Investment, Duration, and Exit Strategies for Corporate and Independent Venture Capital Backed Startups

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Investment, Duration, and Exit Strategies for Corporate and Independent Venture Capital Backed Startups"

Transcription

1 Investment, Duration, and Exit Strategies for Corporate and Independent Venture Capital Backed Startups Bing Guo, Yun Lou, and David Pérez-Castrillo September 26, 2011 Abstract We propose a model of investment, duration, and exit strategies for startups that takes into account first, the high level of uncertainty regarding returns from the investment in the startup, second, the more accurate information in the hands of insiders, and finally, the discount rate of the partners in the startups. According to our theoretical analysis, CVC backed startups stay longer in the market before exit and they invest more than those financed by IVCs. While longer duration leads to a higher likelihood of an exit through acquisition, a larger investment increases the probability of an IPO exit. These predictions find strong empirical support, using venture capital data from U.S. JEL Classification: G32, G24. Keywords: Startups, Corporate Venture Capital, Independent Venture Capital, Investment Amount, Duration, Exit Strategy, IPO, Acquisition. We thank Albert Banal-Estañol, Gary Dushnisky, María Gutiérrez, Inés Macho- Stadler, Philipp Meyer, Pau Olivella-Cunill, Pedro Rey-Biel, Jo Seldeslachts and participants at the MOVE workshop on venture capital, the 2011 LSE Alternative Investments Research Conference and the Symposium of Industrial Organization and Management Strategy in Chengdu 2011 for their helpful suggestions. We are grateful to AGAUR, research projects ECO , 2009SGR-169, and INFOINNOVA (03513A), Barcelona GSE, and ICREA Academia for the financial support. Pérez-Castrillo is MOVE fellow. Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, Business and Administration Department, bing.guo@uc3m.es. London Business School, Accounting Department, ylou.phd2007@london.edu. Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Economics Department, david.perez@uab.es. 1

2 1 Introduction Entrepreneurs and venture capitalists make investment decisions and choose the length of their involvement in a startup to maximize the chances of success and the value of their venture. They also look ahead and plan for a strategy of cashing in on their company allowing, in particular the venture capitalists, to liquidate their shares. Planning an exit strategy is as important as figuring out how to start the enterprise. There are two main exit routes for a successful startup: the company can go to an Initial Public Offering (IPO) or it can be sold to an existing firm (Acquisition). 1 Under an IPO, the venture achieves a stock market listing so that it can receive additional financing for its projects and the insiders can eventually sell their shares to the public. If the startup is acquired, the insiders get immediate cash in return from their shares. The optimal exit route for startups depends on multiple factors, such as expected profitability of the venture; level of uncertainty; asymmetry of information between insiders and outsiders (potential buyers, new investors); 2 possible conflicts of interest among insiders; 3 venture capital characteristics, etc. Some of these factors are affected by the partners investment and duration decisions. Understanding the main trade-offs faced by startups at the exit stage is crucial because it allows to see how venture capitalists and entrepreneurs divest their companies, and also because of the impact of the (anticipated) exit strategy on the decisions taken at the onset of the venture. In this paper, we abstract from possible internal conflicts among insiders and we propose a model of investment, duration, and exit taking into account first, the high level of uncertainty regarding returns from the investment in the startup, second, the more accurate information in the hands of insiders, and finally, the discount rate of the partners in the startups. In our model, the level of investment of a startup influences its expected value. We assume that a higher investment leads to a more favorable distribution of the set of potential values. Furthermore, the decision on the 1 Two other exit routes that are not so commonly used are Management Buy-out and Refinancing (or secondary sale); see, for example Schwienbacher (2009). 2 See Cumming and MacIntosh (2003) for a discussion about the information asymmetries between sellers and potential purchasers of startups. 3 For a recent review of papers that analyze internal conflicts, see for example Macho- Stadler and Pérez-Castillo (2010)). 2

3 duration of the startup before exit, that is, the length of the relationship, affects the market information about the successful probability of the venture. Indeed, the level of uncertainty concerning the actual value of a startup is very high. Some of the uncertainty is resolved during the development stage and the market has access to that information. We assume that the level of the potential value of the venture at the time of the exit will be known by every market participants. Nevertheless, the insiders have more precise information about the expected profitability of the startup because they learn the probability of success. Whether the outsiders can be informed of such probability depends on how long the startup stays in the market before exit. We show that independently on the level of information received by the potential acquirers, the ventures whose probability of success is higher are more likely to try an IPO while those with lower probability prefer looking for an acquirer. Moreover, the likelihood of going to IPO increases with the potential value of the startup, if that value is high enough. Startups with low potential value are liquidated. We link the startup exit strategy with the investment decision and with the market level of information. First, a higher investment level brings about both, a higher likelihood of successful exit and a higher rate of IPO exits among the successful ones. Second, the IPO exit rate is lower when the outsiders receive more precise information, that is, when they are informed about the success probability. Finally, we analyze the optimal investment and duration decision of the startup. We show, in particular, that both the level of investment and the duration of the venture decrease with the discount rate of the startup. Our analysis allows to shed light on the discussion concerning the differences in behavior between the startups that receive financing from Corporate Venture Capital funds (CVCs) and those that are financed only by Independent Venture Capital funds (IVCs). Unlike the traditional IVCs, CVCs are private equity funds invested by large corporations. Therefore, while the sole objective of IVCs is financial return on capital, a very important goal of most CVC programs is strategic: the development of new, related business (see for instance Sykes, 1990; Yost and Devlin, 1993; Dushnitsky and Lenox, 2006; Hellmann, Lindsey and Puri, 2008). According to this strategic argument, CVC backed startups are more likely to exit by acquisition because the affiliated company of the CVCs may be particularly interested in the venture. This argument has 3

4 been confirmed by both theoretical studies (Hellmann, 2002; Riyanto and Schwienbacher, 2006) and empirical studies using European dataset (Cumming, 2008). Based on some questionnaires, Siegel, Siegel and MacMillan (1988) and Sykes (1990) find that the percentage of CVC backed startups that are acquired is higher than that of IVC backed ventures. However, it has been shown that the number of startups acquired by the company behind the CVC funds is small (Maula and Murrey, forthcoming) and our own analysis using the VentureXpert database confirms that the percentage of startups acquired by companies related to CVC investors is around 5%. Moreover, Gompers and Lerner (2000) and Chemmanur and Loutskina (2008) find that startups with CVC investments exit more often through IPO rather than by acquisition. We argue that another important difference between CVC and IVC funds is that IVC funds care more about quick exits than CVCs; that is, IVC backed startups have higher discount rate than those backed by CVCs. Indeed, compared to IVC funds, CVCs have more unused resources such as technology and marketing resources (Sahaym, Steensma and Barden, 2010; Basu, Phelps and Kotha, 2011; Da Gbadji, Gailly and Schwienbacher, 2011). Moreover, IVC managers payment is more based on financial returns and their ability to raise additional funds depends on their reputation, which is influenced by their history of successes (Gompers, 1996; Dushnitsky and Shapira, forthcoming). Therefore, they have strong incentives to cash their return from profitable projects early. According to our model, the difference in the discount rate between IVC and CVC backed startups results in different behavior between the two types of venture. First, a lower discount rate for CVC backed startups implies a higher investment level and longer duration. Second, although the identity of the VC fund does not have a direct effect on the choice of exit, it does have two strong indirect effects: on the one hand, the larger investment decided by CVCs leads to more IPO exits; on the other hand, the longer duration induces more exits through acquisition. Therefore, the two forces that we identify go in opposite directions. Finally, a larger investment implies a higher success rate for CVC backed startups. We empirically test our main results using data on 4801 US startups from the period 1969 to First, we find that startups financed by CVC funds invest around 25% more than those financed by IVC funds. Moreover, the effect is doubled if the syndicate leader of a startup is a CVC fund. Second, CVC backed startups do stay longer before the exit than IVC backed 4

5 startups. Third, one percent increase in the level of investment significantly increases the probability of IPO exit by 0.065%. Fourth, one percent increase in the duration of the venture significantly decreases the likelihood of IPO exit by 0.017%. Fifth, we show that, after controlling for the duration effect and for the level of investment, there is no significant difference in the rate of IPO exits between IVC and CVC backed startups. In fact, we observe that the presence of CVC investors has a positive, although not significant, effect on the IPO exit rate. All the previous empirical results strongly support the predictions of the theoretical model. Finally, we use an enlarged dataset to test the theoretical results concerning the influence of the level of investment, the duration and the fund s characteristics on the successful rate. As suggested by our model, duration and fund s characteristics do not have a significant influence in the rate of successful exists. However, the effect of investment, while positive, is also not significant. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we introduce the model. In Section 3, we develop the analysis of the optimal exit strategy. In Section 4, we analyze the impact of investment and duration decisions on the likelihood of IPO and on the success rate. In section 5, we study the optimal investment and duration decisions. In Section 6, we derive the empirical hypotheses concerning the differences in behavior between CVC and IVC backed startups suggested by our theoretical results. In Section 7, we describe the dataset, which we use to empirically test the hypotheses in Section 8. Finally, Section 9 concludes. All the proofs are included in the Appendix. 2 The Model We analyze the optimal investment and duration decisions and exit strategy of startups (S). In our model, startups decisions at any stage aim to maximize the expected discounted profits. The main characteristics of the model are the following. The first decisions taken by a startup concern the level of investment I and the duration of the venture d. We consider that these decisions are made at the beginning of the life of the startup and we do not take into account their dynamic aspect, which is not relevant for our purpose. The level of investment has a positive impact on the expected quality of the venture while the duration influences the amount of information that will flow to the market. 5

6 The optimal investment and duration decisions depend on the discount rate r of the startups. The parameter r will play an important role in our analysis because, in the empirical sections of the paper, we will differentiate between startups receiving CVC funding and those receiving only IVC funding. As we argued in the Introduction, CVC funds tend to be more patient than IVC funds. When the startup makes its first decisions, there is a high degree of uncertainty with respect to both, the potential value of the venture V and the probability p of being able to realize this value. Part of the uncertainty is resolved as the startup develops. All the market participants will be able to observe some of the information, but the insiders will acquire more precise information on the expected quality of the project. In our model, we reflect this asymmetry in the information between insiders and outsiders in a simple way. When it is revealed, everybody can observe the potential value V. Moreover, the insiders always learn the probability p. However, the precision of the information received by the outsiders about p depends on the duration of the venture: the longer d, the more precise the outsiders information. The venture requires additional financing C to possibly achieve the value V. Hence, if the potential value V is low, the startup will be liquidated (this is the first exit option). If, on the contrary, continuing the venture is profitable, then the startup will either look for a firm (an acquirer) interested in adding the venture into its business, or it will go to an initial public offering (IPO). In the first case, the acquirer will offer a deal to the startup that will reflect the expected value of the business and the bargaining power of the parties. Then, the acquirer will integrate the venture into its organization and, when it confirms that it is worthwhile doing it, it will make the additional financing to obtain V. In case the startup tries an IPO, then the market investors will go through a thorough analysis concerning all possible aspects of the startup. The market investors will make a careful auditing of the corporate valuation, market prospection and so on. The outcome of the analysis will be a new signal on the profitability of the startup that we model also in a simple way: either the market makers are convinced that the startup will be successful with probability 1 (High signal), or they will still not be able to assess it with certainty (Low signal). All these processes are costly and the startup needs to cover the cost. The market investors will make an offer to the startup owners in case of a High signal. 6

7 More precisely, the model is the following: d. At t = 1, the startup decides the level of investment I and the duration The level of I determines the distribution of the potential value of the startup V : the value V follows a distribution function Γ(V ; I), with density function γ(v ; I). For simplicity, we assume that ex ante V is uniformly distributed over the interval [ f(i), V + f(i) ], where f(i) is an increasing function of I. The potential value V can only be cashed if at later stages a fixed new funding C is made. After the investment and before all the other decisions are taken, the value of V is realized and it is observable by everybody. The level of d determines the information learnt by the potential acquirers about a signal p on the likelihood of success, i.e., the probability of realizing V. Also for simplicity, we assume that ex ante p is uniformly distributed over the interval [0, 1]. The startup always learns p. The potential acquirers will learn p with probability h(d), increasing in the duration d. At t = 2, the startup takes the exit decision. It has three possibilities: liquidation, looking for an acquirer, or going to an IPO. The liquidation value of the startup is always 0. In case it decides to look for an acquirer, then a deal price is negotiated, depending on the bargaining power of the two parties and on the acquirer s information. The bargaining power for the startup is denoted by m. In case of acquisition, the acquirer will invest C to realize V if it confirms that the project is successful. Going to an IPO is the most complex and costly exit route for the startup. We denote by F all the fixed costs due to the IPO process. It leads to one public signal β on the profitability of the venture, β {H, L}. We assume that β is the probability for the market to be able to verify a successful project after receiving the public signal. Therefore, the probability of observing β = H is equal to βp. In case the signal is H, the competitive market will set a price Z for IPO. If the startup accepts the price, then a successful IPO is carried out. In order to realize V, in addition to Z, the market needs to raise C to cover the 7

8 Figure 1: The Time Line remaining investment needs. In case the signal is L, then no offer is issued. 4 The time line is captured by Figure 1. We make assumptions on the functions f(i) and h(d) that make sure that the three exit routes are possible. We assume that ˆV + f(0) > C + F β m and that f(i) is concave enough, in particular lim I f(i) C. Also, the screening is informative enough: β > m. Finally, the venture makes interior choices of I and d if lim I 0 f (0) = lim d 0 h (0) = and h(d) is concave enough. 5 4 We assume that a startup that receives a low signal does not get any offer and quits the market. We make this assumption for simplicity. First, for those startups that receive a signal L, the situation is often similar to the lemon s market in Akerlof (1970) s model: there is no price under which market profits are non negative (taking into account the startups that accept that offer). Therefore, the assumption that IPOs do not make offers to startups that receive low signals can be sustained as a result of a more general model. Second, the startups may go to the acquisition market (at t = 3) once they fail at IPO, where the acquirers will take into account the new information produced at IPO. This adds some (small) additional profits to those ventures that choose the IPO exit. However, the qualitative results of our analysis do not change if we add this possibility. (For an analysis of the previous extensions, see Guo, 2010). 5 If β < m, then the IPO is never chosen. If ˆV + f(0) < C + F β m, then some exit routes are never taken for low investment levels while liquidation never happens for high investment levels if lim I f(i) > C. However, our qualitative results would remain with changes in the hypotheses. Similarly, if lim I 0 f (0) = lim d 0 h (0) <, then 8

9 We solve the model by backward induction, taking into account that there may exist asymmetric information among the participants. Therefore, we use sequential equilibrium as the solution concept, since it combines subgame perfection ideas with Bayesian updating. 3 The Analysis of the Optimal Exit Strategy In this section, we start at t = 2, where the duration has already been decided and the investment made at t = 1 is sunk. The potential value for the venture V is realized and observed by all the participants. Moreover, the startup has received the private signal concerning the probability of success p. The potential acquirer may also know p (this happens with probability h(d)) or not. We study the optimal exit strategy in both situations. 3.1 Optimal Exit Strategy with Informed Outsiders As mentioned in the previous section, the value of the startup in case of liquidation is 0. Also, the deal price in an acquisition corresponds to a share m of the expected value of the venture. Taking into account that the acquirer knows p and that he needs to invest C to realize V when the venture is believed to be successful, the expected value of the venture is p [V C]. Therefore, if the startup goes to the acquisition market at t = 2, the deal price is mp [V C], whenever V C > 0. Consider now a startup characterized by (V, p) that goes through an IPO, with V C > 0 (otherwise, profits are always non-positive). 6 After the startup pays F, the market receives the signal β. If the realization is β = L, which happens with probability (1 βp), it will not receive any offer. If the realization is β = H, then the competitive market of investors will offer Z = V C, which the startup will accept. The startup obtains higher expected profits going to an IPO than looking for an acquirer if and only if βp [V C] F mp [V C]. (1) the optimal decision on I and/or d may be the corner solution I = 0 and/or d = 0, which would complicate the analysis without adding new insights. 6 We take the convention that a startup indifferent between being liquidated and not chooses liquidation. Similarly, a startup indifferent between going to an IPO and looking for an aquirer at t = 2 goes to an IPO. 9

10 Proposition 1, whose proof follows the previous discussion, describes the optimal exit strategy for a startup characterized by (V, p) when outsiders are informed about p, where we denote { } 1 F p o (V ) min [β m] [V C], 1. (2) Proposition 1. Consider a startup characterized by (V, p) in a situation where potential acquirers have learned p. The startup s optimal exit strategy is as follows: 1. If V C 0, the startup is liquidated and gets the payoff U o (V, p) = If V C > 0 and p < p o (V ), the startup goes to the acquisition market and gets a deal value U o (V, p) = mp [V C]. 3. If V C > 0 and p p o (V ), the startup invests F and goes to the IPO market. Moreover, (a) if it gets the public signal H, then it receives an offer Z = V C from the IPO market and it accepts it; (b) if it gets the public signal L, then it does not receive any offer from the IPO market. Therefore, in this case, the startup s expected payoff is U o (V, p) = βp [V C] F. The basic trade-off between IPO and acquisition is that while the IPO process is very costly, it also allows the startup owners to get a larger share of the value of profitable ventures. Startups with high enough probability of success are ready to pay the cost of the process. To analyze the effect of the different parameters on this trade off, we conclude the analysis of the optimal exit strategy by doing the comparative statics of p o (V ) with respect to all 1 the parameters, for the interior case where highlights the characteristics of the startups and the market that make it more likely to observe exits through IPO or through acquisition. Indeed, a higher p o (V ) implies a lower likelihood of exit through IPO. F < 1. This analysis [β m] [V C] Corollary 1. Consider situations where potential acquirers learn p. Then, the likelihood of IPO increases with V and β and it decreases with F, C, and m. 10

11 According to Corollary 1, the higher the potential value V (similarly, the lower the additional funding C), the more willing is the startup to go to the IPO market. Given the costly IPO process, only those startups that really benefit from the more competitive IPO market are willing to follow this path. As expected, a higher bargaining power m in the acquisition market leads to less IPO exits. Finally, an efficient IPO process, reflected by a low cost F and powerful screening capability β, makes IPO an appealing exit. 3.2 Optimal Exit Strategy with Uninformed Outsiders The analysis of the optimal strategy of a startup that looks for an exit when the potential acquirers do not know the value of p has some similarities with the one developed previously. First, if the startup s potential value V is lower than C it is liquidated. Second, the IPO offer is Z = V C if it receives a signal β = H which, in particular, implies that the startup will accept the offer. Finally, potential profits from IPO versus Acquisition increase with the value of p; therefore, there will be a cut-off equilibrium value p oo (V ) (that can possibly be equal to 0 or 1) above which the startup goes to IPO. The main new aspect when the value of p is unknown by the potential acquirers is that the price that they may offer does not depend on the real value of p but on its expected value from the point of view of the acquirer, which is a function of the startup equilibrium behavior. The deal that a potential acquirer will make to a startup that approaches it at t = 2 will not be based on the true probability but on the expected (equilibrium) value of p, which is poo(v ) 2. Therefore, the deal price at t = 2 will be m poo(v ) 2 [V C]. Similar to the informed outsiders case, a startup whose probability of success is equal to p oo (V ) must be indifferent (if p oo (V ) (0, 1)) between going to IPO and looking for an acquirer. Therefore, an interior p oo (V ) is characterized by βp oo (V ) [V C] F = m p oo(v ) 2 [V C]. (3) Equation (3) implies that the cut-off value is { } 1 F p oo (V ) min [ ] β m [V C], 1. (4) 2 For completeness, we state the equilibrium behavior of startups when outsiders are uninformed as to the value of p in Proposition 2. 11

12 Proposition 2. Consider a startup characterized by (V, p) in a situation where potential acquirers have not learned p. The startup equilibrium exit strategy is as follows: 1. If V C 0, the startup is liquidated and gets the payoff U oo (V, p) = If V C > 0 and p < p oo (V ), the startup goes to the acquiring market and gets a deal value U oo (V, p) = m poo(v ) 2 [V C]. 3. If V C > 0 and p p oo (V ), the startup invests F and goes to the IPO market. Moreover, (a) if it gets public signal H, then it receives an offer Z = V C from the IPO market and it accepts it; (b) if it gets public signal L, then it does not receive any offer from the IPO market. Therefore, in this case, U oo (V, p) = βp [V C] F. Moreover, at equilibrium, the likelihood of IPO increases with V and β and it decreases with F, C, and m. The intuitions behind Proposition 2 are the same as those explained after Proposition 1 and Corollary 1. 4 The Impact of Investment and Duration on the Likelihood of IPO and on the Rate of Success We now analyze how the optimal exit strategy of a startup is influenced by its investment and duration strategies. 4.1 The Investment Effect The level of investment affects the likelihood of an IPO exit. A higher investment level implies a shift in the distribution of V towards higher values. As shown in propositions 1 and 2 (see also Figure 2), the higher the value V, the more likely it is that the exit happens through an IPO rather than through acquisition, independently on whether potential acquirers have learned p. Therefore, a higher investment level should imply a higher IPO rate among 12

13 successful stories. Proposition 3 states this result. Proposition 3. The likelihood of IPO among the successful exits increases with I both, when the potential acquirers have learned p and when they have not learned p. Moreover, the shift in the distribution of V towards higher values implied by a larger investment should also lead to higher likelihood of successful exit. Proposition 4 states this result, whose proof is immediate. Proposition 4. The rate of successful exits increases with I. 4.2 The Duration Effect Longer duration means that the market has more precise information which, in our model, is reflected by a higher probability for the public to know the successful probability p. The next proposition investigates whether an IPO exit is more likely with informed or with uninformed outsiders. The proof of the proposition is straightforward from equations (2) and (4). Proposition 5. The probability of going to IPO is higher when the potential acquirers have not learned p than when they have learned p. More precisely, p oo (V ) < p o (V ) whenever p oo (V ) (0, 1), and p o (V ) = 1 whenever p oo (V ) = 1. Figure 2 helps to explain Proposition 5. It depicts the optimal exit strategy highlighted in propositions 1 and 2. For high values of p and V, IPO is the optimal exit route independently on the potential acquirers information. Similarly, going to the acquisition market is always the optimal startups strategy for low values of p and V (provided V > C). In the intermediate (shadow) region of Figure 2, startups go to IPO when the outsiders have not learned p, while they prefer going to the acquisition market if outsiders have observed p. The intuition for the existence of the intermediate region in Figure 2 is the following. When the outside acquirers observe the true value of p, they offer a deal according to p. However, when they do not observe the true successful probability, they can only offer a deal according to the expected probability, which is independent of the true value p. Consider a startup whose realized probability is p o (V ), that is, it is indifferent between IPO and acquisition if information about p is public. The deal it will obtain in the 13

14 Figure 2: Optimal Exit Strategy acquisition market if information is not public is lower, as it is based on the expected probability. Therefore, it would rather go to IPO than look for an acquirer. As a consequence, uninformed markets are more likely to lead to IPO exits. Longer duration leads to more information about p for outsiders. According to Proposition 5, this implies, ceteras paribus, a reduction in the likelihood of IPO exit. We state this result in the following corollary. Corollary 2. The likelihood of IPO among the successful exits decreases with d. We note that, according to our model, the duration has no effect on the level of V. Therefore, the successful rate is not influenced by the duration d. 14

15 5 Analysis of the Optimal Investment and Duration Decisions We address now the optimal initial decisions by the startup at t = 1. The analysis of Section 3 allows computing the expected income U o (V, p) or U oo (V, p) of a startup whose potential, publicly known value is V and whose probability of success is p, depending on the level of information by the outsiders. We now calculate the expected profits for a given duration d and a given investment I, denoted as U(d, I), which requires taking the expectation of the expected income over the possible values of V (whose distribution function Γ(V ; I) depends on I) and p: U(d, I) = e rd [h(d)u o (V, p) + [1 h(d)] U oo (V, p)] dpdγ(v ; I) I V p (5) = e rd [h(d)eu o (I) + (1 h(d))eu oo (I)] I where we denote EU o (I) = EU oo (I) = V V p p U o (V, p)dpdγ(v ; I), (6) U oo (V, p)dpdγ(v ; I). (7) We can interpret EU o (I) as the expected profits at the time of exit of a startup that has invested I at t = 0 and whose realized probability p is known by potential acquirers. Similarly, EU oo (I) is the startup s expected profits if the realization of p is unknown by outsiders. The probability that the information is known by the potential acquirers, h(d) increases with the duration. Moreover, the longer d, the lower the expected profits at t = 0 due to the discounting. Lemma 1 shows that EU o (I) is always higher than EU oo (I), that is, the startup s expected profits are higher when the potential acquirers learn p than when they do not. This result, interesting by itself, will be useful in the analysis of the optimal duration and investment decisions. Lemma 1. EU o (I) EU oo (I) for every I > 0, and the inequality is strict whenever p oo (V + f(i)) < 1. The intuition behind Lemma 1 is the following. The asymmetry of information between startups and potential acquirers makes it more profitable 15

16 for some ventures (those whose successful probability lies in the interval (p oo (V ), p o (V ))) to go to the IPO market although they would obtain a better deal in the acquisition market if the information were symmetric. Therefore, in expectation, startup s profits are higher when information about p reaches the potential acquirers, that is, EU o (I) EU oo (I). The optimal duration and investment decisions (d, I ) are interior. Therefore, they satisfy the first-order conditions U d (d, I ) = U I (d, I ) = 0. In Proposition 6, we study the effect of the discount rate r on (d, I ). Proposition 6. The optimal duration d and investment I decrease with the discount rate r. The result in Proposition 6 is quite intuitive. If the participants in the startups care less about the future, they invest less and stay a shorter period of time in the ventures. Proposition 6 allows us to discuss the effect of r on the likelihood of IPO exit. The discount rate r indirectly influences the likelihood of IPO exit through the investment effect and the duration effect. A lower discount rate r means both higher investment level and longer duration which, according to Proposition 3 and Corollary 2, have opposite impacts on the likelihood of IPO exit. On the one hand, a larger investment leads to more exits through IPO. On the other hand, a longer duration implies a better informed potential acquirer, which leads to more acquisitions. 6 CVC vs IVC Backed Startups: Empirical Implications from the Theoretical Model The analysis of the previous sections allows us to contribute to the discussion of the differences between startups that receive funds from CVC and those that only receive IVC funding. CVCs are typically less compelled to recover the investment earlier. We associate this difference with a lower discount rate for startups that receive CVC funding. According to our analysis, the difference in the discount rate between CVC and IVC backed startups has testable implications on their strategies. We use our theoretical results to propose empirical hypotheses concerning the differences in investment amount, duration before exit, exit strategy, and successful rate between CVC and IVC backed 16

17 startups. First, one implication of our model (see Proposition 6) is that startups with lower discount rate choose higher investment levels. Therefore, we should observe higher investments in CVC backed startups than in IVC backed startups. With more unused resources and having strategic aim, CVC funds invest more in the startup projects. We state this empirical implication in the following hypothesis. Hypothesis 1: CVC backed startups receive a higher investment amount than IVC backed startups. Second, Proposition 6 also implies that CVC backed startups (having lower discount rate) choose to stay longer before exit. Since CVC funds are more patient than IVC funds, we expect that CVC invested startups have a longer duration before exit than those backed by IVC funds. This is reflected in Hypothesis 2. Hypothesis 2: backed startups. CVC backed startups have a longer duration than IVC Third, our theoretical model indicates an indirect impact of VC funds characteristics on startups exit strategy. As we mentioned before, startups with CVC backing invest more in their projects than those with IVCs. The theoretical model predicts that a higher investment level increases the probability of an IPO exit (see Proposition 3). Furthermore, a startup with CVC backing also stays longer and, after Corollary 2, longer duration reduces the probability of IPO exits. According to our model, once we take into account the effect of investment and duration, the characteristics of the VC funds do not play a role in the choice of the exit strategy. We will test the theoretical results through Hypotheses 3, 4 and 5. Hypothesis 3: Investment amount has a positive effect on the probability of IPO exit. Hypothesis 4: Duration of a startup before exit has a negative effect on the probability of IPO exit. Hypothesis 5: CVC backed startups have the same probability of IPO exit as IVC backed startups. 17

18 Fourth, higher investments imply higher successful exit rates (see Proposition 4) while the duration and the characteristics of the fund do not have any direct effect on the successful rate. Hypotheses 6, 7 and 8 state these implications from our theoretical model. Hypothesis 6: Investment amount has a positive effect on the probability of successful exit. Hypothesis 7: Duration of a startup before exit has no effect on the probability of successful exit. Hypothesis 8: CVC backed startups have the same probability of successful exit as IVC backed startups. 7 Data Description We obtain the relevant data, i.e., investment amount, IPO date, acquisition date, investment rounds, number of investors, investors type, IPO price, Acquisition deal value, VC fund size, etc, from the VentureXpert database. To test the first five hypotheses, we use a dataset that contains 4801 successful startups in the US market from 1969 to We describe this dataset in detail. In Subsection 7.5, we will comment on the enlarged dataset that includes unsuccessful startups and successful startups with other types of exit besides IPO and Acquisition, which we use to test the last three hypotheses. Our sample of successful startups covers 63 industries in the US. Table 1 provides an overview of the industry composition of the sample (by twodigit SIC code). In the table, we just include industries with more than 20 observations. We observe concentration of industries with SIC code 28, 35, 36, 38 and 73. These codes correspond to Chemical, Electronic and Business Service related industries, where venture capital investments are more common. 7.1 Dependent Variables We use the dataset with successful startups to test the effect of VC funds characteristics (CVC or IVC) on investment amount, startups duration and 18

19 exit strategies. Therefore, we need three dependent variables: the total investment amount, startups duration before exit, and the exit rule (IPO or Acquisition). To measure the investment amount of a startup, we sum up the round level investments to get the total investment amount. The duration before exit is measured by the number of days. It is calculated as the difference between the exit date (IPO date or Acquisition date) and the date at which a startup receives the first investment from venture capital firms. Finally, the exit strategy of a startup is indicated by a dummy variable. It is equal to 1 if a startup exits through an IPO and 0 if it exits through an Acquisition. 7.2 Independent Variables The theoretical model predicts the influence of different VC funds characteristics on startups decisions and exit behavior. The most important independent variable is whether a startup is financed with CVC funds or IVC funds. There are two definitions of CVC backed startups in the literature (Toldra, 2010). Under the first definition, a startup is defined as CVC financed if all the investments are from CVC funds. The second defines a startup as CVC backed if at least one of the investors is a corporate venture fund. We use two variables to measure the VC fund characteristics. Firstly, we use the second definition in Toldra (2010) and create a dummy variable that is equal to 1 if a startup receives at least one investment from CVCs. If all the investments are from IVC funds, the startup is IVC financed and the dummy variable is equal to 0. 7 Secondly, we use a continuous variable to measure the funds characteristics: we calculate the percentage of investment made by CVC funds out of total investment in each startup. 7.3 Controlling Variables Based on the previous literature, we use a set of controlling variables to estimate the effect of VC funds characteristics on the investment amount of startup projects, their duration before exit, and exit strategies. It includes the average VC fund size, average VC fund age, total number of investment rounds, VC syndicate size, syndicate leader characteristics (i.e., whether the leader is a CVC fund or an IVC fund), industry market-to-book value, the 7 We can not use the first definition of CVC in Toldra (2010) because the number of startups that are fully funded by CVCs is very small. 19

20 relationship between CVC funds and their invested startups, 3 months and 6 months MSCI return 8 before the exit date, the industry fixed effect, and the year fixed effect. We also take into account the relative controlling power between the entrepreneur and the VC funds through the Later Stage Dummy variable that takes value of 1 if the startup is at expansion or later stages at the exit. As stated by Smith (2005) and Schwienbacher (2009), VC funds guarantee themselves more controlling rights at the beginning of their involvement and for seed financing than at late-stage financing. Hence, exiting at expansion or later stages proxies for higher entrepreneurs controlling power. 9 Table 2 provides the definitions of all the variables and Table 3 summarizes the basic statistics of these variables. 7.4 Correlations across Variables Table 4 reports the correlation matrix. It represents the correlations across the main variables. The variables in our estimation are not highly correlated, except the 3 months and 6 months MSCI returns. In particular, the correlation between Duration and Investment Amount is This low correlation suggests low multicollinearity of the independent variables. 7.5 Enlarged Dataset with Unsuccessful Startups The last three hypotheses estimate the influence of the level of investment, the duration and the fund s characteristics on the successful rate. We test these hypotheses with an enlarged dataset which includes both successful and unsuccessful startups in the U.S. before the year We define a startup as a Failure if the company status is Defunction in the database of VentureXpert. On the contrary, a startup is a Success if the status is Acquisition, Merger, Went Public, LBO, etc. The enlarged dataset has a similar industry distribution to the one which only contains startups successfully exited through IPO or Acquisition. Around 65% of the startups have a successful exit and 35% are defined as Defunction in the dataset The Morgan Stanley Capital International (MSCI) constructs a free float-adjusted market capitalization weighted index that measures the equity market performance of developed and emerging markets. We use the MSCI ACWI (All Country World Index) Index of the United States in the paper. 9 We use this dummy variable because we can not measure directly the relative controlling power between the entrepreneurs and VC funds due to limited data. 10 The successful rate of the startups in our dataset is very high. This might due to the restrictions of the database. VentureXpert database does not have the information of all the failure cases in the U.S. market. 20

21 We create a new dependent variable F ailure i for the empirical estimation. It is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the startup is a Failure as was defined before and 0 if it is a Success. The independent variables are the same as those described in Section 7.2. We exclude some controlling variables, such as the industry market-to-book value, fund age, due to data insufficiency. From VentureXpert, we can not observe the date that startups are considered as Defunction. Hence, all the controlling variables that need the exact date are excluded in the regressions of the last three hypotheses. The duration of the startups in this case is defined as the number of days between the first and the last investment dates. 8 Empirical Analysis and Results We first look at whether startups backed by CVC funds and those financed by IVC funds have different behavior. We provide some basic statistic differences between CVC and IVC financing in Panel A of Table 5. We observe significant differences between startups with CVC funds and with IVC funds in most variables. CVC backing implies a significantly higher investment than IVC backing. The average investment per venture for both exit strategies is around 50 million USD for CVC backed startups while it is only around 21 million USD for those only backed by IVCs. This fact has already been highlighted by previous literature (Gompers and Lerner, 2000). Moreover, there is a large gap between the mean duration of the two types of venture. The mean duration for CVC backed startups is 1929 days, compared to 1649 days for IVC backed startups. We also find that CVC financing leads to more investment rounds. CVC backed startups exit at later investment stages (i.e. more exits at expansion or later stages than exits at seeds or early stages). Compared to IVC funds, CVC funds are older. However, we have not found any significant difference in IPO exit rate and VC fund size between the two types of VC funds. 8.1 Fund s Characteristics and Investment Strategy The difference in the investment amount might come either from differences in the type of projects in which the funds invest (selection bias), or from the intrinsic characteristics of the type of fund, such as the discount rate. We use the dataset to confirm that the selection bias does not seem important: it is only when CVCs enter the startups that there is a change in the investment 21

22 amount. This analysis is included in Panel B and Panel C of Table 5. Table 5 (Panel B) depicts the number of startups that receive funds from the two types of VCs. The columns stand for different investment rounds and the lines are groups of startups, differentiated by the round in which CVC investors enter. We provide results until group 8, in which CVCs enter the project at the eighth investment round. 11 The highlighted numbers represent the number of survival startups when CVC investors join in the venture. For example, the first line (Gr.0) describes the group of startups that only receive IVC funds. There are 2778 of them, out of which 2117 also receive second round financing, 1492 receive third round financing, and so on. The third line (Gr.2) includes the group of startups that start receiving CVC funds at the second investment round. There are 415 of them, out of which 291 also receive third round financing, and so on. 12 It is worth highlighting that most CVC backed startups start receiving CVC financing at very early stages. One third of them (548 out of 1792) receive CVC funds at the first round, and almost 55% of them get CVC financing at the first two rounds. This is somehow at odds with previous findings suggesting that CVCs often enter at later investment rounds (Hellmann, Lindsey and Puri, 2008; Dushnitsky and Shapira, forthcoming; Masulis and Nahata, 2009). More interestingly, Table 5 (Panel C) shows the average investment per round and per group. Before CVCs enter the ventures, the investment amount is similar for all groups. For example, startups in Group 0 (that never receive CVC funds) invest almost 5.4 million USD in round 1, comparable with the 5.47 million USD of those that will receive CVC backing in round 2. However, these numbers are quite lower than 8.90 million USD received by startups backed by CVCs at round 1. A similar effect appears for all the rounds. Hence, before CVC investors join in the ventures, IVCs invest in similar projects, suggesting no obvious selection bias among the projects. The investment levels are significantly increased when CVCs enter into the startups. To see whether the intrinsic characteristics of the type of fund has an effect on the investment decision, we test Hypothesis 1 using the following 11 There are startups where CVCs only enter after the eighth round. Since the number of these ventures is small, we don t show the details of those cases. 12 The number just before 415 should have been 415. However, it is only 401 due to missing data. A similar problem appears in other lines. 22

23 model: ln Invest i = α I 0 + α I 1F und scharacteristics + 7 αkz I k + ɛ i (8) In equation (8), Invest i is the total investment amount at the startup level. F und scharacteristics measures whether the startup is financed by CVC funds or IVC funds. Z k is a set of controlling variables, including number of investment rounds, VC fund size, VC syndicate size, syndicate leader characteristics, industry market-to-book value, industry and year fixed effect. To obtain a robust estimation of how venture capital funds influence startups investment amount, we have estimated four models. Model 1 We use the dummy variable CV C for the funds characteristics. Model 2 It still uses the dummy variable CV C and it also includes the controlling variable of CVC strategic relationship. The variable measures whether the corporation behind CVC funds is a potential competitor to the invested startups or not. It is included according to Masulis and Nahata (2009). They indicate that because of the strategic aim of CVC funds, they can be competitors to the startups in the future. Therefore, startups ask for a higher investment from CVC funds than from IVC funds in order to be compensated for potential market competition. Model 3 It includes an additional controlling variable: the average fund age across all the investing funds in a startup. More mature VC funds have more experience, better reputation and richer resources. Therefore, they can invest more into startups. Model 4 It uses the percentage of investment made by CVCs (CV C per) as an indicator of CVC backed startups. A higher value means that the startup is more CVC oriented. The results of an OLS regression on the models are reported in Table 6. The four models provide similar estimated results and they give strong support to Hypothesis 1. CVC funds have a significantly positive impact on the total investment amount of startups. Startups financed by CVC funds invest 25% more than those financed by IVC funds if VC fund s characteristic is attributed by the dummy variable. Moreover, if the syndicate leader of a startup is a CVC fund, the startup receives an additional 25% increase in its level of investment. Similarly, if the CVC investment amount as a percentage of the total investment for a startup increases by 1%, the startup 23 k=1

24 receives 0.28% additional investment. Moreover, more investment rounds, larger fund size, more mature VC funds, larger syndicate size and higher industrial market-to-book value lead to more investment in startups. We do not find any significant effect of the corporate venture capital funds relationship with the startups (competitive or not) on startups investment amount. 8.2 Funds Characteristics and Duration Our theoretical model predicts that startups financed by CVC funds stay longer in the market before exit than those financed by IVC funds. The following survival model describes the estimation for Hypothesis 2. Duration = α D 0 + α D 1 F und scharacteristics + 6 α k Z k + ɛ i (9) The dependent variable in Equation (9) is the duration of the startups before exit, which is measured by the number of days between the exit date and the first investment date. The independent variable indicates whether the startup is invested by only IVC funds or by CVC funds. To estimate the duration model, we have the same controlling variables as in the Equation (8) and the industry fixed effect. As before, we have estimated four regression models. We use the dummy variable CVC to indicate that a startup is financed by CVC funds for Models 1 to 3. In Models 2 and 3, we add the controlling variables that measure the competition relation between the startups and the parent company of CVC funds and the VC fund age respectively in the regression. We then use the CVC percentage investment as the dependent variable in Model 4. We estimate the survival model in a parametric way and assuming a Weibull distribution of the residual values. 13 The hazard rates of the regression are shown in Table 7. As is suggested by Hypothesis 2, CVC backed startups do stay longer before the exit than IVC backed startups. Moreover, startups receiving finance from larger and more mature VC funds have a longer duration. Interestingly, more investment rounds reduce the duration for startups. k=1 13 The assumption of a Weibull distribution is based on the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) and the Bayesian Information Criterion (BIC). We also tried the semi-parametric estimation (COX estimation) of the survival model. However, the post estimation PH test rejected the proportional hazards assumption of the COX estimation. 24

Peer Monitoring and Venture Capital Expertise: Theory and Evidence on Syndicate Formation and the Dynamics of VC Interactions

Peer Monitoring and Venture Capital Expertise: Theory and Evidence on Syndicate Formation and the Dynamics of VC Interactions Peer Monitoring and Venture Capital Expertise: Theory and Evidence on Syndicate Formation and the Dynamics of VC Interactions Thomas J. Chemmanur* and Xuan Tian** Current Version: March 2009 *Professor

More information

The Role of the Value Added by the Venture Capitalists in Timing and Extent of IPOs

The Role of the Value Added by the Venture Capitalists in Timing and Extent of IPOs No. 2003/25 The Role of the Value Added by the Venture Capitalists in Timing and Extent of IPOs Tereza Tykvová Center for Financial Studies an der Johann Wolfgang Goethe-Universität Taunusanlage 6 D-60329

More information

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan;

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan; University of New Orleans ScholarWorks@UNO Department of Economics and Finance Working Papers, 1991-2006 Department of Economics and Finance 1-1-2006 Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Grandstanding in the venture capital industry: new evidence from IPOs and M&As

Grandstanding in the venture capital industry: new evidence from IPOs and M&As Grandstanding in the venture capital industry: new evidence from IPOs and M&As Salma Ben Amor* and Maher Kooli** Abstract We provide new evidence on the grandstanding hypothesis by considering initial

More information

Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments

Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments Kentaro Tomoeda October 31, 215 Abstract This article analyzes the implementability of efficient investments for two commonly used mechanisms in single-item

More information

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry Lin, Journal of International and Global Economic Studies, 7(2), December 2014, 17-31 17 Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically

More information

The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis

The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis Oktay Akkus Department of Economics University of Chicago Ali Hortacsu Department of Economics University of Chicago VERY Preliminary Draft:

More information

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Online Appendix for Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Giacomo Rodano Bank of Italy Nicolas Serrano-Velarde Bocconi University December 23, 2014 Emanuele Tarantino University of Mannheim 1 1 Reorganization,

More information

Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers

Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers WP-2013-015 Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers Amit Kumar Maurya and Shubhro Sarkar Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai August 2013 http://www.igidr.ac.in/pdf/publication/wp-2013-015.pdf

More information

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser. University of Konstanz Department of Economics Optimal Contracting with Reciprocal Agents in a Competitive Search Model Maria Breitwieser Working Paper Series 2015-16 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/econdoc/working-paper-series/

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Minh Vo Metropolitan State University Abstract This paper develops a model of financing with informational feedback effect that jointly determines a firm s capital

More information

Grandstanding and Venture Capital Firms in Newly Established IPO Markets

Grandstanding and Venture Capital Firms in Newly Established IPO Markets The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance Volume 9 Issue 3 Fall 2004 Article 7 December 2004 Grandstanding and Venture Capital Firms in Newly Established IPO Markets Nobuhiko Hibara University of Saskatchewan

More information

AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED. November Preliminary, comments welcome.

AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED. November Preliminary, comments welcome. AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED Alex Gershkov and Flavio Toxvaerd November 2004. Preliminary, comments welcome. Abstract. This paper revisits recent empirical research on buyer credulity

More information

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015. FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.) Hints for Problem Set 2 1. Consider a zero-sum game, where

More information

Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective

Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective Olivier Compte and Philippe Jehiel November 2003 Abstract A principal has to choose among several agents to fulfill a task and then provide

More information

Investment Allocation and Performance in Venture Capital

Investment Allocation and Performance in Venture Capital Investment Allocation and Performance in Venture Capital Hung-Chia Hsu, Vikram Nanda, Qinghai Wang November, 2016 Abstract We study venture capital investment decision within and across successive VC funds

More information

Loss-leader pricing and upgrades

Loss-leader pricing and upgrades Loss-leader pricing and upgrades Younghwan In and Julian Wright This version: August 2013 Abstract A new theory of loss-leader pricing is provided in which firms advertise low below cost) prices for certain

More information

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment

Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment University of Konstanz Department of Economics Market Liberalization, Regulatory Uncertainty, and Firm Investment Florian Baumann and Tim Friehe Working Paper Series 2011-08 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/workingpaperseries

More information

IPO Underpricing and Information Disclosure. Laura Bottazzi (Bologna and IGIER) Marco Da Rin (Tilburg, ECGI, and IGIER)

IPO Underpricing and Information Disclosure. Laura Bottazzi (Bologna and IGIER) Marco Da Rin (Tilburg, ECGI, and IGIER) IPO Underpricing and Information Disclosure Laura Bottazzi (Bologna and IGIER) Marco Da Rin (Tilburg, ECGI, and IGIER) !! Work in Progress!! Motivation IPO underpricing (UP) is a pervasive feature of

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH http://www.kier.kyoto-u.ac.jp/index.html Discussion Paper No. 657 The Buy Price in Auctions with Discrete Type Distributions Yusuke Inami

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017 Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 07. (40 points) Consider a Cournot duopoly. The market price is given by q q, where q and q are the quantities of output produced

More information

Information and Evidence in Bargaining

Information and Evidence in Bargaining Information and Evidence in Bargaining Péter Eső Department of Economics, University of Oxford peter.eso@economics.ox.ac.uk Chris Wallace Department of Economics, University of Leicester cw255@leicester.ac.uk

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Problems with seniority based pay and possible solutions. Difficulties that arise and how to incentivize firm and worker towards the right incentives

Problems with seniority based pay and possible solutions. Difficulties that arise and how to incentivize firm and worker towards the right incentives Problems with seniority based pay and possible solutions Difficulties that arise and how to incentivize firm and worker towards the right incentives Master s Thesis Laurens Lennard Schiebroek Student number:

More information

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Evaluating Strategic Forecasters Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Motivation Forecasters are sought after in a variety of

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

Corporate Finance - Yossi Spiegel

Corporate Finance - Yossi Spiegel Tel Aviv University Faculty of Management Corporate Finance - Yossi Spiegel Solution to Problem set 5 Problem (a) If T is common knowledge then the value of the firm is equal to the expected cash flow

More information

Taxation of firms with unknown mobility

Taxation of firms with unknown mobility Taxation of firms with unknown mobility Johannes Becker Andrea Schneider University of Münster University of Münster Institute for Public Economics Institute for Public Economics Wilmergasse 6-8 Wilmergasse

More information

Optimal Ownership of Public Goods in the Presence of Transaction Costs

Optimal Ownership of Public Goods in the Presence of Transaction Costs MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Optimal Ownership of Public Goods in the Presence of Transaction Costs Daniel Müller and Patrick W. Schmitz 207 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/90784/ MPRA

More information

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński Decision Making in Manufacturing and Services Vol. 9 2015 No. 1 pp. 79 88 Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment Andrzej Paliński Abstract. This paper presents a model of bank-loan repayment as

More information

Reputation and Securitization

Reputation and Securitization Reputation and Securitization Keiichi Kawai Northwestern University Abstract We analyze a dynamic market with a seller who can make a one-time investment that affects the returns of tradable assets. The

More information

Journal of Corporate Finance

Journal of Corporate Finance Journal of Corporate Finance 18 (2012) 451 475 Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Journal of Corporate Finance journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jcorpfin What drives the valuation

More information

New product launch: herd seeking or herd. preventing?

New product launch: herd seeking or herd. preventing? New product launch: herd seeking or herd preventing? Ting Liu and Pasquale Schiraldi December 29, 2008 Abstract A decision maker offers a new product to a fixed number of adopters. The decision maker does

More information

Information aggregation for timing decision making.

Information aggregation for timing decision making. MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Information aggregation for timing decision making. Esteban Colla De-Robertis Universidad Panamericana - Campus México, Escuela de Ciencias Económicas y Empresariales

More information

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games CPSC 532l Lecture 10 Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games CPSC 532l Lecture 10, Slide 1 Lecture Overview 1 Recap 2 Stochastic Games 3 Bayesian Games 4 Analyzing Bayesian

More information

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Joan Llull Structural Micro. IDEA PhD Program I. Dynamic Discrete Games with Imperfect Information A. Motivating example: firm entry and

More information

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Appendices A A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Given the structure of venture capital financing just described, the potential mechanisms by which shocks might propagate across companies in

More information

Portfolio Investment

Portfolio Investment Portfolio Investment Robert A. Miller Tepper School of Business CMU 45-871 Lecture 5 Miller (Tepper School of Business CMU) Portfolio Investment 45-871 Lecture 5 1 / 22 Simplifying the framework for analysis

More information

Do Government R&D Subsidies Affect Enterprises Access to External Financing?

Do Government R&D Subsidies Affect Enterprises Access to External Financing? Canadian Social Science Vol. 11, No. 11, 2015, pp. 98-102 DOI:10.3968/7805 ISSN 1712-8056[Print] ISSN 1923-6697[Online] www.cscanada.net www.cscanada.org Do Government R&D Subsidies Affect Enterprises

More information

Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures

Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures Southern Illinois University Carbondale OpenSIUC Discussion Papers Department of Economics 7-2007 Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures Litao Zhong St Charles Community College

More information

Syndication in private equity industry: comparing the strategies of independent and captive venture capitalists

Syndication in private equity industry: comparing the strategies of independent and captive venture capitalists Syndication in private equity industry: comparing the strategies of independent and captive venture capitalists Dominique Dufour 1, Eric Nasica 2 and Dominique Torre 3 July 2013 Abstract This paper aims

More information

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation Journal of Economics and Finance Volume 24 Number 1 Spring 2000 Pages 56-63 Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation Veronika Grimm and Ulrich Schmidt* Abstract This paper considers the classical independent

More information

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours Ekonomia nr 47/2016 123 Ekonomia. Rynek, gospodarka, społeczeństwo 47(2016), s. 123 133 DOI: 10.17451/eko/47/2016/233 ISSN: 0137-3056 www.ekonomia.wne.uw.edu.pl Aggregation with a double non-convex labor

More information

Success in Global Venture Capital Investing: Do Institutional and Cultural Differences Matter?

Success in Global Venture Capital Investing: Do Institutional and Cultural Differences Matter? Success in Global Venture Capital Investing: Do Institutional and Cultural Differences Matter? Sonali Hazarika, Raj Nahata, Kishore Tandon Conference on Entrepreneurship and Growth 2009 Importance and

More information

Supplementary Material for: Belief Updating in Sequential Games of Two-Sided Incomplete Information: An Experimental Study of a Crisis Bargaining

Supplementary Material for: Belief Updating in Sequential Games of Two-Sided Incomplete Information: An Experimental Study of a Crisis Bargaining Supplementary Material for: Belief Updating in Sequential Games of Two-Sided Incomplete Information: An Experimental Study of a Crisis Bargaining Model September 30, 2010 1 Overview In these supplementary

More information

The Cleansing Effect of R&D Subsidies

The Cleansing Effect of R&D Subsidies The Cleansing Effect of R&D Subsidies Tetsugen Haruyama October 2014 Discussion Paper No.1425 GRDUTE SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS KOBE UNIVERSITY ROKKO, KOBE, JPN The Cleansing Effect of R&D Subsidies Tetsugen

More information

JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT, Vol. 1, No. 1, (2003), pp. 1 26

JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT, Vol. 1, No. 1, (2003), pp. 1 26 JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT, Vol. 1, No. 1, (2003), pp. 1 26 JOIM JOIM 2003 www.joim.com PRIVATE EQUITY RETURNS: AN EMPIRICAL EXAMINATION OF THE EXIT OF VENTURE-BACKED COMPANIES Sanjiv R. Das a, Murali

More information

FISCAL FEDERALISM WITH A SINGLE INSTRUMENT TO FINANCE GOVERNMENT. Carlos Maravall Rodríguez 1

FISCAL FEDERALISM WITH A SINGLE INSTRUMENT TO FINANCE GOVERNMENT. Carlos Maravall Rodríguez 1 Working Paper 05-22 Economics Series 13 April 2005 Departamento de Economía Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Calle Madrid, 126 28903 Getafe (Spain) Fax (34) 91 624 98 75 FISCAL FEDERALISM WITH A SINGLE

More information

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Ahmer Tarar Department of Political Science Texas A&M University 4348 TAMU College Station, TX 77843-4348 email: ahmertarar@pols.tamu.edu

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION

STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION BINGCHAO HUANGFU Abstract This paper studies a dynamic duopoly model of reputation-building in which reputations are treated as capital stocks that

More information

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility and Coordination Failures What makes financial systems fragile? What causes crises

More information

Internet Appendix for Cost of Experimentation and the Evolution of Venture Capital

Internet Appendix for Cost of Experimentation and the Evolution of Venture Capital Internet Appendix for Cost of Experimentation and the Evolution of Venture Capital I. Matching between Entrepreneurs and Investors No Commitment Using backward induction we start with the second period

More information

What Drives the Valuation Premium in IPOs versus Acquisitions? An Empirical Analysis

What Drives the Valuation Premium in IPOs versus Acquisitions? An Empirical Analysis What Drives the Valuation Premium in IPOs versus Acquisitions? An Empirical Analysis Onur Bayar* and Thomas J. Chemmanur** Current Version: December 2011 Forthcoming in the Journal of Corporate Finance

More information

Efficiency in Decentralized Markets with Aggregate Uncertainty

Efficiency in Decentralized Markets with Aggregate Uncertainty Efficiency in Decentralized Markets with Aggregate Uncertainty Braz Camargo Dino Gerardi Lucas Maestri December 2015 Abstract We study efficiency in decentralized markets with aggregate uncertainty and

More information

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation May 1, 1997 On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation Yoshitsugu Kanemoto 1 Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo 7-3-1 Hongo, Bunkyo-ku, Tokyo 113 Japan Abstract The most important drawback

More information

Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright

Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals Donald J. Wright January 2014 VERY PRELIMINARY DRAFT School of Economics, Faculty of Arts and Social Sciences, University of Sydney, NSW, 2006, Australia, Ph:

More information

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models Preliminary Lecture Notes Hongbin Cai and Xi Weng Department of Applied Economics, Guanghua School of Management Peking University November 2014 Contents 1 Static Moral Hazard

More information

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi 10.1287/mnsc.1110.1334ec e-companion ONLY AVAILABLE IN ELECTRONIC FORM informs 2011 INFORMS Electronic Companion Trust in Forecast Information Sharing by Özalp Özer, Yanchong Zheng,

More information

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW 2.1 Background on capital structure Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set of assumptions, capital structure is irrelevant. This

More information

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power? International Journal of Business and Management; Vol. 9, No. 9; 2014 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really

More information

Optimal Coexistence of Long-term and Short-term contracts in Labor Markets

Optimal Coexistence of Long-term and Short-term contracts in Labor Markets Optimal Coexistence of Long-term and Short-term contracts in Labor Markets Inés Macho-Stadler David Pérez-Castrillo Nicolás Porteiro May 5, 2011 Abstract We consider a market where firms hire workers to

More information

Technology cooperation between firms of developed and less-developed countries

Technology cooperation between firms of developed and less-developed countries Economics Letters 68 (2000) 203 209 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase Technology cooperation between firms of developed and less-developed countries Shyama V. Ramani* SERD/INRA, Universite Pierre Mendes,

More information

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Jian Liu ** University of Exeter This draft: August 2016 Abstract We examine

More information

Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms

Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms 19 Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms Vol I Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms Annika Westphäling * Four eyes see more than two that information gets more precise being aggregated

More information

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Davit Khantadze September 30, 017 Abstract We are interested in optimal signals for the sender when the decision maker (receiver) has to make two separate decisions.

More information

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets M. Grasselli Mathematics and Statistics McMaster University IMPA - June 28, 2006 Strategic Decision Making Suppose we want to assign monetary values to

More information

Quota bonuses in a principle-agent setting

Quota bonuses in a principle-agent setting Quota bonuses in a principle-agent setting Barna Bakó András Kálecz-Simon October 2, 2012 Abstract Theoretical articles on incentive systems almost excusively focus on linear compensations, while in practice,

More information

Rui Wang, Pengfei Liu(Presenter) and Xun Li. Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of Connecticut

Rui Wang, Pengfei Liu(Presenter) and Xun Li. Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of Connecticut The Effectiveness of Mandatory Regulation v.s. Voluntary Program in Hazardous Waste Abatement: Emperical Evidences from National Partnership for Environmental Priority Program Rui Wang, Pengfei Liu(Presenter)

More information

Sequential-move games with Nature s moves.

Sequential-move games with Nature s moves. Econ 221 Fall, 2018 Li, Hao UBC CHAPTER 3. GAMES WITH SEQUENTIAL MOVES Game trees. Sequential-move games with finite number of decision notes. Sequential-move games with Nature s moves. 1 Strategies in

More information

Resource Allocation and Decision Analysis (ECON 8010) Spring 2014 Foundations of Decision Analysis

Resource Allocation and Decision Analysis (ECON 8010) Spring 2014 Foundations of Decision Analysis Resource Allocation and Decision Analysis (ECON 800) Spring 04 Foundations of Decision Analysis Reading: Decision Analysis (ECON 800 Coursepak, Page 5) Definitions and Concepts: Decision Analysis a logical

More information

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index Marc Ivaldi Vicente Lagos Preliminary version, please do not quote without permission Abstract The Coordinate Price Pressure

More information

Keywords: Corporate governance, Investment opportunity JEL classification: G34

Keywords: Corporate governance, Investment opportunity JEL classification: G34 ACADEMIA ECONOMIC PAPERS 31 : 3 (September 2003), 301 331 When Will the Controlling Shareholder Expropriate Investors? Cash Flow Right and Investment Opportunity Perspectives Konan Chan Department of Finance

More information

Public Market Institutions in Venture Capital: Value Creation for Entrepreneurial Firms

Public Market Institutions in Venture Capital: Value Creation for Entrepreneurial Firms Cornell University School of Hotel Administration The Scholarly Commons Working Papers School of Hotel Administration Collection 3-2017 Public Market Institutions in Venture Capital: Value Creation for

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

Durable Goods Price Cycles: Theory and Evidence from the Textbook Market. By Eric W. Bond and Toshiaki Iizuka

Durable Goods Price Cycles: Theory and Evidence from the Textbook Market. By Eric W. Bond and Toshiaki Iizuka Durable Goods Price Cycles: Theory and Evidence from the Textbook Market By Eric W. Bond and Toshiaki Iizuka June 2005 Abstract: We develop a model of the monopoly pricing of a durable good when there

More information

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3 EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli 32L.G.06 26 January 2015 Failure of the Coase Theorem Recall that the Coase Theorem implies that two parties, when faced with a potential

More information

Exercises Solutions: Game Theory

Exercises Solutions: Game Theory Exercises Solutions: Game Theory Exercise. (U, R).. (U, L) and (D, R). 3. (D, R). 4. (U, L) and (D, R). 5. First, eliminate R as it is strictly dominated by M for player. Second, eliminate M as it is strictly

More information

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade Jesse A. Schwartz Kennesaw State University Quan Wen Vanderbilt University May 2012 Abstract In a bilateral bargaining problem with private

More information

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Harold L. Cole and Narayana Kocherlakota Working Paper 604 September 2000 Cole: U.C.L.A. and Federal Reserve

More information

The Changing Role of Small Banks. in Small Business Lending

The Changing Role of Small Banks. in Small Business Lending The Changing Role of Small Banks in Small Business Lending Lamont Black Micha l Kowalik January 2016 Abstract This paper studies how competition from large banks affects small banks lending to small businesses.

More information

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Corporate Control Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Managerial Discipline and Takeovers Managers often don t maximize the value of the firm; either because they are not capable

More information

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No Junfeng Qiu Central University of Finance and Economics

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No Junfeng Qiu Central University of Finance and Economics QED Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No. 1317 Central Bank Screening, Moral Hazard, and the Lender of Last Resort Policy Mei Li University of Guelph Frank Milne Queen s University Junfeng Qiu

More information

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Definition of Incomplete Contracts Definition of Incomplete Contracts Susheng Wang 1 2 nd edition 2 July 2016 This note defines incomplete contracts and explains simple contracts. Although widely used in practice, incomplete contracts have

More information

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach

Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach Analysis of a highly migratory fish stocks fishery: a game theoretic approach Toyokazu Naito and Stephen Polasky* Oregon State University Address: Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics Oregon

More information

Efficiency and Herd Behavior in a Signalling Market. Jeffrey Gao

Efficiency and Herd Behavior in a Signalling Market. Jeffrey Gao Efficiency and Herd Behavior in a Signalling Market Jeffrey Gao ABSTRACT This paper extends a model of herd behavior developed by Bikhchandani and Sharma (000) to establish conditions for varying levels

More information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information - preliminary and incomplete, please do not cite - Working Paper R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information Andreas Frick Heidrun C. Hoppe-Wewetzer Georgios Katsenos June 28, 2016 Abstract

More information

The Limits of Reputation

The Limits of Reputation The Limits of Reputation Naveen Khanna Michigan State University Richmond D. Mathews University of Maryland March 7, 2017 Abstract Having a reputation for a desirable attribute (such as skill) generally

More information

Optimal Risk Adjustment. Jacob Glazer Professor Tel Aviv University. Thomas G. McGuire Professor Harvard University. Contact information:

Optimal Risk Adjustment. Jacob Glazer Professor Tel Aviv University. Thomas G. McGuire Professor Harvard University. Contact information: February 8, 2005 Optimal Risk Adjustment Jacob Glazer Professor Tel Aviv University Thomas G. McGuire Professor Harvard University Contact information: Thomas G. McGuire Harvard Medical School Department

More information

Auditing in the Presence of Outside Sources of Information

Auditing in the Presence of Outside Sources of Information Journal of Accounting Research Vol. 39 No. 3 December 2001 Printed in U.S.A. Auditing in the Presence of Outside Sources of Information MARK BAGNOLI, MARK PENNO, AND SUSAN G. WATTS Received 29 December

More information

A note on strategic piracy in the economics of software: an explanation by learning costs

A note on strategic piracy in the economics of software: an explanation by learning costs A note on strategic piracy in the economics of software: an explanation by learning costs Bruno Chaves and Frédéric Deroian, FORUM 1 Abstract: In a two-period model, a monopoly sells a software, the use

More information

October 9. The problem of ties (i.e., = ) will not matter here because it will occur with probability

October 9. The problem of ties (i.e., = ) will not matter here because it will occur with probability October 9 Example 30 (1.1, p.331: A bargaining breakdown) There are two people, J and K. J has an asset that he would like to sell to K. J s reservation value is 2 (i.e., he profits only if he sells it

More information

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Trading Company and Indirect Exports Trading Company and Indirect Exports Kiyoshi atsubara August 0 Abstract This article develops an oligopoly model of trade intermediation. In the model, two manufacturing firms that want to export their

More information

KRANNERT GRADUATE SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT

KRANNERT GRADUATE SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT KRANNERT GRADUATE SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT Purdue University West Lafayette, Indiana EARNOUTS: A STUDY OF FINANCIAL CONTRACTING IN ACQUISITION AGREEMENTS by Matthew D. Cain David J. Denis Diane K. Denis Paper

More information

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited Leonardo P. Santiago & Pirooz Vakili November 2004 Abstract In this paper we consider the question of whether an increase in uncertainty increases

More information