Mutual Fund Performance. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Mutual Fund Performance. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract"

Transcription

1 First draft: October 2007 This draft: August 2008 Not for quotation: Comments welcome Mutual Fund Performance Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract In aggregate, mutual funds produce a portfolio close to the market portfolio but with high costs of active management that show up intact as lower returns. Persistence tests that sort funds on three-factor α estimates suggest information effects in the future returns of past winners and losers, but persistence is temporary, it is weak to nonexistent in sorts on average return, and it largely disappears after Bootstrap simulations that use entire histories of fund returns do not identify information effects in three-factor or fourfactor α estimates. Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago (Fama) and Amos Tuck School of Business, Dartmouth College (French). We are grateful for the comments of John Cochrane and seminar participants at the University of Chicago. Electronic copy available at:

2 Equilibrium accounting says that investors in U.S. equities in aggregate get the value-weight U.S. equity market return less their investment costs. Suppose that when returns are measured before costs, passive investors get passive returns; that is, they have zero α (abnormal expected return with respect to the true asset pricing model). Then if some active investors have positive α before costs, it is, dollar for dollar, at the expense of other active investors. Thus, like passive investment, active investment is in aggregate a zero sum game aggregate α is zero before costs. After costs (that is, in terms of net returns to investors) active investment is a negative sum game. This is the argument in French (2008), and he gives references to earlier papers that make a similar point. 1 We examine mutual fund performance from the perspective of equilibrium accounting. For example, at the aggregate level, if we find that the value-weight (VW) portfolio of all mutual funds produces a positive α before costs, we can infer that the VW portfolio held by investors outside mutual funds has a negative α. In other words, the mutual fund industry wins at the expense of investments held outside mutual funds. Our tests, however, do not produce this result. We find (Section I) that mutual funds in aggregate do not gain from or lose to other investors. The VW portfolio of mutual funds that invest primarily in U.S. equities is close to the market portfolio, and estimated before fees and expenses, its α is close to zero. Since the VW portfolio of funds produces an α close to zero in gross returns, the α estimated on the net returns to investors is negative by about the amount of fees and expenses. All this echoes equilibrium accounting, but for a subset of investment managers where the implications of equilibrium accounting for aggregate investor returns need not hold. The aggregate results for mutual funds imply that if there are funds with positive α, they must be balanced by funds with negative α. Our main goal is to test for the existence of such winner and loser funds. The challenge is to distinguish skill from luck. Given the multitude of funds, many have extreme returns by chance. A common approach to this problem is to test for persistence in fund returns, that is, whether past winners continue to produce high returns and losers continue to underperform (for example, Grinblatt and Titman 1992, Hendricks, Patel, and Zeckhauser 1993, Goetzmann and Ibbotson 1994, Carhart 1 The implications of equilibrium accounting are often overlooked. For example, Berk and Green (2004) develop a model in which active investors in aggregate produce zero α after (rather than before) fees and expenses. Equilibrium accounting says this equilibrium is impossible unless passive investors lose massively to active investors. French (2008) provides evidence that this is not the case. Electronic copy available at:

3 1997). If past performance is due to chance, it does not predict future performance. But if some managers have stock selection skills, persistence tests are a way to infer their existence. Persistence tests also have a downside. They typically rank funds based on short-term past performance. We may find little evidence of persistence because the allocation of funds to winner and loser portfolios is largely based on noise. Section II extends and updates Carhart s (1997) evidence on return persistence. There are post- Carhart persistence studies, but they leave important open issues. For example, Carhart s (1997) informal evidence (plots of post-ranking raw returns) suggests that any persistence in performance is short-term. His results also suggest that performance is sensitive to the way funds are ranked. In formal tests that attack these issues, Bollen and Busse (2004) find no evidence of persistence when funds are ranked on past average return, but persistence shows up in rankings on α estimates from Carhart s (1997) four-factor model. They also find that the persistence uncovered in their tests is short-term, less than a year. Finally, Barras et al (2008) find that mutual fund performance is weaker in more recent time periods. Bollen and Busse (2004) examine a small sample of 230 funds for the rather short period. They sort funds using at most twelve months of past returns, which raises the possibility that the sorts are in large part based on noise. Our persistence tests use all mutual funds in the CRSP database that are available during and invest primarily in U.S. equities, and our sorts use 12 to 60 months of past returns. Our tests confirm that persistence results are sensitive to how funds are ranked. When we sort funds on past market-adjusted gross returns, we find little persistence in post-sort returns. Persistence is stronger when we sort on four-factor α or three-factor α estimates from the model of Fama and French (1993). These α sorts suggest that the loser decile contains some funds with bad information that lowers expected returns and the winner decile contains some funds with good information that enhances expected returns. The persistence results from sorts on α estimates are stronger for smaller funds, and they are weak after The main contribution of this paper is a bootstrap simulation alternative to persistence tests that uses the entire return histories of all funds to infer the existence of superior and inferior managers. We compare the actual cross-section of fund α estimates to the results from 10,000 bootstrap simulations of the cross-section. The returns of the funds in a simulation run have all the properties of actual fund returns, except that in the 2 Electronic copy available at:

4 simulations true α is set to zero. The simulations thus provide the distribution of the cross-section of α estimates when in truth there is no abnormal performance, good or bad, in fund returns. Comparing the distribution of α estimates from the simulations to the cross-section of α estimates for actual fund returns allows us to draw inferences about the existence of skilled managers. For example, if the 10,000 simulation runs for gross returns (before fees and expenses) rarely produce a 10 th percentile α estimate below the 10 th percentile α estimate from the cross-section of actual gross fund returns, we can infer that there are fund managers with bad information that reduces expected returns. Likewise, if the 90 th percentile of α estimates from the simulation runs for gross returns is rarely above the 90 th percentile of the cross-section of actual fund α estimates from gross returns, we can infer that there are some managers with good information that enhances expected returns. The simulations share a shortcoming of all performance tests. They only allow inferences about the existence of inferior or superior funds. Since a large cross-section of funds produces some extreme α estimates simply by chance, we cannot identify the specific managers that are skillful rather than lucky. For fund investors the results from the simulations (Section III) are disheartening. The tests say clearly that the cross-section of precision-adjusted α estimates, t(α), for actual net fund returns to investors is dominated by funds that do not have information that produces expected returns sufficient to cover the costs the funds impose on investors. This result holds even for the extreme right tail of t(α) estimates for actual fund returns. Thus, if there are funds with sufficient information to cover costs, they are hidden among the mass of funds with insufficient information. Mutual funds look better when returns are measured gross, that is, before fees and expenses. Comparing the cross-section of t(α) estimates from gross fund returns to the average cross-section of t(α) estimates from the simulation runs suggests that there are managers with bad information that lowers expected returns and there are managers with good information that enhances expected returns. Formal support for this inference is, however, lacking. Large fractions of the simulation runs (in which true α is zero) produce left and right tails for t(α) more extreme than the tails observed for actual gross fund returns. In the end, gross returns produce hints of information effects, but only hints. Formally, we cannot reject the hypothesis that the cross- 3

5 section of α estimates from gross fund returns comes from a population of managers with no special stock selection skills, good or bad. Persistence tests that examine future α for the winner and loser deciles from sorts of funds on past α (Section II) seem similar to simulation tests that examine the 10 th and 90 th percentiles of α estimates (Section III). There is, however, an important difference. If some funds consistently have private information, 2 the simulations may have more power to infer their existence because the tests use longer periods to estimate α. The weak performance evidence from the simulations then suggests that few if any funds have consistent access to information. On the other hand, if access to information is temporary, it can be masked in a long return history. Persistence tests (which sort funds on recent performance) might then be better for identifying when funds have information. Similar comments apply when funds by chance temporarily hold stocks that expose failures of the three- or four-factor models. Confirming Bollen and Busse (2004), our more extensive results suggest that any post-ranking performance identified in the persistence tests is indeed temporary. Finally, the paper closest to ours is Kosowski et al (2006). They do persistence tests and bootstrap simulations that seem to produce stronger inferences about positive information effects in mutual fund returns. We discuss their tests after presenting our results. I. Average Returns for EW and VW Portfolios of U.S. Equity Mutual Funds Our mutual fund sample is from the CRSP (Center for Research in Security Prices) database. We include only funds that invest primarily in U.S. common stocks, and we combine, with value weights, different classes of the same fund into a single fund. (See French 2008 for details.) The data cover January 1962 to September 2006 (henceforth ), but our central persistence and simulation tests use the period after 1983, when there are fewer data issues (Elton, Gruber, and Blake 2001). Our benchmarks for evaluating fund performance are the three-factor model of Fama and French (1993), and Carhart s (1997) four-factor model. To measure performance, these models use two variants of the time-series regression, R it R ft = a i + b i (R Mt R ft ) + s i SMB t + v i VMG t + m i MOM t + e it. (1) 2 We define private information as any information (including publicly available information) that is not reflected in prices. 4

6 In this regression, R it is the return on fund i for month t, R ft is the riskfree rate (the one-month U.S. Treasury bill rate), R Mt is the market return (the return on a value-weight portfolio of NYSE, Amex, and NASDAQ stocks), SMB t and VMG t are the size and value-growth returns of Fama and French (1993), MOM t is our version of Carhart s (1997) momentum return, a i is the average return left unexplained by the benchmark model (the estimate of α i ), and e it is the regression residual. The full version of (1) is Carhart s four-factor model, and the regression without MOM t is the Fama-French three-factor model. The construction of SMB t and VMG t (also known as HML t ) follows Fama and French (1993). The momentum return, MOM t, is defined like VMG t, except that we sort on prior return rather than the book-to-market equity ratio and the momentum sort is refreshed monthly rather than annually. (See Table 1 for details.) Table 1 shows summary statistics for the explanatory returns in (1) for periods examined later in tests of mutual fund performance. The average value of the value-growth return, VMG t, is large for (0.48% per month, t = 3.82) and for each subperiod. The average value of the market premium, R Mt R ft, for (0.45% per month, t = 2.36) is close to the average VMG t return. The size return, SMB t, has the smallest average value for (0.23% per month, t = 1.65). For every period in Table 1, the average momentum return is by far the largest factor premium (for example, 0.82% per month, t = 4.80, for ). Large average MOM t returns imply that the MOM t slopes in (1) can have a big effect on intercept (α) estimates a comment of some import for the persistence tests presented later. There is controversy about whether the average SMB t, VMG t, and MOM t returns are rewards for risk or the result of mispricing. For our purposes, there is no need to take a stance on this issue. On an intuitive level, we can interpret SMB t, VMG t, and MOM t as common factors in stock returns associated with patterns in average returns during our sample period. Abstracting from the variation in returns associated with SMB t, VMG t, and MOM t then allows us to focus better on the effects of information about individual stocks (stock picking ability), which should show up in three- and four-factor intercepts. Formally, our null hypothesis in the tests that use the three-factor model is that U.S equity mutual funds have no private information, and the riskfree security, the market, SMB, and VMG together span the ex ante mean-variance-efficient (MVE) portfolios that can be constructed from the portfolios of these funds. This 5

7 implies that, measured before costs, the expected values of the three-factor intercepts for these funds are zero (Huberman and Kandel 1987). The alternative hypothesis is that some mutual funds have private information about individual stocks, so the riskfree security, the market, SMB, and VMG do not span the MVE portfolios that can be constructed from the portfolios of these funds. This implies that the expected values of the intercepts for these funds are positive or negative, depending on whether private information is good or bad. Similar statements apply when we use the four-factor model to evaluate performance. Table 2 shows estimates of regression (1) for equal-weight (EW) and value-weight (VW) portfolios of the funds in our sample. The intercepts in (1) for EW fund returns tell us whether funds on average have information about stocks that allows them to produce expected returns different from those implied by their exposures to common factors in returns. In contrast, VW returns tell us about the fate of the average dollar (or aggregate wealth) invested in funds. Part A of Table 2 shows the regression intercepts (α estimates) for the three- and four-factor variants of (1) for returns measured gross and net of fund fees and expenses. Part B shows the regression slopes for the four-factor model. The market, SMB, and VMG slopes for the three-factor model are close to the slopes in the four-factor model. Only the slopes for net returns are shown. The slopes for gross returns are the same up to three decimal places. 3 All the market slopes in Table 2 are close to 1.0, which is not surprising since our sample is restricted to funds that invest primarily in U.S. equities. The slopes on SMB t are around 0.20 for EW fund returns and around 0.06 for VW returns. We can infer that smaller funds are more likely to invest in smaller stocks, but total dollars invested in funds (captured by VW returns) show little tilt toward smaller stocks. More interesting, the tilt toward smaller stocks in EW and VW returns, as captured by SMB t slopes, is a bit lower after Thus, Banz (1981) discovery of the size effect (higher average returns of small stocks) does not produce a shift in either funds or dollars invested in funds toward smaller stocks. The slopes for VMG t in fund returns for are (EW and VW returns), which suggests a slight tilt toward growth stocks. The VMG t slopes in fund returns for rise to 0.05 (EW) and Information about fees and expenses is sometimes missing on CRSP, especially early in the period. When a fund is missing fees and expenses for a year, we assume its expense ratio is the same as other funds with similar AUM, with separate estimates for active and passive funds. 6

8 (VW), which suggests a slight move away from growth stocks toward a more neutral position. Again, however, academic trumpeting of the higher returns of value stocks relative to growth stocks (Fama and French 1992, Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny 1994) does not result in much aggregate movement of funds or dollars invested in funds toward value stocks. Finally, the discovery of return momentum (Jegadeesh and Titman 1993) produces little aggregate movement of funds or dollars invested in funds toward positive momentum stocks. In fact, the momentum slopes for EW and VW fund returns move from slightly positive for to values closer to zero for The intercepts in the estimates of (1) summarize the average performance of funds (EW returns) and the performance of aggregate wealth invested in funds (VW returns). In terms of net returns to investors, performance is poor. The three-factor intercepts for EW and VW net returns are negative for all the periods in Table 2, but the estimates for and are close to zero statistically and economically. The EW and VW fund returns of and have slightly positive exposure to momentum, however, and controlling for momentum leads to strongly negative four-factor intercepts for these periods, like the negative estimates for and The annualized four-factor intercepts for different periods range from -0.71% to -1.38%, and they are to standard errors from zero. These results are in line with previous work (for example, Jensen 1968, Malkiel 1995, Gruber 1996). The intercepts in (1) for net returns tell us whether funds have sufficient private information to cover the costs they impose on investors. Gross returns are better for testing whether funds have any private information. For EW and VW gross fund returns, three-factor intercepts are positive for all periods except , but only the EW estimate for (0.97% per year, t = 2.14) is more than 1.61 standard errors above zero. Again, however, the positive three-factor α estimates for periods before 1993 seem to be due to positive momentum exposure. For VW gross returns, four-factor intercepts for all periods in Table 2 are negative but close to zero. For EW gross returns, four-factor intercepts are randomly positive and negative, but again always close to zero. We can offer an equilibrium accounting perspective on the results in Table 2. During , when there are fewer concerns about biases in the CRSP data, the annualized three- and four-factor α estimates 7

9 for VW net fund returns are -0.80% and -0.93% (t = and -2.98). Thus, for total wealth invested in funds, any benefits from active management are overwhelmed by fees and expenses. When we add back fees and expenses, there is no evidence that total wealth invested in funds gets benefits or suffers losses from active management. The annualized three- and four-factor α estimates for VW gross fund returns for are close to zero, 0.10% and -0.03% (t = 0.32 and -0.09). VW fund returns also show little exposure to the size, value, and momentum factors during , and we can report that during this period the excess market return alone explains 99% of the variance of the monthly VW excess return for our universe of funds. Together these facts say that during , mutual fund investors in aggregate hold a portfolio that, before fees and expenses, mimics market portfolio returns. The aggregate portfolio of funds is, however, dominated by active funds, and the average return to investors is reduced by the high fees and expenses of these funds. As noted earlier, these results echo equilibrium accounting, but for a subset of investment managers where the implications of equilibrium accounting for aggregate investor returns need not hold. Finally, our net returns ignore load fees, so they overstate the returns to investors in load funds. On the other hand, our gross returns are before fees and expenses, but they are net of trading costs. We do not attempt to add trading costs to gross returns because turnover is often missing on CRSP, and even when turnover data are available, differences across funds in investment styles and trading strategies make estimates of trading costs imprecise. We prefer to argue that (unlike management fees) trading costs are inherent in a fund s strategy, and actively managed funds should at a minimum provide expected returns that cover trading costs. Four-factor α estimates that are close to zero for EW and VW gross returns (Table 2) suggest that, at least on average, funds may achieve this bare minimum result. II. Return Persistence Table 2 says that on average mutual funds do not have information that produces gross returns above (or below) those predicted by the three- and four-factor benchmarks. But this result may just mean that funds with good information that allows them to outperform the benchmarks are balanced by funds with bad information that leads to underperformance. Persistence tests are one way to examine this possibility. If some 8

10 managers have access to good or bad information, when we sort funds on past performance we should find that past winners are on average future winners and past losers are future losers. We sort funds in several ways. Specifically, each month of we allocate funds to deciles based on the t-statistic for the average monthly net-of-market return of the preceding 12 or 60 months or the t- statistic for the three-factor α estimate from 60 months of past returns. We sort on t-statistics since the precision of the sort variable should be a factor in identifying return persistence. To focus on stock picking ability, the persistence tests we show use gross returns, but we also comment on results for net returns. Finally, we can report that (i) sorts on net-of-market average returns and α estimates produce results similar to sorts on their t-statistics, (ii) sorts on 36-month past performance produce results similar to the 60-month sorts, and (iii) sorts on four-factor t(α) estimates produce results like the sorts on three-factor t(α). If stock-picking talent is persistent, its tracks in future returns should be most apparent in the extremes of sorts on past performance. Thus, to enhance the power of the tests we focus on t(α) estimates for the postranking returns of the deciles with the best and worst past performance. We can report that when there is evidence of persistence, it decays quickly for less extreme deciles of the sorts. And when the extremes show no evidence of persistence, less extreme deciles support this inference. We examine α estimates for monthly returns for each of the first three months, the second, third, and fourth quarters, and the first, second, and third years after portfolio formation. We use a calendar-based approach to compute the returns for multi-month intervals. We first compute the EW and VW single-month returns in month t for portfolios formed each of the preceding 36 months. Each EW single-month return for month t equally weights the funds assigned to a portfolio in month t-k. The VW return for month t weights each fund by its assets under management when the portfolio is formed at the end of month t-k times its compounded (gross or net) return for the next k-1 months, AUM(t-k) * [1 + R(t-k+1)] * * [1 + R(t-1)]. The EW or VW month t return for a multi-month interval is the EW average of the month t returns for the portfolios formed during the interval. For example, the 1-to-12-month return in month t is an EW average of the (EW or VW) month t returns for the portfolios formed at the end of each of the preceding 12 months. 9

11 If fund managers consistently have private information, we do not expect much change in α estimates in the periods after portfolio formation. If there is evidence of performance but it decays toward zero, we infer either that (i) managers have only temporary access to information, or (ii) benchmark problems produce spurious but temporary α estimates, because, for example, funds by chance temporarily hold stocks whose expected returns do not conform well to the benchmark model. We limit the persistence tests to and to funds that reach the equivalent of five million 2006 dollars in assets under management (AUM) sometime before portfolio formation. For example, since the AUM minimum is in 2006 dollars, portfolios formed during 1984 include only funds that have reached about $2.5 million in AUM sometime before portfolio formation. Once a fund passes the AUM minimum, it is included in all subsequent tests, so this requirement does not create survivor bias. During about 15% of the funds on CRSP report only annual returns, and the average annual EW return for these funds is 5.29% lower than for funds that report monthly returns. As a result, the EW average return on all funds is a nontrivial 0.65% per year lower than the EW return of funds that report monthly returns. Thus, during there is a survival bias in tests (like our persistence tests) that use only funds that report monthly returns. (The problem is minor in VW returns because funds that report annual returns tend to be small.) After 1983 almost all funds report monthly returns. (See Elton, Gruber and Blake 2001 for a discussion of CRSP data problems for the period before 1984.) There is another survival bias that leads us to drop funds that have not reached $5 million AUM. Fund management companies commonly provide seed money to new funds to develop a return history. Funds are then opened to the public when their return histories turn out to be attractive. We have no reliable way to identify a fund s returns that are subject to this selection bias. The $5 million AUM bound for admission to the tests alleviates the problem since AUM is likely to be low during the pre-release period. A. Persistence Results for 12-Month Return Sorts Sorts on 12-month average return seem unattractive since an average for 12 months is an imprecise estimate of expected return. Part A of Table 3 shows, however, that when funds are sorted on the t-statistic of the average net-of-market gross return of the last 12 months, post-sort three-factor α is reliably positive for the 10

12 gross returns of the extreme decile of past winners and reliably negative for extreme losers, but only for six to nine months after portfolio formation. Much of this short-run persistence is likely due to momentum. As Carhart (1997) notes, the funds that perform best during the last 12 months are likely to hold more of the best performing stocks of that period, and the funds that have done poorly are likely to hold more of the stocks that have done poorly. Momentum (Jegadeesh and Titman 1993) then implies that the strong returns of recent winner funds and the poor returns of losers persist for a few months after portfolio formation. Carhart (1997) suggests that the momentum exposures of winner and loser funds are inadvertent and temporary. There is a simple test. If momentum exposure is part of a long-term investment strategy, we do not expect much change in four-factor MOM t slopes in the months after portfolio formation. But if momentum exposure is inadvertent and temporary, we expect that MOM t slopes move toward zero after portfolio formation. The momentum slopes in Part A of Table 3 support the temporary exposure story. All the MOM t slopes for the top decile of funds are positive in the first year after funds are sorted on past return, and all but one for the bottom decile are negative. But the MOM t slopes decay to values close to zero within a year, and actually switch sign from months 1-12 to months and Whether or not momentum tilts are intentional, controlling for momentum exposure with the fourfactor model shrinks the α estimates for the first year of post-sort returns. Four-factor α produces no evidence of persistence in the post-sort EW or VW gross returns of the worst performing funds. The α estimates for EW loser returns for post-sort months 1, 2, and 3 are -0.01%, 0.02%, and -0.01% per month, with tiny t-statistics. The four-factor model also absorbs the persistence in the VW post-sort returns of the best performing funds, but EW returns suggest that for smaller funds some temporary persistence remains. Although they decay quickly, the four-factor α estimates for the EW returns of last year s winners are 0.29%, (t = 3.36), 0.14% (t = 1.76), and 0.12% (t = 1.58) for post-sort months 1, 2, and 3, and 0.14% per month (t = 2.01) for months 4-6. B. Persistence Results for 60-Month Return Sorts If some funds have consistent access to information, ranking funds on a longer period of past returns should produce stronger evidence of persistence since average returns for longer periods are more precise estimates of expected return. Part B of Table 3 shows, however, that sorts of funds on the t-statistic for the 11

13 average net-of-market gross return of the last 60 months fail to produce stronger evidence of persistence than the 12-month sorts. Three-factor α estimates for post-ranking gross returns are almost always closer to zero in the 60-month sorts. The four-factor regressions explain why. Most of the persistence in three-factor α from sorts on 12-month return is due to transitory momentum exposure. The 60-month sorts also produce some post-sort momentum exposure, which again decays quickly. But initial post-sort exposure to momentum is weaker in the 60-month sorts. This is not surprising. Because momentum exposure is short-term, 12-month return sorts produce stronger exposures than 60-month sorts. All this is consistent with our inference that the momentum exposures of winner and loser funds are chance results rather than conscious strategy. In the sorts on 60-month average return, the four-factor post-ranking α estimates for EW gross returns for are positive for the winner decile and negative for the loser decile, but the α estimates are close to zero. For the winners, the four-factor α for the year after portfolio formation is 0.05% per month (t = 0.86), which is a faint hint that, after controlling for momentum, extreme winners have good information that enhances expected returns. For the EW loser decile, the four-factor α for the year after portfolio formation is -0.10% per month (t = -1.50), a hint that extreme losers have bad information that lowers expected returns. But even these weak hints apply primarily to smaller funds. Four-factor α for the year after portfolio formation is closer to zero in VW returns, 0.02% per month for winners and -0.05% for losers. All hints of persistence in the post-ranking momentum-adjusted gross returns of the extreme winners and losers of the last 60 months seem to be special to the early years of Part B of Table 3 shows that in EW and VW gross returns for , four-factor post-ranking α estimates for winners and losers are economically and statistically close to zero (for example, 0.00% per month, t = 0.05, for EW losers, and -0.03%, t = -0.36, for EW winners for the year after portfolio formation). Thus, if extreme winners and losers once had a bit of private information about stocks, access seems to have disappeared. C. Sorts on 60-Month Three-Factor α Estimates There is a case for sorting funds on α estimates, since (i) they are more precise than average returns and (ii) sorts on α estimates may focus better on the effects of information about individual stocks. But α sorts have a downside. They may in part focus on the benchmark model s problems in explaining the average 12

14 returns on some stocks (Carhart 1997). Part C of Table 3 shows results for sorts of funds on t-statistics for three-factor α estimates from 60 months of past gross returns. In the t(α) sorts for , post-ranking three-factor α estimates for the winner and loser deciles are typically more extreme than those from the sorts on 60 months of net-of-market returns. For example, the α for the EW decile of winners is 0.19% per month (t = 3.17) for the first year after funds are sorted on t(α) (Table 3 Part C), and only 0.09% (t = 1.40) in sorts on net-of-market average return (Table 3, Part B). Controlling for momentum with the four-factor model weakens the evidence of persistence a bit in the first year after portfolios are formed, but four-factor α estimates for EW returns remain reliably different from zero out to a year (longer for losers). Similar results are observed in unreported sorts on four-factor t(α). The stronger evidence of persistence when we sort on three-factor t(α) may indicate that past winner and loser funds have information about individual stocks that is uncovered better by these sorts than by sorts on average return. But it is also possible that α sorts just home in better on shortcomings of the three-factor model. This explanation seems attractive given that the persistence in the three-factor t(α) sorts for is largely due to smaller funds, which are likely to be less diversified. When we value-weight funds, the strong return persistence observed in post-ranking α estimates on EW loser returns disappears almost entirely, and persistence is also much weaker in VW winner returns. In any case, for current investment purposes, the issue may be moot. In tests for the more recent period (Part C of Table 3), the three-factor post-ranking α estimates from sorts on three-factor t(α) are closer to zero, and when we add a control for momentum, the α estimates are indistinguishable from zero for EW and VW fund returns. Thus, the return persistence identified in the three-factor t(α) sorts for is rather special to the early years of the period. E. Synopsis When we sort funds on t-statistics for market-adjusted average gross returns, there is persistence in returns, but it seems to be due to temporary and thus probably inadvertent momentum exposure. Controlling for momentum with the four-factor model eliminates most if not all persistence. Thus, sorts on past average gross returns suggest that funds do not have access to private information (good or bad) about stocks. 13

15 Average returns estimate expected returns without imposing a model for expected returns. In contrast, sorts on t(α) estimates from a benchmark model produce more precise estimates of expected returns left unexplained by the model, but they are more exposed to bad model problems. Our sorts on three-factor t(α) estimates from gross returns produce some evidence that, at least in the extremes, either (i) mutual fund managers have access to private information (bad information for losers and good for winners) or (ii) the sorts are subject to a bad model problem. The evidence of persistence is, however, special to the early years of and to smaller funds. In the results for , sorts on three-factor (or four-factor) t(α) estimates produce little evidence of persistence in VW fund returns, and in the results for , t(α) sorts produce little evidence of persistence in EW or VW fund returns. Gross returns (before fees and expenses) are more relevant than net returns for judging whether funds have any access to information. Net returns are better for judging whether investors get what they pay for, that is, whether managers produce expected returns that cover the costs they impose on investors. We have replicated the persistence tests on net returns. Skipping the details (available on request), we can report, not surprisingly, that net returns produce systematically lower post-sort α estimates than gross returns. When the four-factor model is used to evaluate performance, the persistence tests that use net returns produce no reliable evidence of funds with more than sufficient information to cover costs. There is, however, sometimes a power problem that leads to ambiguity about whether on average funds have sufficient private information to cover costs. Specifically, in the sorts on three-factor t(α) estimates on 60 months of past net returns, post-sort four-factor α estimates for the year after portfolio formation are -0.10% per month ( t = -1.42) for the VW losers and -0.08% (t = -0.98) for the VW winners, both quite close to average VW fees and expenses (about 0.08% per month). Thus, in VW net returns for , winners and losers underperform by about the amount of fees and expenses, which suggests that they have no access to private information. But average fees and expenses are similar to the standard errors of the α estimates. As a result, the four-factor α estimates for the VW returns of also do not allow us to reject the hypothesis that winners and losers have sufficient information to cover costs. For the winners this inference problem arises in the net return results for and , whether we use EW or VW 14

16 returns and whether we sort on t-statistics for market adjusted average returns or three-factor t(α) estimates. For the losers, the inference problem is specific to VW returns for and t(α) sorts. Otherwise, we can always reject the hypothesis that the losers have sufficient information to cover costs. If the VW net returns in the persistence sorts on t(α) for lead us to entertain the hypothesis that during this period funds in general have sufficient information to cover costs, the more powerful tests on overall fund returns in Table 2 are more relevant. For the EW and VW portfolios of all funds produce four-factor t(α) estimates for gross returns that are negative but within 1.21 standard errors of zero. In net returns the α estimates are lower by the amount of average fees and expenses, and they are more than 2.38 standard errors below zero. We can comfortably infer that during , indeed during all periods examined in Table 2, funds in aggregate do not have sufficient information to cover costs. Kosowski et al (2006) draw stronger positive conclusions about persistence in mutual fund returns. They focus on EW net returns for a period beginning in 1975 and on four-factor post-ranking α estimates from sorts on four-factor α. Sorts on three-factor t(α) produce the strongest results in our reported tests for , and our unreported results from sorts on four-factor t(α) are similar. Our evidence suggests that the inferences of Kosowski et al (2006) are special to time period, EW returns, and sorts on α. III. Bootstrap Simulations Persistence tests rank winners and losers based on short-term performance. We turn now to a simulation approach that uses longer return histories to infer the existence of superior and inferior managers. A. Setup The period for the simulations is , and we include funds only after they pass $5 million AUM. For perspective on the performance of funds of different sizes, we also show results for funds after they pass $250 million and $1 billion. Since we estimate benchmark regressions for each fund, we limit the tests to funds that have at least eight months of returns after they pass an AUM bound, so there is a bit of survival bias. To avoid having lots of new funds with short return histories, we only use funds that appear on CRSP at least five years before the end of our sample period. 15

17 The population data for the simulations are monthly benchmark-adjusted fund returns. Specifically, a fund s returns are measured net of its α estimate for the part of after the fund passes an AUM bound. For example, to compute three-factor-adjusted gross returns for a fund in the $5 million group, we estimate its three-factor α using its monthly gross returns for the part of the fund is in the $5 million group. We then subtract the estimated α from the fund s monthly returns. Thus, the fund s three-factor α is zero in the population of three-factor-adjusted gross returns for the $5 million sample used in the simulations. We calculate benchmark-adjusted returns for the three-factor and four-factor models, for gross and net returns, and for the three AUM bounds. The result is 12 sets of benchmark-adjusted returns (gross and net for two benchmarks and three AUM bounds). For each set, a fund s α is zero in the population of adjusted gross or net returns for that combination of benchmark model and AUM bound. A simulation run is a random sample with replacement of the calendar months of A simulation sample has 273 months (like January 1984 to September 2006). For each of the 12 sets of benchmark-adjusted returns, we estimate, fund by fund, the relevant (three-factor or four-factor) benchmark model on the simulation draw of months of adjusted returns for that benchmark, dropping funds that are in the simulation run for less than eight months. Each run thus produces 12 cross-sections of α estimates using the same random sample of months from 12 populations of adjusted fund returns that have the properties of actual fund returns, except that in each population of adjusted returns, the assumed benchmark model holds exactly (α is zero) for every fund. We do 10,000 simulation runs to produce 12 distributions of t-statistics, t(α), for a world in which true α is zero. We focus on t(α), rather than raw estimates of α, to control for differences in precision due to differences in residual variance and in the number of months funds are in a simulation run. A prime advantage of our simulation approach is that it mimics the joint distribution of fund returns. It thus captures all effects of the cross-correlation of fund returns on the distribution of t(α) estimates for funds. Because we jointly sample fund returns and explanatory returns we also capture all effects of (for example) correlated heteroscedasticity of the explanatory returns and disturbances of a benchmark model. Note, however, that except for funds that are in our tests for the entire period, a fund is likely to show up 16

18 in a simulation run for more or less than the number of months of it is on CRSP. This is not serious since we focus on t(α) estimates and the distribution of t(α) depends on the number of months a fund is in a simulation run only through the degrees of freedom effect. Note also that the information effects built into the simulations are different for gross and net returns. For gross returns, setting true α equal to zero simulates a world where no fund has private information. In contrast, setting true α equal to zero for net returns simulates a world where all funds have information sufficient to generate expected returns that cover the costs imposed on investors. To develop perspective on the simulations, we first compare, in qualitative terms, the percentiles of the cross-section of t(α) estimates from actual fund returns and the average values from the simulations. We then turn to formal inferences about information effects in the tails of the cross-section of t(α). B. First Impressions Net Returns When we estimate a benchmark model on the actual returns of each fund in an AUM group, we get a cross-section of t(α) estimates that can be ordered into a cumulative distribution function (CDF) of t(α) estimates for actual fund returns. A simulation run for the same combination of benchmark model and AUM group also produces a cross-section of t(α) estimates and its CDF for a world in which true α is zero. In our initial examination of the simulations we compare (i) the values of t(α) at selected percentiles of the CDF of t(α) estimates from actual fund returns and (ii) the averages across the 10,000 simulation runs of the t(α) estimates at the same percentiles. For example, the first percentile of three-factor t(α) estimates for the net returns of funds in the $5 million AUM group is -3.92, versus an average first percentile of from the 10,000 three-factor simulation runs for the net returns of funds in this group (Table 4). For each combination of gross or net returns, AUM group, and benchmark model, Table 4 shows the CDFs of t(α) estimates for actual returns and the average of the 10,000 simulation CDFs. The average simulation CDFs are quite similar for gross and net returns and for the two benchmark models. This is not surprising given that true α is always zero in the simulations. Note, however, that the dispersion of the average simulation CDFs decreases a bit from lower to higher AUM groups. This is at least in part a degrees of freedom effect. All $1 billion funds are also $5 million and $250 million funds, but lots of funds in lower 17

19 AUM groups die without reaching higher AUM groups. As a result, smaller funds have shorter average sample periods. Differences in the cross-correlations of fund returns may also play a role in the lower dispersion of the average simulation CDFs of the larger AUM groups. The hypothesis that mutual funds have sufficient information to generate expected returns that cover costs fares poorly in Table 4. For every combination of benchmark model and AUM group, the CDF of the cross-section of t(α) estimates from actual net fund returns is entirely to the left of the average CDF from the simulations. In other words, the average percentile values of t(α) from the simulations of net fund returns (in which, by construction, funds have sufficient information to generate expected returns that cover costs) always beat (are larger than) the corresponding percentile values of t(α) for actual net fund returns. This evidence does not rule out the existence of some funds with information sufficient to cover costs, but it is a strong hint that formal tests (discussed later) are unlikely to produce this positive inference. Gross Returns It is possible that the fruits of information do not show up in net fund returns because they are absorbed by fees and expenses. Gross returns provide more direct evidence on whether fund managers have any information that is not reflected in prices. Adding back fees and expenses (inevitably) pushes t(α) for actual fund returns toward higher values. But Table 4 shows that for all three AUM groups, the left tail of the CDF of three-factor t(α) estimates for actual gross returns is still to the left of the average from the simulations. For example, the simulations say that in the absence of private information, on average the fifth percentile of t(α) for gross returns for the $5 million group is -1.85, but the actual fifth percentile is lower, Thus, the left tails of the CDFs of t(α) suggest that there are misinformed active managers with poor information. Conversely, the right tails of the CDFs of three-factor t(α) hint at the existence of active managers with good information. For the $5 million AUM group, the CDF of t(α) estimates for actual gross fund returns moves to the right of the average from the simulations between the 60 th and 70 th percentiles. For example, on average the 95 th percentile of t(α) estimates for funds in the $5 million group is 1.88 in the simulations, but the actual 95 th percentile is slightly higher, For the two larger AUM groups the crossovers occur at higher percentiles, around the 80 th for the $250 million group and the 95 th for the $1 billion group. 18

20 In short, comparing the CDFs of three-factor t(α) estimates for actual gross fund returns with the average CDFs from the simulations suggests the existence of both the informed and the misinformed active investors of Fama and French (2007). The underperformance in the left tail of t(α) is, however, typically more extreme than the overperformance in the right tail. For example, the 5 th percentile of the cross-section of threefactor t(α) estimates for the actual gross returns of funds in the $5 million group is 0.33 standard errors below the average from the simulations, but the 95 th percentile for actual fund returns is only 0.10 standard errors above the simulation average. The four-factor results for gross returns in Table 4 are similar to the three-factor results, with an interesting nuance. Adding a control for momentum exposure tends to shrink slightly the left and right tails of the cross-sections of t(α) for actual fund returns. This is consistent with what we saw in the persistence tests; that is, funds with negative three-factor α tend to have negative MOM t exposure and those with positive threefactor α tend to have positive exposure. Controlling for momentum pulls the α estimates toward zero. This shrinkage effect is small but at least at the at the 99 th percentile of t(α) estimates it suffices to kill the systematic advantage of the t(α) estimates for actual fund returns over the averages from the simulations. Finally, the simulation distributions of t(α) are fat-tailed. The average simulation distribution of t(α) for the $5 million group (our full sample) is like a t distribution with eight degrees of freedom. Since every α estimate uses at least eight observations and most use many more, we can conclude that the simulation distributions of t(α) are more fat-tailed than can be explained by degrees of freedom. This suggests that properties of the joint distribution of fund returns and of fund and factor returns have important effects on the cross-section of α estimates a comment of some import in our later discussion of Kosowski et al (2006). C. Formal Tests Comparing the percentiles of t(α) estimates for actual fund returns with the simulation averages gives hints about where there may be information effects. Table 4 also provides likelihood statements, in particular, the fractions of the 10,000 simulation runs that produce lower values of t(α) at selected percentiles than actual fund returns. These likelihoods allow us to judge more formally whether the tails of the cross-section of t(α) estimates for actual fund returns are extreme relative to what we observe when true α is zero. 19

Dissecting Anomalies. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French. Abstract

Dissecting Anomalies. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French. Abstract First draft: February 2006 This draft: June 2006 Please do not quote or circulate Dissecting Anomalies Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French Abstract Previous work finds that net stock issues, accruals,

More information

Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance: Analysis of Holdings Returns

Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance: Analysis of Holdings Returns Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance: Analysis of Holdings Returns Samuel Kruger * June 2007 Abstract: Do mutual funds that performed well in the past select stocks that perform well in the future? I

More information

15 Week 5b Mutual Funds

15 Week 5b Mutual Funds 15 Week 5b Mutual Funds 15.1 Background 1. It would be natural, and completely sensible, (and good marketing for MBA programs) if funds outperform darts! Pros outperform in any other field. 2. Except for...

More information

Volatility Lessons Eugene F. Fama a and Kenneth R. French b, Stock returns are volatile. For July 1963 to December 2016 (henceforth ) the

Volatility Lessons Eugene F. Fama a and Kenneth R. French b, Stock returns are volatile. For July 1963 to December 2016 (henceforth ) the First draft: March 2016 This draft: May 2018 Volatility Lessons Eugene F. Fama a and Kenneth R. French b, Abstract The average monthly premium of the Market return over the one-month T-Bill return is substantial,

More information

Dissecting Anomalies EUGENE F. FAMA AND KENNETH R. FRENCH ABSTRACT

Dissecting Anomalies EUGENE F. FAMA AND KENNETH R. FRENCH ABSTRACT Dissecting Anomalies EUGENE F. FAMA AND KENNETH R. FRENCH ABSTRACT The anomalous returns associated with net stock issues, accruals, and momentum are pervasive; they show up in all size groups (micro,

More information

Monthly Holdings Data and the Selection of Superior Mutual Funds + Edwin J. Elton* Martin J. Gruber*

Monthly Holdings Data and the Selection of Superior Mutual Funds + Edwin J. Elton* Martin J. Gruber* Monthly Holdings Data and the Selection of Superior Mutual Funds + Edwin J. Elton* (eelton@stern.nyu.edu) Martin J. Gruber* (mgruber@stern.nyu.edu) Christopher R. Blake** (cblake@fordham.edu) July 2, 2007

More information

The evaluation of the performance of UK American unit trusts

The evaluation of the performance of UK American unit trusts International Review of Economics and Finance 8 (1999) 455 466 The evaluation of the performance of UK American unit trusts Jonathan Fletcher* Department of Finance and Accounting, Glasgow Caledonian University,

More information

Modern Fool s Gold: Alpha in Recessions

Modern Fool s Gold: Alpha in Recessions T H E J O U R N A L O F THEORY & PRACTICE FOR FUND MANAGERS FALL 2012 Volume 21 Number 3 Modern Fool s Gold: Alpha in Recessions SHAUN A. PFEIFFER AND HAROLD R. EVENSKY The Voices of Influence iijournals.com

More information

MUTUAL FUND PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS PRE AND POST FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 2008

MUTUAL FUND PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS PRE AND POST FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 2008 MUTUAL FUND PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS PRE AND POST FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 2008 by Asadov, Elvin Bachelor of Science in International Economics, Management and Finance, 2015 and Dinger, Tim Bachelor of Business

More information

Bayesian Alphas and Mutual Fund Persistence. Jeffrey A. Busse. Paul J. Irvine * February Abstract

Bayesian Alphas and Mutual Fund Persistence. Jeffrey A. Busse. Paul J. Irvine * February Abstract Bayesian Alphas and Mutual Fund Persistence Jeffrey A. Busse Paul J. Irvine * February 00 Abstract Using daily returns, we find that Bayesian alphas predict future mutual fund Sharpe ratios significantly

More information

Can Norwegian Mutual Fund Managers Pick Stocks?

Can Norwegian Mutual Fund Managers Pick Stocks? Can Norwegian Mutual Fund Managers Pick Stocks? SUPERVISOR Valeriy Zakamulin MORTEN BLØRSTAD AND BJØRN OTTO BAKKEJORD This master s thesis is carried out as part of the education at the University of Agder

More information

On luck versus skill when performance benchmarks are style-consistent

On luck versus skill when performance benchmarks are style-consistent On luck versus skill when performance benchmarks are style-consistent Andrew Mason a, Sam Agyei-Ampomah b, Andrew Clare c, Stephen Thomas c a Surrey Business School, University of Surrey, Guildford GU2

More information

Discussion Paper No. DP 07/02

Discussion Paper No. DP 07/02 SCHOOL OF ACCOUNTING, FINANCE AND MANAGEMENT Essex Finance Centre Can the Cross-Section Variation in Expected Stock Returns Explain Momentum George Bulkley University of Exeter Vivekanand Nawosah University

More information

Sector Fund Performance

Sector Fund Performance Sector Fund Performance Ashish TIWARI and Anand M. VIJH Henry B. Tippie College of Business University of Iowa, Iowa City, IA 52242-1000 ABSTRACT Sector funds have grown into a nearly quarter-trillion

More information

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach Hossein Asgharian and Björn Hansson Department of Economics, Lund University Box 7082 S-22007 Lund, Sweden

More information

A test of momentum strategies in funded pension systems - the case of Sweden. Tomas Sorensson*

A test of momentum strategies in funded pension systems - the case of Sweden. Tomas Sorensson* A test of momentum strategies in funded pension systems - the case of Sweden Tomas Sorensson* This draft: January, 2013 Acknowledgement: I would like to thank Mikael Andersson and Jonas Murman for excellent

More information

Reconcilable Differences: Momentum Trading by Institutions

Reconcilable Differences: Momentum Trading by Institutions Reconcilable Differences: Momentum Trading by Institutions Richard W. Sias * March 15, 2005 * Department of Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate, College of Business and Economics, Washington State University,

More information

The cross section of expected stock returns

The cross section of expected stock returns The cross section of expected stock returns Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER This version: March 2013 First draft: October 2010 Tel: 603-646-8650; email: jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu. I am grateful

More information

Alternative Benchmarks for Evaluating Mutual Fund Performance

Alternative Benchmarks for Evaluating Mutual Fund Performance 2010 V38 1: pp. 121 154 DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6229.2009.00253.x REAL ESTATE ECONOMICS Alternative Benchmarks for Evaluating Mutual Fund Performance Jay C. Hartzell, Tobias Mühlhofer and Sheridan D. Titman

More information

How to measure mutual fund performance: economic versus statistical relevance

How to measure mutual fund performance: economic versus statistical relevance Accounting and Finance 44 (2004) 203 222 How to measure mutual fund performance: economic versus statistical relevance Blackwell Oxford, ACFI Accounting 0810-5391 AFAANZ, 44 2ORIGINAL R. Otten, UK D. Publishing,

More information

VOLUME 40 NUMBER 2 WINTER The Voices of Influence iijournals.com

VOLUME 40 NUMBER 2  WINTER The Voices of Influence iijournals.com VOLUME 40 NUMBER 2 www.iijpm.com WINTER 2014 The Voices of Influence iijournals.com Can Alpha Be Captured by Risk Premia? JENNIFER BENDER, P. BRETT HAMMOND, AND WILLIAM MOK JENNIFER BENDER is managing

More information

Department of Finance Working Paper Series

Department of Finance Working Paper Series NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LEONARD N. STERN SCHOOL OF BUSINESS Department of Finance Working Paper Series FIN-03-005 Does Mutual Fund Performance Vary over the Business Cycle? Anthony W. Lynch, Jessica Wachter

More information

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2012 The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Abdullah Al Masud Utah State University

More information

The Equity Premium. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract

The Equity Premium. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract First draft: March 2000 This draft: July 2000 Not for quotation Comments solicited The Equity Premium Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract We compare estimates of the equity premium for 1872-1999

More information

Swedish Equity Mutual Funds : Performance, Persistence and Presence of Skill

Swedish Equity Mutual Funds : Performance, Persistence and Presence of Skill Separate Title Page Swedish Equity Mutual Funds 1993-2013: Performance, Persistence and Presence of Skill Harry Flam a, Roine Vestman b a Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm University,

More information

Focused Funds How Do They Perform in Comparison with More Diversified Funds? A Study on Swedish Mutual Funds. Master Thesis NEKN

Focused Funds How Do They Perform in Comparison with More Diversified Funds? A Study on Swedish Mutual Funds. Master Thesis NEKN Focused Funds How Do They Perform in Comparison with More Diversified Funds? A Study on Swedish Mutual Funds Master Thesis NEKN01 2014-06-03 Supervisor: Birger Nilsson Author: Zakarias Bergstrand Table

More information

The Value Premium and the January Effect

The Value Premium and the January Effect The Value Premium and the January Effect Julia Chou, Praveen Kumar Das * Current Version: January 2010 * Chou is from College of Business Administration, Florida International University, Miami, FL 33199;

More information

Temporary movements in stock prices

Temporary movements in stock prices Temporary movements in stock prices Jonathan Lewellen MIT Sloan School of Management 50 Memorial Drive E52-436, Cambridge, MA 02142 (617) 258-8408 lewellen@mit.edu First draft: August 2000 Current version:

More information

Behind the Scenes of Mutual Fund Alpha

Behind the Scenes of Mutual Fund Alpha Behind the Scenes of Mutual Fund Alpha Qiang Bu Penn State University-Harrisburg This study examines whether fund alpha exists and whether it comes from manager skill. We found that the probability and

More information

New Zealand Mutual Fund Performance

New Zealand Mutual Fund Performance New Zealand Mutual Fund Performance Rob Bauer ABP Investments and Maastricht University Limburg Institute of Financial Economics Maastricht University P.O. Box 616 6200 MD Maastricht The Netherlands Phone:

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

New Evidence on Mutual Fund Performance: A Comparison of Alternative Bootstrap Methods. David Blake* Tristan Caulfield** Christos Ioannidis*** And

New Evidence on Mutual Fund Performance: A Comparison of Alternative Bootstrap Methods. David Blake* Tristan Caulfield** Christos Ioannidis*** And New Evidence on Mutual Fund Performance: A Comparison of Alternative Bootstrap Methods David Blake* Tristan Caulfield** Christos Ioannidis*** And Ian Tonks**** October 2015 Forthcoming Journal of Financial

More information

HOW TO GENERATE ABNORMAL RETURNS.

HOW TO GENERATE ABNORMAL RETURNS. STOCKHOLM SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS Bachelor Thesis in Finance, Spring 2010 HOW TO GENERATE ABNORMAL RETURNS. An evaluation of how two famous trading strategies worked during the last two decades. HENRIK MELANDER

More information

Industry Concentration and Mutual Fund Performance

Industry Concentration and Mutual Fund Performance Industry Concentration and Mutual Fund Performance MARCIN KACPERCZYK CLEMENS SIALM LU ZHENG May 2006 Forthcoming: Journal of Investment Management ABSTRACT: We study the relation between the industry concentration

More information

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios RESEARCH Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios March 2016 Wei Dai, PhD Research The predictability of expected stock returns is an old topic and an important one. While investors may increase expected returns

More information

International Journal of Management Sciences and Business Research, 2013 ISSN ( ) Vol-2, Issue 12

International Journal of Management Sciences and Business Research, 2013 ISSN ( ) Vol-2, Issue 12 Momentum and industry-dependence: the case of Shanghai stock exchange market. Author Detail: Dongbei University of Finance and Economics, Liaoning, Dalian, China Salvio.Elias. Macha Abstract A number of

More information

Smart Beta #

Smart Beta # Smart Beta This information is provided for registered investment advisors and institutional investors and is not intended for public use. Dimensional Fund Advisors LP is an investment advisor registered

More information

Do Indian Mutual funds with high risk adjusted returns show more stability during an Economic downturn?

Do Indian Mutual funds with high risk adjusted returns show more stability during an Economic downturn? Do Indian Mutual funds with high risk adjusted returns show more stability during an Economic downturn? Kalpakam. G, Faculty Finance, KJ Somaiya Institute of management Studies & Research, Mumbai. India.

More information

Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds. Kevin C.H. Chiang*

Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds. Kevin C.H. Chiang* Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds Kevin C.H. Chiang* School of Management University of Alaska Fairbanks Fairbanks, AK 99775 Kirill Kozhevnikov

More information

in Mutual Fund Performance On Persistence

in Mutual Fund Performance On Persistence THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE. VOL. LII, NO. 1. MARCH 1997 On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance MARK M. CARHART* ABSTRACT Using a sample free of survivor bias, I demonstrate that common factors in stock

More information

Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower Propensity to Pay? Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French

Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower Propensity to Pay? Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French Center for Research in Security Prices Working Paper No. 509 Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower Propensity to Pay? Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French First draft: July 1998

More information

Changes in Analysts' Recommendations and Abnormal Returns. Qiming Sun. Bachelor of Commerce, University of Calgary, 2011.

Changes in Analysts' Recommendations and Abnormal Returns. Qiming Sun. Bachelor of Commerce, University of Calgary, 2011. Changes in Analysts' Recommendations and Abnormal Returns By Qiming Sun Bachelor of Commerce, University of Calgary, 2011 Yuhang Zhang Bachelor of Economics, Capital Unv of Econ and Bus, 2011 RESEARCH

More information

additional cost to stock-picking.

additional cost to stock-picking. Neglected risks in mutual fund performance measurement: An additional cost to stock-picking. Justus Heuer Version 1 - November 2012 Abstract This paper takes a closer look at utility based performance

More information

14 Week 4b Mutual Funds

14 Week 4b Mutual Funds 14 Week 4b Mutual Funds 14.1 Background 1. It would be natural, and completely sensible, (and good marketing for MBA programs) if funds outperform darts! Pros outperform in any other field. 2. Except for...

More information

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru i Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE 2012 ii Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru (B.Sc National University

More information

1 Funds and Performance Evaluation

1 Funds and Performance Evaluation Histogram Cumulative Return 1 Funds and Performance Evaluation 1.1 Carhart 1 Return history.8.6.4.2.2.4.6.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5 Years 25 Distribution of survivor's 5 year returns True Sample 2 15

More information

The performance of mutual funds on French stock market:do star funds managers exist or do funds have to hire chimpanzees?

The performance of mutual funds on French stock market:do star funds managers exist or do funds have to hire chimpanzees? MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The performance of mutual funds on French stock market:do star funds managers exist or do funds have to hire chimpanzees? Michel Blanchard and philippe Bernard INALCO,

More information

Great Company, Great Investment Revisited. Gary Smith. Fletcher Jones Professor. Department of Economics. Pomona College. 425 N.

Great Company, Great Investment Revisited. Gary Smith. Fletcher Jones Professor. Department of Economics. Pomona College. 425 N. !1 Great Company, Great Investment Revisited Gary Smith Fletcher Jones Professor Department of Economics Pomona College 425 N. College Avenue Claremont CA 91711 gsmith@pomona.edu !2 Great Company, Great

More information

Risk adjusted performance measurement of the stock-picking within the GPFG 1

Risk adjusted performance measurement of the stock-picking within the GPFG 1 Risk adjusted performance measurement of the stock-picking within the GPFG 1 Risk adjusted performance measurement of the stock-picking-activity in the Norwegian Government Pension Fund Global Halvor Hoddevik

More information

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009 Long Chen Washington University in St. Louis Fresh Momentum Engin Kose Washington University in St. Louis First version: October 2009 Ohad Kadan Washington University in St. Louis Abstract We demonstrate

More information

Active portfolios: diversification across trading strategies

Active portfolios: diversification across trading strategies Computational Finance and its Applications III 119 Active portfolios: diversification across trading strategies C. Murray Goldman Sachs and Co., New York, USA Abstract Several characteristics of a firm

More information

Economics of Behavioral Finance. Lecture 3

Economics of Behavioral Finance. Lecture 3 Economics of Behavioral Finance Lecture 3 Security Market Line CAPM predicts a linear relationship between a stock s Beta and its excess return. E[r i ] r f = β i E r m r f Practically, testing CAPM empirically

More information

Portfolio performance and environmental risk

Portfolio performance and environmental risk Portfolio performance and environmental risk Rickard Olsson 1 Umeå School of Business Umeå University SE-90187, Sweden Email: rickard.olsson@usbe.umu.se Sustainable Investment Research Platform Working

More information

Does fund size erode mutual fund performance?

Does fund size erode mutual fund performance? Erasmus School of Economics, Erasmus University Rotterdam Does fund size erode mutual fund performance? An estimation of the relationship between fund size and fund performance In this paper I try to find

More information

Industry Indices in Event Studies. Joseph M. Marks Bentley University, AAC Forest Street Waltham, MA

Industry Indices in Event Studies. Joseph M. Marks Bentley University, AAC Forest Street Waltham, MA Industry Indices in Event Studies Joseph M. Marks Bentley University, AAC 273 175 Forest Street Waltham, MA 02452-4705 jmarks@bentley.edu Jim Musumeci* Bentley University, 107 Morrison 175 Forest Street

More information

Ulaş ÜNLÜ Assistant Professor, Department of Accounting and Finance, Nevsehir University, Nevsehir / Turkey.

Ulaş ÜNLÜ Assistant Professor, Department of Accounting and Finance, Nevsehir University, Nevsehir / Turkey. Size, Book to Market Ratio and Momentum Strategies: Evidence from Istanbul Stock Exchange Ersan ERSOY* Assistant Professor, Faculty of Economics and Administrative Sciences, Department of Business Administration,

More information

ONLINE APPENDIX. Do Individual Currency Traders Make Money?

ONLINE APPENDIX. Do Individual Currency Traders Make Money? ONLINE APPENDIX Do Individual Currency Traders Make Money? 5.7 Robustness Checks with Second Data Set The performance results from the main data set, presented in Panel B of Table 2, show that the top

More information

The Puzzle of Frequent and Large Issues of Debt and Equity

The Puzzle of Frequent and Large Issues of Debt and Equity The Puzzle of Frequent and Large Issues of Debt and Equity Rongbing Huang and Jay R. Ritter This Draft: October 23, 2018 ABSTRACT More frequent, larger, and more recent debt and equity issues in the prior

More information

Performance persistence and management skill in nonconventional bond mutual funds

Performance persistence and management skill in nonconventional bond mutual funds Financial Services Review 9 (2000) 247 258 Performance persistence and management skill in nonconventional bond mutual funds James Philpot a, Douglas Hearth b, *, James Rimbey b a Frank D. Hickingbotham

More information

Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns

Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns Wei Huang, Qianqiu Liu, S.Ghon Rhee and Liang Zhang Shidler College of Business University of Hawaii at Manoa 2404 Maile Way Honolulu, Hawaii,

More information

Journal of Financial Economics

Journal of Financial Economics Journal of Financial Economics 102 (2011) 62 80 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Financial Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jfec Institutional investors and the limits

More information

An Examination of Mutual Fund Timing Ability Using Monthly Holdings Data. Edwin J. Elton*, Martin J. Gruber*, and Christopher R.

An Examination of Mutual Fund Timing Ability Using Monthly Holdings Data. Edwin J. Elton*, Martin J. Gruber*, and Christopher R. An Examination of Mutual Fund Timing Ability Using Monthly Holdings Data Edwin J. Elton*, Martin J. Gruber*, and Christopher R. Blake** February 7, 2011 * Nomura Professor of Finance, Stern School of Business,

More information

An Assessment of Managerial Skill based on Cross-Sectional Mutual Fund Performance

An Assessment of Managerial Skill based on Cross-Sectional Mutual Fund Performance An Assessment of Managerial Skill based on Cross-Sectional Mutual Fund Performance Ilhan Demiralp Price College of Business, University of Oklahoma 307 West Brooks St., Norman, OK 73019, USA Tel.: (405)

More information

EMPIRICAL STUDY ON STOCK'S CAPITAL RETURNS DISTRIBUTION AND FUTURE PERFORMANCE

EMPIRICAL STUDY ON STOCK'S CAPITAL RETURNS DISTRIBUTION AND FUTURE PERFORMANCE Clemson University TigerPrints All Theses Theses 5-2013 EMPIRICAL STUDY ON STOCK'S CAPITAL RETURNS DISTRIBUTION AND FUTURE PERFORMANCE Han Liu Clemson University, hliu2@clemson.edu Follow this and additional

More information

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr.

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr. The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving James P. Dow, Jr. Department of Finance, Real Estate and Insurance California State University, Northridge

More information

"Does It Pay to Be Informed?" Expenditure Efficiency in the US Mutual Fund Industry

Does It Pay to Be Informed? Expenditure Efficiency in the US Mutual Fund Industry Gettysburg Economic Review Volume 5 Article 5 2011 "Does It Pay to Be Informed?" Expenditure Efficiency in the US Mutual Fund Industry Jan Cerny Gettysburg College Class of 2011 Follow this and additional

More information

On the Use of Multifactor Models to Evaluate Mutual Fund Performance

On the Use of Multifactor Models to Evaluate Mutual Fund Performance On the Use of Multifactor Models to Evaluate Mutual Fund Performance Joop Huij and Marno Verbeek * We show that multifactor performance estimates for mutual funds suffer from systematic biases, and argue

More information

On the robustness of the CAPM, Fama-French Three-Factor Model and the Carhart Four-Factor Model on the Dutch stock market.

On the robustness of the CAPM, Fama-French Three-Factor Model and the Carhart Four-Factor Model on the Dutch stock market. Tilburg University 2014 Bachelor Thesis in Finance On the robustness of the CAPM, Fama-French Three-Factor Model and the Carhart Four-Factor Model on the Dutch stock market. Name: Humberto Levarht y Lopez

More information

New Lists and Seasoned Firms: Fundamentals and Survival Rates. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract

New Lists and Seasoned Firms: Fundamentals and Survival Rates. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract First Draft: March 2001 Revised: July 2002 Not for quotation Comments solicited New Lists and Seasoned Firms: Fundamentals and Survival Rates Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract The class of

More information

Do hedge funds exhibit performance persistence? A new approach

Do hedge funds exhibit performance persistence? A new approach Do hedge funds exhibit performance persistence? A new approach Nicole M. Boyson * October, 2003 Abstract Motivated by prior work that documents a negative relationship between manager experience (tenure)

More information

The Smart Money Effect: Retail versus Institutional Mutual Funds

The Smart Money Effect: Retail versus Institutional Mutual Funds The Smart Money Effect: Retail versus Institutional Mutual Funds Galla Salganik ABSTRACT Do sophisticated investors exhibit a stronger smart money effect than unsophisticated ones? In this paper, we examine

More information

Yale ICF Working Paper No February 2002 DO WINNERS REPEAT WITH STYLE?

Yale ICF Working Paper No February 2002 DO WINNERS REPEAT WITH STYLE? Yale ICF Working Paper No. 00-70 February 2002 DO WINNERS REPEAT WITH STYLE? Roger G. Ibbotson Yale School of Mangement Amita K. Patel Ibbotson Associates This paper can be downloaded without charge from

More information

How Good Are Analysts at Handling Crisis? - A Study of Analyst Recommendations on the Nordic Stock Exchanges during the Great Recession

How Good Are Analysts at Handling Crisis? - A Study of Analyst Recommendations on the Nordic Stock Exchanges during the Great Recession Stockholm School of Economics Department of Finance Bachelor s Thesis Spring 2014 How Good Are Analysts at Handling Crisis? - A Study of Analyst Recommendations on the Nordic Stock Exchanges during the

More information

Value Stocks and Accounting Screens: Has a Good Rule Gone Bad?

Value Stocks and Accounting Screens: Has a Good Rule Gone Bad? Value Stocks and Accounting Screens: Has a Good Rule Gone Bad? Melissa K. Woodley Samford University Steven T. Jones Samford University James P. Reburn Samford University We find that the financial statement

More information

The Adequacy of Investment Choices Offered By 401K Plans. Edwin J. Elton* Martin J. Gruber* Christopher R. Blake**

The Adequacy of Investment Choices Offered By 401K Plans. Edwin J. Elton* Martin J. Gruber* Christopher R. Blake** The Adequacy of Investment Choices Offered By 401K Plans Edwin J. Elton* Martin J. Gruber* Christopher R. Blake** * Nomora Professors of Finance, New York University ** Professor of Finance, Fordham University

More information

Problem Set 6. I did this with figure; bar3(reshape(mean(rx),5,5) );ylabel( size ); xlabel( value ); mean mo return %

Problem Set 6. I did this with figure; bar3(reshape(mean(rx),5,5) );ylabel( size ); xlabel( value ); mean mo return % Business 35905 John H. Cochrane Problem Set 6 We re going to replicate and extend Fama and French s basic results, using earlier and extended data. Get the 25 Fama French portfolios and factors from the

More information

One Brief Shining Moment(um): Past Momentum Performance and Momentum Reversals

One Brief Shining Moment(um): Past Momentum Performance and Momentum Reversals One Brief Shining Moment(um): Past Momentum Performance and Momentum Reversals Usman Ali, Kent Daniel, and David Hirshleifer Preliminary Draft: May 15, 2017 This Draft: December 27, 2017 Abstract Following

More information

Volume 36, Issue 1. Aneel Keswani Cass Business School

Volume 36, Issue 1. Aneel Keswani Cass Business School Volume 36, Issue 1 UK fund returns and sector diversification Aneel Keswani Cass Business School David Stolin University of Toulouse, Toulouse Business School Maxim Zagonov University of Toulouse, Toulouse

More information

A Portrait of Hedge Fund Investors: Flows, Performance and Smart Money

A Portrait of Hedge Fund Investors: Flows, Performance and Smart Money A Portrait of Hedge Fund Investors: Flows, Performance and Smart Money Guillermo Baquero and Marno Verbeek RSM Erasmus University Rotterdam, The Netherlands mverbeek@rsm.nl www.surf.to/marno.verbeek FRB

More information

Diversified or Concentrated Factors What are the Investment Beliefs Behind these two Smart Beta Approaches?

Diversified or Concentrated Factors What are the Investment Beliefs Behind these two Smart Beta Approaches? Diversified or Concentrated Factors What are the Investment Beliefs Behind these two Smart Beta Approaches? Noël Amenc, PhD Professor of Finance, EDHEC Risk Institute CEO, ERI Scientific Beta Eric Shirbini,

More information

The Volatility of Mutual Fund Performance

The Volatility of Mutual Fund Performance The Volatility of Mutual Fund Performance Miles Livingston University of Florida Department of Finance Gainesville, FL 32611-7168 miles.livingston@warrrington.ufl.edu Lei Zhou Northern Illinois University

More information

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly Online Appendix Section I provides details of the calculation of the variables used in the paper. Section II examines the robustness of the beta anomaly.

More information

Swedish Equity Mutual Funds : Performance, Persistence and Presence of Skill

Swedish Equity Mutual Funds : Performance, Persistence and Presence of Skill 6713 2017 October 2017 Swedish Equity Mutual Funds 1993-2013: Performance, Persistence and Presence of Skill Harry Flam, Roine Vestman Impressum: CESifo Working Papers ISSN 2364 1428 (electronic version)

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

Risk Taking and Performance of Bond Mutual Funds

Risk Taking and Performance of Bond Mutual Funds Risk Taking and Performance of Bond Mutual Funds Lilian Ng, Crystal X. Wang, and Qinghai Wang This Version: March 2015 Ng is from the Schulich School of Business, York University, Canada; Wang and Wang

More information

PERSISTENCE IN NEW ZEALAND GROWTH MUTUAL FUNDS RETURNS: An Examination of New Zealand Mutual Funds from

PERSISTENCE IN NEW ZEALAND GROWTH MUTUAL FUNDS RETURNS: An Examination of New Zealand Mutual Funds from Indian Journal of Economics & Business, Vol. 9, No. 2, (2010) : 303-314 PERSISTENCE IN NEW ZEALAND GROWTH MUTUAL FUNDS RETURNS: An Examination of New Zealand Mutual Funds from 1997-2003 AMITABH S. DUTTA

More information

A Comparative Simulation Study of Fund Performance Measures

A Comparative Simulation Study of Fund Performance Measures A Comparative Simulation Study of Fund Performance Measures Shafiqur Rahman School of Business Administration Portland State University Portland, Oregon 97207-0751 Shahidur Rahman Department of Economics

More information

Using Pitman Closeness to Compare Stock Return Models

Using Pitman Closeness to Compare Stock Return Models International Journal of Business and Social Science Vol. 5, No. 9(1); August 2014 Using Pitman Closeness to Compare Stock Return s Victoria Javine Department of Economics, Finance, & Legal Studies University

More information

Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis

Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2015 Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis Seth E. Williams Utah State University

More information

It is well known that equity returns are

It is well known that equity returns are DING LIU is an SVP and senior quantitative analyst at AllianceBernstein in New York, NY. ding.liu@bernstein.com Pure Quintile Portfolios DING LIU It is well known that equity returns are driven to a large

More information

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power? International Journal of Business and Management; Vol. 9, No. 9; 2014 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really

More information

Some Features of the Three- and Four- -factor Models for the Selected Portfolios of the Stocks Listed on the Warsaw Stock Exchange,

Some Features of the Three- and Four- -factor Models for the Selected Portfolios of the Stocks Listed on the Warsaw Stock Exchange, Some Features of the Three- and Four- -factor Models for the Selected Portfolios of the Stocks Listed on the Warsaw Stock Exchange, 2003 2007 Wojciech Grabowski, Konrad Rotuski, Department of Banking and

More information

BEYOND SMART BETA: WHAT IS GLOBAL MULTI-FACTOR INVESTING AND HOW DOES IT WORK?

BEYOND SMART BETA: WHAT IS GLOBAL MULTI-FACTOR INVESTING AND HOW DOES IT WORK? INVESTING INSIGHTS BEYOND SMART BETA: WHAT IS GLOBAL MULTI-FACTOR INVESTING AND HOW DOES IT WORK? Multi-Factor investing works by identifying characteristics, or factors, of stocks or other securities

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 2: Factor models and the cross-section of stock returns Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Next week (30

More information

Does Book-to-Market Equity Proxy for Distress Risk or Overreaction? John M. Griffin and Michael L. Lemmon *

Does Book-to-Market Equity Proxy for Distress Risk or Overreaction? John M. Griffin and Michael L. Lemmon * Does Book-to-Market Equity Proxy for Distress Risk or Overreaction? by John M. Griffin and Michael L. Lemmon * December 2000. * Assistant Professors of Finance, Department of Finance- ASU, PO Box 873906,

More information

Should Benchmark Indices Have Alpha? Revisiting Performance Evaluation *

Should Benchmark Indices Have Alpha? Revisiting Performance Evaluation * Should Benchmark Indices Have Alpha? Revisiting Performance Evaluation * Martijn Cremers Antti Petajisto Eric Zitzewitz July 3, 8 Abstract Standard Fama-French and Carhart models produce economically and

More information

Topic Nine. Evaluation of Portfolio Performance. Keith Brown

Topic Nine. Evaluation of Portfolio Performance. Keith Brown Topic Nine Evaluation of Portfolio Performance Keith Brown Overview of Performance Measurement The portfolio management process can be viewed in three steps: Analysis of Capital Market and Investor-Specific

More information

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less?

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less? Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less? Jia Chen, Kewei Hou, and René M. Stulz* January 2015 Abstract Using theories from the behavioral finance literature to predict that investors are attracted to

More information

The Right Answer to the Wrong Question: Identifying Superior Active Portfolio Management

The Right Answer to the Wrong Question: Identifying Superior Active Portfolio Management The Right Answer to the Wrong Question: Identifying Superior Active Portfolio Management W. V. Harlow Fidelity Research Institute 82 Devonshire Street Boston, Massachusetts 02109 (617) 563-2673 E-mail:

More information

High conviction: Creating multi-asset portfolios designed to achieve investors objectives

High conviction: Creating multi-asset portfolios designed to achieve investors objectives The Invesco White Paper Series High conviction: Creating multi-asset portfolios designed to achieve investors objectives Contributors: Duy Nguyen, CFA, CAIA Senior Portfolio Manager Chief Investment Officer

More information