New Lists and Seasoned Firms: Fundamentals and Survival Rates. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "New Lists and Seasoned Firms: Fundamentals and Survival Rates. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract"

Transcription

1 First Draft: March 2001 Revised: July 2002 Not for quotation Comments solicited New Lists and Seasoned Firms: Fundamentals and Survival Rates Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract The class of firms eligible for public equity financing expands dramatically in the 1980s and 1990s. After 1979, the rate at which new firms are listed on major U.S. stock exchanges jumps from about 140 to near 600 per year. The characteristics of new lists also change. Cross-sections of profitability and growth become progressively more disperse, profitability becomes more left skewed, and growth becomes more right skewed. The result is a sharp decline in new list survival rates. The flood of new lists eventually causes similar but more subdued changes in the characteristics of seasoned firms, with a corresponding decline in survival rates. * Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago (Fama), and Tuck School of Business, Dartmouth College (French). We gratefully acknowledge the helpful comments of Frank Easterbrook, Owen Lamont, Kenneth Lehn, Jonathan Macey, Richard Roll, Hans Stoll, and seminar participants at UCLA. We thank Jay Ritter for giving us his list of initial public offerings.

2 The market for publicly traded equity is the heart of a modern capitalist system, signaling the terms on which investors are willing to bear residual corporate risks. The market for newly listed firms is in turn a bellwether for the public equity market. It is the point of entry that gives firms expanded access to equity capital, allowing them to emerge and grow. Examining the characteristics of newly listed firms can provide interesting information about changes through time in the kinds of firms that are viable candidates for public equity financing. The issue is important. In a perfect capital market (that is, absent monitoring costs and other frictions), investment is efficient: all wealth-creating projects are publicly financed, and their risks are efficiently shared among investors. But when frictions cause some profitable projects to be financed privately, or not undertaken at all, investment and risk sharing are inefficient relative to the zero-frictions optimum. If security prices are rational, evidence that the class of firms that are publicly financed broadens through time is evidence that demand conditions (the tastes of investors for different types of risk) or supply conditions (monitoring costs or other frictions) have changed. To the extent that the changes are due to supply conditions, the efficiency of investment and risk sharing improve. Fama and French (2001) document that the rate of new listings, largely on NASDAQ, explodes after 1979, from about 140 to near 600 per year. After 1979, on average about ten percent of listed firms are new each year. Our earlier paper examines the characteristics (profitability and growth) of new lists only in the listing year and not in much detail. Here we develop a detailed picture of the profitability and growth of the NYSE-AMEX-NASDAQ new lists of for the first five years after listing. And we examine how changes in the characteristics of new lists during the sample period affect whether they survive, disappear in mergers, or are delisted for poor performance. Our results about the evolving characteristics of firms that are viable candidates for public equity financing are easily summarized. The key words are dispersion and skewness. During , when new lists are abundant, the cross-section of new list profitability drifts down, and the drift is stronger in the left tail, that is, toward lower profitability. In contrast, the percentiles of new list growth drift up, and the drift is stronger in the right tail, toward more rapid growth. New lists eventually become seasoned

3 firms, and the profitability and growth of seasoned firms show subdued versions of the patterns observed for new lists; profitability and growth become progressively more disperse, profitability becomes more left skewed and growth becomes more right skewed. And we emphasize that although the process accelerates after 1994 (when high-tech and internet-related new lists are abundant), the increasing incidence of low-profitability high-growth firms is a long-term phenomenon, evolving slowly over the last 20 years. The drift in profitability and growth has a big effect on survival rates. The probability that a seasoned firm continues to trade beyond the next ten years falls from 59.5% for the cohort of 1973 to 44.3% for the 1991 cohort. The probability that a new list survives its first ten years falls further, from 64.4% for the 1973 cohort to 37.0% for the 1991 cohort. Rates of disappearance in mergers do not trend much during the sample period; on average, about one-third of the seasoned firms and one-fourth of the new lists of a given year are absorbed within ten years in mergers. The decline in survival rates is thus due to delistings for poor performance. The ten-year delist rate rises from 13.5% for the seasoned firms of 1973 to 21.7% for the 1991 cohort. The ten-year delist rate for new lists rises much further, from 14.4% for the 1973 cohort to 40.2% for the cohorts of Thus, about two in five of the new lists of are delisted within ten years for poor performance. For both new lists and seasoned firms, most of the changes in the cross-sections of profitability and growth during trace to small new lists. Since large firms account for the lion s share of most economic aggregates, one might argue that changes in the characteristics of small new lists are unimportant. The changes are, however, important for understanding the market for listed firms, that is, the kinds of firms that are viable candidates for public equity financing and thus unrestricted risk sharing. In essence, our results say that that changes in demand or supply conditions lead to increased sharing of the risks of firms with low profitability and high growth, a combination that produces a large dose of unhappy outcomes. Again, to the extent that this broadening of the kinds of firms publicly traded is due to supply conditions (reductions in the costs of trading and holding such firms), the efficiency of the economy s investment and risk sharing are enhanced as long as risks are properly priced. 2

4 Finally, our results are related to those of Campbell, Lettau, Malkiel, and Xu (2001). They find that the idiosyncratic dispersion of individual stock returns increases through time and the increase is largely due to small firms. Our results suggest that the source of the higher return dispersion is increased dispersion of profitability and growth, which largely traces to the post-1979 flood of small new lists. We begin (section I) by detailing the rate of new listings during Section II examines the average profitability and growth of new lists and seasoned firms. The central evidence on the evolution of the cross-sections of profitability and growth is in section III. Section IV examines survival rates, and section V studies the links between survival rates and the profitability and growth of new lists and seasoned firms. Section VI concludes and offers some perspective on whether the expansion of the class of publicly traded firms during is due to changes in demand or supply conditions. I. New Lists: Counts and Size Figure 1 shows annual counts of combined NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ new lists for To be in the sample, a firm must be on the files of the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) and have a share code of 10 or 11 (ordinary common shares), so ADRs and closed end mutual funds are excluded. We define a new list as the first appearance of a firm on CRSP. Thus, our new lists do not include firms that switch from one of the three exchanges to another. We also exclude tracking stocks, spin-offs, and firms that go public after going private. The tests start in 1973, the beginning of the CRSP NASDAQ period. Prior to 1973, newly public firms typically trade over the counter (OTC, not covered by CRSP), and new listings on the NYSE and AMEX (covered by CRSP) are mostly seasoned firms. NASDAQ absorbs most of the OTC market, and for the post-1972 period, the CRSP files provide a rather complete picture of publicly traded firms. We examine two types of new lists: initial public offerings (IPOs) and non-ipos. A firm is defined as an IPO if it is in the IPO sample provided by Jay Ritter (an updated version of that in Loughran and Ritter (1995)) and its CRSP listing month is no more than ten months after its IPO. Non-IPO new lists include (i) a small set of firms that are in the Ritter IPO sample but are listed on one of the three 3

5 exchanges more than ten months after their IPO, and (ii) a larger set of new lists not in the Ritter IPO sample. The latter are primarily (i) tiny firms that trade OTC (pink sheets) and do not make it to one of the three exchanges soon after their IPO, and (ii) some financial firms that are missing from the Ritter IPO sample but would qualify as IPOs under the ten-month rule. Since our main focus is the economic fundamentals of non-financial firms, we do not attempt to more accurately allocate financial new lists between IPOs and non-ipos. One can argue that, to study the kinds of firms that are viable candidates for public equity financing, the ideal sample is all IPOs. Our IPOs include only those listed quickly on one of the three exchanges (primarily NASDAQ). We miss IPOs that initially trade OTC. Many of these eventually appear in the sample of non-ipo new lists, and this is why we use IPOs and non-ipo new lists to make inferences about the characteristics of new publicly traded firms. There is, however, a survivor bias in this approach; (financials aside) non-ipo new lists include only those initially unlisted IPOs that are relatively successful and so eventually make it to one of the three exchanges. It is thus likely that our inferences about the kinds of firms that qualify for public equity financing are conservative. There is a more aggressive justification for our approach. One can argue that during , IPOs not traded on the NYSE, AMEX, or NASDAQ are typically illiquid and so do not get the benefits of unrestricted risk-sharing. In this view, during , an exchange listing is the better signal that a firm qualifies for unrestricted risk sharing. Thus, examining new lists (IPOs and non-ipo) is a sound approach. Moreover, changes in the characteristics of new lists related to changes in listing requirements are not a problem if the exchanges compete for listings. Competition implies that listing requirements are themselves the result of demand conditions (the tastes of investors for different types of risks) and supply conditions (monitoring costs, information costs, and other frictions) that determine the types of firms that qualify for unrestricted risk sharing. Two facts are apparent in Figure 1. First, after moderate increases from 1973 to 1979, new lists surge from 220 in 1979 to 438 in 1980 and 620 in After 1979, only four years have less than 400 new lists. For , new lists average 598 per year (Table 1). There are not many IPOs in the 4

6 period (on average 30 per year); most new lists are non-ipos (119 per year). But during , IPOs are more numerous than non-ipo new lists, averaging 372 per year, versus 226 for non-ipo new lists. We can also report that more than 90% of the new lists of are on NASDAQ. Table 1 summarizes the size of annual new lists. We measure size as market capitalization, ME, stock price times shares outstanding. The table shows the averages of the yearly average NYSE ME percentile of new lists and the average local (listing) exchange ME percentile. When compared to firms on their respective exchanges (NYSE, AMEX, or NASDAQ), new lists are on average medium sized. For the average local exchange ME percentile of all new lists, 50.3, is just a bit above the local exchange median. There is only one year, 1976, when the average local exchange ME percentile of all new lists is below 40. IPOs are on average larger than non-ipo new lists. For the average local exchange ME percentile of IPOs is 57.9, versus 43.1 for non-ipo new lists. But in absolute terms new lists are typically tiny. The average NYSE ME percentile of the new lists of is 12.1 (Table 1). IPOs are on average at the 15.1 NYSE ME percentile, versus 8.5 for non-ipo new lists. The surge in new lists after 1979 is not associated with a decline in size. The average NYSE and local exchange ME percentiles of new lists (IPOs and non-ipos) increase from to (Table 1). More important, during there is a progressive thinning of the extreme left tails of the size distributions of new lists (IPOs and non-ipo). For example, the proportion of new lists below the 20 th NYSE ME percentile falls from 85.3% for to 70.1% for (Table 1) and the proportion below the 10 th percentile falls from 75.2% to 50.0%. Thus, the evolution of new list fundamentals documented below (increasing left skewness of profitability and right skewness of growth) is not due to higher frequencies of the tiniest firms. This point is important when we later (in the concluding section) discuss whether the broadening in the types of firms publicly traded during is due to demand or supply conditions. Finally, with the high rate of new listings for , on average around ten percent of listed firms are new each year (Table 1). New lists are mostly small, however, and despite the explosion in their 5

7 numbers, the fraction of the aggregate market value of listed firms accounted for by annual new lists is also small, averaging 2.08% for and never exceeding 4.1%. II. Average Profitability and Growth Table 2 summarizes the evolution of fundamentals (average profitability and growth rates) for the non-financial new lists of for the first five years firms are listed. The fundamentals are also shown for matched cohorts of seasoned non-financial firms. Seasoned firms are defined as NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ firms listed more than five years, and firms already on NASDAQ at the end of the CRSP startup period (April 1973). Fundamentals for all firms (not shown) are similar to those of seasoned firms. The samples in Table 2 are smaller than in Table 1 because financial firms are excluded from Table 2 and because the fundamentals are sometimes missing from the Compustat data source. The fundamental variables in Table 2 are ratios of aggregates. For example, the profitability in year t+τ of the new lists of year t, E t+τ /A t+τ, is the ratio of aggregate earnings before interest for t+τ of the new lists of year t divided by their aggregate t+τ assets. In effect, then, we measure fundamentals as if the new lists of year t are a single firm. Equivalently, ratios of aggregates are size-weighted averages of the ratios for individual firms. For example, the estimate of new list profitability weights the profitability of an individual year t new list by the ratio of its t+τ assets to the total t+τ assets of all year t new lists. Size-weighted averages give more weight to larger firms and so might not provide a picture of fundamentals for the typical firm. But Table 2 is just an introduction to salient characteristics of fundamentals for new lists and seasoned firms. We later examine time-series of cross-sections of profitability and growth, which are the core of our story. Finally, our estimates of fundamentals for t+τ can cover only the firms of year t with Compustat data for t+τ. Firms that disappear before t+τ are not covered in the estimates. 6

8 A. Growth New lists grow faster than seasoned firms. The growth rate of total assets, da/a = (A t -A t-1 )/A t-1, for the seasoned firms of averages 10.1% per year. The average first-year growth of IPOs is 78.7%, declining rapidly to 20.0% in the fifth listed year. The average first-year growth of non-ipo new lists is 19.9%, with no systematic tendency in subsequent years. Thus, IPOs initially grow faster but eventually converge on the growth rates of non-ipo new lists, which in turn grow about twice as fast as seasoned firms. These results suggest that non-ipo new lists come into the sample while still in a high growth phase but after the period of extreme initial growth typical of IPOs. B. Profitability In the listing year, IPOs are on average more profitable than non-ipo new lists. This is true for the full sample period and all subperiods in Table 2. For the full sample period, IPO profitability declines in the years after listing, but E/A rises for non-ipo new lists. As a result, the two groups have similar average profitability after the second listed year. Thus, as they age, the profitability and growth of IPOs come to look more like those of non-ipo new lists. More interesting, for the full period, IPOs are on average more profitable in the listing year than seasoned firms. But after the listing year, IPO profitability falls and they become progressively less profitable than seasoned firms. Figures 2a to 2c give year-by-year details on the average profitability of new lists and seasoned firms in the first, third, and fifth listed years. The year on the horizontal axis is always the listing year. For example, plotted at 1973 in Figures 2a to 2c are the 1973, 1975, and 1977 average profitability of the new lists of 1973 and the seasoned firms of The figures thus compare the evolution of average profitability for cohorts of new lists and seasoned firms. The average profitability of new lists in Figures 2a to 2c varies much more across cohorts than the average profitability of seasoned firms. Despite this high volatility, there are clear patterns in the relation between new list profitability and that of seasoned firms. The first-year average profitability of IPOs (in Figure 2a) is higher than the profitability of seasoned firms in all but two of the first 22 years, 7

9 from 1973 to In contrast, the first-year profitability of non-ipo new lists tends to be below that of both IPOs and seasoned firms throughout the sample period. After 1994 the first-year profitability of new lists (IPOs and non-ipos) falls progressively further below that of seasoned firms. The first-year profitability of IPOs goes negative in 1999, for the first time in the sample period. The first-year profitability of non-ipo new lists is negative in 2000, but the highly volatile first-year profitability of these firms is also negative in three earlier years. The decline in IPO profitability in the years after listing is evident in Figures 2b and 2c. In contrast to the higher listing year average profitability of IPOs in the years up to 1994, IPO average profitability in the third and fifth listed years tends to be below that of seasoned firms for cohorts after 1980 or perhaps And after the listing year, IPOs are not systematically more or less profitable than non-ipo new lists. In short, for at least the last 20 years of the sample period, new lists (IPOs and non- IPOs) are on average less profitable after their second listed year than seasoned firms. C. The Small-Firm Depression Fama and French (1995) document a sustained decline in the profitability of small firms relative to big firms in the 1980s. Figure 3 confirms that small firms (total assets below the NYSE median) are more profitable than big firms until Thereafter, small firms are less profitable than big firms. After narrowing in , the gap between big and small firm profitability widens dramatically. In 2000, average E/A is 6.4% for big firms and only 0.7% for small firms. Since new lists are mostly small, it is interesting to examine whether the relatively low profitability of small firms during the 1980s and 1990s is related to the flood of small new lists and the low profitability of new lists as they age. 1 Figure 3 confirms that much of the small-firm depression of the 1990s is due to new lists. Until 1990, the profitability of small new lists (defined as firms listed within the last five years with total assets below the NYSE median) is similar to the profitability of small seasoned firms. Thereafter, small 1 When we examine fundamentals (profitability and growth rates), we define size in terms of assets, not market equity. Defining size in terms of market equity tends to allocate firms that are large in terms of assets but have low profitability to the small group. As a result, small market equity firms tend to look more like weak firms than when size is defined in terms of assets. 8

10 seasoned firms are only a bit less profitable than big firms, but small new lists are much less profitable. In 2000, for example, average E/A is 6.4% for big firms and 5.5% for small seasoned firms, but it is a miserable -8.8% for small new lists. (And keep in mind that we can measure profitability only for firms that survive.) Skipping the details, the gap between the profitability of big firms and seasoned small firms narrows further if we restrict seasoned firms to those listed for at least ten years. In fact, with this tighter definition, seasoned small firms are actually more profitable than big firms in 1992, 1993, and It is clear that, with their sustained low profitability, the flood of small new lists in the 1980s and 1990s plays a substantial role in the sustained low profitability of all small firms. Finally, Jain and Kini (1994) examine the profitability of the IPOs of They find that when firms go public, median IPO profitability is higher than the median profitability of firms in the same industry. After the IPO, median profitability falls toward that of the industry-matched sample, and the median investment of IPO firms is higher than for the industry-matched sample. Mikkelson, Partch, and Shah (1997) report similar results for the IPOs of 1980 to This earlier IPO evidence is roughly similar to our results for the IPOs of the late 1970s and early 1980s, but it does not describe IPO performance later in our sample. In the 1990s, post-listing IPO profitability deteriorates to levels far below that of seasoned firms. And after 1994, even the first-year profitability of IPOs is lower than the profitability of seasoned firms. We also show that the new lists of that are not recent IPOs look much like aging IPOs; that is, they are less profitable but grow faster than seasoned firms. III. Cross-Sections of Profitability and Growth The average profitability and growth of new lists are not necessarily surprising, at least prior to the profitability plunge after Thus, it is not surprising that firms have initial public offerings when profitability is high and they have strong demand for equity capital to finance rapid growth. And if initial profitability is unusually high, it is not surprising that it falls in the years after listing, as growth causes firms to deplete their most profitable investment options. The interesting surprises, and the core of our 9

11 story, are in the changes through time in the dispersion and skewness of profitability and growth for new lists and seasoned firms. A. Profitability Figure 4a shows time series of the cross-sections (10 th, 25 th, 50 th, 75 th, and 90 th percentiles) of first-year profitability, E/A, for new lists. Until 1978, the 10 th to 90 th percentiles of new list profitability cover a rather narrow range (relative to subsequent years) and unprofitable firms are rare. Thereafter, all percentiles of new list profitability fall. For example, median first-year E/A for the new lists of 1978 is 0.115; it declines to in 1990 and in 1998, and then drops below 0.0 in 1999 and Thus, more than half of the new lists of 1999 and 2000 are unprofitable in their listing year. But the dominant trait of Figure 4a is the increasing dispersion in first-year profitability, due to increasing left skewness. The 25 th percentile of E/A falls from in 1978 to in 1990 and in The decline in the 10 th percentile is even more extreme, from in 1978 to in 1990 and in In short, during , when new lists are consistently abundant, firms with low indeed severely negative current profitability become progressively more acceptable candidates for public equity financing. Figure 4b shows annual cross-sections of profitability for firms listed in the previous five years. Cumulating over five years provides longer-term perspective on the performance of new lists. Though smoother, the percentiles of E/A for new lists of the previous five years are similar to those of first-year E/A. Thus, the increasing dispersion and left skewness of new list profitability are not just a listing-year phenomenon. Skipping the details, we can also report that increasing dispersion and left skewness are common to the evolution of profitability for both IPO and non-ipo new lists. Typically, more than 95% of new lists are small (assets below the NYSE median), so small firms dominate the distributions of profitability in Figures 4a and 4b. (Indeed, since they are so similar to Figures 4a and 4b, we do not include plots for small new lists.) Figure 4c shows that big new lists do not share the extreme profitability traits of their small counterparts. Though the percentiles of E/A for big 10

12 new lists of the previous five years decline a bit through time, the cross-sections are rather compact and do not show the strong left skewness that characterizes the distributions for all new lists. Averaging over , about ten percent of listed firms are new each year. How does this flood of new lists affect the cross-sections of profitability for seasoned firms and all listed firms? After they have been listed for five years, we reclassify new lists as seasoned. The cross-sections of profitability for all seasoned firms in Figure 5a become progressively left skewed during , but less so than for new lists. This is not surprising. Economic logic along with the evidence below on the low survival rates of new lists says that firms cannot sustain large losses indefinitely. As in the case of new lists, the profitability cross-sections for all seasoned firms are dominated by small firms. Figure 5b shows that the dispersion of profitability for big seasoned firms increases only a bit through time, and the distribution remains relatively compact and roughly symmetric. The median profitability of seasoned big firms is stable, in 1973 and in 2000, but the most profitable seasoned big firms become a bit more profitable, and the least profitable become a bit less profitable. The cross-sections of profitability for seasoned firms listed at least ten years (Figure 5c) show that much of the increasing left skewness of profitability observed in Figure 5a (seasoned firms listed at least five years) is driven by unprofitable new lists. Tightening the definition of seasoned firms reducing the impact of aging new lists has little effect on the right tail of the distribution; there is little difference between the 75 th and 90 th percentiles in Figures 5a and 5c. Tightening the definition does, however, dampen the distribution s left skewness. For example, the 10 th percentile of E/A for firms listed more than five years (Figure 5a) falls from 3.5% in 1978 to -11.4% in 1990 and -17.9% in The 10 th percentile for firms listed more than ten years (Figure 5c) falls only about half as much, from 3.6% in 1978 to -5.2% in 1990 and -9.1% in Figure 6 shows how new lists and seasoned firms combine to produce the cross-sections of profitability for all listed firms. From 1980 to 2000, the distribution of profitability for all listed firms drifts down and becomes increasingly skewed left, more so than for seasoned firms but less strongly than for new lists. This is not surprising, given the evidence on the evolution of profitability for new lists and 11

13 seasoned firms. Our point is that the mostly small new lists of play an important role in the evolution of the cross-section of profitability for all listed firms (the population of firms that get the benefits of unrestricted risk sharing) both because new lists are so numerous and because aging new lists are influential in the evolution of profitability for seasoned firms. B. Growth Rates There are also substantial changes in the growth characteristics of listed firms during the period of abundant new lists. Like profitability, the distribution of growth for all listed firms (Figure 7a) becomes more disperse. While profitability becomes more left skewed, growth becomes more right skewed. Median growth does not change much during , fluctuating around 10% per year (close to the size-weighted average growth of seasoned firms in Table 2). But firms with shrinking assets become more common. In 1973 about 10% of listed firms decrease in size from one year to the next; after 1981, typically more than 25% shrink from one year to the next. Increasing right skewness is, however, the obvious feature of the cross-section of growth rates. The 75 th percentile of da/a rises from 24.3% in 1973 to 42.3% in 2000; the 90 th percentile rises from 43.6% to 184.2%. Figure 7b shows that the increasing right skewness of asset growth for all listed firms is much subdued in the cross-section of seasoned firms (listed more than five years). Thus, the more extreme skewness observed for all listed firms is due to new lists. Indeed, to accommodate the increasing right skewness of da/a for new lists of the previous five years, the upper end of the scale in Figure 7c must be stretched to 6.0 (600 percent per year), versus 2.2 for all listed firms in Figure 7a. Figures 8a and 8b show that the cross-sections of da/a for IPO and non-ipo new lists are skewed to the right, but the asymmetry is more extreme for IPOs. And the right skewness of da/a observed for new lists of the previous five years (in Figures 8a and 8b) is dwarfed by the skewness of growth rates in the first listed year (in Figures 9a and 9b), especially for IPOs. One quarter of the IPOs in 1999 have one-year asset growth rates that exceed 1100 percent, and ten percent of the growth rates 12

14 exceed 3000 percent. The 75 th and 90 th percentiles of one-year asset growth rates for IPOs in 2000, 682 percent and 1375 percent, are smaller, but still extraordinary. Perhaps the extreme initial growth of IPOs is not surprising. Many firms go public because they are in a high growth phase and have strong demands for external equity financing. Toward the end of the sample period, many firms (especially internet related firms) go public early in their life cycles, when they have few tangible assets. Enormous asset growth in percentage terms is not surprising from a base close to zero. But Figures 8a and 8b show that strong right skewness characterizes cross-sections of new list (IPO and non-ipo) growth rates for the first five listed years. And the increasing right skewness occurs while there are fewer and fewer new lists in the extreme left tail of the size distribution (Table 1). Moreover, Figure 8c shows that many big new lists, with assets above the NYSE median, experience extreme growth toward the end of our sample. Each year from 1995 to 2000, one quarter of the big new lists of the last five years have annual asset growth rates above 65% and ten percent have growth rates above 145%. In 2000, the 10 th percentile for big firms listed in the last five years is 814%. Though right skewness is the dominant characteristic of new list growth, there is also interesting action in the left tail of the distribution. The 10 th percentile of first-year da/a for IPOs is always positive (Figure 9a); few IPOs shrink in their first listed year. And for IPOs, all percentiles of first-year da/a increase in the 1980s and 1990s; stronger first-year growth is a general characteristic of the IPOs of later years. In contrast, though difficult to see because of the extreme scale of the graphs, after 1981 about 25% of non-ipo new lists have shrinking assets even in the listing year (Figure 9b). Moreover, after 1981 about 25% of the IPOs of the previous five years have shrinking assets (Figure 8a). And if anything, the median and lower percentiles of asset growth for new lists (IPOs and non-ipos) of the previous five years decline after 1981 (Figures 8a and 8b). These results suggest that the increasingly low and left skewed post-listing profitability of the new lists of the last 20 years eventually produces a substantial fraction of new lists that begin to shrink soon after listing. In sum, during , more and more new firms with high growth and low profitability become viable candidates for unrestricted risk sharing via publicly held equity. Because these new firms 13

15 are plentiful, their characteristics eventually dominate the characteristics of listed firms (the population of firms that get the benefits of unrestricted risk sharing). But new lists are mostly small, and the changes they induce in the characteristics of listed firms are largely special to small firms. Profitability and growth also become more disperse for large firms, large-firm growth becomes somewhat right skewed, but large-firm profitability does not become noticeably left skewed. In general, the changes in growth and profitability for large firms are dwarfed by those for small firms, especially small new lists. And with the flood of new lists after 1979, more and more small seasoned firms are aging new lists with continuing high growth and low profitability. In the end, then, the central role in the changing characteristics of listed firms falls to new lists, especially small new lists. IV. Survival Rates Some of the changes in profitability discussed above may be a spurious result of accounting rules. For example, the high profitability of the early sample years may be due in part to the high inflation of the 1970s and early 1980s, which causes profitability to be overstated because earnings grow with inflation but assets are measured at historical cost. Another common story is that profitability is understated later in the sample period because firms invest more in intangible assets like R&D and human capital, which are expensed rather than depreciated over time. We doubt that vagaries of accounting can explain the major changes in profitability we observe the increasing left skewness of E/A for small firms and especially small new lists, which is not shared by big firms. In any case, there is a simple test. If the increasing skewness of profitability is a matter of accounting rules, it should not be associated with changes in survival rates. But if the left skewness of profitability is real, survival rates, especially for small firms and small new lists, are likely to decline through time. Table 3 summarizes average survival rates, specifically, percents of firms still trading after ten years and percents lost within ten years in mergers or through delisting for poor performance. Year-byyear details are in Figures 10 and 11. Survival rates indeed decline through time. For seasoned firms, the ten-year survival rate falls about 15 percentage points, from 59.5% for the 1973 cohort to 44.3% for the 14

16 cohort of 1991 (Figure 10a). Survival rates for new lists are close to those of seasoned firms early in the sample period, but new list survival rates fall more through time. The ten-year new list survival rate falls more than 25 percentage points, from 64.4% for the new lists of 1973 to 37.0% for the 1991 cohort (Figure 10a). Though there are no clear trends after 1981, survival rates fall more after 1973 for non-ipo new lists than for IPOs. The ten-year survival rate for IPOs falls from 56.7% for the cohort of 1973 (Figure 10b) to an average of 39.7% for the cohorts (Table 3). The decline for non-ipo new lists is from 68.7% to 30.6%. Thus, for (when new lists are plentiful and their profitability declines, becomes more disperse, and more left skewed), only about 40% of IPOs and 31% of non-ipo new lists survive more than ten years. Firms disappear from CRSP in mergers or because poor performance causes them to be delisted. Merger targets include strong and weak firms, so takeovers are ambiguous signals about performance. There is, however, no ambiguity about the poor health of firms delisted for cause. And, in line with the profitability evidence, new lists are more likely to be delisted for poor performance than seasoned firms. Figure 11a shows that the rate at which seasoned firms are delisted for poor performance increases through time; 13.5% of the seasoned firms of 1973 are delisted within ten years (Figure 11a), and the average ten-year drop rate rises to 18.4% for the seasoned cohorts of (Table 3). The drop rates for new lists, which are always above those for seasoned firms, rise sharply from 1973 to roughly Thereafter, the new list drop rates are too variable to identify a clear trend. The ten-year drop rate for the new lists of 1973, 14.4%, is a bit higher than for seasoned firms, but the average for the cohorts of is about twice as high, 40.2%. Thus, about one in five of the seasoned firms of is dropped within ten years for poor performance, versus two in five new lists. The 1973 IPOs and non-ipo new lists (Figure 11b) have similar ten-year drop rates, 13.3% and 15.0%, but the rate for non-ipo new lists rises more thereafter, averaging 47.5% for cohorts, versus 33.5% for IPOs 15

17 (Table 3). Thus, almost half of the non-ipo new lists of are dropped for poor performance within ten years of listing, versus (a still impressive) one-third of IPOs. 2 The profitability of big seasoned firms becomes only a bit more disperse during the 1980s and 1990s, and it does not show the left skewness observed for small seasoned firms (Figure 5b). Not surprisingly, then, the (always low) ten-year drop rate for big seasoned firms rises only slightly, from 1.7% for the cohorts of to 2.1% for (Table 3). The profitability of big new lists (Figure 4c) is more disperse than that of big seasoned firms but much less disperse and left skewed than that of all new lists (Figure 4a) and, by implication, small new lists. Thus, it is also not surprising that ten-year drop rates for big new lists, which average 7.1% for and 6.7% for , are higher than the rates for big seasoned firms but much lower than for small new lists. Mergers are the main exit route for big firms; 27.4% of the cohorts of big seasoned firms and 36.4% of big new lists are absorbed within ten years in mergers. In sum, the evidence on performance delistings conforms nicely with the profitability results. Specifically, with the surge in new lists after 1979, the cross-section of profitability for listed firms drifts down and becomes progressively more left skewed. These changes in profitability are mostly due to small firms and they are stronger for new lists than for seasoned firms. Likewise, performance delistings increase after 1979, the increase is primarily due to small firms, and it is larger for new lists than for seasoned firms. V. Profitability for Outcome Groups of New Lists The analysis above presumes that firms delisted for poor performance are from the fattening left tail of the cross-section of profitability. Table 4 provides evidence. The table shows the average profitability and growth of new lists and seasoned firms for one, three, and five years before each of the possible outcomes, survival, merger, or performance delisting. For example, current average profitability 2 Some readers have asked how new lists fare in the difficult markets of 2000 and The one-year delist rate for the cohort of 2000, 3.0%, and the two-year rate for the 1999 cohort, 9.2%, are not extraordinary. They are lower, for example, than five of the ten one-year rates and eight of the two-year rates for the cohorts of

18 is shown for portfolios of firms listed within the previous five years that delist for cause within the next one, three, and five years. Three merger portfolios are defined in the same way. And there are three complement portfolios that include new lists of the previous five years that survive at least through the next one, three, and five years. Table 4 also shows average profitability for seasoned firms (listed at least five years) that merge within, delist within, or survive beyond the next one to five years. The general decline in profitability from to hits different groups of firms at different times and to different extents. In the 1970s and 1980s, survival implies strong average profits for seasoned firms. IPO survivors are even more profitable and grow about three times faster than seasoned survivors. Seasoned survivors share the general decline in profitability from to , but the decline is stronger for IPO survivors. In the 1990s, when E/A averages 6.1% to 6.3% for seasoned survivors, it is 6.0% for IPOs that survive beyond the next five years, and only 4.6% for those that survive beyond one year. The decline in profitability shows up earlier among non-ipo new lists that survive. For , the average profitability of non-ipo new list survivors is similar to that of seasoned survivors. By the 1980s (and in 1990s), the average profitability of non-ipo new list survivors while still respectable is 1.5% to 2.0% lower than for seasoned survivors. Overall, however, survivors among new lists and seasoned firms tend to be profitable with strong growth, which is not surprising. Survivors are, however, declining proportions of all seasoned firms and new lists. The evidence on the profitability and growth of firms lost in mergers is more interesting and novel. Merger rates do not trend much during the sample period. During , on average about one in three seasoned firms and one in four new lists are absorbed in mergers within ten years (Table 3). But the characteristics of merged firms change. The seasoned firms of lost in mergers are about as profitable and grow nearly as fast as seasoned survivors (Table 4). But in the 1980s and 1990s, the average profitability and growth of merged seasoned firms fall relative to seasoned survivors. Thus, through time the merger arrow is aimed more at mediocre seasoned firms. (This is a likely explanation for the low pre-announcement stock returns of merged firms (Mitchell and Stafford (2000)).) 17

19 The picture for IPOs lost in mergers is a bit different. In the 1980s and 1990s, their average profitability and growth for years far in advance of merger are high, like those of IPOs that survive. Average profitability deteriorates as merger approaches, but growth remains strong. These results suggest that merged IPOs tend to be firms that continue to grow despite poor returns on investment. Non-IPO new lists lost in mergers also experience declining profitability in the years preceding merger. As expected, the biggest effects of the downward drift and increasing left skewness of profitability after 1979 show up in the expanding set of firms delisted for poor performance. They have terrible earnings for five years before delisting, and profitability deteriorates as delisting approaches (Table 4). New lists (IPOs and non-ipo) delisted for poor performance are less profitable than delisted seasoned firms. Consistent with the increasing left skewness of profitability, the poor profitability of delisted firms (seasoned and new lists) becomes more extreme from to And the delisted firms of have negative and declining profitability for five years before delisting. The average growth of firms delisted for poor performance is interesting. Delisted seasoned firms have low growth in the years preceding delisting and shrinking assets in the delisting year (Table 4). More surprising, but in line with the results for merged new lists, the new lists of delisted for poor performance on average grow strongly in the years preceding delisting, despite typically negative profitability; they do not begin to shrink until the delisting year (if then). Thus, the high delist rates of new lists tend to be the result of growth un-rewarded by earnings. These results suggest that new lists delisted for poor performance tend to be firms that (at least on an ex post basis) have wasted resources on unprofitable investments. And the suggestion is stronger than for merged new lists. VI. Conclusions After 1979, the rate at which new firms are listed on the major U.S. stock exchanges jumps from about 140 to near 600 per year. The profile of new lists also changes. Profitability and growth become progressively more disperse, profitability becomes more left skewed, and growth becomes more right skewed. The result is a sharp decline in new list survival rates due to delistings for poor performance. 18

20 The flood of new lists with low long-term profitability and high growth eventually causes seasoned firms to acquire subdued versions of the profitability and growth characteristics of new lists, with a corresponding decline in survival rates. The dramatic changes in the profitability and growth characteristics of listed firms during are largely due to small firms. The changes are nevertheless important for understanding the market for listed firms, in particular, the kind of firms that are viable candidates for public equity financing. Our results say that changes in demand or supply conditions lead to increased sharing of the risks of firms with high growth and low profitability, a combination that produces a large dose of unhappy eventual outcomes. And these changes occur slowly over the post-1979 period. They are not special to the hightech and internet-related new lists of last few years. The broadening of the kinds of firms publicly traded during may be due to changes in supply conditions, such as lower monitoring costs and reductions in other costs of holding and trading small, relatively unprofitable, but rapidly growing firms. If changes in supply conditions are responsible, and if new firms are properly priced, expanding the set of firms eligible for public trading enhances the efficiency of the economy s aggregate investment and risk sharing. There is, of course, controversy on the pricing issue. Behavioralists, like Ritter (1991) and Loughran and Ritter (1995), argue that IPOs are overpriced and yield abnormally low post-listing returns; in effect, there is too much investment in IPOs and their activities. Others, like Fama (1998) and Brav, Geczy, and Gompers (2000), argue that the way returns are risk-adjusted has a big effect on inferences about IPO pricing, rendering all inferences shaky. In a provocative recent paper, Schultz (2002) argues that because IPOs bunch in periods following high returns, the average return on the typical IPO is likely to appear low, even if IPOs are properly priced. Suffice it to say that the pricing issue remains open. Is the broadening of the types of publicly traded firms during due to demand or supply conditions? This is a big question, and we only offer some possibilities. There are many changes in corporate governance in the 1980s and 1990s, perhaps including improvements in monitoring technology. The breakdown of fixed commissions and the introduction of NASDAQ and its automated quotation 19

21 system reduce the costs of trading and so increase the liquidity of traded firms. General increases in liquidity and the efficiency of monitoring (supply conditions) are likely to expand the class of firms that are viable candidates for public equity financing. There is, however, reason to judge that changes in demand also play an important role. The broadening of the class of firms publicly traded during is not toward smaller size. If anything, the average size of newly public firms increases, and there is a general thinning of the extreme left tail of the size distribution of new lists (Table 1). Rather the broadening is toward firms with lower initial profitability and higher growth. And the key is lower profitability; these are probably firms that in the past would be judged negative net present value investments and so not viable candidates for public equity financing. What changes to give them positive value? Fama and French (2002) argue that the rise in price-earnings ratios during is largely due to declining expected stock returns, or equivalently, a lower cost of equity capital. With a lower cost of capital, less profitable firms become positive net present value projects and viable candidates for public equity financing. Finally, our sample period ( ) is relatively short, and it is reasonable to ask whether there are similar hot markets for new lists with similar growth and profitability characteristics in earlier periods. Other evidence suggests that this is not the case. Gompers and Lerner (2001) study the IPOs of the period preceding NASDAQ. Their sample is fairly complete; it is not restricted to IPOs listed on major exchanges. They find that from 1935 to 1945, there are few IPOs (typically less than ten per year). Prior to 1959, there are no hot markets; the largest number of IPOs in any year is 51. From 1959 to 1962 there is a spurt of IPOs, ranging from 122 in 1959 to 321 in There is a bigger surge from 1968 to 1972, ranging from 204 IPOs in 1971 to 683 in 1969, numbers more like those of the sustained hot market of the last 20 years of our sample. Most of the IPOs of the pre-nasdaq period are not on Compustat in their IPO year, so we do not have information about initial profitability and growth. But the firms on NASDAQ by the end of the CRSP startup period (April 1973), which we classify as seasoned, and the non-ipo new lists of the early NASDAQ years, are probably heavy with the surviving IPOs of the hot market. In the early 20

New Lists: Fundamentals and Survival Rates. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract

New Lists: Fundamentals and Survival Rates. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract First Draft: March 2001 Revised: May 2003 Not for quotation Comments solicited New Lists: Fundamentals and Survival Rates Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract The class of firms that obtain

More information

Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower Propensity to Pay? Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French

Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower Propensity to Pay? Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French Center for Research in Security Prices Working Paper No. 509 Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower Propensity to Pay? Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French First draft: July 1998

More information

Dissecting Anomalies. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French. Abstract

Dissecting Anomalies. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French. Abstract First draft: February 2006 This draft: June 2006 Please do not quote or circulate Dissecting Anomalies Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French Abstract Previous work finds that net stock issues, accruals,

More information

Volatility Lessons Eugene F. Fama a and Kenneth R. French b, Stock returns are volatile. For July 1963 to December 2016 (henceforth ) the

Volatility Lessons Eugene F. Fama a and Kenneth R. French b, Stock returns are volatile. For July 1963 to December 2016 (henceforth ) the First draft: March 2016 This draft: May 2018 Volatility Lessons Eugene F. Fama a and Kenneth R. French b, Abstract The average monthly premium of the Market return over the one-month T-Bill return is substantial,

More information

Dissecting Anomalies EUGENE F. FAMA AND KENNETH R. FRENCH ABSTRACT

Dissecting Anomalies EUGENE F. FAMA AND KENNETH R. FRENCH ABSTRACT Dissecting Anomalies EUGENE F. FAMA AND KENNETH R. FRENCH ABSTRACT The anomalous returns associated with net stock issues, accruals, and momentum are pervasive; they show up in all size groups (micro,

More information

Mutual Fund Performance. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract

Mutual Fund Performance. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract First draft: October 2007 This draft: August 2008 Not for quotation: Comments welcome Mutual Fund Performance Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract In aggregate, mutual funds produce a portfolio

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

Inflation Targeting and Revisions to Inflation Data: A Case Study with PCE Inflation * Calvin Price July 2011

Inflation Targeting and Revisions to Inflation Data: A Case Study with PCE Inflation * Calvin Price July 2011 Inflation Targeting and Revisions to Inflation Data: A Case Study with PCE Inflation * Calvin Price July 2011 Introduction Central banks around the world have come to recognize the importance of maintaining

More information

Value and Reason: Analyzing Stock Split Excess Returns

Value and Reason: Analyzing Stock Split Excess Returns 1 Value and Reason: Analyzing Stock Split Excess Returns Emmeline Kuo David Martinez Department of Economics Department of Economics Pomona College Pomona College 425 N. College Avenue 425 N. College Avenue

More information

The cross section of expected stock returns

The cross section of expected stock returns The cross section of expected stock returns Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER This version: March 2013 First draft: October 2010 Tel: 603-646-8650; email: jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu. I am grateful

More information

The Value Premium and the January Effect

The Value Premium and the January Effect The Value Premium and the January Effect Julia Chou, Praveen Kumar Das * Current Version: January 2010 * Chou is from College of Business Administration, Florida International University, Miami, FL 33199;

More information

By most standards, the price of equities in the United States has

By most standards, the price of equities in the United States has Are Stocks Overvalued? Richard W. Kopcke Vice President and Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. The author thanks Kathryn Cosgrove for valuable research assistance. By most standards, the price

More information

The Equity Premium. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract

The Equity Premium. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract First draft: March 2000 This draft: July 2000 Not for quotation Comments solicited The Equity Premium Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract We compare estimates of the equity premium for 1872-1999

More information

The Characteristics of Stock Market Volatility. By Daniel R Wessels. June 2006

The Characteristics of Stock Market Volatility. By Daniel R Wessels. June 2006 The Characteristics of Stock Market Volatility By Daniel R Wessels June 2006 Available at: www.indexinvestor.co.za 1. Introduction Stock market volatility is synonymous with the uncertainty how macroeconomic

More information

An Analysis of the ESOP Protection Trust

An Analysis of the ESOP Protection Trust An Analysis of the ESOP Protection Trust Report prepared by: Francesco Bova 1 March 21 st, 2016 Abstract Using data from publicly-traded firms that have an ESOP, I assess the likelihood that: (1) a firm

More information

Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know?

Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know? Preliminary Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know? by Robert Harris*, Tim Jenkinson** and Steven N. Kaplan*** This Draft: September 9, 2011 Abstract We present time series evidence on the performance

More information

COMMENTARY NUMBER 462 June Trade Balance, Consumer Credit. August 9, Bernanke Bemoans GDP Not Reflecting Common Experience

COMMENTARY NUMBER 462 June Trade Balance, Consumer Credit. August 9, Bernanke Bemoans GDP Not Reflecting Common Experience COMMENTARY NUMBER 462 June Trade Balance, Consumer Credit August 9, 2012 Bernanke Bemoans GDP Not Reflecting Common Experience Trade Data Place Upside Pressure on Second-Quarter GDP Revision Consumer Credit

More information

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios RESEARCH Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios March 2016 Wei Dai, PhD Research The predictability of expected stock returns is an old topic and an important one. While investors may increase expected returns

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MISMEASUREMENT OF PENSIONS BEFORE AND AFTER RETIREMENT: THE MYSTERY OF THE DISAPPEARING PENSIONS WITH IMPLICATIONS FOR THE IMPORTANCE OF SOCIAL SECURITY AS A SOURCE OF RETIREMENT

More information

Growing Income and Wealth with High- Dividend Equities

Growing Income and Wealth with High- Dividend Equities Growing Income and Wealth with High- Dividend Equities September 9, 2014 by C. Thomas Howard, PhD Advisor Perspectives welcomes guest contributions. The views presented here do not necessarily represent

More information

ASSA 2006 SESSION: New Evidence About the Impact of Taxing Corporate-Source Income (H2) Presiding: JOEL SLEMROD, University of Michigan

ASSA 2006 SESSION: New Evidence About the Impact of Taxing Corporate-Source Income (H2) Presiding: JOEL SLEMROD, University of Michigan ASSA 2006 SESSION: New Evidence About the Impact of Taxing Corporate-Source Income (H2) Presiding: JOEL SLEMROD, University of Michigan The Effect of the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut on Corporate Behavior: Interpreting

More information

An Assessment of the Operational and Financial Health of Rate-of-Return Telecommunications Companies in more than 700 Study Areas:

An Assessment of the Operational and Financial Health of Rate-of-Return Telecommunications Companies in more than 700 Study Areas: An Assessment of the Operational and Financial Health of Rate-of-Return Telecommunications Companies in more than 700 Study Areas: 2007-2012 Harold Furchtgott-Roth Kathleen Wallman December 2014 Executive

More information

Investment Performance of Common Stock in Relation to their Price-Earnings Ratios: BASU 1977 Extended Analysis

Investment Performance of Common Stock in Relation to their Price-Earnings Ratios: BASU 1977 Extended Analysis Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2015 Investment Performance of Common Stock in Relation to their Price-Earnings Ratios: BASU 1977 Extended

More information

Lazard Insights. Capturing the Small-Cap Effect. The Small-Cap Effect. Summary. Edward Rosenfeld, Director, Portfolio Manager/Analyst

Lazard Insights. Capturing the Small-Cap Effect. The Small-Cap Effect. Summary. Edward Rosenfeld, Director, Portfolio Manager/Analyst Lazard Insights Capturing the Small-Cap Effect Edward Rosenfeld, Director, Portfolio Manager/Analyst Summary Historically, small-cap equities have outperformed large-cap equities across several regions.

More information

Global population projections by the United Nations John Wilmoth, Population Association of America, San Diego, 30 April Revised 5 July 2015

Global population projections by the United Nations John Wilmoth, Population Association of America, San Diego, 30 April Revised 5 July 2015 Global population projections by the United Nations John Wilmoth, Population Association of America, San Diego, 30 April 2015 Revised 5 July 2015 [Slide 1] Let me begin by thanking Wolfgang Lutz for reaching

More information

ENVIRONMENTAL FINANCE CENTER AT THE UNIVERSITY OF NORTH CAROLINA AT CHAPEL HILL SCHOOL OF GOVERNMENT REPORT 4

ENVIRONMENTAL FINANCE CENTER AT THE UNIVERSITY OF NORTH CAROLINA AT CHAPEL HILL SCHOOL OF GOVERNMENT REPORT 4 ENVIRONMENTAL FINANCE CENTER AT THE UNIVERSITY OF NORTH CAROLINA AT CHAPEL HILL SCHOOL OF GOVERNMENT REPORT 4 Using the Utility Financial Data Compiled by the LGC to Assess Infrastructure Condition, Needs,

More information

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates) Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates) Emmanuel Saez March 2, 2012 What s new for recent years? Great Recession 2007-2009 During the

More information

MONETARY POLICY COMING OUT OF RECESSION. Anna J. Schwartz National Bureau of Economic Research

MONETARY POLICY COMING OUT OF RECESSION. Anna J. Schwartz National Bureau of Economic Research MONETARY POLICY COMING OUT OF RECESSION Anna J. Schwartz National Bureau of Economic Research Since 1959 the U. S. has experienced six recessions, not counting the recession that began, according to the

More information

Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations

Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations IFS Briefing Note BN192 Andrew Hood Robert Joyce Andrew Hood Robert Joyce Copy-edited by Judith Payne Published by The Institute for Fiscal Studies

More information

Out of the Shadows: Projected Levels for Future REO Inventory

Out of the Shadows: Projected Levels for Future REO Inventory ECONOMIC COMMENTARY Number 2010-14 October 19, 2010 Out of the Shadows: Projected Levels for Future REO Inventory Guhan Venkatu Nearly one homeowner in ten is more than 90 days delinquent on his mortgage

More information

Celgene: A Primer on Growth Stock Value Investing (GARP): Part 2

Celgene: A Primer on Growth Stock Value Investing (GARP): Part 2 Celgene: A Primer on Growth Stock Value Investing (GARP): Part 2 November 13, 2015 by Chuck Carnevale of F.A.S.T. Graphs Introduction This article is the second in a two-part series on applying the principles

More information

The Impact of Recent Pension Reforms on Teacher Benefits: A Case Study of California Teachers

The Impact of Recent Pension Reforms on Teacher Benefits: A Case Study of California Teachers P R O G R A M O N R E T I R E M E N T P O L I C Y RESEARCH REPORT The Impact of Recent Pension Reforms on Teacher Benefits: A Case Study of California Teachers Richard W. Johnson November 2017 Contents

More information

Plan Management Navigator

Plan Management Navigator Plan Management Navigator S CALE, G ROWTH AND C OST M ANAGEMENT S TRATEGY April 2018 Healthcare Analysts Douglas B. Sherlock, CFA sherlock@sherlockco.com John Park, CFA jpark@sherlockco.com Christopher

More information

New Statistics of BTS Panel

New Statistics of BTS Panel THIRD JOINT EUROPEAN COMMISSION OECD WORKSHOP ON INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENT OF BUSINESS AND CONSUMER TENDENCY SURVEYS BRUSSELS 12 13 NOVEMBER 27 New Statistics of BTS Panel Serguey TSUKHLO Head, Business

More information

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan;

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan; University of New Orleans ScholarWorks@UNO Department of Economics and Finance Working Papers, 1991-2006 Department of Economics and Finance 1-1-2006 Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using

More information

Economic Forecast May 2016: After nine years, the Danish economy will reach the level prior to the financial

Economic Forecast May 2016: After nine years, the Danish economy will reach the level prior to the financial May 2016 ØPA Economic Forecast May 2016: After nine years, the Danish economy will reach the level prior to the financial crisis DI predicts a growth in GDP of 0.9 per cent in 2016 and therefore GDP is

More information

Liquidity and IPO performance in the last decade

Liquidity and IPO performance in the last decade Liquidity and IPO performance in the last decade Saurav Roychoudhury Associate Professor School of Management and Leadership Capital University Abstract It is well documented by that if long run IPO underperformance

More information

2013 Hedge Fund. Compensation Report SAMPLE REPORT

2013 Hedge Fund. Compensation Report SAMPLE REPORT 2013 Hedge Fund Hedge Fund Compensation Report Compensation Report JobSearchDigest.com SAMPLE REPORT HedgeFundCompensationReport.com Introduction It is our pleasure to share with you, for the sixth time,

More information

Income inequality and the growth of redistributive spending in the U.S. states: Is there a link?

Income inequality and the growth of redistributive spending in the U.S. states: Is there a link? Draft Version: May 27, 2017 Word Count: 3128 words. SUPPLEMENTARY ONLINE MATERIAL: Income inequality and the growth of redistributive spending in the U.S. states: Is there a link? Appendix 1 Bayesian posterior

More information

STOCK MARKET EXTREMES AND PORTFOLIO PERFORMANCE

STOCK MARKET EXTREMES AND PORTFOLIO PERFORMANCE STOCK MARKET EXTREMES AND PORTFOLIO PERFORMANCE A study commissioned by Towneley Capital Management and conducted by Professor H. Nejat Seyhun, University of Michigan TABLE OF CONTENTS Letter from Dr.

More information

Gauging Current Conditions:

Gauging Current Conditions: Gauging Current Conditions: The Economic Outlook and Its Impact on Workers Compensation Vol. 2 2005 The gauges below indicate the economic outlook for the current year and for 2006 for factors that typically

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

Statement of. Alan Greenspan. Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. before the. Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs

Statement of. Alan Greenspan. Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. before the. Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs For release on delivery 10:00 a.m. EDT April 13, 2000 Statement of Alan Greenspan Chairman Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs United

More information

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2017 preliminary estimates)

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2017 preliminary estimates) Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2017 preliminary estimates) Emmanuel Saez, UC Berkeley October 13, 2018 What s new for recent years? 2016-2017: Robust

More information

Securities Class Action Filings

Securities Class Action Filings CORNERSTONE RESEARCH Securities Class Action Filings 2010 Year in Review Research Sample The Stanford Law School Securities Class Action Clearinghouse in cooperation with Cornerstone Research has identified

More information

Penny Stock Guide. Copyright 2017 StocksUnder1.org, All Rights Reserved.

Penny Stock Guide.  Copyright 2017 StocksUnder1.org, All Rights Reserved. Penny Stock Guide Disclaimer The information provided is not to be considered as a recommendation to buy certain stocks and is provided solely as an information resource to help traders make their own

More information

Income Inequality in Korea,

Income Inequality in Korea, Income Inequality in Korea, 1958-2013. Minki Hong Korea Labor Institute 1. Introduction This paper studies the top income shares from 1958 to 2013 in Korea using tax return. 2. Data and Methodology In

More information

A Balanced View of Storefront Payday Borrowing Patterns Results From a Longitudinal Random Sample Over 4.5 Years

A Balanced View of Storefront Payday Borrowing Patterns Results From a Longitudinal Random Sample Over 4.5 Years Report 7-C A Balanced View of Storefront Payday Borrowing Patterns Results From a Longitudinal Random Sample Over 4.5 Years A Balanced View of Storefront Payday Borrowing Patterns Results From a Longitudinal

More information

Olivier Blanchard. July 7, 2003

Olivier Blanchard. July 7, 2003 Comments on The case of missing productivity growth; or, why has productivity accelerated in the United States but not the United Kingdom by Basu et al Olivier Blanchard. July 7, 2003 NBER Macroeconomics

More information

Indicators Related to Liquidity in JGB Markets

Indicators Related to Liquidity in JGB Markets Bank of Japan Review -E- Indicators Related to Liquidity in JGB Markets Financial Markets Department Kenji Nishizaki, Akira Tsuchikawa, Tomoyuki Yagi November Japanese government bonds (JGBs) have a range

More information

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS*

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS* Chapter 4 A FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS* Key Concepts Origins and Issues of Macroeconomics Modern macroeconomics began during the Great Depression, 1929 1939. The Great Depression was a decade of high

More information

APPENDIX SUMMARIZING NARRATIVE EVIDENCE ON FEDERAL RESERVE INTENTIONS FOR THE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE. Christina D. Romer David H.

APPENDIX SUMMARIZING NARRATIVE EVIDENCE ON FEDERAL RESERVE INTENTIONS FOR THE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE. Christina D. Romer David H. APPENDIX SUMMARIZING NARRATIVE EVIDENCE ON FEDERAL RESERVE INTENTIONS FOR THE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE Christina D. Romer David H. Romer To accompany A New Measure of Monetary Shocks: Derivation and Implications,

More information

Economics of Behavioral Finance. Lecture 3

Economics of Behavioral Finance. Lecture 3 Economics of Behavioral Finance Lecture 3 Security Market Line CAPM predicts a linear relationship between a stock s Beta and its excess return. E[r i ] r f = β i E r m r f Practically, testing CAPM empirically

More information

DECREASING NUMBER OF PUBLIC COMPANIES

DECREASING NUMBER OF PUBLIC COMPANIES M E K E T A I N V E S T M E N T G R O U P BOSTON MA CHICAGO IL MIAMI FL PORTLAND OR SAN DIEGO CA LONDON UK Roberto Obregon Frank Benham MEKETA INVESTMENT GROUP 1 Lowder Brook Drive, Suite 11 Westwood,

More information

The Impact of Trade on US Job Loss,

The Impact of Trade on US Job Loss, 6 The Impact of Trade on US Job Loss, 2000 03 MARTIN NEIL BAILY and ROBERT Z. LAWRENCE After growing strongly in the 1990s, the US economy entered a period of weakness after 2000. Economic growth and employment

More information

Risk changes around convertible debt offerings

Risk changes around convertible debt offerings Journal of Corporate Finance 8 (2002) 67 80 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Risk changes around convertible debt offerings Craig M. Lewis a, *, Richard J. Rogalski b, James K. Seward c a Owen Graduate

More information

Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence

Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence Joshua Livnat Department of Accounting Stern School of Business Administration New York University 311 Tisch Hall

More information

CEPR CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH

CEPR CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH CEPR CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH The Wealth of Households: An Analysis of the 2016 Survey of Consumer Finance By David Rosnick and Dean Baker* November 2017 Center for Economic and Policy Research

More information

Malawi Tea 2020 Revitalisation programme towards living wage. Wages Committee progress report 2016

Malawi Tea 2020 Revitalisation programme towards living wage. Wages Committee progress report 2016 Malawi Tea 2020 Revitalisation programme towards living wage Wages Committee progress report 2016 By Richard Anker and Martha Anker October 2016 This paper provides an update to October 2016 (date of

More information

COMMENTARY NUMBER 776 November Durable Goods Orders, New-Home Sales December 23, 2015

COMMENTARY NUMBER 776 November Durable Goods Orders, New-Home Sales December 23, 2015 COMMENTARY NUMBER 776 November Durable Goods Orders, New-Home Sales December 23, 2015 Net of Inflation and Commercial Aircraft Orders, November Durable Orders Were Stronger than the Headline Unchanged

More information

Fifth Annual Fisher Real Estate Conference St. Francis Hotel San Francisco For delivery June 6, 2000, approximately 8:15 AM P.D.T.

Fifth Annual Fisher Real Estate Conference St. Francis Hotel San Francisco For delivery June 6, 2000, approximately 8:15 AM P.D.T. Fifth Annual Fisher Real Estate Conference St. Francis Hotel San Francisco For delivery June 6, 2000, approximately 8:15 AM P.D.T. A Look at the Regional and National Economies I. Good morning. It's a

More information

Characterizing the Risk of IPO Long-Run Returns: The Impact of Momentum, Liquidity, Skewness, and Investment

Characterizing the Risk of IPO Long-Run Returns: The Impact of Momentum, Liquidity, Skewness, and Investment Characterizing the Risk of IPO Long-Run Returns: The Impact of Momentum, Liquidity, Skewness, and Investment RICHARD B. CARTER*, FREDERICK H. DARK, and TRAVIS R. A. SAPP This version: August 28, 2009 JEL

More information

Opting out of Retirement Plan Default Settings

Opting out of Retirement Plan Default Settings WORKING PAPER Opting out of Retirement Plan Default Settings Jeremy Burke, Angela A. Hung, and Jill E. Luoto RAND Labor & Population WR-1162 January 2017 This paper series made possible by the NIA funded

More information

STUDY OF HEALTH, RETIREMENT AND AGING

STUDY OF HEALTH, RETIREMENT AND AGING STUDY OF HEALTH, RETIREMENT AND AGING experiences by real people--can be developed if Introduction necessary. We want to thank you for taking part in < Will the baby boomers become the first these studies.

More information

the U.S. balance of payments deficit showed substantial improvement after midyear.

the U.S. balance of payments deficit showed substantial improvement after midyear. DURING 1963 THE Federal Reserve continued to encourage monetary and credit expansion with a view to stimulating a further rise in economic activity. The availability of bank reserves was reduced somewhat

More information

THE EFFECT OF LIQUIDITY COSTS ON SECURITIES PRICES AND RETURNS

THE EFFECT OF LIQUIDITY COSTS ON SECURITIES PRICES AND RETURNS PART I THE EFFECT OF LIQUIDITY COSTS ON SECURITIES PRICES AND RETURNS Introduction and Overview We begin by considering the direct effects of trading costs on the values of financial assets. Investors

More information

Croatia and the European Union: an Opportunity, not a Guarantee

Croatia and the European Union: an Opportunity, not a Guarantee and the European Union: an Opportunity, not a Guarantee Europe has invented a Convergence Machine. Much as the United States takes in poor people and transforms them into high income households, the EU

More information

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Zhangkai Huang * and Xingzhong Xu Guanghua School of Management Peking University Abstract Unlike in other countries, negotiated block shares have

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 2 Summer 1997 AN ANALYSIS OF VALUE LINE S ABILITY TO FORECAST LONG-RUN RETURNS

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 2 Summer 1997 AN ANALYSIS OF VALUE LINE S ABILITY TO FORECAST LONG-RUN RETURNS Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 2 Summer 1997 AN ANALYSIS OF VALUE LINE S ABILITY TO FORECAST LONG-RUN RETURNS Gary A. Benesh * and Steven B. Perfect * Abstract Value Line

More information

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN The International Journal of Business and Finance Research Volume 5 Number 1 2011 DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN Ming-Hui Wang, Taiwan University of Science and Technology

More information

Actuarial Highlights FARM Valuation as at December 31, Ontario Alberta. Facility Association Actuarial 11/9/2012

Actuarial Highlights FARM Valuation as at December 31, Ontario Alberta. Facility Association Actuarial 11/9/2012 FARM Valuation as at December 31, 2011 Ontario Alberta Facility Association Actuarial 11/9/2012 Contents A. Executive Summary... 3 B. General Information... 7 B.1 Transition to Hybrid Model for Actuarial

More information

Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments

Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments Ric Battellino: Recent financial developments Address by Mr Ric Battellino, Deputy Governor of the Reserve Bank of Australia, at the Annual Stockbrokers Conference, Sydney, 26 May 2011. * * * Introduction

More information

The Variability of IPO Initial Returns

The Variability of IPO Initial Returns The Variability of IPO Initial Returns Michelle Lowry Penn State University, University Park, PA 16082, Micah S. Officer University of Southern California, Los Angeles, CA 90089, G. William Schwert University

More information

Crestmont Research. Rowing vs. The Roller Coaster By Ed Easterling January 26, 2007 All Rights Reserved

Crestmont Research. Rowing vs. The Roller Coaster By Ed Easterling January 26, 2007 All Rights Reserved Crestmont Research Rowing vs. The Roller Coaster By Ed Easterling January 26, 2007 All Rights Reserved Why are so many of the most knowledgeable institutions and individuals shifting away from investment

More information

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1 Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1 Andreas Fagereng (Statistics Norway) Luigi Guiso (EIEF) Davide Malacrino (Stanford University) Luigi Pistaferri (Stanford University

More information

The Equity Premium Revisited

The Equity Premium Revisited First draft: January 2009 Current version: February 2009 The Equity Premium Revisited BRADFORD CORNELL CALIFORNIA INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY PASADENA, CA 91125 626 564-2001 bcornell@hss.caltech.edu ROB ARNOTT

More information

Do Moving Average Strategies Really Work?

Do Moving Average Strategies Really Work? Do Moving Average Strategies Really Work? August 19, 2014 by Paul Allen Advisor Perspectives welcomes guest contributions. The views presented here do not necessarily represent those of Advisor Perspectives.

More information

The Effects of the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut on Corporate Behavior: Interpreting the Evidence

The Effects of the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut on Corporate Behavior: Interpreting the Evidence The Effects of the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut on Corporate Behavior: Interpreting the Evidence By RAJ CHETTY AND EMMANUEL SAEZ* The 2003 dividend tax reform has generated renewed interest in understanding the

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS, DIVERSIFICATION, AND THE FIRM S LIFECYCLE. Asli M. Arikan René M. Stulz

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS, DIVERSIFICATION, AND THE FIRM S LIFECYCLE. Asli M. Arikan René M. Stulz NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CORPORATE ACQUISITIONS, DIVERSIFICATION, AND THE FIRM S LIFECYCLE Asli M. Arikan René M. Stulz Working Paper 17463 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17463 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Comparing Estimates of Family Income in the Panel Study of Income Dynamics and the March Current Population Survey,

Comparing Estimates of Family Income in the Panel Study of Income Dynamics and the March Current Population Survey, Comparing Estimates of Family Income in the Panel Study of Income Dynamics and the March Current Population Survey, 1968-1999. Elena Gouskova and Robert F. Schoeni Institute for Social Research University

More information

Diversified Stock Income Plan

Diversified Stock Income Plan Joseph E. Buffa, Equity Sector Analyst Michael A. Colón, Equity Sector Analyst Diversified Stock Income Plan 2017 Concept Review The Diversified Stock Income Plan (DSIP List) focuses on companies that

More information

Monitoring the Performance

Monitoring the Performance Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market An overview of the Sector from 2014 Quarter 1 to 2017 Quarter 1 Factsheet 19 November 2017 South Africa s Sector Government broadly defined

More information

Financing Profiles SMALL BUSINESS. Women Entrepreneurs. SME Financing Data Initiative October 2010

Financing Profiles SMALL BUSINESS. Women Entrepreneurs. SME Financing Data Initiative October 2010 SMALL BUSINESS Financing Profiles SME Financing Data Initiative October Women Entrepreneurs Owen Jung Small Business and Tourism Branch, Industry Canada highlights $ $ female-owned small and medium-sized

More information

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations Online Appendix of Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality By ANDREAS FAGERENG, LUIGI GUISO, DAVIDE MALACRINO AND LUIGI PISTAFERRI This appendix complements the evidence

More information

Response by Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez to: The Top 1%... of What? By ALAN REYNOLDS

Response by Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez to: The Top 1%... of What? By ALAN REYNOLDS Response by Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez to: The Top 1%... of What? By ALAN REYNOLDS In his December 14 article, The Top 1% of What?, Alan Reynolds casts doubts on the interpretation of our results

More information

Determinants of Dividend Initiation by IPO Issuing Firms

Determinants of Dividend Initiation by IPO Issuing Firms Determinants of Dividend Initiation by IPO Issuing Firms By Bharat A. Jain Department of Finance Towson University Towson, MD 21252 (410)-704-3542 bjain@towson.edu and Chander Shekhar Melbourne Business

More information

WHERE IS BANKING HEADED IN THE

WHERE IS BANKING HEADED IN THE WHERE IS BANKING HEADED IN THE 1970's? By Darryl R. Francis To the Wisconsin Bankers Association Bank Executive Seminar At University of Wisconsin, Madison, Wisconsin February 3, 1971 I am delighted to

More information

COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. The Check Is in the Mail. Get Paid to Invest with Dividends

COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. The Check Is in the Mail. Get Paid to Invest with Dividends Chapter One The Check Is in the Mail Get Paid to Invest with Dividends T HE CONTROLLER OF MY COMPANY IS NAMED PAM. Besides being a great controller, Pam has a great smile, one of those toothy ones that

More information

Disappearing Dividends in the Thai Capital Market: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower Propensity to Pay

Disappearing Dividends in the Thai Capital Market: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower Propensity to Pay Journal of Economic and Social Policy Volume 1 Issue 1 Enterprising Finance Article 7 7-1-2 Disappearing Dividends in the Thai Capital Market: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower Propensity to Pay Malinee

More information

The State of Working Utah, Looking Back on the Boom

The State of Working Utah, Looking Back on the Boom The State of Working Utah, 2008 Looking Back on the Boom State of Working Utah, 2008 Executive Summary At the peak of the latest business cycle in 2007, Utah posted impressive gains in overall economic

More information

The IPO Derby: Are there Consistent Losers and Winners on this Track?

The IPO Derby: Are there Consistent Losers and Winners on this Track? The IPO Derby: Are there Consistent Losers and Winners on this Track? Konan Chan *, John W. Cooney, Jr. **, Joonghyuk Kim ***, and Ajai K. Singh **** This version: June, 2007 Abstract We examine the individual

More information

Consequences of present Euro area monetary policy on savings and capital wealth formation. 14 November Parliamentary evening in Brussels

Consequences of present Euro area monetary policy on savings and capital wealth formation. 14 November Parliamentary evening in Brussels Jacques de Larosière Consequences of present Euro area monetary policy on savings and capital wealth formation 14 November 2016 Parliamentary evening in Brussels As we all know, the ECB has engaged in

More information

The Conversation We ll Be Having for Years to Come

The Conversation We ll Be Having for Years to Come LEADERSHIP SERIES SEPTEMBER 2017 A feature article from our U.S. partners The Conversation We ll Be Having for Years to Come It s time to consider what a return to conventional monetary policy could mean

More information

A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968): Comparative Analysis of China and the US *

A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968): Comparative Analysis of China and the US * DOI 10.7603/s40570-014-0007-1 66 2014 年 6 月第 16 卷第 2 期 中国会计与财务研究 C h i n a A c c o u n t i n g a n d F i n a n c e R e v i e w Volume 16, Number 2 June 2014 A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968):

More information

Volume Title: The Formation and Stocks of Total Capital. Volume URL:

Volume Title: The Formation and Stocks of Total Capital. Volume URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Formation and Stocks of Total Capital Volume Author/Editor: John W. Kendrick Volume Publisher:

More information

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001

THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001 THE NEW ECONOMY RECESSION: ECONOMIC SCORECARD 2001 By Dean Baker December 20, 2001 Now that it is officially acknowledged that a recession has begun, most economists are predicting that it will soon be

More information

Mr Bäckström elucidates the economic situation in Sweden and describes the consequences it may have for future monetary policy

Mr Bäckström elucidates the economic situation in Sweden and describes the consequences it may have for future monetary policy Mr Bäckström elucidates the economic situation in Sweden and describes the consequences it may have for future monetary policy Speech given by Mr Urban Bäckström, Governor of the Sveriges Riksbank at Föreningssparbanken,

More information

Boomers at Midlife. The AARP Life Stage Study. Wave 2

Boomers at Midlife. The AARP Life Stage Study. Wave 2 Boomers at Midlife 2003 The AARP Life Stage Study Wave 2 Boomers at Midlife: The AARP Life Stage Study Wave 2, 2003 Carol Keegan, Ph.D. Project Manager, Knowledge Management, AARP 202-434-6286 Sonya Gross

More information

CHAPTER 6: ANSWERS TO CONCEPTS IN REVIEW

CHAPTER 6: ANSWERS TO CONCEPTS IN REVIEW CHAPTER 6: ANSWERS TO CONCEPTS IN REVIEW 6.1 A common stock is an equity investment that represents ownership in a corporate form of business. Each share represents a fractional ownership interest in the

More information