) ( s ct s ct + 2ct U π1 (T t, s) = Φ exp(2cs 2c 2 t)φ T t T t In the special case of c = 0 this yields the optimal strategy ( ) 2 s π 1 T t φ s T t (t, s) = ( ) > 0. 2Φ s T t 1 This strategy can also be represented as π 1 (t, s) = 1 s 2 E Qs [ 1 T 0 min 0 u T t ] W u > 0 where T 0 denotes the first hitting time of zero by W.

Conclusion No equivalent local martingale measure needed to find an optimal hedging strategy based upon the familiar delta hedge. Allows for bigger class of models which include more realistic stock price models. The dynamics of stochastic processes under a non-equivalent measure and a generalized Bayes rule might be of interest themselves. From an analytic point of view we have obtained results concerning non-uniqueness of a Cauchy problem. We have computed some optimal trading strategies in standard examples for which so far only ad-hoc and not necessarily optimal strategies have been known.

Thank you!