Skewness of Firm Fundamentals, Firm Growth, and Cross-Sectional Stock Returns

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Skewness of Firm Fundamentals, Firm Growth, and Cross-Sectional Stock Returns"

Transcription

1 Skewness of Firm Fundamentals, Firm Growth, and Cross-Sectional Stock Returns Yuecheng Jia Shu Yan December 2015 Abstract We present a novel interpretation of the conditional sample skewness of firm fundamentals as a proxy of the expected growth rate of firm cash flows and therefore being positively related to the expected stock return. Empirically, we document significant evidence that the skewness of firm fundamentals positively predicts cross-sectional stock returns and future firm growth. Our findings cannot be explained by existing predictors and risk factors. The evidence further indicates that the alternative skewness measures of firm fundamentals are proxies of different factors driving firm cash flows. We would like to thank Yuzhao Zhang for helpful comments. All errors are our own. Both Jia and Yan are at Department of Finance, Spears School of Business, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, OK 74078, USA. Phone: (Yan). Fax: Please address correspondence to yuecheng.jia@okstate.edu or yanshu@okstate.edu.

2 Skewness of Firm Fundamentals, Firm Growth, and Cross-Sectional Stock Returns Abstract We present a novel interpretation of the conditional sample skewness of firm fundamentals as a proxy of the expected growth rate of firm cash flows and therefore being positively related to the expected stock return. Empirically, we document significant evidence that the skewness of firm fundamentals positively predicts cross-sectional stock returns and future firm growth. Our findings cannot be explained by existing predictors and risk factors. The evidence further indicates that the alternative skewness measures of firm fundamentals are proxies of different factors driving firm cash flows. JEL Classification: G12 Keyword: Skewness, fundamental, growth, stock return, earnings, profitability

3 1 Introduction Fama and French (2006, 2008) point out that most stock return anomalies, no matter whether they are rational or irrational, are consistent with the basic stock valuation equation, which is a mathematical identity that relates firm cash flows and stock returns (e.g., Campbell and Shiller (1988) and Vuolteenaho (2002)). According to the equation, higher expected growth rate of future cash flows implies higher expected stock return if the book-to-market ratio is fixed. 1 Fama and French argue that the anomaly variables such as book-to-market ratio, net stock issuance, accruals, lagged stock return, asset growth, and profitability are proxies of expected cash flows. One notable feature of the aforementioned return predictors is that they are the first moments of firm fundamentals or stock returns. In this paper, we propose the conditional sample skewness of firm fundamentals as a new proxy of expected growth rate of cash flows. We demonstrate analytically and numerically that, for very general data-generating specifications, the conditional sample skewness of firm cash flows is positively correlated with the expected growth rate of the underlying process. 2 Based on the basic stock valuation equation, this interpretation of skewness of firm fundamentals implies our main testable hypothesis: The conditional sample skewness of firm fundamentals positively predicts future stock returns. Beyond the first moments, researchers have examined whether the second moments of firm fundamentals can predict stock returns and firm performance (e.g., Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002), Johnson (2004), Dichev and Tang (2009), and Gow and Taylor (2009)). 3 To our knowledge, our paper is the first to examine the return predictability of the skewness 1 This conclusion can also be drawn from the q-theory of investment (e.g., Hou, Xue, and Zhang (2014)). The valuation equation is a tautology and can be interpreted in alternative ways. 2 In addition, we show that a high value of the conditional sample skewness implies high acceleration rate and high level of the underlying process. Both effects strengthen the positive relation between the conditional sample skewness of firm fundamentals and future stock returns. 3 There is also a literature on return predictability by stock volatility, the second moment of stock returns. See, for example, Goyal and Santa-Clara (2003), Ang, Hodrick, Xing, and Zhang (2006), and Jiang, Xu, and Yao (2009). 1

4 of firm fundamentals. Using the conditional sample skewness of firm fundamentals to infer the expected growth rate of firm cash flows has a couple of advantages over other econometric approaches. First it is very easy to calculate. Second, the approach does not make any assumptions about the underlying data-generating mechanism and is robust to many alternative model specifications. Our paper also differs from the previous studies on the return predictability of stock return skewness in several ways. 4 First, our analysis is preference-free as we do not require investors to prefer positive skewness in stock returns. Second, in contrast to the negative relation between the return skewness and future stock returns documented in the literature, our model dictates a positive relation between the skewness of firm fundamentals and future stock returns. Third, as we will see later, incorporating the return skewness as a control variable in the empirical analysis does not change our results for the skewness of firm fundamentals. To test our hypothesis, we use three measures of cash flows: gross profitability of Novy- Marx (2013) (GP), earnings per share (EP S), and analyst earnings forecasts (AF ). 5 We denote the skewness of these three measures by SK GP, SK EP S, and SK AF. Unlike the first two skewness measures which are time-series estimates, SK AF is the cross-sectional skewness of analysts forecasts, and does not conform to our argument that the conditional sample skewness is a proxy of expected growth rate of the underlying cash flow process. To see that the return predictability of SK AF is consistent with that of SK GP and SK EP S, we draw support from the literature of stock analysts. 6 Both theory and empirical evidence in the 4 The literature on stock return (co)skewness dates back to the seminal work of Kraus and Litzenberger (1976). Recent studies include Harvey and Siddique (2000), Dittmar (2002), Barone-Adesi, Gagliardini, and Urga (2004), Chung, Johnson, and Schill (2006), Mitton and Vorkink (2007), Boyer, Mitton, and Vorkink (2010), Engle (2011), Chang, Christoffersen, and Jacobs (2013), Conrad, Dittmar, and Ghysels (2013), and Chabi-Yo, Leisen, and Renault (2014). 5 We have also considered alternative cash flow measures including ROE and earnings surprises. The results for the alternative measures are very similar and available upon request. 6 The important and relevant articles in this literature include Scharfstein and Stein (1990), Avery and Chevalier (1999), Hong, Kubik, and Solomon (2000), Clement and Tse (2005), Clarke and Subramanian (2006), and Evgeniou, Fang, Hogarth, and Karelaia (2013). 2

5 literature indicate that less skilled analysts tend to herd while more skilled analysts tend to be bolder and are likely to deviate from the consensus. Because skewness is driven by outliers, SK AF is likely to pick up the forecasts of more skilled analysts, which are supposed to be more accurate. Consequently, SK AF should be positively correlated with expected future earnings and predict future stock returns. Strongly supporting our hypothesis, all three skewness measures are positively significant in predicting cross-sectional stock returns. For example, when stocks are sorted on SK GP into decile portfolios, the equal-weighted average next-quarter return increases from decile 1 to decile 10. The H-L spread between deciles 10 and 1 is 1.55% per quarter and statistically significant. Value-weighting stock returns and adjusting average returns by the conventional risk factors do not change the results. The predictability evidence is corroborated by the Fama-MacBeth regressions, even in the presence of other return predictors including the level of GP. To strengthen our argument, we further test whether the skewness measures positively predict future firm cash flows, which are measured by ROE and GP. The evidence overwhelmingly supports our argument. All three skewness measures can significantly forecast future ROE and GP for up to 4 quarters. If we sort stocks on SK GP into decile portfolios, the next-quarter H-L spread in ROE is 1.20% and statistically significant. The next-quarter H-L spread in GP is much higher at 3.76%. We find similar evidence for SK EP S but weaker evidence for SK AF. These results suggest that the alternative skewness measures are related to different aspects of firm cash flows. We further examine the differences across the alternative skewness measures by comparing their return predictability. Only for the sample of stocks with valid observations of SK AF, the predictability of SK EP S is subsumed by that of SK AF. We don t find SK GP and SK AF to dominate each other. For the larger sample of stocks with valid observations of SK GP and SK EP S, neither skewness measure dominates the other. These findings further support the view that the alternative skewness measures are proxies of different factors of firm cash 3

6 flows. An alternative motivation of our main hypothesis is the positive impact of cash flow skewness on firm growth option. In the literature, a firm s growth options are treated as options written on the firm s cash flow process (e.g., Berk, Green, and Naik (1999) and Carlson, Fisher, and Giammarino (2004)). A standard option pricing argument illustrates that everything else fixed, higher skewness of firm cash flows leads to higher value of firm growth option. Following the approach of Bernardo, Chowdhry, and Goyal (2007), this implies higher stock risk and therefore higher stock return. We also test this argument with two proxies of growth option: market asset-to-book asset ratio and Tobin s q. We find strong evidence supporting this argument as well. Studies of higher moments of firm fundamentals or macroeconomic variables are scarce. Colacito, Ghysels, and Meng (2013) show that the skewness of forecasts on the GDP growth rate made by professional forecasters can predict stock market return. In a separate study, we consider the skewness of aggregate stock market and find that it can predict stock market return. The current paper differs from these two studies in a couple of ways. First, we consider the skewness of firm fundamentals and individual stock returns. Second but more importantly, we do not make specific assumptions on the data-generating processes and investors utility functions as our approach is based on the basic stock valuation equation. Also related to our paper, Scherbina (2008) constructs a non-parametric skewness measure of analysts earnings forecasts as the difference of median and mean forecasts and finds that it negatively predicts future stock returns, opposite to the positive relation we find for SK AF. 7 In addition to the methods of measuring skewness of analyst forecasts, there are a couple of important differences between our papers. First, Scherbina s evidence is weak for large firms while our evidence is very strong for large firms. Second, she argues that her findings are caused by negative information withheld by analysts being incorporated in stock 7 The non-parametric skewness measure is not an accurate proxy of population skewness for many probability distributions. One such example is a bi-modal distribution where the non-parametric skewness measure can have the wrong sign. 4

7 prices with a significant delay while we argue that more skilled analysts are more likely to issue bolder (but more accurate) forecasts. The rest of the paper is organized as following. In Section 2, we show why the conditional sample skewness of firm fundamentals contains information on the firm cash flows and as a result positively predicts stock returns. We describe the data and econometric methodology in Section 3. Section 4 discusses the empirical evidence. Section 5 concludes. 2 Information Content of Conditional Sample Skewness of Firm Fundamentals In this section, we first demonstrate a novel approach to infer sampling properties of general time-series processes from the conditional sample skewness. Then we apply the results to firm fundamentals, and derive the relation between the conditional sample skewness of firm fundamentals and expected stock return. 2.1 Conditional Skewness of Small Samples To estimate the conditional skewness of a time-series process at time t using the past sample of size n, {x t n+1,..., x t }, the standard formula is 1 n m 3 ˆb = s = n i=1 (x t n+i x) 3 3 [ 1 n i=1 (x t n+i x) 2], (1) 3/2 n 1 where x is the sample mean, s is the sample standard deviation, and m 3 is the sample third central moment. Alternative formulas can be used but they do not affect our results. We show next that the estimated ˆb is informative about the order of the sample observations of the change of x. Define the change of x as x t = x t x t 1. For the ease of presentation, assume x t n = 0. Using x t = n i=1 x t n+i, we can express the first three 5

8 sample moments as x = 1 n s 2 = = 1 n n i=1 i j=1 x t n+j n (n i + 1) x t n+i, (2) i=1 1 n 1 ( n i x t n+j x i=1 j=1 ) 2 ( 1 n i j 1 = n 1 n x t n+j i=1 j=1 ( m 3 = 1 n i ) 3 x t n+j x n = 1 n i=1 j=1 ( n i i=1 j=1 j 1 n x t n+j n j=i+1 n j=i+1 ( 1 j 1 ) ) 2 x t n+j, (3) n ( 1 j 1 ) ) 3 x t n+j. (4) n In the sample mean x, earlier observations of x t n+i are clearly over-weighed than later observations. To see how the location of an observation affects its weight in s 2 and m 3, we consider two examples. For n = 3, simple calculations show s 2 = 2 3 ( ) x x 2 x 3 + x 2 3, m 3 = 1 9 ( x 3 x 2 ) ( 2 x x 2 x x 2 3). In this case, s 2 is symmetric with respect to x 2 and x 3 while m 3 is monotonically increasing in x 3 x 2. For n = 4, we can write s 2 = 1 4 ( 3 x x x x 2 x x 2 x x 3 x 4 ), m 3 = 3 8 ( x 4 x 2 ) ( x x x 2 x x 2 x x 3 x 4 ). In this case, s 2 is symmetric with respect to x 2 and x 4. m 3 is monotonically increasing in x 4 x 2 if the second part of m 3 is positive, which is the case when x 3 = 0. These two 6

9 examples suggest that the sign and magnitude of m 3 depend on the order of observations { x i } while s 2 is not. This seems intuitive from the construction of s 2 and m 3. The second moment is insensitive to whether an observation occurs early or late in the sample but the third moment may over-weighs/under-weighs an observation depending on its location in the sample. Taken together, a high value of ˆb seems to suggest relatively high (low) values for more recent (earlier) observations of x t. It is messy to extend the above examples to general settings without specifying the underlying data-generating process. In the following, we consider the class of AR(1) processes x t = ρx t 1 + u t, (5) where ρ 1 is a constant and u t is an iid standard white noise process. Note that x t is a random walk when ρ = 1. The initial value x 0 is set to be zero for simplicity. There is no constant term on the right-hand side although including one does not change the results. Instead of providing analytical proofs, we conduct the following numerical analysis. To be consistent with our later empirical work, we consider n = 8, 12, 16, and 20 and ρ = 0.9, 0.95, and 1. 8 To take into account of sampling errors, we use the Monte Carlo simulation method to examine the correlations between the conditional sample skewness and cross-sections of sample observations of x t. The steps are detailed as following. Step 1: For fixed n and ρ, independently generate N = 1, 000, 000 paths of x t according to equation (5). Denote the observations of the ith path by {x it } n t=0. Step 2: For the ith path, compute the sample skewness ˆb i. 8 The small sample sizes are appropriate when we consider low-frequency financial accounting data such as the quarterly earnings. Using larger sample sizes to estimate the conditional skewness is problematic if the underlying data-generating mechanism is time-varying and non-stable. The near-unit-root or unit-root specification for x is also reasonable as most financial accounting variables are highly persistent. Negative values may arise in the AR(1) process, which are undesirable since most accounting variables are nonnegative. This problem can be solved by taking logarithm. In most practical cases, the results are not affected by the log transformation. 7

10 Step 3: For each value of t = 2,..., n, compute the correlation of ˆb i and x it across the N sample paths and denote it by c(t). Figure 1 shows the plots of c(t) as a function of t for different values of n and ρ. Several patterns are important to note. First, for every (n, ρ) pair, the value of c(t) is negative during the first half of the sample but positive during the second half of the sample. Second, c(t) is monotonically increasing in t for the cases of n = 8, from less than 0.2 to over 0.2 when ρ = 1. For the cases of n = 12, 16, 20, c(t) is monotonically increasing except for the two ends of the sample. The minimum and maximum of c(t) still occur near the beginning and ending of the sample, respectively. Third, when n is fixed, the increasing pattern of c(t) becomes more significant as ρ increases to 1. Fourth, when ρ is fixed, the shape of c(t) becomes flatter as n increases. The minimum and maximum of c(t) are located further away from the first and last observations. These correlation patterns of c(t) are not sensitive to the iid assumption for u t as we have checked various heteroskedastic specifications for u t. We have also considered numerous alternative ARMA(p,q) specifications for x t and find qualitatively similar results. The numerical results confirm our conjecture that the conditional sample skewness ˆb is informative about the order of observations of x t at least for small sample size up to 20. A high value of ˆb suggests that the recent growth rates are likely high while the earlier growth rates are likely low. A low value of ˆb suggests the opposite. Moreover, ˆb is not only an indicator of the current growth rate of x t but also positively associated with the acceleration rate (change of growth rate) of x t. In addition to the growth rate of x t, it is also interesting to examine the correlations of ˆb with the levels of x t. To this end, we use the same Step 1 an Step 2 of the previous analysis. But in the new Step 3, we calculate the cross-sectional correlations of ˆb i with x it (denoted by C(t)) instead of x it. Figure 2 shows the plots of C(t). We make several comments. First, C(t) is mostly negative except when t is close to the sample end n. Second, C(t) is initially decreasing but becomes increasing as t increases, with the maximum attained at 8

11 t = n. The near-convexity of C(t) is consistent with the near-monotonicity of c(t) shown in Figure 1. Third, with fixed n, C(t) becomes smaller when ρ increases. Fourth, with fixed ρ, C(t) becomes larger when n increases. Overall, the most important finding is that a higher value of ˆb is more likely associated with a higher value of the last sample observation than past observations and the effect is stronger for lower ρ and higher n. Having seen how ˆb is related to the past growth rates of x, an important question is: What does ˆb tell us about the expected future growth rate of x. If x t is iid over time, the above results are not useful for prediction purpose because knowing ˆb and therefore the order of the past observations of x t does not provide additional information about future x t. In real financial data, however, x t is often non-iid, and ˆb can be informative about the expected growth of x. As an example, consider the following process x t = u t + ε t (6) u t = µ + θu t 1 + e t (7) where µ and 0 < θ < 1 are constants, and ε t and e t are iid standard white noise processes. In this model, u t is the expected growth rate of x and follows an AR(1) process which is unobserved. A high value of x t implies a high value of u t and consequently higher future growths of x due to the persistence of the growth rate process. Estimates and predictions of this type of models can be obtained using methods such as the Kalman filters. But there are some serious issues with the parametric approach. First, accurate estimates of such models require long time-series data, which are not available. Second, the models are not stable over time. This can happen, for example, when there are structural breaks in the underlying data-generating process. Third, the models are likely misspecified. Alternative ARMA specifications or regime-switching models can provide similar fit of the same data. Using the conditional sample skewness ˆb to imply the expected growth rate of x circum- 9

12 vents these problems. It doesn t need long time series to estimate. More importantly, it doesn t rely on any parametric models. It allows many different types of model specifications. As long as the growth rate of x is positively autocorrelated to a certain extent, a high value of ˆb implies that the future growth rate of x is also likely high. The same argument also implies potentially high acceleration and level of x when ˆb is high. 2.2 Skewness of Firm Fundamentals and Stock Returns We now apply the previous results for general time series to firm fundamentals. Let A t denote a measure of the fundamental cash flows of a firm at time t. We do not impose any parametric specifications on A t other than that it satisfies certain time-series properties so that, as shown in the last section, the conditional sample skewness is positively related to the growth rate, acceleration, and level of A t. Suppose that we have calculated ˆb using the historical data of size n 20, {A t n+1,..., A t }. As we will argue next, there are three channels through which ˆb positively predicts future stock returns. First, we have demonstrated that a high value of ˆb implies that the recent growth rates of A are likely high. If the growth rate of A is persistent, then the expected future growth rate of A will also be high. According to the basic stock valuation equation, higher expected growth rate of firm cash flows implies higher stock returns. Consequently, ˆb positively predicts future stock returns. Second, we have also shown previously that a high value of ˆb implies positive acceleration of A, in other words, increasing growth rate of A during the recent sample period. If the positive acceleration persists into the future, then the expected future growth rate of A will be even higher than that implied by the previous point. This second-order effect strengthens the positive return predictability of ˆb. Lastly, recall that a high value of ˆb also implies that the current level of A is potentially high. To see how this fact leads to higher future stock returns, we resort to the literature of firm growth options. In this literature, the firm value is decomposed into two parts: firm 10

13 fundamental cash flows and growth option. We follow the approach of Bernardo, Chowdhry, and Goyal (2007) by treating the growth option as a call option on A. It is well-known that the call option value is an increasing function of the underlying process. Hence a high value of ˆb likely causes the value of firm growth option to increase, which leads to more weight of the growth option in the firm total value. As demonstrated in Bernardo, Chowdhry, and Goyal (2007), the risk and therefore return of the growth option are higher than those of the firm cash flows. Combining the above results leads to the third channel that ˆb positively predicts future stock returns. The effects of all three channels are in the same direction regardless which of them is at work. We therefore conclude that the conditional sample skewness of firm fundamentals positively predicts future stock returns. 3 Data and Methodology In this section, we first show the definitions of skewness measures of firm fundamentals. We then describe the data. Finally, we discuss our econometric methods. 3.1 Definition of Skewness Measures In quarter t, we follow Gu and Wu (2003) to define skewness of GP and EP S as the standard skewness coefficient of lagged observations during the rolling window of quarters t n to t 1: SK GP,t = SK EP S,t = n (n 1)(n 2) n (n 1)(n 2) t 1 τ=t n τ=t n ( ) 3 GPτ µ GP, (8) s GP t 1 ( ) 3 EP Sτ µ EP S, (9) s EP S where µ GP (µ EP S ) and s GP (s EP S ) are, respectively, the sample average and standard deviation of GP (EP S) for the rolling window. In the benchmark case reported in the paper, we 11

14 fix n = 8. The results for n up to 20 are very similar and available upon request. Note that we don t use the quarter t GP and EP S in the definitions because they not reported until quarter t + 1. When examining whether the skewness of earnings skewness up to quarter t predicts the stock returns in quarter t + 1, using future information that is available in quarter t + 1 but not in quarter t biases the statistical inference. We in fact have conducted (unreported) empirical analysis without skipping quarter t and have found even stronger (but biased) results. To define the skewness of analysts forecasts, we follow Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002) to use the most recent valid analysts annual earning forecasts by the end of quarter t. 9 We restrict our sample to stocks with at least three analyst forecasts in a quarter so that skewness is well defined. The skewness across analysts is then SK AF,t = N (N 1)(N 2) N ( ) 3 epsj µ eps, (10) where eps j is the earnings forecast of the jth analyst, µ eps and s eps are, respectively, the sample average and standard deviation of all forecasts, and N is the number of analysts. Note that we don t skip quarter t as for the first two skewness measures of firm fundamentals j=1 because analyst forecasts are known before quarter t + 1. s eps 3.2 Data Stock return and accounting data are obtained from CRSP and COMPUSTAT. The I/B/E/S provides analysts earnings forecasts. We consider all NYSE, AMEX and NASDAQ firms in the CRSP monthly stock return files up to December, 2013 except financial stocks (four digit SIC codes between 6000 and 6999) and stocks with share price less than $5. To be 9 Our measure is updated every quarter while Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002) construct their dispersion in analysts forecasts at monthly frequency. We have also considered dropping the forecasts made in the last five days of quarter t to make sure all forecasts are observed. The results are almost identical to those reported in paper. 12

15 included in the sample of SK GP or SK EP S, we require a firm to have at least 16 quarters of gross profitability or earnings data during The construction of each observation of skewness measure needs observations of 8 consecutive quarters. We begin portfolio sorting and regression analysis for SK GP and SK EP S from Q1, 1973, and for SK AF from Q1, For each quarter, the accounting variables are defined as follows. GP : Following Novy-Marx (2013), gross profitability is quarterly revenues minus quarterly cost of goods sold scaled by quarterly asset total. EP S: Quarterly earnings per share before extraordinary items. M C: Market capitalization is the quarter-end shares outstanding multiplied by the stock price. BM: Book-to-market ratio is the ratio of quarterly book equity to quarter-end market capitalization. Quarterly book equity is constructed by following Hou, Xue, and Zhang (2014) (footnote 9), which is basically a quarterly version of book equity of Davis, Fama, and French (2000). ROE: Return on equity is defined as income before extraordinary items (IBQ) divided by 1-quarter-lagged book equity. M ABA: Market asset-to-book asset ratio is defined as [Total Asset Total Book Common Equity+Market Equity]/Total Assets. Tobin s q: It is defined as [Market Equity+Preferred Stock+Current Liabilities Current Assets Total+Long Term Debt]/Total Assets. Disp: Dispersion of analysts forecasts is defined in almost the same way as Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002) using the detail history file of I/B/E/S. The only difference is that we use quarterly frequency instead of monthly frequency. If an analyst makes more than one forecast in a given quarter, only the most recent forecast is used in the calculation. 13

16 Firm size and book-to-market ratio are standard control variables in asset pricing studies. ROE is a popular measure of firm cash flows and has been shown to predict stock returns (e.g., Hou, Xue, and Zhang (2014)). We follow Cao, Simin, and Zhao (2008) to use MABA and Tobin s q as proxies of firm growth options. We have also considered the dispersion in analysts forecasts defined in Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002) as a control variable when we examine the return predictability of SK AF. But controlling the dispersion does not change the results. So we do not include it in the paper. The variables related to stock returns are defined in the following. MOM: Momentum for month t is defined as the cumulative return between months t 6 and t 1. We follow the convention in the literature by skipping month t when MOM is used to predict returns in month t + 1. We have also used the cumulative return between months t 11 and t 1 and obtained similar results. Idvol: Idiosyncratic volatility is, following Jiang, Xu, and Yao (2009), the standard deviation of the residuals of the Fama and French (1993) 3-factor model using daily returns in the quarter. Idskew: Following Harvey and Siddique (2000) and Bali, Cakici, and Whitelaw (2011), it is defined as the skewness of the regression residuals of the market model augmented by the squared market excess return. We use daily returns in the quarter to estimate the regression. P rskew: It is predicted idiosyncratic skewness defined in Boyer, Mitton, and Vorkink (2010). We obtain the P rskew data from Brian Boyer s website. M AX: Following Bali, Cakici, and Whitelaw (2011), it is the average of the two highest daily returns in quarter t. Note that we use quarterly frequency instead of monthly frequency. 14

17 We use Iddvol as a control because a number of studies have documented that it predicts returns. The skewness measures of stock returns, Idskew, P rskew, and M AX are good controls to evaluate additional return explanatory power of skewness of firm fundamentals. We have also considered total return skewness of daily stock returns in the quarter and obtained similar results. We winsorize all the variables at 1% and 99% levels although the results do not change significantly without winsorizing or winsorizing at 0.5% and 99.5% levels. 3.3 Econometric Methods We rely on the portfolio sorts and cross-sectional regressions of Fama and MacBeth (1973) for our empirical investigation. For single portfolio sorts, we rank stocks on a skewness measure of firm fundamentals into decile portfolios and then consider both equally-weighted and value-weighted portfolio returns. If the skewness is positively related to stock returns, we expect an increasing pattern of portfolio returns from decile 1 to decile 10. For double portfolio sorts, we first rank stocks into quintiles by a control variable such as MC and then further sort stocks within each portfolio into quintiles by the skewness measure. If the control variable can explain the predictability of skewness, we expect the increasing pattern of returns in skewness to be much less significant in each quintile of the control variable. To compute t-statistics of average portfolio returns, we use the Newey-West adjusted standard errors because of the persistence in the portfolios. For the Fama-MacBeth regressions, we expect the estimated average coefficient of the skewness measure to be positive and significant. The cross-sectional regressions allow us to estimate the marginal effect of the skewness measure when controlling for other variables known to predict stock returns. In the most general specification, we include all the control variables in the regression. If the skewness measure captures information about expected stock returns beyond that in other variables, the coefficient of the skewness measure should be significant even in the presence of all the control variables. 15

18 We also use the Fama-MacBeth regression approach to compare the explanatory power of different skewness measures. To do so, we include two or three skewness measures in one regression. If the coefficient of one skewness measure is no longer significant in the presence of another skewness measure, it indicates that the later skewness measure dominates the first measure in the sense that it subsumes all the explanatory power of the first measure. 4 Empirical Evidence 4.1 Data Descriptions The data of skewness measures are unbalanced. There are 350,050, 384,402, and 162,782 firm-quarter observations for SK GP, SK EP S, and SK AF, respectively. The sample size for SK AF is less than half of those for the other two measures because not only the sample period for the I/B/E/S data is shorter but also many small firms do not have enough analyst coverage to compute skewness. Table 1 reports the average contemporaneous cross-sectional correlations of quarterly skewness measures and some control variables. Amongst the three skewness measures, SK GP and SK EP S are mildly correlated with correlation coefficient of The forward-looking measure, SK AF, is essentially uncorrelated with the other two time-series measures. The results indicate that different skewness measures have different information contents about firm cash flows. SK GP is mildly correlated with MOM and level of GP but uncorrelated with other controls. SK EP S seems to be slightly correlated with the control variables but all correlation coefficients are below In contrast, the forward-looking skewness, SK AF, is uncorrelated with all the control variables. 16

19 4.2 Single Portfolio Sorts Table 2 reports the average time-series returns and characteristics of the decile portfolios formed by sorting stocks on the three skewness measures. When sorted on SK GP as in panel A, the average equal-weighted quarterly return increases from decile 1 (2.99%) to decile 10 (4.54%). The average H-L spread between is 1.55% per quarter (or 6.20% per year) and highly significant (t = 5.67). To make sure that the significant H-L spread is not driven by higher stock risks, we estimate the risk-adjusted α using the four-factor model of Carhart (1997). The risk-adjusted H-L spread is even higher at 1.69% and significant. The results for value-weighted returns are very similar to those for equal-weighted returns, implying that the findings are not dominated by small stocks. Looking at the characteristics of the decile portfolios, low-sk GP stocks have low past return, GP, and ROE but slightly high book-to-market ratio and idiosyncratic volatility. One reason of these patterns in control variables is that low-sk GP stocks are past underperformers in terms of profitability. To make sure that the return predictability of SK GP is not a result of the firm characteristics, we will use double portfolio sorts and Fama-MacBeth regressions. The results of portfolios sorts on SK EP S in panel B are very close to those for SK GP. The unadjusted and adjusted H-L spreads for SK EP S are actually slightly higher than those for SK GP. The firm characteristics of the decile portfolios also exhibit similar patterns as those in panel A. Panel C shows the results for SK AF. The portfolio returns are generally increasing from decile 1 to decile 10. All average equal-weighted/value-weighted unadjusted/adjusted H-L spreads are higher than 1.26% per quarter and statistically significant. The numbers for SK AF are smaller and less significant than those for SK GP and SK EP S. Interestingly, we do not observe any significant patterns in firm characteristics. There are several reasons why the results for SK AF are different from those for SK GP and SK EP S. First, the sample period for SK AF is shorter. Second, the stocks for SK AF tend to be larger and better followed firms. 17

20 Third, as we see in Table 1, SK AF are uncorrelated with firm characteristics. Overall, in spite of the obvious differences across the three skewness measures, we find consistent positive predictive relation between skewness of firm fundamentals and future stock returns, confirming our hypothesis. The results are robust regardless whether the returns are equal-weighted or value-weighted, and unadjusted or risk-adjusted. 4.3 Double Portfolio Sorts We now investigate whether the predictability of the skewness measures are caused by firm characteristics. We use the double portfolio sort approach by first sorting stocks on firm characteristics and then sorting on the skewness measures. Table 3 reports the average equalweighted returns of double-sorted portfolios for the six characteristics reported in Table 2. The results for value-weighted returns are very similar and not shown for brevity. We have also considered a number of other control variables and their results are available upon requests. First, we consider the results for SK GP in panel A. When stocks are initially ranked by MC, the H-L spreads of skewness quintiles show a decreasing pattern from MC quintile 1 (2.51%) to MC quintile 5 (0.58%), suggesting that the predictability of SK GP is stronger for small stocks. In contrast, the predictability of SK GP is stronger for high momentum, GP, and idiosyncratic volatility stocks but there is no clear pattern for BM and ROE. No matter which firm characteristic is considered, all H-L spreads remain positive and most of them are statistically significant. The evidence indicates that the return predictive power of SK GP can not be explained the firm characteristics. The results for SK EP S in panel B are similar to those for SK GP with a few differences. The predictability of SK EP S is strong for low BM and high ROE stocks. The H-L spreads for GP quintiles exhibit a U-shape pattern. If any firm characteristic can explain SK EP S, it is ROE because only one of the five H-L spreads is significant. Some loss of statistical significance can be attributed to the higher standard errors due to smaller sample sizes. Close 18

21 inspection of the ROE quintiles reveals non-linear interactions among stock return, SK EP S, and ROE. We will get a clearer picture when we estimate Fama-MacBeth regressions with other control variables. Finally, we consider the results for SK AF in panel C. In all cases but one, the H-L spreads are positive, many of which are significant. The relations between H-L spreads and the firm characteristics are not generally linear. For example, the H-L spreads for BM quintiles are hump-shaped. In sum, no characteristic seems to be able to explain the predictive power of SK AF. 4.4 Fama-MacBeth Regressions We further examine the return predictability of the skewness measures with the Fama- MacBeth regressions, which allow us to control for other return predictors. The results are reported in Table 4. For each skewness measure, we estimate eight regressions. The first model uses a skewness as the only explanatory variable. Models (2)-(7) consider the six control variables, one at a time. Because of different sample sizes for different measures, we reestimate these models for each skewness measure. Model (8) includes the skewness measure and all six control variables. First, let us look at the results for SK GP in panel A. The average coefficient of SK GP in model (1) is positive and significant at the 1% level (0.24 and t = 6.18). Every control variables but MC is significant when it is used alone to forecast returns. In model (8) where all controls are incorporated, the average coefficient of SK GP is smaller in magnitude than that in model (1) but still significant at the 1% level (0.11 and t = 3.87). Interestingly, the average coefficient for MC is now significant at the 10% level and has the same negative sign as that documented in the literature. Next, as shown in panel B, the estimation results for SK EP S are very similar to those for SK GP. By itself, SK EP S positively predicts stock returns in model (1). Even when all controls are included in model (8), the average coefficient of SK EP S remains positive and 19

22 significant at the 5% level (0.09 and t = 2.37). Finally, panel C shows the results for SK AF. The average coefficient of SK AF in model (1) is 0.21 and significant at the 5% level (t = 2.60). Among the control variables, MOM, GP, and ROE are significant while MC, BM, and Idvol are insignificant in predicting stock returns by themselves. In model (8), the average coefficient of SK AF is even larger and more significant (0.28 and t = 3.31) than that in model (1). Among the control variables, GP and ROE are consistently significant return predictors in all three samples, confirming the evidence documented in Novy-Marx (2013) and Hou, Xue, and Zhang (2014). In sum, the results of Fama-MacBeth regressions are consistent with those of portfolio sorts. All three skewness measures of firm fundamentals positively predict stock returns. While in the presence of control variables some evidence is not as significant as in the portfolios sorts, the overall return predictability by the skewness measures cannot be explained by other predictors. 4.5 Skewness and Future Firm Profitability We now test the implication of our model that the skewness of firm fundamentals is positively related to future profitability or growth of firm cash flows. We proxy growth rate by ROE and GP. We look forward for four quarters. We use both portfolio sorts and Fama-MacBeth regressions to examine the issue. Table 5 reports the average equal-weighted future ROE and GP of decile portfolios formed by sorting stocks on the skewness measures. Value-weighted results are very similar and not reported for brevity. The results of panel A for SK GP indicate that high-skewness stocks have higher profitability in future four quarters. The H-L spreads of both ROE and GP are positive and significant at the 1% level for all four quarters. The H-L spreads decline gradually as horizon increases, suggesting mean reversion in firm performance. Panel B shows the results for SK EP S. The results are similar to those for SK GP as stocks with high values of SK EP S have higher profitability in terms of ROE and GP in the 20

23 futures. There are a couple of small differences. First, the H-L spreads in ROE in panel B are larger than those in panel A. Second, the H-L spreads in GP in panel B are smaller than those in panel A. These results are not surprising as the skewness of earnings should be more significant in predicting ROE than the skewness of GP while the opposite is true for the skewness of GP. The results for SK AF shown in panel C are in start contrast to those for SK GP and SK EP S. Although the H-L spreads in ROE and GP are all positive and significant at the 10% level, they are much smaller than those in panels A and B. Looking closely, the positive H-L spread are mostly driven by the high profitability of decile 10. There is no increasing pattern in ROE or GP from decile 1 to decile 10. The results of the portfolio sorts strongly support our argument for SK GP and SK EP S but the evidence for SK AF is weak. We reexamine the above evidence using the Fama-MacBeth regressions and report the regression estimates in Table 6. We only show the results where the dependent variable is the next-quarter ROE and GP as the estimates for long horizons up to four quarter are very similar. The regression results confirm what we have found with the portfolio sorts: the skewness measures positively predicts future profitability. The results are robust to inclusion of control variables. Interestingly, SK AF becomes more significant in predicting ROE and GP when the control variables are included. Overall the evidence in this section confirms our hypothesis that the skewness measures forecast future profitability. 4.6 Skewness and Future Growth Option We have argued for a second channel through which the skewness of firm fundamentals is positively related to expected stock return: skewness is positively related to the growth option. We test this argument using two measures of growth option, MABA and Tobin s q. Again we conduct both portfolio sorts and Fama-MacBeth regressions. Table 7 reports the average equal-weighted future MABA and Tobin s q up to four quarters of decile portfolios formed by sorting stocks on the skewness measures. The results 21

24 of portfolio sorts generally support our argument that higher skewness implies higher growth option. The evidence is very strong for SK GP and SK EP S as the H-L spreads are all positive and significant at the 1% level for all four future quarters and both growth option proxies. The evidence for SK AF is weaker but is still consistent with that for SK GP and SK EP S. The H-L spreads are much smaller than those for SK GP and SK EP S albeit still positive and marginally significant in most cases, particularly in the short run. In Table 8, we present the estimates of Fama-MacBeth regressions where the dependent variable is the next-quarter MABA or Tobin s q. The results for the two proxies of growth options are very similar. When a skewness measure is the only predictor, its estimated coefficient is positive. The estimates for SK GP and SK EP S are significant at the 1% level while the estimate for SK AF is significant at the 10% level. When all control variables including the lagged value of the growth option proxy are incorporated, the coefficients on the skewness measures are much smaller and less significant. The estimates for SK GP and SK EP S are still significant at the 10% level but the estimate for SK AF becomes insignificant. Taken together with the evidence of portfolio sorts, these results are consistent with our hypothesis that high skewness of firm fundamentals implies high growth option. But this effect seems less significant than that on the growth rate of cash flows shown earlier. 4.7 Controlling for Skewness of Stock Returns One concern about our main findings so far is whether the return predictability of the skewness of firm fundamentals is related to the return predictability of the skewness of stock returns. We address this concern by incorporating three popular return skewness measures (M ax, Idskew, and P rskew) in the Fama-MacBeth regressions of the fundamental skewness measures. Table 9 reports the estimation results of the Fama-MacBeth regressions. In models (1) (3), we only use one of the three return skewness measures. MAX and P rskew are significant but Idskew is insignificant in predicting returns. However, the sign of average coefficient for MAX changes signs for different samples. Model (4) use all three 22

25 measures, Max, Idskew, and P rskew. MAX and Idskew are significant in the sample of SK GP while P rskew is significant in the samples of SK EP S and SK AF. For our samples, the return skewness measures do not appear to consistently predict stock returns. We next combine the skewness of fundamentals with the return skewness measures. In model (4), we only include one skewness measure of fundamentals. The average coefficients of all three skewness measures of fundamentals are significant at the 1% level but among the skewness measures of returns only MAX is significant at the 1% level for the SK GP sample and P rskew is significant at the 10% level in the SK EP S and SK AF samples. Model (5) augments model (4) by including all the control variables that we used in Table 3. MAX and P rskew are still significant in some cases. Most importantly, the estimates for all three skewness measures of fundamentals are significant at the 1% level even when all the control variables are incorporated. The evidence of this section indicates that our findings for SK GP, SK EP S, and SK AF can not be explained by the skewness measures of stock returns. 4.8 Comparison of Alternative Skewness Measures Given the different constructions of the skewness measures, it is interesting to investigate their relative return predictive power. To do this, we estimate Fama-MacBeth regressions with multiple skewness measures as explanatory variables. The estimation results are reported in Table 10. In models (1) (3), we compare one skewness measure against another. Model (4) includes all three measures. There is no control variables in models (1) (4). We include all control variables in model (5) together with all three skewness measures. The estimated coefficients of the control variables are not shown for brevity. In model (1), the average coefficients of SK GP and SK EP S are both positive (0.19 and 0.13) and significant at the 5% level, indicating that the two time-series skewness measures do not dominate each other. In model (2), the average coefficient of SK AF is significant but the average coefficient of SK EP S is insignificant. This suggests that for the sample of 23

26 stocks with valid SK AF, the return predictability of SK EP S is subsumed by that of SK AF. In contrast, the estimates of model (3) show that both SK GP and SK AF are significant in positively predicting returns when they are considered together. The estimates of model (4) are consistent with those of the first three models as SK GP and SK AF are significant but SK EP S is no longer significant. Finally, when all the control variables are incorporated in model (5), the average coefficients of SK GP and SK AF remain significant at the 1% level and the average coefficient of SK EP S is insignificant. Despite the loss of significance in the joint regressions above, we should not dismiss the return predictability of SK EP S. One reason is that the sample of stocks with valid SK AF is much smaller than that for SK EP S. Furthermore, as seen in the estimates of model (1), for the larger sample of stocks with valid SK GP and SK EP S, the predictability of SK EP S is not subsumed by that of SK GP. In summary, the evidence suggests that the alternative skewness measures capture different factors driving the firm cash flows. 5 Conclusions We present a novel interpretation of sample skewness of a general time series as a proxy of the growth rate of the underlying process. Applying this interpretation to the firm cash flows together with the basic stock valuation equation, we posit a positive relation between the skewness of firm fundamentals and expected stock return. Using three skewness measures of firm fundamentals based on gross profitability, earnings, and analysts earnings forecasts, we find strong evidence supporting our hypothesis. The skewness measures positively predict not only cross-sectional stock returns but also future firm performance in terms of growth rate and growth option. The evidence is robust to control variables including the skewness of stock returns. The evidence also suggests that the alternative skewness measures capture different factors of the underlying firm cash flow process. 24

What Does Skewness of Firm Fundamentals Tell Us about Firm Growth, Profitability, and Stock Return

What Does Skewness of Firm Fundamentals Tell Us about Firm Growth, Profitability, and Stock Return What Does Skewness of Firm Fundamentals Tell Us about Firm Growth, Profitability, and Stock Return Yuecheng Jia Shu Yan January 2016 Abstract This paper investigates whether the skewness of firm fundamentals

More information

There is a Growth Premium After All

There is a Growth Premium After All There is a Growth Premium After All Yuecheng Jia Shu Yan Haoxi Yang February 6, 2018 Abstract The conventional wisdom argues that the growth stocks are riskier to earn a higher premium. However, the empirical

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

There is a Growth Premium After All

There is a Growth Premium After All There is a Growth Premium After All Yuecheng Jia Shu Yan Haoxi Yang January 16, 2018 Abstract The conventional wisdom argues that the growth stocks are more risky to earn higher premium. However the empirical

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? Supplementary Online Appendix

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? Supplementary Online Appendix What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? Supplementary Online Appendix 1 Tercile Portfolios The main body of the paper presents results from quintile RNS-sorted portfolios. Here,

More information

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly Online Appendix Section I provides details of the calculation of the variables used in the paper. Section II examines the robustness of the beta anomaly.

More information

Variation of Implied Volatility and Return Predictability

Variation of Implied Volatility and Return Predictability Variation of Implied Volatility and Return Predictability Paul Borochin School of Business University of Connecticut Yanhui Zhao School of Business University of Connecticut This version: January, 2017

More information

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor In this online appendix, we provide a comparative static analysis of the theoretical model as well as further robustness checks on the trend factor.

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Yuhang Xing Rice University This version: July 25, 2006 1 I thank Andrew Ang, Geert Bekaert, John Donaldson, and Maria Vassalou

More information

Dispersion in Analysts Target Prices and Stock Returns

Dispersion in Analysts Target Prices and Stock Returns Dispersion in Analysts Target Prices and Stock Returns Hongrui Feng Shu Yan January 2016 Abstract We propose the dispersion in analysts target prices as a new measure of disagreement among stock analysts.

More information

Realization Utility: Explaining Volatility and Skewness Preferences

Realization Utility: Explaining Volatility and Skewness Preferences Realization Utility: Explaining Volatility and Skewness Preferences Min Kyeong Kwon * and Tong Suk Kim March 16, 2014 ABSTRACT Using the realization utility model with a jump process, we find three implications

More information

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LVI, NO. 6 DEC. 2001 Dividend Changes and Future Profitability DORON NISSIM and AMIR ZIV* ABSTRACT We investigate the relation between dividend changes and future profitability,

More information

The cross section of expected stock returns

The cross section of expected stock returns The cross section of expected stock returns Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER This version: March 2013 First draft: October 2010 Tel: 603-646-8650; email: jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu. I am grateful

More information

Expected Idiosyncratic Skewness and Price Momentum: Does Lottery-Like Return Structure Affect Momentum Profits?

Expected Idiosyncratic Skewness and Price Momentum: Does Lottery-Like Return Structure Affect Momentum Profits? Expected Idiosyncratic Skewness and Price Momentum: Does Lottery-Like Return Structure Affect Momentum Profits? Hongrui Feng Oklahoma State University Yuecheng Jia* Oklahoma State University * Correspondent

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns

Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns Return Reversals, Idiosyncratic Risk and Expected Returns Wei Huang, Qianqiu Liu, S.Ghon Rhee and Liang Zhang Shidler College of Business University of Hawaii at Manoa 2404 Maile Way Honolulu, Hawaii,

More information

Preference for Skewness and Market Anomalies

Preference for Skewness and Market Anomalies Preference for Skewness and Market Anomalies Alok Kumar 1, Mehrshad Motahari 2, and Richard J. Taffler 2 1 University of Miami 2 University of Warwick November 30, 2017 ABSTRACT This study shows that investors

More information

Predicting the Equity Premium with Implied Volatility Spreads

Predicting the Equity Premium with Implied Volatility Spreads Predicting the Equity Premium with Implied Volatility Spreads Charles Cao, Timothy Simin, and Han Xiao Department of Finance, Smeal College of Business, Penn State University Department of Economics, Penn

More information

Market Efficiency and Idiosyncratic Volatility in Vietnam

Market Efficiency and Idiosyncratic Volatility in Vietnam International Journal of Business and Management; Vol. 10, No. 6; 2015 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Market Efficiency and Idiosyncratic Volatility

More information

Maxing Out: Stocks as Lotteries and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns

Maxing Out: Stocks as Lotteries and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns Maxing Out: Stocks as Lotteries and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns Turan G. Bali, a Nusret Cakici, b and Robert F. Whitelaw c* August 2008 ABSTRACT Motivated by existing evidence of a preference

More information

Arbitrage Asymmetry and the Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle

Arbitrage Asymmetry and the Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle Arbitrage Asymmetry and the Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle Robert F. Stambaugh, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania and NBER Jianfeng Yu, Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota

More information

Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection

Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection of Stock Returns Cameron Truong Monash University, Melbourne, Australia February 2015 Abstract We document a significant positive relation

More information

Cross-Sectional Dispersion and Expected Returns

Cross-Sectional Dispersion and Expected Returns Cross-Sectional Dispersion and Expected Returns Thanos Verousis a and Nikolaos Voukelatos b a Newcastle University Business School, Newcastle University b Kent Business School, University of Kent Abstract

More information

Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Badrinath Kottimukkalur * January 2018 Abstract This paper provides an arbitrage based explanation for the puzzling negative

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

Asubstantial portion of the academic

Asubstantial portion of the academic The Decline of Informed Trading in the Equity and Options Markets Charles Cao, David Gempesaw, and Timothy Simin Charles Cao is the Smeal Chair Professor of Finance in the Smeal College of Business at

More information

Are Idiosyncratic Skewness and Idiosyncratic Kurtosis Priced?

Are Idiosyncratic Skewness and Idiosyncratic Kurtosis Priced? Are Idiosyncratic Skewness and Idiosyncratic Kurtosis Priced? Xu Cao MSc in Management (Finance) Goodman School of Business, Brock University St. Catharines, Ontario 2015 Table of Contents List of Tables...

More information

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect?

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? Yi Jiang Department of Finance, California State University, Fullerton SGMH 5160, Fullerton, CA 92831 (657)278-4363 yjiang@fullerton.edu Yiming Qian

More information

Do stock fundamentals explain idiosyncratic volatility? Evidence for Australian stock market

Do stock fundamentals explain idiosyncratic volatility? Evidence for Australian stock market Do stock fundamentals explain idiosyncratic volatility? Evidence for Australian stock market Bin Liu School of Economics, Finance and Marketing, RMIT University, Australia Amalia Di Iorio Faculty of Business,

More information

The Trend in Firm Profitability and the Cross Section of Stock Returns

The Trend in Firm Profitability and the Cross Section of Stock Returns The Trend in Firm Profitability and the Cross Section of Stock Returns Ferhat Akbas School of Business University of Kansas 785-864-1851 Lawrence, KS 66045 akbas@ku.edu Chao Jiang School of Business University

More information

Have we solved the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle?

Have we solved the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle? Have we solved the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle? Roger Loh 1 Kewei Hou 2 1 Singapore Management University 2 Ohio State University Presented by Roger Loh Proseminar SMU Finance Ph.D class Hou and Loh

More information

Is Stock Return Predictability of Option-implied Skewness Affected by the Market State?

Is Stock Return Predictability of Option-implied Skewness Affected by the Market State? Is Stock Return Predictability of Option-implied Skewness Affected by the Market State? Heewoo Park and Tongsuk Kim * Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology 2016 ABSTRACT We use Bakshi, Kapadia,

More information

Arbitrage Asymmetry and the Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle

Arbitrage Asymmetry and the Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle Arbitrage Asymmetry and the Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle Robert F. Stambaugh The Wharton School University of Pennsylvania and NBER Jianfeng Yu Carlson School of Management University of Minnesota Yu

More information

The Rational Part of Momentum

The Rational Part of Momentum The Rational Part of Momentum Jim Scott George Murillo Heilbrunn Center for Graham and Dodd Investing Columbia Business School Value Investing Research Consortium 1 Outline The Momentum Effect A Rationality

More information

Expected Idiosyncratic Skewness

Expected Idiosyncratic Skewness Expected Idiosyncratic Skewness BrianBoyer,ToddMitton,andKeithVorkink 1 Brigham Young University December 7, 2007 1 We appreciate the helpful comments of Andrew Ang, Steven Thorley, and seminar participants

More information

April 13, Abstract

April 13, Abstract R 2 and Momentum Kewei Hou, Lin Peng, and Wei Xiong April 13, 2005 Abstract This paper examines the relationship between price momentum and investors private information, using R 2 -based information measures.

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

Dose the Firm Life Cycle Matter on Idiosyncratic Risk?

Dose the Firm Life Cycle Matter on Idiosyncratic Risk? DOI: 10.7763/IPEDR. 2012. V54. 26 Dose the Firm Life Cycle Matter on Idiosyncratic Risk? Jen-Sin Lee 1, Chwen-Huey Jiee 2 and Chu-Yun Wei 2 + 1 Department of Finance, I-Shou University 2 Postgraduate programs

More information

Appendix. In this Appendix, we present the construction of variables, data source, and some empirical procedures.

Appendix. In this Appendix, we present the construction of variables, data source, and some empirical procedures. Appendix In this Appendix, we present the construction of variables, data source, and some empirical procedures. A.1. Variable Definition and Data Source Variable B/M CAPX/A Cash/A Cash flow volatility

More information

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less?

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less? Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less? Jia Chen, Kewei Hou, and René M. Stulz* January 2015 Abstract Using theories from the behavioral finance literature to predict that investors are attracted to

More information

Disagreement in Economic Forecasts and Expected Stock Returns

Disagreement in Economic Forecasts and Expected Stock Returns Disagreement in Economic Forecasts and Expected Stock Returns Turan G. Bali Georgetown University Stephen J. Brown Monash University Yi Tang Fordham University Abstract We estimate individual stock exposure

More information

Dispersion in Analysts Earnings Forecasts and Credit Rating

Dispersion in Analysts Earnings Forecasts and Credit Rating Dispersion in Analysts Earnings Forecasts and Credit Rating Doron Avramov Department of Finance Robert H. Smith School of Business University of Maryland Tarun Chordia Department of Finance Goizueta Business

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

Liquidity Variation and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns *

Liquidity Variation and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns * Liquidity Variation and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns * Fangjian Fu Singapore Management University Wenjin Kang National University of Singapore Yuping Shao National University of Singapore Abstract

More information

Accruals and Conditional Equity Premium 1

Accruals and Conditional Equity Premium 1 Accruals and Conditional Equity Premium 1 Hui Guo and Xiaowen Jiang 2 January 8, 2010 Abstract Accruals correlate closely with the determinants of conditional equity premium at both the firm and the aggregate

More information

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility B Volatility Appendix The aggregate volatility risk explanation of the turnover effect relies on three empirical facts. First, the explanation assumes that firm-specific uncertainty comoves with aggregate

More information

Betting against Beta or Demand for Lottery

Betting against Beta or Demand for Lottery Turan G. Bali 1 Stephen J. Brown 2 Scott Murray 3 Yi Tang 4 1 McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University 2 Stern School of Business, New York University 3 College of Business Administration, University

More information

Internet Appendix Arbitrage Trading: the Long and the Short of It

Internet Appendix Arbitrage Trading: the Long and the Short of It Internet Appendix Arbitrage Trading: the Long and the Short of It Yong Chen Texas A&M University Zhi Da University of Notre Dame Dayong Huang University of North Carolina at Greensboro May 3, 2018 This

More information

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves issn 1936-5330 Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves Brent Bundick Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City First Version: October 2007 This Version: June 2008 RWP 07-08 Abstract Piazzesi and Swanson

More information

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009 Long Chen Washington University in St. Louis Fresh Momentum Engin Kose Washington University in St. Louis First version: October 2009 Ohad Kadan Washington University in St. Louis Abstract We demonstrate

More information

Accruals, Heterogeneous Beliefs, and Stock Returns

Accruals, Heterogeneous Beliefs, and Stock Returns Accruals, Heterogeneous Beliefs, and Stock Returns Emma Y. Peng An Yan* and Meng Yan Fordham University 1790 Broadway, 13 th Floor New York, NY 10019 Feburary 2012 *Corresponding author. Tel: (212)636-7401

More information

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios RESEARCH Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios March 2016 Wei Dai, PhD Research The predictability of expected stock returns is an old topic and an important one. While investors may increase expected returns

More information

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information Critical Finance Review, 2016, 5: 165 175 Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information Kent Daniel Sheridan Titman 1 Columbia Business School, Columbia University, New York,

More information

Maxing Out: Stocks as Lotteries and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns

Maxing Out: Stocks as Lotteries and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns Maxing Out: Stocks as Lotteries and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns Turan G. Bali, a Nusret Cakici, b and Robert F. Whitelaw c* February 2010 ABSTRACT Motivated by existing evidence of a preference

More information

Fama-French in China: Size and Value Factors in Chinese Stock Returns

Fama-French in China: Size and Value Factors in Chinese Stock Returns Fama-French in China: Size and Value Factors in Chinese Stock Returns November 26, 2016 Abstract We investigate the size and value factors in the cross-section of returns for the Chinese stock market.

More information

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power? International Journal of Business and Management; Vol. 9, No. 9; 2014 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really

More information

The Relationship between the Option-implied Volatility Smile, Stock Returns and Heterogeneous Beliefs

The Relationship between the Option-implied Volatility Smile, Stock Returns and Heterogeneous Beliefs University of Nebraska - Lincoln DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln Finance Department Faculty Publications Finance Department 7-1-2015 The Relationship between the Option-implied Volatility

More information

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data Edith Cowan University Research Online ECU Publications 2013 2013 Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data A. Tsui C.Y. Xu Zhaoyong Zhang Edith Cowan University, zhaoyong.zhang@ecu.edu.au

More information

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables Huacheng Zhang * University of Arizona This draft: 8/31/2012 First draft: 2/28/2012 Abstract We

More information

Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty?

Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty? Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty? Alexander Barinov Terry College of Business University of Georgia E-mail: abarinov@terry.uga.edu http://abarinov.myweb.uga.edu/ This version: July 2009 Abstract The

More information

Does Transparency Increase Takeover Vulnerability?

Does Transparency Increase Takeover Vulnerability? Does Transparency Increase Takeover Vulnerability? Finance Working Paper N 570/2018 July 2018 Lifeng Gu University of Hong Kong Dirk Hackbarth Boston University, CEPR and ECGI Lifeng Gu and Dirk Hackbarth

More information

Dispersion in Analysts Earnings Forecasts and Credit Rating

Dispersion in Analysts Earnings Forecasts and Credit Rating Dispersion in Analysts Earnings Forecasts and Credit Rating Doron Avramov Department of Finance Robert H. Smith School of Business University of Maryland davramov@rhsmith.umd.edu Tarun Chordia Department

More information

The predictive power of investment and accruals

The predictive power of investment and accruals The predictive power of investment and accruals Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu Robert J. Resutek Dartmouth College robert.j.resutek@dartmouth.edu This version:

More information

The Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle: A Behavioral Explanation

The Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle: A Behavioral Explanation Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2015 The Idiosyncratic Volatility Puzzle: A Behavioral Explanation Brad Cannon Utah State University Follow

More information

Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information Revisited

Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information Revisited Critical Finance Review, 2016, 5: 135 163 Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information Revisited Joseph Gerakos Juhani T. Linnainmaa 1 University of Chicago Booth School of Business, USA, joseph.gerakos@chicagobooth.edu

More information

Economic Fundamentals, Risk, and Momentum Profits

Economic Fundamentals, Risk, and Momentum Profits Economic Fundamentals, Risk, and Momentum Profits Laura X.L. Liu, Jerold B. Warner, and Lu Zhang September 2003 Abstract We study empirically the changes in economic fundamentals for firms with recent

More information

High Idiosyncratic Volatility and Low Returns: International and Further U.S. Evidence

High Idiosyncratic Volatility and Low Returns: International and Further U.S. Evidence High Idiosyncratic Volatility and Low Returns: International and Further U.S. Evidence Andrew Ang Columbia University and NBER Robert J. Hodrick Columbia University and NBER Yuhang Xing Rice University

More information

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market?

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market? International Review of Finance, 2017 Can Hedge Funds Time the Market? MICHAEL W. BRANDT,FEDERICO NUCERA AND GIORGIO VALENTE Duke University, The Fuqua School of Business, Durham, NC LUISS Guido Carli

More information

Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence

Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence Joshua Livnat Department of Accounting Stern School of Business Administration New York University 311 Tisch Hall

More information

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence

GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New Zealand Evidence Journal of Money, Investment and Banking ISSN 1450-288X Issue 5 (2008) EuroJournals Publishing, Inc. 2008 http://www.eurojournals.com/finance.htm GDP, Share Prices, and Share Returns: Australian and New

More information

Firm specific uncertainty around earnings announcements and the cross section of stock returns

Firm specific uncertainty around earnings announcements and the cross section of stock returns Firm specific uncertainty around earnings announcements and the cross section of stock returns Sergey Gelman International College of Economics and Finance & Laboratory of Financial Economics Higher School

More information

What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium?

What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium? What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium? Hae mi Choi Loyola University Chicago This study investigates what drives the earnings announcement premium. Prior studies have offered various explanations

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FUNDAMENTALLY, MOMENTUM IS FUNDAMENTAL MOMENTUM. Robert Novy-Marx. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FUNDAMENTALLY, MOMENTUM IS FUNDAMENTAL MOMENTUM. Robert Novy-Marx. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FUNDAMENTALLY, MOMENTUM IS FUNDAMENTAL MOMENTUM Robert Novy-Marx Working Paper 20984 http://www.nber.org/papers/w20984 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

When Low Beats High: Riding the Sales Seasonality Premium

When Low Beats High: Riding the Sales Seasonality Premium When Low Beats High: Riding the Sales Seasonality Premium Gustavo Grullon Rice University grullon@rice.edu Yamil Kaba Rice University yamil.kaba@rice.edu Alexander Núñez Lehman College alexander.nuneztorres@lehman.cuny.edu

More information

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Liuren Wu Baruch College, City University of New York Joint work with Jian Hua 6th Annual Conference of the Society for Financial Econometrics June 12-14,

More information

Prospective book-to-market ratio and expected stock returns

Prospective book-to-market ratio and expected stock returns Prospective book-to-market ratio and expected stock returns Kewei Hou Yan Xu Yuzhao Zhang Feb 2016 We propose a novel stock return predictor, the prospective book-to-market, as the present value of expected

More information

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Abdulrahman Alharbi 1 Abdullah Noman 2 Abstract: Bansal et al (2009) paper focus on measuring risk in consumption especially

More information

Institutional Skewness Preferences and the Idiosyncratic Skewness Premium

Institutional Skewness Preferences and the Idiosyncratic Skewness Premium Institutional Skewness Preferences and the Idiosyncratic Skewness Premium Alok Kumar University of Notre Dame Mendoza College of Business August 15, 2005 Alok Kumar is at the Mendoza College of Business,

More information

Product Market Competition, Gross Profitability, and Cross Section of. Expected Stock Returns

Product Market Competition, Gross Profitability, and Cross Section of. Expected Stock Returns Product Market Competition, Gross Profitability, and Cross Section of Expected Stock Returns Minki Kim * and Tong Suk Kim Dec 15th, 2017 ABSTRACT This paper investigates the interaction between product

More information

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach Hossein Asgharian and Björn Hansson Department of Economics, Lund University Box 7082 S-22007 Lund, Sweden

More information

Have we solved the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle?*

Have we solved the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle?* Have we solved the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle?* Kewei Hou Ohio State University Roger K. Loh Singapore Management University This Draft: June 2014 Abstract We propose a simple methodology to evaluate

More information

Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth

Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth Abstract Several previous studies show that consensus analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts are excessively influenced by past firm

More information

Internet Appendix to Is Information Risk Priced? Evidence from Abnormal Idiosyncratic Volatility

Internet Appendix to Is Information Risk Priced? Evidence from Abnormal Idiosyncratic Volatility Internet Appendix to Is Information Risk Priced? Evidence from Abnormal Idiosyncratic Volatility Table IA.1 Further Summary Statistics This table presents the summary statistics of further variables used

More information

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru i Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE 2012 ii Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru (B.Sc National University

More information

Institutional Ownership and Aggregate Volatility Risk

Institutional Ownership and Aggregate Volatility Risk Institutional Ownership and Aggregate Volatility Risk Alexander Barinov School of Business Administration University of California Riverside E-mail: abarinov@ucr.edu http://faculty.ucr.edu/ abarinov/ This

More information

Variation in Liquidity and Costly Arbitrage

Variation in Liquidity and Costly Arbitrage and Costly Arbitrage Badrinath Kottimukkalur * December 2018 Abstract This paper explores the relationship between the variation in liquidity and arbitrage activity. A model shows that arbitrageurs will

More information

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Yongsik Kim * Abstract This paper provides empirical evidence that analysts generate firm-specific

More information

Relation between Time-Series and Cross-Sectional Effects of. Idiosyncratic Variance on Stock Returns

Relation between Time-Series and Cross-Sectional Effects of. Idiosyncratic Variance on Stock Returns Relation between Time-Series and Cross-Sectional Effects of Idiosyncratic Variance on Stock Returns Hui Guo a and Robert Savickas b* First Version: May 2006 This Version: February 2010 *a Corresponding

More information

Internet Appendix. Table A1: Determinants of VOIB

Internet Appendix. Table A1: Determinants of VOIB Internet Appendix Table A1: Determinants of VOIB Each month, we regress VOIB on firm size and proxies for N, v δ, and v z. OIB_SHR is the monthly order imbalance defined as (B S)/(B+S), where B (S) is

More information

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2012 The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Abdullah Al Masud Utah State University

More information

Dissecting Anomalies. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French. Abstract

Dissecting Anomalies. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French. Abstract First draft: February 2006 This draft: June 2006 Please do not quote or circulate Dissecting Anomalies Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French Abstract Previous work finds that net stock issues, accruals,

More information

University of California Berkeley

University of California Berkeley University of California Berkeley A Comment on The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns : The Statistical Significance of FVIX is Driven by a Single Outlier Robert M. Anderson Stephen W. Bianchi

More information

The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs

The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs John L. Glascock 1 University of Connecticut Ran Lu-Andrews 2 California Lutheran University (This version: August 2016) Abstract The traditional

More information

High Short Interest Effect and Aggregate Volatility Risk. Alexander Barinov. Juan (Julie) Wu * This draft: July 2013

High Short Interest Effect and Aggregate Volatility Risk. Alexander Barinov. Juan (Julie) Wu * This draft: July 2013 High Short Interest Effect and Aggregate Volatility Risk Alexander Barinov Juan (Julie) Wu * This draft: July 2013 We propose a risk-based firm-type explanation on why stocks of firms with high relative

More information

Daily Winners and Losers a

Daily Winners and Losers a Daily Winners and Losers a Alok Kumar b, Stefan Ruenzi, Michael Ungeheuer c First Version: November 2016; This Version: March 2017 Abstract The probably most salient feature of the cross-section of stock

More information

The High Idiosyncratic Volatility Low Return Puzzle

The High Idiosyncratic Volatility Low Return Puzzle The High Idiosyncratic Volatility Low Return Puzzle Hai Lu, Kevin Wang, and Xiaolu Wang Joseph L. Rotman School of Management University of Toronto NTU International Conference, December, 2008 What is

More information

Investor Gambling Preference and the Asset Growth Anomaly

Investor Gambling Preference and the Asset Growth Anomaly Investor Gambling Preference and the Asset Growth Anomaly Kuan-Cheng Ko Department of Banking and Finance National Chi Nan University Nien-Tzu Yang Department of Business Management National United University

More information

Cross Sectional Asset Pricing Tests: Ex Ante versus Ex Post Approaches

Cross Sectional Asset Pricing Tests: Ex Ante versus Ex Post Approaches Cross Sectional Asset Pricing Tests: Ex Ante versus Ex Post Approaches Mahmoud Botshekan Smurfit School of Business, University College Dublin, Ireland mahmoud.botshekan@ucd.ie, +353-1-716-8976 John Cotter

More information