Opening Secondary Markets: A Durable Goods Oligopoly with Transaction Costs

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Opening Secondary Markets: A Durable Goods Oligopoly with Transaction Costs"

Transcription

1 Opening Secondary Markets: A Durable Goods Oligopoly with Transaction Costs Jiawei Chen Department of Economics UC-Irvine Susanna Esteban Department of Economics Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Matthew Shum Department of Economics Johns Hopkins University February 27, 2007 Preliminary and Incomplete Draft Abstract In this paper, we introduce a model of durable goods oligopoly, in which consumers face lumpy costs of transacting in the car market. With transactions costs, the timing of purchases becomes important on the demand side, and consumers buy and sell in the automobile market infrequently in order to avoid incurring the lumpy adjustment costs. We present simulation results from simple monopoly and duopoly versions of the model, and discuss the empirical methodology for structural estimation of this model. Having modeled transaction costs provides us with a direct measure of the separate effects of secondary markets and durability on firms behavior. For a quantified example, making the good durable decreases profits for the monopolist by 14.78%; adding frictionless secondary markets increases them by 31.26%. Keywords: Secondary Markets, Durable Goods, Oligopoly, Transaction Costs, Automobile Industry The authors can be contacted by at jiaweic@uci.edu (Chen), sesteban@eco.uc3m.es (Esteban) and mshum@jhu.edu (Shum). 1

2 2 1 Introduction In this paper, we consider the effects of secondary markets on the producers of durable goods. Are secondary markets good or bad for producers? The existing literature has returned ambiguous answers to this question. As has been pointed out in the literature going back to Coase (1972), durability per se erodes a monopolist s market power, and profits, due to its inability to commit to keeping prices high (equivalently, keeping production low) in the future. Consider a market with heterogenous consumers: having sold to the higher valuation consumers, the monopolist is left with a market of lower valuation types to whom it can only sell if it lowers prices. Forward looking consumers, anticipating the price decrease, delay their purchases and force the monopolist to start decreasing prices earlier on. In the limit, if the good is infinitely durable, does not depreciate, and the monopolist can make instantaneous price adjustments, price converges immediately to the marginal cost of production. In such a setting, as pointed out by Liang (1999), secondary markets refrain the firm from overproducing in the future. Higher valuation types who might own a used product can now sell it in the secondary market and return to the primary market. Thus, the secondary market works by improving the efficiency in the allocation of new and used products and allows the monopolist to sell to higher types in every period. The monopolist has less incentives to drop prices in the future, which can lead to higher prices and, hence, higher profits. Therefore, although durability erodes profits for the firm, the ability to trade the product in a competitive secondary market mitigates (at least partially) the decrease in profits. If the secondary market will be active, increasing durability might have an ambiguous effect on profits. Indeed, the planned obsolescence literature (eg. Swan (1985) and Bulow (1986)) has pointed out how the firm may have an incentive to reduce the durability of its product, as a means of shrinking the secondary market. The existing literature has examined these issues in models which differed in their assumptions about consumer preferences and the nature of durability, for instance which makes it difficult to compare results across the models. In this paper, we introduce a dynamic equilibrium durable goods model with secondary markets and consumer transactions costs and use this model to study the effects of secondary markets on firms profits. In our model, we use consumer transactions costs as a measure of the level of activity or

3 3 trade in secondary markets, with larger values of the transaction costs leading to an endogenously smaller or less active secondary market. The existing literature on secondary markets (eg. Rust (1985) and Esteban and Shum (2004)) has for the most part considered the case of zero transactions costs, so that secondary markets are completely active. This has mainly been for tractability reasons, as the demand functions with positive transactions costs are very nonlinear step functions. At the opposite extreme, when transactions costs approach infinity, no consumers will ever trade, which corresponds to the setting originally consider in the Coase literature. The advantage of our setting is that, by modifying the value of transaction costs, we can close down the secondary market and obtain the effects of secondary markets separate from those of durability. (In contrast, in the planned obsolescence literature, closing down the secondary market isdone at the expense of reducing durability.) We construct a model of durable goods oligopoly, in which consumers face lumpy costs of transacting in the car market. By allowing for these transactions costs, we build upon the work in Esteban and Shum (2004), in which a dynamic equilibrium model of durable goods oligopoly was considered. In that paper, a convenient and tractable linear-quadratic specification was derived due to some simplifying assumptions, an important one of which was that consumers faced zero transaction costs in buying or selling in the automobile market. By introducing transactions costs, nontrivial dynamics result on the demand side. Specifically, with transactions costs, the timing of purchases becomes important on the demand side, and consumers will buy and sell in the automobile market infrequently in order to avoid incurring the lumpy adjustment costs. At the individual consumer level, the demand functions display the (S,s) -type of nonlinearities, and resemble the demand functions considered in much of the macro literature on durables (including Eberly (1994), Attanasio (2000), Stolyarov (2002), and Adda and Cooper (2000)). More recently, the empirical literature on durable goods demand has also consider the case where consumers have transactions costs (eg. Gowrisankaran and Rysman (2006), Schiraldi (2006)). Most closely related to our paper is Porter and Sattler (1999), who derive and test the properties of an overlapping generations durable goods monopoly model with secondary markets and transactions costs under the assumption that firms can commit to a production sequence. In our model, firms are not able to commit, and we analyze the time-consistent Markov-perfect equilibrium paths. This difference is significant, because if firms are able to commit, then the Coase problem disappears and one benefit of secondary markets that of limiting the overproduction by the firm is no longer relevant. As far as we are aware,

4 4 our model is the first Markov perfect equilibrium model of a durable goods industry with transactions costs and secondary markets. 1 Results to date show that a secondary market is desirable for durable goods producers in that it outweighs the competitive pressure resulting from the durability of the product. Simulations quantify the gains of an active frictionless secondary market: profits for a durable goods monopolist increase by 31.26% when transactions costs are decreased from a high level (one which closes down the secondary market) to zero (indicating frictionless secondary markets). Furthermore, when we compare the case of no durability to durability with zero transactions costs, the firm s profits increase by 11.86%, whereas when we compare the case of no durability to durability with high transactions costs, the firm s profits decrease by 14.78%, suggesting that secondary markets make durability more desirable to the firm. One caveat of the model is that it might understate the gain in allocative efficiency resulting from active secondary markets. In our model, consumers are ex-ante identical except for their current durable good endowment, but are hit with iid preference shocks each period. Each period, consumers with high preference shocks will trade their used products to consumers hit with lower preference shocks, and upgrade to a new product. Since these preference shocks are iid, however, consumers are ex-ante identical, and there is no intertemporal allocative role of the secondary market in that consumers might decide to make one purchase or the other based on their persistant valuations. In the next section, we set up the model, and describe the dynamic equilibrium of the model. In Section 2, we describe the computational algorithm, and discuss simulations from a simple monopoly version of the model. In Section 3, we discuss the existing results regarding the effects of secondary market obtained by varying the size of consumer transactions costs. In Section 4, we briefly discuss the results from a duopoly version of the model. 2 Model There are J products in the market (this includes both new and used cars). Assume that the per-period utility offered by each product j is α j. Let all the available cars be indexed j = 1,..., J. Let I {1, 2,..., J} denote the subset of indexes which are the indexes of the new cars 1 Huang, Yang, and Anderson (2001) considered a framework similar to ours, but the equilibrium derivation appears to be non-standard.

5 5 produced by the firms in the market. Assume for simplicity that each firm produces only one car model. With some abuse of notation, let i = 1,..., I index the firms (as well as the models they produce). Let r t ( {1,..., J}) denote the index of the car owned in at the beginning of period t by some consumer. Also, let r t = 0 denote the index of no car ownership (or ownership of a car that has died). We set α 0 = 0 and p 0t = 0, for all periods t. Also, let v(r t ) ( {1,..., J}) denotes next period s index of a car which is currently indexed r t (with the convention that v(0) = 0). Also, let w(j) denote the previous period s index of a car which currently has index j. That is, consider three years t, t + 1, t + 2: then the indexes for a car which has index j in period t + 1 is r t = w(j), r t+1 = j, r t+2 = v(j). In what follows, we consider both the firm and consumer problems in partial equilibrium. Afterwards, we consider equilibrium. 2.1 Consumer problem Consumers are are differentiated in two dimensions. First, we allow consumers to vary in their taste for quality; second, a consumer s utility from a particular product choice is perturbed every period by idiosyncratic utility shocks which are independent over time. If the consumer l keeps the car she has in period t, she gets utility α rt + ɛ lrtt. If she sells and purchases a car with index j (where j r t ) instead, she gets utility α j + γ l (p rtt p jt k) + ɛ ljt. γ l measures consumer l s marginal utility of money, which varies across consumers. We assume that there are a finite number (L) of consumer types, so that γ l {γ 1,..., γ L }. Let π 1,..., π L denote the population shares of the L consumer types (with l π l = 1). (In another abuse of notation, we use l to index both consumer types (of which there are a finite number) as well as consumers, of which there are a continuum. k denotes the transaction cost: we assume that k is k > 0 if the transaction involves the buying or selling of a used car, and is zero otherwise. The vector ɛ lt (ɛ l1t,..., ɛ ljt ) are the idiosyncratic shocks of consumer l for period t. Importantly, we assume that selling and buying decisions are made at the beginning of each period, before depreciation, so that buying a car with index s t in period t yields car utility of α st.

6 6 Let K lit denote the share of the population who are type l and who own a i-ranked car at the beginning of period t, with i {0, 1,..., J} and l {1,..., L}. Let the vector K t = (K 10t,..., K 1Jt, K 20t,..., K L0t,..., K LJt ). Similarly, let B t denote the vector of used car production in period t, with elements K lit, i {1,..., J} \ I, and l {1,..., L}. We put the consumer s problem in a dynamic programming framework. The state variables are r t, the prices p t {p 1t,..., p Jt }, and the consumer s shocks ɛ lt. Let the control variable be denoted s t {0,..., J}. Then the current utility in period t is: u(r t, s t, p t ; γ l, ɛ lt ) = α st + 1(s t r t ) γ l (p rt p st k) + ɛ lstt ũ(r t, s t, p t ; γ l ) + ɛ istt. The second term represents the disutility incurred when the consumer sells her r t -indexed car and buys the s t -indexed car, which includes the transactions cost term k. The consumer s Bellman equation is: V (r t, p t ; γ l, ɛ lt ) = max s t [ u(rt, s t, p t ; γ l, ɛ lt ) + βe rt+1, p t+1, ɛ it+1 r t, p t,s t, ɛ lt V (r t+1, p t+1 ; γ l, ɛ lt+1 ) ]. The expectation is taken over the transition equations for the state variables, which are the index of the current car, r t, as well as the prices p t. For the state variable r t, the transition is deterministic given s t : r t+1 = { v(r t ) v(s t ) if s t = r t otherwise. The Bellman Eq. (1) also has expectations over future prices p t. In equilibrium, prices will depend on the firms past, current, and future car production. For the time being, however, we will work in partial equilibrium, and only assume that consumers beliefs about the evolution of prices are captured in a conditional distribution G(p p). The consumer s optimal policy function will be a function of the state variables: s t = s (r t, p t, γ, ɛ lt ; G), where we have also included the price beliefs G as an argument to emphasize the dependence of consumers optimal choices on these beliefs. (1) Note that, given transaction costs, the optimal car choice is state-dependent, because the choice of s t depends explicitly on r t, the index of the currently-owned car.

7 7 Define Ṽ (r, p, γ) E ɛv (r, p, γ, ɛ). Then the Bellman equation in (1) above can be written as [ ]} Ṽ (r, p, γ) = E ɛ {max ũ(r, s, p, γ) + ɛ is + βe r s, p r, p,sṽ (r, p, γ). (2) Deriving aggregate demand functions Consider the demand for car j in period t. We make the assumption that each idiosyncratic shock ɛ ljt is i.i.d. across (l, j, t). With this assumption, for all consumers who currently have car ranked r t and have type γ, the proportion of them who will switch to car j is: 1 [s (r t, p t,, γ, ɛ lt ; G) = j] df ( ɛ lt ), for all j {0, 1,..., J}. If we further assume that each ɛ ijt is distributed extreme-value (with CDF F (ɛ) = exp( exp( ɛ))), then this expression becomes ( ) exp ũ(r t, j, p t ; γ) + βeṽ (r t+1 = v(r t ), p t+1 ; γ) Q j (r t, p t ; γ, G) = ( ) (3) J j =0 exp ũ(r t, j, p t ; γ) + βeṽ (r t+1 = v(r t ), p t+1 ; γ) where the expectation is taken over p t+1. (If r t = j, then Q j (r t, p t, p t, γ) denotes the proportion of type-γ consumers having car j in period t who do not buy another one.) The assumptions that the ɛ ljt s are i.i.d. is very important here, because it implies that F ( ɛ r t ) = F ( ɛ), for all r t. If these shock are persistent over time, this is no longer true, and we would have to carry around the joint distribution of (r t, ɛ lt ) as a state variable. However, the presence of different γ s across consumers implies that even when the ɛ s are assumed to be i.i.d. across time, we would need to carry around the joint distribution of (r t, γ l ) as a state variable. The discreteness of (r t, γ l ) is important, because it implies that the joint distribution is finite-dimensional, so that the state space is also finite-dimensional. 2 Our assumptions on heterogeneity can be contrasted with those in Porter and Sattler (1999). The model in that paper is a vertically differentiated model, where the distribution of γ is continuous and uniform, and there are no ɛ errors. It is similar to the pure vertical model in Berry and Pakes (1999). However, the pure vertical differentiation model is not so convenient for computational reasons, as the market shares may be discontinuous functions of the model parameters. 2 If γ is continuous, the approach of Krusell and Smith to approximate the infinite-dimensional joint distribution of (r, γ) by its moments may be helpful.

8 8 With the extreme-value assumptions on the error terms, Eq. (2) can be written as { J ( Ṽ (r, p; γ) = log exp ũ(r, s, p; γ) + βe r, p r, p;γ,sṽ (r, p ; γ)) } (4) s=0 which is a functional equation that one could iterate over to solve for the expected value function Ṽ (r, p; γ). This is as in Rust (1987). The total demand for car j in period t is ( ) D Bt j, p t ; G = M where M is the population size. l J π l j =0,j j,j I K lj t Q j (j, p t ; γ l, G) (5) Note that the demand for car j does not include the consumers who currently own car j (ie. l j), who decide to keep their car and not sell it. Also, given our assumption that consumers make their car purchase decision at the beginning of periods, while depreciation occurs at the end of periods, the summation in the aggregate demand (5) does not include the new cars (j I), because no one owns a new car at the beginning of any period (ie. consumer who had a new car in the previous period now have a used car at the beginning of the current period). Also define ( ) H Bt j, p t ; G = M π l K ljt Q j (j, p t ; G), j = 1,..., J, j I, (6) l the consumers for whom r t = j, and who keep their car in period t instead of switching to another one. Finally, define the supply for each used car in period t as S j ( Bt, p t ; G) = M J π l l j =0,j j K lj t Q j (j, p t ; γ l G), j {1,..., J} \ I which are the number of consumers who own car j at the beginning of period t, who choose another car j j. 2.2 Firm problem We assume that firms choose quantities. To formulate the firm problem, we must define the inverse demand functions. For each new car i I, define the inverse demand function

9 ( ) g Bt i, p t, i, q it ; G, which is the inverse of the aggregate demand function D i ( ) with respect to p it, evaluated at q it. ( p t, i denotes all the prices except the price for car i, p it.) For each new car model i I, firm i s static profits are Π i (q it, B t ) q it (g i ( B t, p t, i, q it ; G) c i ). (7) The Bellman equation is W i ( B t ) = max q it Π i (q it, B t ) + βeb t+1 B t,q it W i ( B t+1 ). (8) [ ] Firm i s equilibrium production strategy would be a state-contingent function q it = q i ( B t ), for i I, which solves the RHS of Eq. (8). The prices will be determined by market-clearing conditions period-by-period. For new cars i I, the prices must satisfy the following market-clearing conditions: q i ( Bt ) = D i ( Bt, p t ; G). (9) The prices p j, j = 1,..., J, j I, for the used cars in period t, must satisfy the market clearing condition S j ( B t, p t ; G) = D j ( B t, p t ; G) where D j ( B t, p t ) is defined in Eq. (5) above. These market-clearing conditions will define the equilibrium prices p jt, for all i = 1,..., J. Let ρ( B t ) denote the full J-dimensional vector of prices derived by solving this J-dimensional nonlinear equation system jointly Equilibrium In rational expectations equilibrium, consumers beliefs about the price evolution, summarized by the conditional distribution G, must correspond to the actual evolution. In equilibrium, consumers will recognize the functional dependence of prices on the state vector B t, so that the consumer problem in equilibrium will also have B t as the state variable, rather than prices. In what follows, we use an asterisk ( ) to denote equilibrium functions. Let q ( B t ) denote the equilibrium policy function, p ( B t ) denote the equilibrium pricing functions. Let h ( B t ) 3 Note that, if we were to solve the new-car market-clearing conditions (9) on an equation-by-equation basis, for arbitrary q and fixed values of p t, j, then we get the inverse demand functions g j B t, p t, j, q; G which we defined at the beginning of this section.

10 10 denote the equilibrium transition vector for B t, and G the equilibrium transition for prices. We will describe these functions in more detail here. Since, in equilibrium, the evolution of prices is driven by evolution of B t, we can rewrite the consumer problem to have B t be the state vector, in place of p t., and with the transition h( B t, q ( B t )) governing equilibrium beliefs about the evolution of B t, and prices each period given by p ( B t ). The Bellman equation for the new consumer problem would be V (r t, B ) [ t ; γ, ɛ it = max u(r t, s t, p (B t ); γ, ɛ it ) + βev (r t+1, )] B t+1 ; γ, ɛ it+1 s t (10) where the consumers beliefs over the evolution of Bt will be given by the equilibrium transition function h( B t, q ( B t )), which will be endogenously determined in the consumer problem, as we will show later. In order to describe the market-clearing conditions which determine the equilibrium price sequences p ( B t ), we still need to define firms inverse demand functions as follows. Consider firm i, and consider the production vector q i ( B t ; q), which sets q it = q and q i t = q i ( B t ) for all other firms i i. Corresponding to this production vector would be the transition function h( B t, q i ( B t ; q)), which gives the values of B t+1 given that all other firms besides firm i produce according to the policy function q ( B t ), but firm i produces q. The prices p i ( B t ; q) which would result at state B t, and production vector q t = q i ( B t ; q)) are given by the market clearing conditions: ( q i = D Bt i, p t ; h( B t, q i ( B ) t ; q)), i I ( S Bt j, p t ; h( B t, q i ( B ) ( t ; q)) = D Bt j, p t ; h( B t, q i ( B ) t ; q)), j {1,..., J} \ I. The locus of p i s generated by solving the mkt-clearing conditions for different values of q it = q (while holding all q i t fixed at q i ( B t )) yields the inverse demand function for firm i, which we denote p( B t, q). In the above market-clearing conditions, the demand curve D j ( B t, p t ; h) is defined, analogously to Eq. (5), as ( ) D Bt j, p t ; h = M l J j =0,j j,j I K lj tπ l Q j (j, B t, p t ; γ l, h) and Q j (r, p t ; γ l, h) denotes the state r-dependent probability of choosing product j, which (11)

11 11 is defined (analogously to Eq. (3)) as ( Q j (r t, B exp ũ(r t, j, p t ; γ) + βe h Ṽ (v(j), ) B t+1 = h; γ) t, p t ; γ, h) = ( J j =0 exp ũ(r t, j, p t ; γ) + βṽ (v(j ), B ). t+1 = h; γ) The supply function S j ( B t, p t ; h) is defined analogously. Given this notation, we note that the transition function h( B t, q) is defined implicitly by the requirement that the function must yield correct predictions of next period stocks, given optimizing consumer behavior. That is, for all used products j {1,..., J}\I, the (l, j)-th element of h( B t, q) is K l,j,t+1 = π l K l,j,tq w(j) (j, p( B t, q); γ l, h( B t, q)) j (this is the share of product j in period t + 1 among type k consumers, which is just equal to the demand for car w(j) in period t among type k consumers). In the above, the marketclearing prices p( B t, q) are the prices consistent with the market-clearing conditions (11), and the transition h( B t, q). In equilibrium: 1. q ( B t ) solves firm problem: q i ( B t ) = argmax q q ( p i ( B t, q) c i ) + βew ( B t+1 ) where expectation of B t+1 is according to h( B t, q i ( B t ; q)). 2. Consumer value functions are given by Ṽ (r, B; γ) = E ɛ {max s [ ũ(r, s, p ( B); γ) + ɛ is + βṽ (r, h( B, q ( B t )); γ) ]}. 3. Equilibrium prices p ( B t ) satisfy the market-clearing conditions qi ( B ( t ) = D Bt i, p t ; h( B t, q ( B ) t )), i I ( S Bt j, p t ; h( B t, q ( B ) ( t )) = D Bt j, p t ; h( B t, q ( B ) t )), j {1,..., J} \ I. 4. The transition B t+1 = h( B t, q ( B t )) is consistent with consumer maximization, and the equilibrium prices: K l,j,t+1 = π l j K l,j,tq w(j) (j, p ( B t ); γ l, h( B t, q ( B t )))

12 12 3 Monopoly example In this section, we focus on a simplified monopoly version of the model, and present some computational results which illustrate features of the Markov equilibrium paths. Consider the example where there is only one firm, producing a car that lasts for two periods. Thus J = 2, with v(1) = 2 and v(2) = 0. Assume that the firm chooses quantity, and the prices adjust to clear the market. Consider the monopoly model with two-period goods as above, but amended to have two consumer types (ie. L = 2). The state vector for this model will be B t = K 2t (K 12t, K 22t ) The firm s Bellman equation is W ( K [ 2t ) = max Π(q t, p t ) + βw ( ] K 2t+1 ) q t (12) s.t. q t M l (1 K 2t ), p t = p(q t, K 2t ), and K l2t+1 = h( K 2t, q t ), where p t = p(q t, K 2t ) is the solution to the following system of 2 equations: { = D 1 ( K 2t, p t, h( K 2t, q)) q t S 2 ( K 2t, p t ) = D 2 ( K 2t, p t, h( K 2t, q)) (13) Eq. (3) can be written as Q j (r t, K 2t p t, K 2t, γ, h) = ( exp ũ(r t, j, p t, γ) + βṽ (v(j), h( K ) 2t, q, γ) ( J j =0 exp ũ(r t, j, p t, γ) + βṽ (v(j ), h( K ), (14) 2t, q), γ) and the system of equations in (13) becomes { q t /M l π l i=0,1 K l2t Q i (2, K 2t p t, K l2t, γ l, h) = l π l i=0,2 K lit Q 1 (i, K 2t p t, K 2t, γ l, h) = l π l i=0,1 K lit Q 2 (i, K 2t, p t, K 2t, γ, h). (15) 3.1 Algorithm for model with consumer heterogeneity The main difference is that the state vector is bigger now: Bt is two-dimensional. Also, now the consumer value function V has an additional argument, which is γ. An additional difficulty is that the transition function h( B t, q) must be iterated and solved for as part of the consumer problem.

13 13 Make initial guesses of firm policy function q 0 ( K 2t ) and consumer value functions Ṽ 0 (r t, K 2t, γ l ), for l = 1, 2. First solve consumer problem. Start with a guess of h 0 ( B t, q). By the end of the consumer loop, we will obtain values for h( ) consistent with q 0 and V 0, as well as an iterated guess for the consumer value functions V 1. Given q 0 ( B t ), and the guess of consumer value functions V 0, and h 0, we can solve for market clearing prices p( B t ) using (15). Given these market clearing prices, we can evaluate the choice probabilities in Eq. (14). Then we can evaluate next period stocks as l = 1, 2. K l2t+1 = π l j=0,1 K ljt Q 2 (j, B t, p t ( B t ), γ l, h 0 ), Set h 01 = K 2t+1, and repeat previous two steps until you get a convergent value for h function. Call this h 1. Using h, evaluate the consumer Bellman equation { J Ṽ 1 (r, K ( 2, γ l ) = log exp ũ(r, s, p( K 2 ), γ l ) + βṽ 0 (v(r), h( K 2, q 0 ( K ) } 2 )), γ l ) s=0 for types l = 1, 2 to get Ṽ 1 (r t, K 2t, γ l ). Solve the firm s problem to obtain q 1 ( K 2t ). Make initial guesses of q 00 ( K 2t ) and W 00 ( K 2t ). Solve for the firm s optimal policy q 01 ( K 2t ) using the firm s Bellman equation (16) in (12), the transition function h 1 ( K 2, q) derived from the consumer problem, and the inverse demand function p t = p(q t, K 2t ) as the solution to the system of equations in (15). Update the firm s value function W 01 ( K 2t ) according to the firm s Bellman equation. The loop terminates if the relative changes from q 00 ( K 2t ) to q 01 ( K 2t ) and from W 00 ( K 2t ) to W 01 ( K 2t ) are both below a pre-specified tolerance. Otherwise update the guesses and iterate on.

14 14 Set q 1 (K 2t ) = q 01 (K 2t ). The algorithm terminates if the relative changes from Ṽ 0 (r t, K 2t ) to Ṽ 1 (r t, K 2t ) and from q 0 (K 2t ) to q 1 (K 2t ) are both below a pre-specified tolerance. Otherwise update the guesses and iterate on. Note that the algorithm consists of three loops: two inner loops (one for the consumer s problem and one for the firm s problem) and an outer loop. 3.2 Approximation Approximate the firm s policy function as n q (K 2 ) d i φ i (K 2 ), i=1 where φ 1, φ 2,..., φ n are Chebychev polynomials and d 1,..., d n are a set of coefficients to be determined. Ṽ (r, K 2 ) and W (K 2 ) are approximated analogously. 3.3 Parameterization We use the following parameter values in our baseline model: 4 The effects of secondary markets on firm profits: preliminary results In this section, we consider results from simulations which address the question raised at the very beginning of this paper: what are the effects of secondary markets on durable goods producers? As we discussed earlier, we use the level of transactions costs to measure the activity in the secondary market, with higher transactions costs inducing a less active secondary market. Table 1 shows the effect of durability and secondary markets, both individually and combined, on profits. Making the good durable the effect of durability implies a change in profits for the firm of 14.78% relative to the nondurable good case. Adding to durability no frictions the effect of secondary markets and thus making the secondary market most

15 15 Table 1: Effects of Durability and Secondary Markets (c = 0) Not durable Durable Secondary markets (S = 0) New car production New car price Profit Used car transactions n.a % Durability a % Secondary markets (S = 0) b New car production New car price Profit % Durability & Secondary markets (S = 0) c. New car production New car price Profit a Relative to the Not durable numbers. b Relative to the Durability numbers. c Secondary markets numbers relative to Not durable numbers

16 16 active, increases profits for the firm by 31.26%. Overall, if we simply compare no durability to durability with zero transaction costs, we obtain a net gain of 11.86% in profit. Thus, the cause for the increases in profit is per se the secondary market. Notice that if we were quantify the effects of secondary markets by eliminating durability, we would understate the effect: 11.86% relative to the true 31.26% increase. This results illustrate clearly the separate effects of secondary markets and durability on firm s behavior. Durability erodes market power by standard Coasian arguments. Secondary markets mitigate this erosion by improving allocative efficiency and refraining the firm s incentives to overproduce. The preliminary results show that the gains for the firm in reducing frictions in the secondary market are large. Nonetheless, the qualitative results in Table 1 are sensitive to the marginal cost of production. Intuitively, a positive marginal cost of production raises the profitability of producing a durable good. On the one hand, durability brings the consistency problems for the firm and is responsible for the previously described decrease in profit. On the other, by producing a durable good, the firm can accrue revenues from sales in multiple periods, since the new car price is the capitalized value of the asset, without having to manufacture the good in each one of these periods. If the cost is high, see Table 2, the savings in cost may outweigh the competitive dynamic arising from durability. Table 2: Effects of Durability and Secondary Markets (c = 1) Not durable Durable Secondary markets (S = 0) New car production New car price Profit Used car transactions n.a To understand the marginal effects of secondary markets on firm s behavior, we build two statistics. Let y(s) be an industry variable, e.g., price, profit, etc, for a give level of transaction costs S 0. Let S 0 0, which corresponds to he secondary market being most active. Let S max be the level of transaction costs that close down the secondary market. Then compute: y(s+ ) y(s) y(s) S η y (S), for all S [0, S max ], (17) as the change in y from a marginal increase in transaction costs. That is, η y (S) is the

17 17 elasticity of y to a change in transaction costs. Our second statistic directly imputes changes in y to changes in used car transactions the level of activity in the secondary market. That is, we compute η y (S) x U (S+ ) x U (S) x U (S) υ y (S), (18) where x U are secondary market transactions. This latter measure the impact of the secondary market on market variables, and is an elasticity of y to changes in used car transactions. 5 Estimating the model Here we consider how the monopoly model could be estimated. How we estimate depends on what data is observed. Here I assume that in each period t, we observe (p t, K 1t, K 2t ): prices, and the ownership/purchases of new and used cars, for each type of consumers. We assume that we can classify consumers into the different type groups. For simplicity, assume there are only two groups. For example, we could consider two types of consumers, those with income > $50, 000, and those with income < $50, 000. Then π 1 and π 2, the population proportion of type 1 and type 2 consumers, is observed. In order to confirm that a classification scheme makes sense, we could do a simple test for consumer heterogeneity. We check whether the percentage of new cars owned is different across the proposed classification groups: if so, then there is heterogeneity across the classification groups. Intuitively, because the prices of new and used cars are identical across the two groups of consumers, heterogeneity in WTP to quality γ should be reflected in heterogeneity across groups in propensity to own new vs. used cars (which differ in quality). If we find no differences between the groups, then we should go back and redefine the consumer groups. The estimation will proceed in three steps. First, because we observe K 12t and K 22t, we observe all the state variables. Hence, we can estimate the h, the equilibrium transition function for the observed state variables. This is crucial, since with knowledge of h, we can simulate both the consumer and firm dynamic optimization problems. Second, we estimate the parameters related to the consumer problem. On the consumer side, we observe K ljt, for each consumer type l, and each vintage j. Given knowledge of the

18 18 transition function h, we can solve the consumers dynamic choice problem (Eq. (10)) and obtain the choice probabilities Q j (r t, B t, p t ; γ, h). For each l and j, then, we can estimate by matching the observed stocks to the predicted stocks: K ljt = K l,j,t 1Q j (j, B t, p t ; γ l, h) j where the LHS is observed, and the RHS can be computed given parameter values and the solution to the consumer problem. Note that in this way, we could estimate the consumerrelated parameters (the γ s and the α s) separately from the supply side. Third, we estimate the parameters related to the supply side. In each period t, we observe q t, the new production that period. Given our knowledge of the equilibrium transition function h and the consumer parameters from the previous steps, we can solve the firm problem to derive q(k 12t, K 22t ), the equilibrium production function of the firm. Estimation of the firm-level parameters (the cost parameters) can be based on matching observed to predicted production: q t = q(k 12t, K 22t ). References Adda, J., and R. Cooper (2000): Balladurette and Jupette: A Discrete Analysis of Scrapping Subsidies, Journal of Political Economy, 108, Attanasio, O. (2000): Consumer Durables and Inertial Behavior: Estimation and Aggregation of (s,s) Rules, Review of Economic Studies, 67, Berry, S., and A. Pakes (1999): Estimating the Pure Hedonic Discrete Choice Model, Manuscript, Yale University. Bulow, J. (1986): An Economic Theory of Planned Obsolescence, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101, Coase, R. (1972): Durability and Monopoly, Journal of Law and Economics, 15, Eberly, J. (1994): Adjustment of Consumers Durables Stocks: Evidence from Automobile Purchases, Journal of Political Economy, 102, Esteban, S., and M. Shum (2004): Durable Goods Oligopoly with Secondary Markets: the Case of Automobiles, Forthcoming, RAND Journal of Economics.

19 19 Gowrisankaran, G., and M. Rysman (2006): Dynamics of Consumer Demand for New Durable Goods, mimeo, Boston University. Huang, S., Y. Yang, and K. Anderson (2001): A Theory of Finitely Durale Goods Monopoly with Used-Goods Market and Transaction Costs, Management Science, 47, Liang, M. (1999): Does a Second-Hand Market Limit a Durable Goods Monopolist s Market Power?, Manuscript, University of Western Ontario. Porter, R., and P. Sattler (1999): Patterns of Trade in the Market for Used Durables: Theory and Evidence, NBER working paper, #7149. Rust, J. (1985): When is it Optimal to Kill off the Market for Used Durable Goods?, Econometrica, 54, (1987): Optimal Replacement of GMC Bus Engines: An Empirical Model of Harold Zurcher, Econometrica, 55, Schiraldi, P. (2006): Automobile Replacement: a Dynamic Structural Approach, mimeo, Boston University. Stolyarov, D. (2002): Turnover of Used Durables in a Stationary Equilibrium: are Older Goods traded More?, Journal of Political Economy, 110, Swan, P. (1985): Optimal Durability, Second-Hand Markets, and Planned Obsolescence, Journal of Political Economy, 53,

When do Secondary Markets Harm Firms? Online Appendixes (Not for Publication)

When do Secondary Markets Harm Firms? Online Appendixes (Not for Publication) When do Secondary Markets Harm Firms? Online Appendixes (Not for Publication) Jiawei Chen and Susanna Esteban and Matthew Shum January 1, 213 I The MPEC approach to calibration In calibrating the model,

More information

How Much Competition is a Secondary Market? Online Appendixes (Not for Publication)

How Much Competition is a Secondary Market? Online Appendixes (Not for Publication) How Much Competition is a Secondary Market? Online Appendixes (Not for Publication) Jiawei Chen, Susanna Esteban, and Matthew Shum March 12, 2011 1 The MPEC approach to calibration In calibrating the model,

More information

Journal of Econometrics. Demand and supply estimation biases due to omission of durability

Journal of Econometrics. Demand and supply estimation biases due to omission of durability Journal of Econometrics 147 (2008) 247 257 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Econometrics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jeconom Demand and supply estimation biases due to

More information

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets Metin Cakir Purdue University December 6, 2010 Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 1 / 28 Outline Outline Estimating

More information

Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2

Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2 Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2 Due Tues Oct 3. Question 1 Consider the following model of entry. There are two firms. There are two entry scenarios in each period. With probability only one firm is able

More information

A simple wealth model

A simple wealth model Quantitative Macroeconomics Raül Santaeulàlia-Llopis, MOVE-UAB and Barcelona GSE Homework 5, due Thu Nov 1 I A simple wealth model Consider the sequential problem of a household that maximizes over streams

More information

3. PRICE DYNAMICS FOR DURABLE GOODS. 3.1 Introduction

3. PRICE DYNAMICS FOR DURABLE GOODS. 3.1 Introduction 3. PRICE DYNAMICS FOR DURABLE GOODS 3.1 Introduction Expenditure on durable goods accounts for 60% of consumption expenditure and all of investment expenditure. It is the most volatile component of GDP

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Joan Llull Structural Micro. IDEA PhD Program I. Dynamic Discrete Games with Imperfect Information A. Motivating example: firm entry and

More information

The Costs of Environmental Regulation in a Concentrated Industry

The Costs of Environmental Regulation in a Concentrated Industry The Costs of Environmental Regulation in a Concentrated Industry Stephen P. Ryan MIT Department of Economics Research Motivation Question: How do we measure the costs of a regulation in an oligopolistic

More information

Pakes (1986): Patents as Options: Some Estimates of the Value of Holding European Patent Stocks

Pakes (1986): Patents as Options: Some Estimates of the Value of Holding European Patent Stocks Pakes (1986): Patents as Options: Some Estimates of the Value of Holding European Patent Stocks Spring 2009 Main question: How much are patents worth? Answering this question is important, because it helps

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers

Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers , JPE 1996 Presented by: Rustom Irani, NYU Stern November 16, 2009 Outline Introduction 1 Introduction Motivation Contribution 2 Assumptions Equilibrium 3 Mechanism Empirical Implications of Idiosyncratic

More information

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico Thomas F. Cooley New York University Vincenzo Quadrini Duke University and CEPR May 2, 2000 Abstract This paper develops a two-country monetary

More information

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence A The infinite horizon model This section defines the equilibrium of the infinity horizon model described in Section III of the paper and characterizes

More information

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations Tommy Sveen Norges Bank January 28, 2009 TS (NB) ECON 4325 January 28, 2009 / 35 Introduction A simple model of a classical monetary economy. Perfect

More information

Short-time-to-expiry expansion for a digital European put option under the CEV model. November 1, 2017

Short-time-to-expiry expansion for a digital European put option under the CEV model. November 1, 2017 Short-time-to-expiry expansion for a digital European put option under the CEV model November 1, 2017 Abstract In this paper I present a short-time-to-expiry asymptotic series expansion for a digital European

More information

Estimating a Dynamic Oligopolistic Game with Serially Correlated Unobserved Production Costs. SS223B-Empirical IO

Estimating a Dynamic Oligopolistic Game with Serially Correlated Unobserved Production Costs. SS223B-Empirical IO Estimating a Dynamic Oligopolistic Game with Serially Correlated Unobserved Production Costs SS223B-Empirical IO Motivation There have been substantial recent developments in the empirical literature on

More information

Lec 1: Single Agent Dynamic Models: Nested Fixed Point Approach. K. Sudhir MGT 756: Empirical Methods in Marketing

Lec 1: Single Agent Dynamic Models: Nested Fixed Point Approach. K. Sudhir MGT 756: Empirical Methods in Marketing Lec 1: Single Agent Dynamic Models: Nested Fixed Point Approach K. Sudhir MGT 756: Empirical Methods in Marketing RUST (1987) MODEL AND ESTIMATION APPROACH A Model of Harold Zurcher Rust (1987) Empirical

More information

Reasoning with Uncertainty

Reasoning with Uncertainty Reasoning with Uncertainty Markov Decision Models Manfred Huber 2015 1 Markov Decision Process Models Markov models represent the behavior of a random process, including its internal state and the externally

More information

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment Eduardo Engel Cowles Lunch. March 3rd, 2010 Eduardo Engel 1 1. Motivation Micro adjustment is lumpy for many aggregates of interest: stock of durable good nominal

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Making Complex Decisions

Making Complex Decisions Ch. 17 p.1/29 Making Complex Decisions Chapter 17 Ch. 17 p.2/29 Outline Sequential decision problems Value iteration algorithm Policy iteration algorithm Ch. 17 p.3/29 A simple environment 3 +1 p=0.8 2

More information

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk Vasia Panousi Catarina Reis April 27 WP 27/64 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This

More information

Price Theory of Two-Sided Markets

Price Theory of Two-Sided Markets The E. Glen Weyl Department of Economics Princeton University Fundação Getulio Vargas August 3, 2007 Definition of a two-sided market 1 Two groups of consumers 2 Value from connecting (proportional to

More information

The Zero Lower Bound

The Zero Lower Bound The Zero Lower Bound Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 4 Introduction In the standard New Keynesian model, monetary policy is often described by an interest rate rule (e.g. a Taylor rule) that

More information

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism RIETI Discussion Paper Series 09-E-05 Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism INABA Masaru The Canon Institute for Global Studies KOBAYASHI Keiichiro RIETI The

More information

UCLA Department of Economics Ph.D. Preliminary Exam Industrial Organization Field Exam (Spring 2010) Use SEPARATE booklets to answer each question

UCLA Department of Economics Ph.D. Preliminary Exam Industrial Organization Field Exam (Spring 2010) Use SEPARATE booklets to answer each question Wednesday, June 23 2010 Instructions: UCLA Department of Economics Ph.D. Preliminary Exam Industrial Organization Field Exam (Spring 2010) You have 4 hours for the exam. Answer any 5 out 6 questions. All

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

Generalized Multi-Factor Commodity Spot Price Modeling through Dynamic Cournot Resource Extraction Models

Generalized Multi-Factor Commodity Spot Price Modeling through Dynamic Cournot Resource Extraction Models Generalized Multi-Factor Commodity Spot Price Modeling through Dynamic Cournot Resource Extraction Models Bilkan Erkmen (joint work with Michael Coulon) Workshop on Stochastic Games, Equilibrium, and Applications

More information

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Phuong V. Ngo,a a Department of Economics, Cleveland State University, 22 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland,

More information

Market Survival in the Economies with Heterogeneous Beliefs

Market Survival in the Economies with Heterogeneous Beliefs Market Survival in the Economies with Heterogeneous Beliefs Viktor Tsyrennikov Preliminary and Incomplete February 28, 2006 Abstract This works aims analyzes market survival of agents with incorrect beliefs.

More information

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Consumption and Asset Pricing Consumption and Asset Pricing Yin-Chi Wang The Chinese University of Hong Kong November, 2012 References: Williamson s lecture notes (2006) ch5 and ch 6 Further references: Stochastic dynamic programming:

More information

STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION

STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION BINGCHAO HUANGFU Abstract This paper studies a dynamic duopoly model of reputation-building in which reputations are treated as capital stocks that

More information

Multiproduct-Firm Oligopoly: An Aggregative Games Approach

Multiproduct-Firm Oligopoly: An Aggregative Games Approach Multiproduct-Firm Oligopoly: An Aggregative Games Approach Volker Nocke 1 Nicolas Schutz 2 1 UCLA 2 University of Mannheim ASSA ES Meetings, Philadephia, 2018 Nocke and Schutz (UCLA &Mannheim) Multiproduct-Firm

More information

Pricing Problems under the Markov Chain Choice Model

Pricing Problems under the Markov Chain Choice Model Pricing Problems under the Markov Chain Choice Model James Dong School of Operations Research and Information Engineering, Cornell University, Ithaca, New York 14853, USA jd748@cornell.edu A. Serdar Simsek

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound Timothy Hills Taisuke Nakata Sebastian Schmidt New York University Federal Reserve Board European Central Bank 1 September 2016 1 The views expressed

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model

The Basic New Keynesian Model Jordi Gali Monetary Policy, inflation, and the business cycle Lian Allub 15/12/2009 In The Classical Monetary economy we have perfect competition and fully flexible prices in all markets. Here there is

More information

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle 1 E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 1 A Lucas Tree Model Consider a pure exchange, representative household economy. Suppose there exists an asset called a tree.

More information

Unobserved Heterogeneity Revisited

Unobserved Heterogeneity Revisited Unobserved Heterogeneity Revisited Robert A. Miller Dynamic Discrete Choice March 2018 Miller (Dynamic Discrete Choice) cemmap 7 March 2018 1 / 24 Distributional Assumptions about the Unobserved Variables

More information

Problem set Fall 2012.

Problem set Fall 2012. Problem set 1. 14.461 Fall 2012. Ivan Werning September 13, 2012 References: 1. Ljungqvist L., and Thomas J. Sargent (2000), Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, sections 17.2 for Problem 1,2. 2. Werning Ivan

More information

Revenue Management Under the Markov Chain Choice Model

Revenue Management Under the Markov Chain Choice Model Revenue Management Under the Markov Chain Choice Model Jacob B. Feldman School of Operations Research and Information Engineering, Cornell University, Ithaca, New York 14853, USA jbf232@cornell.edu Huseyin

More information

Obtaining Analytic Derivatives for a Class of Discrete-Choice Dynamic Programming Models

Obtaining Analytic Derivatives for a Class of Discrete-Choice Dynamic Programming Models Obtaining Analytic Derivatives for a Class of Discrete-Choice Dynamic Programming Models Curtis Eberwein John C. Ham June 5, 2007 Abstract This paper shows how to recursively calculate analytic first and

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Games when Players Beliefs are not in Equilibrium

Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Games when Players Beliefs are not in Equilibrium and of Dynamic Games when Players Beliefs are not in Equilibrium Victor Aguirregabiria and Arvind Magesan Presented by Hanqing Institute, Renmin University of China Outline General Views 1 General Views

More information

EC316a: Advanced Scientific Computation, Fall Discrete time, continuous state dynamic models: solution methods

EC316a: Advanced Scientific Computation, Fall Discrete time, continuous state dynamic models: solution methods EC316a: Advanced Scientific Computation, Fall 2003 Notes Section 4 Discrete time, continuous state dynamic models: solution methods We consider now solution methods for discrete time models in which decisions

More information

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator

Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Practical example of an Economic Scenario Generator Martin Schenk Actuarial & Insurance Solutions SAV 7 March 2014 Agenda Introduction Deterministic vs. stochastic approach Mathematical model Application

More information

Durable Goods Price Cycles: Theory and Evidence from the Textbook Market. By Eric W. Bond and Toshiaki Iizuka

Durable Goods Price Cycles: Theory and Evidence from the Textbook Market. By Eric W. Bond and Toshiaki Iizuka Durable Goods Price Cycles: Theory and Evidence from the Textbook Market By Eric W. Bond and Toshiaki Iizuka June 2005 Abstract: We develop a model of the monopoly pricing of a durable good when there

More information

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model. Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model. Olivier Blanchard May 25 14.452. Spring 25. Topic 7. 1 Why introduce nominal rigidities, and what do they imply? An informal walk-through. In the model we

More information

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico

Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico Foreign Competition and Banking Industry Dynamics: An Application to Mexico Dean Corbae Pablo D Erasmo 1 Univ. of Wisconsin FRB Philadelphia June 12, 2014 1 The views expressed here do not necessarily

More information

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan Optimal Credit Market Policy Matteo Iacoviello 1 Ricardo Nunes 2 Andrea Prestipino 1 1 Federal Reserve Board 2 University of Surrey CEF 218, Milan June 2, 218 Disclaimer: The views expressed are solely

More information

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization Notes on Intertemporal Optimization Econ 204A - Henning Bohn * Most of modern macroeconomics involves models of agents that optimize over time. he basic ideas and tools are the same as in microeconomics,

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

Exact microeconomic foundation for the Phillips curve under complete markets: A Keynesian view

Exact microeconomic foundation for the Phillips curve under complete markets: A Keynesian view DBJ Discussion Paper Series, No.1005 Exact microeconomic foundation for the Phillips curve under complete markets: A Keynesian view Masayuki Otaki (Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo) and

More information

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy George Alogoskoufis* Athens University of Economics and Business September 2012 Abstract This paper examines

More information

A Continuous-Time Asset Pricing Model with Habits and Durability

A Continuous-Time Asset Pricing Model with Habits and Durability A Continuous-Time Asset Pricing Model with Habits and Durability John H. Cochrane June 14, 2012 Abstract I solve a continuous-time asset pricing economy with quadratic utility and complex temporal nonseparabilities.

More information

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment Goal: Endogenize firm characteristics and risk. Value/growth Size Leverage New issues,... This lecture: q theory of investment Irreversible investment and real

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application Russell Cooper, John Haltiwanger and Jonathan Willis January 2005 Abstract This paper studies capital adjustment costs. Our goal here

More information

Macroeconomics and finance

Macroeconomics and finance Macroeconomics and finance 1 1. Temporary equilibrium and the price level [Lectures 11 and 12] 2. Overlapping generations and learning [Lectures 13 and 14] 2.1 The overlapping generations model 2.2 Expectations

More information

Housing Prices and Growth

Housing Prices and Growth Housing Prices and Growth James A. Kahn June 2007 Motivation Housing market boom-bust has prompted talk of bubbles. But what are fundamentals? What is the right benchmark? Motivation Housing market boom-bust

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

A Rational, Decentralized Ponzi Scheme

A Rational, Decentralized Ponzi Scheme A Rational, Decentralized Ponzi Scheme Ronaldo Carpio 1,* 1 Department of Economics, University of California, Davis November 17, 2011 Abstract We present a model of an industry with a dynamic, monopoly

More information

The Cagan Model. Lecture 15 by John Kennes March 25

The Cagan Model. Lecture 15 by John Kennes March 25 The Cagan Model Lecture 15 by John Kennes March 25 The Cagan Model Let M denote a country s money supply and P its price level. Higher expected inflation lowers the demand for real balances M/P by raising

More information

A Quantitative Theory of Unsecured Consumer Credit with Risk of Default

A Quantitative Theory of Unsecured Consumer Credit with Risk of Default A Quantitative Theory of Unsecured Consumer Credit with Risk of Default Satyajit Chatterjee Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Makoto Nakajima University of Pennsylvania Dean Corbae University of Pittsburgh

More information

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities 14.452. Topic 7. Nominal rigidities Olivier Blanchard April 2007 Nr. 1 1. Motivation, and organization Why introduce nominal rigidities, and what do they imply? In monetary models, the price level (the

More information

Online Appendix: Extensions

Online Appendix: Extensions B Online Appendix: Extensions In this online appendix we demonstrate that many important variations of the exact cost-basis LUL framework remain tractable. In particular, dual problem instances corresponding

More information

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010 Problem set 5 Asset pricing Markus Roth Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Juli 5, 200 Markus Roth (Macroeconomics 2) Problem set 5 Juli 5, 200 / 40 Contents Problem 5 of problem

More information

Time-Varying Employment Risks, Consumption Composition, and Fiscal Policy

Time-Varying Employment Risks, Consumption Composition, and Fiscal Policy 1 / 38 Time-Varying Employment Risks, Consumption Composition, and Fiscal Policy Kazufumi Yamana 1 Makoto Nirei 2 Sanjib Sarker 3 1 Hitotsubashi University 2 Hitotsubashi University 3 Utah State University

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Dynamic Inconsistency and Non-preferential Taxation of Foreign Capital

Dynamic Inconsistency and Non-preferential Taxation of Foreign Capital Dynamic Inconsistency and Non-preferential Taxation of Foreign Capital Kaushal Kishore Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas, USA. Santanu Roy Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas, USA June

More information

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy Vasco Cúrdia FRB New York Michael Woodford Columbia University Conference on Monetary Policy and Financial Frictions Cúrdia and Woodford () Credit Frictions

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

Oil Monopoly and the Climate Oil Monopoly the Climate By John Hassler, Per rusell, Conny Olovsson I Introduction This paper takes as given that (i) the burning of fossil fuel increases the carbon dioxide content in the atmosphere,

More information

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains Maria-Augusta Miceli University of Rome Sapienza Claudia Nardone University of Rome Sapienza October 8, 06 Abstract We here want to analyze how the imperfect competition

More information

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014 I. The Solow model Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis Universidad Autónoma de Madrid Autumn 2014 Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) I. The Solow model Autumn 2014 1 / 38 Objectives In this first lecture

More information

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University April 12, 2008 Abstract A model of mixed oligopoly is constructed in which a Home public firm

More information

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) Monetary Policy, 16/3 2017 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) 1. Money in the short run: Incomplete

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk Pricing Unexpected Growth Fluctuations Lars Peter Hansen 1 2007 Nemmers Lecture, Northwestern University 1 Based in part joint work with John Heaton, Nan Li,

More information

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model Guido Ascari University of Pavia Nicola Branzoli University of Pavia October 27, 2006 Abstract This note shows that full price indexation

More information

1 The Solow Growth Model

1 The Solow Growth Model 1 The Solow Growth Model The Solow growth model is constructed around 3 building blocks: 1. The aggregate production function: = ( ()) which it is assumed to satisfy a series of technical conditions: (a)

More information

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries BACKGROUND PAPER FOR THE WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2008 Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries Larry Karp The findings, interpretations, and conclusions

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Eric Sims University of otre Dame Spring 7 Introduction This set of notes studies fiscal policy in the RBC model. Fiscal policy refers to government

More information

From Consumer Incomes to Car Ages: How the Distribution of Income Affects the Distribution of Vehicle Vintages

From Consumer Incomes to Car Ages: How the Distribution of Income Affects the Distribution of Vehicle Vintages From Consumer Incomes to Car Ages: How the Distribution of Income Affects the Distribution of Vehicle Vintages Anna V. Yurko National Research University - Higher School of Economics Pokrovski Bulvar,

More information

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel Appendix to: Why Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down? AMoreElaborateModel Antti Petajisto Yale School of Management February 2004 1 A More Elaborate Model 1.1 Motivation Our earlier model provides a

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

TDT4171 Artificial Intelligence Methods

TDT4171 Artificial Intelligence Methods TDT47 Artificial Intelligence Methods Lecture 7 Making Complex Decisions Norwegian University of Science and Technology Helge Langseth IT-VEST 0 helgel@idi.ntnu.no TDT47 Artificial Intelligence Methods

More information

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE Macroeconomic Dynamics, (9), 55 55. Printed in the United States of America. doi:.7/s6559895 ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE KEVIN X.D. HUANG Vanderbilt

More information

Lecture 6 Search and matching theory

Lecture 6 Search and matching theory Lecture 6 Search and matching theory Leszek Wincenciak, Ph.D. University of Warsaw 2/48 Lecture outline: Introduction Search and matching theory Search and matching theory The dynamics of unemployment

More information

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M Macroeconomics MEDEG, UC3M Lecture 5: Consumption Hernán D. Seoane UC3M Spring, 2016 Introduction A key component in NIPA accounts and the households budget constraint is the consumption It represents

More information

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015 I. The Solow model Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis Universidad Autónoma de Madrid September 2015 Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) I. The Solow model September 2015 1 / 43 Objectives In this first lecture

More information

Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction

Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction Online Appendix for Missing Growth from Creative Destruction Philippe Aghion Antonin Bergeaud Timo Boppart Peter J Klenow Huiyu Li January 17, 2017 A1 Heterogeneous elasticities and varying markups In

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information