Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index"

Transcription

1 Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index Marc Ivaldi Vicente Lagos Preliminary version, please do not quote without permission Abstract The Coordinate Price Pressure Index (CPPI) measures the incentives of two competitors to engage on a specific kind of Parallel Accommodating Conduct (PAC). Specifically, it measures the incentives of a given firm to initiate a unilateral percentage price increase, with the expectation that at least one of its competitors will follow it. Using a large set of simulated economies, we measure the accuracy of the index in terms of predicting the impact of a merger on firms incentives to engage on PAC. In addition, we propose two alternative indexes that incorporate the positive pricing externalities existent between substitute brands produced by the merged firm. The results suggest that the original index displays a good performance when predicting the direction of the change on firm s incentives to engage in PAC, but only in mergers with low values of the diversion ratios between the merged firm brands. However, the percentage of cases with Error Type I is not negligible. In addition, it is shown that both alternative indexes dramatically outperform the original one in terms of predicting mergers with a significant anticompetitive impact. 1

2 1. Introduction The aim of this paper is to evaluate the performance of the Coordinate Price Pressure Index (CPPI) introduced by Moresi et al. (2011), and to propose and evaluate an alternative version of this index that incorporates more information. The CPPI measures the incentives of two competitors to engage on a specific kind of tacit coordination strategy to increase prices. Specifically, a leader firm increases its price by a certain percentage, expecting that its competitor will observe this change and will match exactly the same percentage price increase. This specific conduct is considered as a form of Parallel Accommodating Conduct (PAC). As explained by Harrington (2013), the PAC could lead firms to reach a supra-competitive outcome. Nevertheless, the conduct requires some kind of retaliation or deterrence in order to be successfully implemented by firms. The game considered by Moresi et al. (2011) is in line with this argumentation. The CPPI index is derived from a simple model of repeated interaction between two firms, which explicitly considers monitoring and retaliation. The game is as follows. (i) On a certain period, a leading firm increases its price by a given percentage. (ii) In the subsequent period a follower firm observes the price increase and decides whether to match it or not. (iii) When matching occurs, then the price increase becomes permanent. While when there is no matching, the leading firm reverses to its initial price level, with the promise of not initiating any further attempt to engage on PAC. We constructed a set of 50,000 simulated economies. The demand is derived from a model of discrete choice with random coefficients. The supply side is composed by a set of heterogeneous firms that offer differentiated products and compete in prices. The initial level of prices is obtained by computing the Bertrand-Nash equilibrium. On each economy, we considered the engagement on PAC by two firms (let s say and ), and for each firm, we simulated the percentage price increase that would maximize the present value of the firm expected profits. Then the pre-merger Actual Coordinate Price Pressure (ACPP) was computed as the minimum of these two percentage price increases. Thus, this measure can be seen as the lower bound of the supra-competitive prices that two firms could reach through PAC. 2

3 The next step was to simulate a merger between one of these firms (let s say ), the acquiring firm, and a third firm (let s say ), the acquired or target firm. Under this new scenario, we recomputed the ACPP. The impact of the merger on firms incentives to engage on PAC was measured as the variation of the ACPP induced by the acquisition. Then the ACPP variation is used as the benchmark to measure the performance of the variation predicted by the CPPI index. Note that we use a modified version of the CPPI index. The baseline index proposed by Moresi et al. (2011), considers the percentage price increase that leaves to the leader firm indifferent between increasing and not increasing its price (just-profitable variation). While the index used by us considers the percentage price increase that maximizes the present value of its expected profits (profit-maximizing variation). However, as already stated in the Section II.C.3 of Moresi et al. (2011), in practice this is translated just into a small difference with respect to the baseline index: the index built under the profit-maximization assumption, is equal to one half of the baseline one. The accuracy of the index is measured in two situations: (i) its ability to correctly predict the sign of the change ( or ), and (ii) its ability to identify mergers that generate a significant anticompetitive impact ( or ). Then we measured the percentage of cases where the index would lead us to incur on Error Type I and Error Type II. Recall that an Error Type I denotes a case for which the index erroneously identifies a merger as anticompetitive, when it is not. While Error Type II, refers to the case of the index failing to identify an anticompetitive merger. First, regarding the direction of the change, the results suggest that the CPPI displays a good performance for mergers involving brands with low diversion ratios between them. However, the percentage of cases with Error Type I is not negligible. Second, the results suggest that the CPPI index displays a poor performance when predicting mergers that generate a significant increase of firms incentives to engage on PAC. While the percentage of cases with Error Type I is almost zero, the percentage of cases where the index incurs on Error Type II is considerably high. The reason is that the index consistently underestimates the magnitudes of the actual ACPP variations. We believe that the cause of this problem, is that the index omits important information regarding the strategic interaction between the brands produced by the merging 3

4 parties. Indeed, the index does not consider any of the diversion rations between the acquiring and the target firms products. When the acquiring firm decides to increase its prices, part of the loss of sales from one brand goes to its other brand, and vice versa. Thus, the higher the diversion ratios between the brands produced by the acquiring and target firms, the lower the cost of initiating a PAC. Therefore, not considering this information, would lead us to underestimate the impact of the merger. Two alternative indexes are proposed. The first one requires the same set of information as the original one, plus the diversion ratio from the target firm to the acquiring firm. The second one instead, requires a much richer set of information, including: the diversion ratio from the target to the acquiring firm and vice versa, the pre-merger price, margin and own-price elasticity of the target firm. We tested the performance of these alternative indexes against the original one. The results suggest that the original index still outperform the two alternative ones in terms of predicting the sign of the change. Nevertheless, the two alternative indexes dramatically outperform the original one in terms of predicting mergers with a significant anticompetitive impact. Indeed, the percentage of cases with Error Type II decreases substantially, while the percentage of cases with Error Type I is just moderately increased. Thus, considering the interaction between the merged firm brands significantly increases the effectiveness of the index in this regard. In addition, the results show that the alternative index that uses more information, on average outperform the one with less information. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. On Section 2 we briefly review the CPPI index proposed by Moresi et al. (2011). On Section 3 we explain the simulations approach. On Section 4 the main results are shown. Finally, on Section 5 we present our main conclusions and policy recommendations. 4

5 2. The CPPI index 2.1 Pre-merger case We closely follow the definition proposed by Moresi et al. (2011). The PAC strategy consists on a game where two (or more) competitors engage on a joint price increase without the need of explicit communication among them. A leader firm increases its price by a certain percentage with the expectation that its competitors will accommodate and follow a similar strategy. The game is defined as follows. (i) On period, Firm will raise its price by a percentage equal to for at least two periods. (ii) On period, Firm observes the price increase and decides whether to match it or not, by increasing its price by the exact same percentage. (iii) On period there are two possible results. If Firm decides to match the price increase, then the change becomes permanent for both firms. If Firm decides not to match the price increase, then Firm will return to its initial price level and will not make any additional attempt to engage on PAC anymore. Moresi et al. (2011) propose an index that captures a firm s incentives to initiate a unilateral price increase (assuming that its competitor will match it). However, we chose to study a variation of the original index. Instead of using the maximum percentage price increase that a firm would be willing to initiate (just-profitable variation), we use the percentage price increase that maximizes the expected profits from initiating a PAC (profit-maximizing variation). In practice, it is equal to one half of the original index 1. The percentage price increase that Firm is willing to initiate is given by; With: 1 The mathematical derivations of both indexes are presented on the Technical Appendix of Moresi et al. (2011). 5

6 With being equal to the original index proposed by Moresi et al. (2011). The pre-merger market shares of Firms and are given by and, respectively. The term is the percentage margin charged by Firm, and are the own-price elasticities of firms and respectively and is the inter-temporal discount rate assumed to be equal for every firm in the market. The term is the diversion ratio from Firm to Firm The cost/benefit trade-off faced by Firm when initiating a price increase is captured by the term. The numerator represents the size of the demand that Firm will capture once its competitor decides to match the price increase. While the denominator contains the size of the demand lost by Firm when initiating a unilateral price increase. The term measures potential deviations of Firm with respect to the Bertrand-Nash equilibrium in prices. In equilibrium, it has to be the case that and. Therefore, when Firm is already pricing above the equilibrium, its incentives to initiate a price increase are reduced ( ). The percentage price increase that Firm procedure and it mirrors equation (1). is willing to initiate is obtained by an identical Finally, the pre-merger CPPI index is given by; { } With being equal to the original (or baseline) index proposed by Moresi et al. (2011). Notice that as pointed out by Moresi et al. (2011), the percentage price increase that a firm is willing to follow should be always higher that the percentage price increase that a firm is willing to initiate. Thus, the index captures the lower bound of the range of percentage price increases that two firms and could sustain through PAC. 6

7 2.2 Post-merger variation The idea is to measure the change on Firms and incentives to engage on PAC, after the acquisition of a third Firm. Thus, assuming that Firm (the acquiring firm) merges with Firm (the target firm), we re-build the post-merger index considering the exact same set of assumptions as in Moresi et al. (2011). These are: The is measured in relation to the pre-merger price level We abstract from any unilateral effects The merged Firm would raise the price of all its products by the same percentage The post-merger sales volume of the merger Firm, is going to be equal to the sum of the pre-merger sales of the merging parties The diversion ratio from Firm to the merged Firm will be equal to the sum of the pre-merger diversion ratios and. The diversion ratio from the merged Firm to Firm, will be equal to the share of lost sales from the merged Firm that goes to Firm. We approximate it by the following expression: The product produced by Firm has the same price and margin than the product produced by Firm. After the acquisition, the merged Firm will face the same elasticity, price and margin for both products. Then the post-merger percentage price increase that the merged Firm given by; is willing to initiate is While the percentage price increase that the outsider Firm given by; is willing to initiate post-merger is 7

8 Note that both formulas are derived from our interpretation of Moresi et al. (2011), since they do not present an explicit equation for the post-merger CPPI index on the paper. Finally, the impact of the merger on firms incentives to engage on PAC, is given by: { } { } 3. Simulations We simulated 50,000 economies, with 10,000 consumers and 5 single-brand firms on each of them. It is assumed that consumer preferences behave according to a model of discrete choice demand with random coefficients. In addition, we assume that firms offer products with differentiated characteristics or attributes, including a continuous one and a discrete one. Firms have heterogeneous and constant marginal costs of production and compete in prices. Under the absence of collusion or PAC, on each period prices are determined by the static Bertrand- Nash equilibrium. Using this approach, it is ensured that the simulated economies exhibit a much more realistic pattern of own and cross-price elasticities (See Nevo (2000)). In addition, having both continuous and discrete quality attributes gives more generality to the model and allows us to capture a wider range of preferences (See Grigolon and Verboven (2013)). On each economy we simulated a PAC strategy among Firm 1 (Firm or acquiring firm) and Firm 3 (Firm or outsider firm). The actual percentage price increases (as opposite to the predicted ones presented in the previous section) initiated by firms involved on PAC, are computed by maximizing the sum of firms present and future stream of expected payoffs, assuming that the competitor will follow the price increase. Therefore, we observe two percentage price increases: the one potentially initiated by Firm and the one potentially initiated by Firm. Then the Actual Coordinate Price Pressure (ACPP) is defined as the minimum of these two values. In other words, the ACPP represents the actual (instead of the 8

9 predicted one by the CPPI) lower bound of supra-competitive prices that firms and could reach through PAC. As a next step, we simulated the impact of a merger between Firm 1 and Firm 2 (Firm or target firm) on firms incentives to engage on PAC. Specifically, we recomputed the percentage price increase that Firm would be willing to initiate after acquiring Firm (which we call merged firm ), assuming that it applies the same percentage increase to both brands. At the same time, we recomputed the percentage price increase that Firm would be willing to initiate, assuming that it will be followed by the two brands of the merged firm. The post-merger ACPP is then defined as the minimum of these two corrected percentage price increases, and the impact of the merger is measured as the change on the ACPP. Thus, a positive ACPP variation represents an increase on the lower bound of prices that two firms could reach through PAC, and it could be considered as anticompetitive. However, an additional adjustment was made to the simulated price increase initiated by the acquiring firm post-merger. Since we are evaluating the impact of the merger with respect to the pre-merger level of prices, we need to adjust for the potential presence of unilateral effects. In order to do it, we compute the percentage price increase that the merged firm would be willing to unilaterally initiate, even if there are not competitors willing to follow it. Thus, the post-merger price increase initiated by the acquiring firm and motivated only by PAC, is obtained as follows: PAC Percentage Price Increase initiated by the merged (or acquiring) firm = Percentage price increase initiated by the merged firm and followed by a third competitor - Percentage price increase that the merger firm would unilaterally initiate In other words: Coordinated Effects = Overall Effect - Unilateral Effects 9

10 Note that it is assumed that competitors that are not involved on the PAC strategy do not react and keep their prices at the Bertrand-Nash level. In addition, we are restricting the unilateral effects to be a percentage price increase equally applied to all the brands produced by the merged firm. However, the post-merger level of prices (the Bertrand-Nash equilibrium) does not necessarily satisfy this condition. We will try to relax these assumptions in the robustness checks section of a future version of this paper. For more details regarding the maximization problem, please refer to the Appendix. The Table 3.1 summarizes the main descriptive statistics of the set of simulated economies. There are already two interesting results that can be taken from this table. First, on average the CPPI index significantly underestimates the actual impact of the merger. Second, as predicted by Moresi et al. (2011), the merger can actually reduce firms incentives to engage on PAC (a negative ACPP variation). Indeed, the ACPP change is negative on 13.57% of the sample. Table Summary statistics Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max. Own-price elasticity Firm Own-price elasticity Firm Diversion Ratio (Firm to Firm ) Diversion Ratio (Firm to Firm ) HHI pre-merger Predicted HHI variation ACPP pre-merger ACPP variation CPPI pre-merger CPPI variation* Number of observations 46,093 *It only considers observations with a CPPI variation higher than

11 4. Results 4.1 The index significantly underestimates the ACPP variation Graph 4.1 contains a set of scatter plots displaying the relationship between the value predicted by the index ( ( ) and the actual variation on firms incentives to engage on PAC ). The sample was classified in four groups, according to the actual value of the diversion ratio from the acquired Firm to the acquiring Firm. The upper left panel displays the scatter plot of the observations under the 25% percentile, while the upper right one displays the plot of the observations between the 25% and 50% percentiles, and so on. It is clear from a visual examination of the graph, that the index have a better predictive power for those acquisitions with lower diversion ratios between the merging parties. Graph 4.1 Predicted ( variation on firms incentives ) and actual ( to engage on PAC p25 - p50 p50 - p75 p75 - p p0 - p CPPI (Predicted var.) ACPP (Actual var.) Fitted values Graphs by Diversion Ratio (Firm C to Firm A) Percentiles The obvious explanation for the existence of this asymmetry, it is that the index omits important information regarding the diversion ratios between the brands produced by the merged firm. Indeed, when the acquiring Firm is evaluating to initiate a post-merger PAC with Firm, it has to consider the cost of unilaterally initiating the price increase. However, the higher the diversion ratios between the merging parties brands, the lower the cost of initiating the PAC, and thus the 11

12 higher the impact of the merger on the acquiring firm s incentives to initiate such a conduct. Therefore, for higher values of the merging parties diversion ratios, the index will tend to underestimate the real impact of the merger and to be considerably less accurate. Graph 4.2 displays the empirical distribution of the ratio between the predicted variation of the percentage price increase that the acquiring firm is willing to initiate ( ), and its actual variation. In other words, it shows the percentage of the actual variation that is explained by the index, and it is denoted by. As is can be seen from the graph, for higher values of the diversion ratio from the acquired Firm to the acquiring Firm, the distribution is centered around 0 (zero). This fact has two implications. First, the index consistently underestimates the actual price variation. And second, for higher values of this diversion ratio, the index predicts the wrong direction (or sign) of the change on a high percentage of the sample (almost half of it). Graph Histogram of p0 - p25 p25 - p50 Percent p50 - p75 p75 - p rs Graphs by Diversion Ratio (Firm C to Firm A) Percentiles Result 1 For higher values of the diversion ratios between the brands produced by the merged firm, the index tends to significantly underestimate the actual impact of the merger of firms incentives to engage on PAC and to be significantly less accurate when predicting the direction of the change. 12

13 4.2 Predicting the sign of the ACPP change To study the performance of the index when predicting the direction of the change, the sample was classified in two groups: cases with and cases with.. Then we measured the percentage of cases where the index would lead us to incur on Error Type I and Error Type II. Recall that Error Type I refers to the case when the index erroneously classify a merger as potentially anticompetitive, when it is not. While Error Type II, corresponds to the case when the index fails to detect an anticompetitive merger. Table 4.1 summarizes the results. It can be seen that in terms of Error Type II cases, the index displays a better performance for mergers with a low value of the diversion ratio Type I is still significant., however the number of cases with Error Table Accuracy when predicting the sign of the change Diversion Ratio (Firm / Firm ) Percentiles Freq. Type-I Error Freq. Type-II Error 25% 2, % 9, % 50% 2, % 9, % 75% 1, % 10, % 100% % 11, % Total 6, % 39, % Result 2 When predicting the sign of the ACPP change, the index displays a better performance for mergers with low values for the of the diversion ratios between the brands produced by the merged firm. However, the probability of incurring on an Error Type I is not negligible. 4.3 Identifying mergers that generates a significant increase on ACPP To study the performance of the index when predicting a significant increase on firms incentives to engage on PAC, the sample was classified in two groups: cases with and cases with. Then as before, we measured the percentage of cases where the index would lead us to incur on Error Type I and Error Type II. Table 4.2 summarizes the results. First, the percentage of cases with Error Type I is really low (0.41% for the whole sample) and stable across the sample. Second, there is a positive relationship between and the percentage of cases that incur on Error Type II. Nevertheless, the overall predictive power of the index for 13

14 detecting anticompetitive cases is quite poor. The index incurs on Type II Error on 75.08% of the cases, and almost on 100% of the cases for mergers with high values of the diversion ratio from the acquired Firm to the acquiring Firm. Table 4.2 Accuracy when predicting a significant variation of the ACPP Diversion Ratio (Firm / Firm ) Percentiles Freq. Type-I Error Freq. Type-II Error 25% 8, % 3, % 50% 9, % 2, % 75% 9, % 1, % 100% 8, % 2, % Total 36, % 9, % Result 3 The port-merger variation of the CPPI index displays a poor performance when detecting mergers that generate a significant anticompetitive impact ( engage on PAC. on firms incentives to 4.4 Incorporating the strategic interactions between the merged firm brands In order to overcome this drawback of the original CPPI index, we propose an alternative version that incorporates the strategic interaction between the brands produced by the acquiring and acquired firms, respectively. When the merged firm is evaluating to initiate a unilateral percentage price increase, its decision has to incorporate the fact that some of the sales lost by one brand are captured by the other brand and vice versa. This effect generates a positive externality between the merged firm brands and it could increase the acquiring firm incentives to initiate a PAC. However, the fact that the merged firm is generating a loss of sales for two brands instead of only one (as in the pre-merger case), it could increase the cost of initiating such a conduct in the first place. Therefore, the merger could also decrease the acquiring firm incentives to engage on PAC. The direction of the overall impact is going to depend on which of these effects predominates. 14

15 Two alternative indexes are proposed: 1. The first one uses the same information than the original index, plus the value of the diversion ratio from the acquired Firm to the acquiring Firm ( ). We denote it by. For its construction we kept the same set of assumptions from section The second one uses much more information. In addition to the information required for the construction of the original index, it also requires: the diversion ratios between the two brands produced by the merged firm, the pre-merger own price elasticity of the acquired firm, the pre-merger margin and price of the product produced by the acquired firm. We denote it by. For its construction we relaxed the assumption than the pre-merger prices, margins, diversion rations and own-price elasticities are the same for the brans produced by the merged firm. For further details about the derivation of both indexes, please refer to the Appendix at the end of this document. Table 4.3 displays the performance of the three indexes (the original one plus the two alternative ones) when predicting the direction of the ACPP change. The two alternative indexes display a better performance in terms of Error Type II, however the percentage of cases with Error Type I is considerably higher. Therefore, there is no evidence that the alternative indexes have a better performance in this regard. Table Accuracy when predicting the sign of the change Diversion Ratio (Firm / Firm ) Percentiles Freq. Type-I Error Freq. Type-II Error 25% 2, % 39.43% 41.16% 9, % 8.87% 7.57% 50% 2, % 42.26% 37.16% 9, % 9.45% 9.02% 75% 1, % 71.51% 58.67% 10, % 7.76% 9.75% 100% % 88.34% 80.76% 11, % 5.09% 7.26% Total 6, % 49.16% 45.18% 39, % 7.66% 8.39% Result 4 In terms of predicting the direction of the ACPP change, the two alternative indexes do not display a better performance than the original one. 15

16 Table 4.4 compares instead the performance of the indexes in terms of predicting mergers that generate a significant anticompetitive effect. It can be seen that the two alternative indexes incur on a higher percentage of Type I Error, however, this increase seems to be moderate. Regarding the Type II Error, both indexes dramatically outperform the original one. As expected, from the two alternative indexes, the one that uses the most information is the most accurate one. Table Accuracy when predicting a significant variation of the ACPP Diversion Ratio (Firm / Firm ) Percentiles Freq. Type-I Error Freq. Type-II Error 25% 8, % 2.77% 2.87% 3, % 48.79% 31.82% 50% 9, % 1.89% 1.27% 2, % 57.20% 36.14% 75% 9, % 3.82% 2.28% 1, % 52.40% 37.37% 100% 8, % 12.63% 6.5% 2, % 26.95% 25.14% Total 36, % 5.24% 3.19% 9, % 45.44% 31.99% Result 5 The two alternative versions of the CPPI index significantly outperform the original index in terms of identifying mergers that generate a significant anticompetitive impact ((, while moderately increasing the occurrence of Error Type I. And as expected, the alternative index which uses more information is the one with the best performance. 5 Conclusions We tested the accuracy of the CPPI index in a simulated environment, considering a system of non-linear demands and a supply side composed by heterogeneous firms that compete in prices. The results suggest that the index displays a poor performance when predicting significant changes on firm s incentives to engage on PAC. There are two potential explanations for this result. First, the index was derived from a model with linear demands. Thus, it is expected that its accuracy will be reduced on a model based on non-linear demands. Second, the index does not consider the strategic interactions between the merged firm brands. Indeed, the cost of initiating a PAC is reduced by the fact that some of the lost sales by a given brand go 16

17 to the other brands. Therefore, not considering this positive externality could lead us to inaccurate predictions. We showed that incorporating the strategic interactions between the merged firm brands substantially increase the accuracy of the index. The number of Error Type II cases decreases dramatically, while the number of Error Type I cases increases just moderately. Therefore, these results highlight the importance of considering these interactions when building a model or an index which attempts to predict the coordinated effects of a merger. 6 References Foncel, Jérôme, Marc Ivaldi and Aleksandra Khimich (2013), Assessing the accuracy of merger guidelines' screening tools, Preliminary version July 8, Grigolon, Laura and Frank Verboven (2013), Nested logit or random coefficients logit? A comparison of alternative discrete choice models of product differentiation, The Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming. Harrington, Joseph (2013), Evaluating Mergers for Coordinated Effects and the Role of Parallel Accommodating Conduct, 78 Antitrust Law Journal No. 3 (2013) Moresi, Serge, David Reitman, Steven C. Salop and Yianis Sarafidis (), Gauging Parallel Accommodating Conduct Concerns with the CPPI Nevo, Aviv (2000), A Practitioner's Guide to Estimation of Random-Coefficients Logit Models of Demand, Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume 9, Number 4, Winter 2000, 513_

18 7 Appendix 7.1 Alternative CPPI variation 1: { } { } 1. With having the same formulas introduced on Section The post-merger percentage price increase initiated by the acquiring firm is given by: With; 3. While the post-merger price increase initiated by the outsider firm is given by: 18

19 7.2 Alternative CPPI variation 2: { } { } 1. With having the same formulas introduced on Section The post-merger percentage price increase initiated by the acquiring firm is given by: With; And; 3. While the post-merger price increase initiated by the outsider firm is given by: With: 19

20 7.3 Simulations baseline setting We almost replicated the baseline simulations setting used by Foncel, Ivaldi and Khimich (2013), there are a few differences marked with a (*) in the table below. Parameter Baseline Setting Number of firms is fixed to 5 for all the economies. Each firm produces only one product. Number of consumers is set to 10,000 for all the economies. Number of simulations for computing the expected market shares is fixed to 10,000 for all the economies. (*) It is constant within each economy, but it varies across economies with uniform distribution [ ]. For a given economy varies among consumers with exponential distribution. The parameter is distributed uniformly [ ] across economies. (*) It is constant within each economy, but it varies across economies with uniform distribution [ ]. (*) It is constant within each economy, but it varies across economies with uniform distribution [ ]., For a given economy both vary among consumers with normal distributions [ ] and [ ], respectively. The parameters and are distributed uniformly [ ] across economies., They are both drawn from an extreme value distribution [ ], where the scale parameter is equal to 0.5. (*) For each economy where and are distributed normally with [ ]. For each economy where are distributed normally with [ ]. For each economy is drawn from a normal distribution [ ]. For a given economy varies among consumers with normal distribution [ ]. The parameter is distributed uniformly [ ] across economies. For each economy is drawn from a normal distribution [ ]., Both are fixed for each economy, but they vary across economies with the same uniform distribution [ ]. It is fixed on each economy and common for all firms. It is either equal to zero (when marginal costs are assumed to be constant), or vary across economies with uniform distribution [ ] (when marginal costs are increasing). 20

21 7.4 Simulations of the actual and The actual pre-merger, for, is computed as follows: { ( ) } While the post-merger, for, are obtained with the following equations: { ( ) ( ) ( ) } { ( ) ( ) } { ( ) } 21

22 7.5 Derivation of the corrected post-merger CPPI index We propose a modified version of the CPPI index that takes into consideration the strategic interactions between the brands produced by the merged firm. For the construction of this index we closely follow the methodology proposed by Moresi et al. (2011) Acquiring firm (Firm A) 1. At period the acquiring firm increases the prices of its two brands by percent. It incurs on a loss of profits equal to the difference between: (i) the lower volume of sales generated by the price increase, times the margin charged for the two brands, and (ii) the higher price charged on its remaining sales. This is given by the following expression: [ ] [ ] [ ] [ ] We define and, and the previous formula becomes: [ ] [ ] 2. Assuming that from period the price increase is followed by Firm, then the acquiring firm gets profits equal to the difference between: (i) the higher price charged on its overall sales, and (ii) the lower volume of sales generated by the price increase, times the margin charged for each of its two brands. Thus the per-period gain from PAC is given by: 22

23 [ ] [ ] 3. Assuming that the price increase followed by Firm becomes permanent, then the merged firm will choose in order to maximize the present value of its expected payoffs. Therefore, the optimal is found by maximizing the following expression: { } And is given by; With; 4. However, we need to make an additional adjustment to this formula. Provided that the PAC incentives are evaluated at the pre-merger prices, the merging parties should have an incentive to initiate an unilateral percentage price increase, regardless the fact that competitor follows the price increase or not. Therefore, since the considers the strategic interactions between the merged firm brands, it also consider this unilateral price increase. In order to clean our index from this effect, we propose the following corrected formula:. 23

24 The unilateral price increase can be found by maximizing the following expression: { } And it is given by; Thus, the post-merger percentage price increase that the acquiring firm is willing to initiate, assuming that competitor will follow the same conduct, is given by: Finally, considering the same set of assumptions than in section 2.2 2, the previous formula is simplified to: 2 The assumptions are: 1. The prices, margins and own-price elasticities of the brands produced by the merged firm are the same (, and ). 2. The diversion ratios between the brands produced by the merged firm are identical ( ). 24

25 7.3.2 Outsider firm (Firm B) 1. At period the outsider firm increases it price by percent. It incurs on a loss of profits equal to the difference between: (i) the lower volume of sales generated by the price increase, times the margin charged for its brand, and (ii) the higher price charged on its remaining sales. This is given by the following expression: [ ] [ ] 2. Assuming that from period the price increase is followed by the merged Firm, then the outsider firm gets profits equal to the difference between: (i) the higher price charged on its overall sales, and (ii) the lower volume of sales generated by the price increase, times the margin charged for its brand. Thus the per-period gain from PAC is given by: [ ] 3. Assuming that the price increase followed by the merged firm Firm becomes permanent, then the outsider firm will choose in order to maximize the present value of its expected payoffs. Therefore, the optimal is found by maximizing the following expression: { } And is given by; 25

26 With: Finally, considering the same set of assumptions than in section 2.2, the previous formula is simplified to: Alternative variations of the CPPI index 1. Finally, and considering the previous formulas, the corrected versions of the postmerger variation of CPPI indexes are given by: { } { } And; { } { } 26

Gauging Parallel Accommodating Conduct Concerns with the CPPI

Gauging Parallel Accommodating Conduct Concerns with the CPPI Gauging Parallel Accommodating Conduct Concerns with the CPPI Serge X. Moresi* David Reitman* Steven C. Salop** Yianis Sarafidis* Abstract The 2010 Merger Guidelines give greater prominence to the concept

More information

Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2

Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2 Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2 Due Tues Oct 3. Question 1 Consider the following model of entry. There are two firms. There are two entry scenarios in each period. With probability only one firm is able

More information

Upward pricing pressure of mergers weakening vertical relationships

Upward pricing pressure of mergers weakening vertical relationships Upward pricing pressure of mergers weakening vertical relationships Gregor Langus y and Vilen Lipatov z 23rd March 2016 Abstract We modify the UPP test of Farrell and Shapiro (2010) to take into account

More information

Risk Aversion and Tacit Collusion in a Bertrand Duopoly Experiment

Risk Aversion and Tacit Collusion in a Bertrand Duopoly Experiment Risk Aversion and Tacit Collusion in a Bertrand Duopoly Experiment Lisa R. Anderson College of William and Mary Department of Economics Williamsburg, VA 23187 lisa.anderson@wm.edu Beth A. Freeborn College

More information

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets Metin Cakir Purdue University December 6, 2010 Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 1 / 28 Outline Outline Estimating

More information

The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis

The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis Oktay Akkus Department of Economics University of Chicago Ali Hortacsu Department of Economics University of Chicago VERY Preliminary Draft:

More information

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Christopher Phelan Working Paper 676 December 2009 Phelan: University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve

More information

Endogenous Cartel Formation with Differentiated Products and Price Competition

Endogenous Cartel Formation with Differentiated Products and Price Competition Endogenous Cartel Formation with Differentiated Products and Price Competition Tyra Merker * February 2018 Abstract Cartels may cause great harm to consumers and economic efficiency. However, literature

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap

Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap Peter N Bell University of Victoria 12. April 2012 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/38347/ MPRA Paper

More information

DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION

DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION APPENDIX DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION PART 1 SUMMARIZATION 1: BUILDING BLOCKS OF DATA ANALYSIS 294 PART 2 PART 3 PART 4 VISUALIZATION: GRAPHS AND TABLES FOR SUMMARIZING AND ORGANIZING DATA 296

More information

Monetary policy under uncertainty

Monetary policy under uncertainty Chapter 10 Monetary policy under uncertainty 10.1 Motivation In recent times it has become increasingly common for central banks to acknowledge that the do not have perfect information about the structure

More information

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Module No. # 03 Illustrations of Nash Equilibrium Lecture No. # 04

More information

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models Managerial Economics November 16, 2012 Prof. Dr. Sebastian Rausch Centre for Energy Policy and Economics Department of Management, Technology and Economics ETH Zürich

More information

Measuring and managing market risk June 2003

Measuring and managing market risk June 2003 Page 1 of 8 Measuring and managing market risk June 2003 Investment management is largely concerned with risk management. In the management of the Petroleum Fund, considerable emphasis is therefore placed

More information

Annual risk measures and related statistics

Annual risk measures and related statistics Annual risk measures and related statistics Arno E. Weber, CIPM Applied paper No. 2017-01 August 2017 Annual risk measures and related statistics Arno E. Weber, CIPM 1,2 Applied paper No. 2017-01 August

More information

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012 Game Theory Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 22 COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY Correlated Strategies and Correlated

More information

Basic Procedure for Histograms

Basic Procedure for Histograms Basic Procedure for Histograms 1. Compute the range of observations (min. & max. value) 2. Choose an initial # of classes (most likely based on the range of values, try and find a number of classes that

More information

Alternative VaR Models

Alternative VaR Models Alternative VaR Models Neil Roeth, Senior Risk Developer, TFG Financial Systems. 15 th July 2015 Abstract We describe a variety of VaR models in terms of their key attributes and differences, e.g., parametric

More information

Axioma Research Paper No January, Multi-Portfolio Optimization and Fairness in Allocation of Trades

Axioma Research Paper No January, Multi-Portfolio Optimization and Fairness in Allocation of Trades Axioma Research Paper No. 013 January, 2009 Multi-Portfolio Optimization and Fairness in Allocation of Trades When trades from separately managed accounts are pooled for execution, the realized market-impact

More information

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Miguel Antón, Florian Ederer, Mireia Giné, and Martin Schmalz August 13, 2016 Abstract This internet appendix provides

More information

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text. 1 Oligopoly The key feature of the oligopoly (and to some extent, the monopolistically competitive market) market structure is that one rm

More information

Business Cycles II: Theories

Business Cycles II: Theories Macroeconomic Policy Class Notes Business Cycles II: Theories Revised: December 5, 2011 Latest version available at www.fperri.net/teaching/macropolicy.f11htm In class we have explored at length the main

More information

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly Exercise - Quantity competition 1 Take firm 1 s perspective Total revenue is R(q 1 = (4 q 1 q q 1 and, hence, marginal revenue is MR 1 (q 1 = 4 q 1 q Marginal cost is MC

More information

Comparison of theory and practice of revenue management with undifferentiated demand

Comparison of theory and practice of revenue management with undifferentiated demand Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam Research Paper Business Analytics Comparison of theory and practice of revenue management with undifferentiated demand Author Tirza Jochemsen 2500365 Supervisor Prof. Ger Koole

More information

Pricing Behavior in Markets with State Dependence in Demand. Technical Appendix. (for review only, not for publication) This Draft: July 5, 2006

Pricing Behavior in Markets with State Dependence in Demand. Technical Appendix. (for review only, not for publication) This Draft: July 5, 2006 Pricing Behavior in Markets with State Dependence in Demand Technical Appendix (for review only, not for publication) This Draft: July 5, 2006 1 Introduction In this technical appendix, we provide additional

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 More on strategic games and extensive games with perfect information Block 2 Jun 11, 2017 Auctions results Histogram of

More information

Choice Probabilities. Logit Choice Probabilities Derivation. Choice Probabilities. Basic Econometrics in Transportation.

Choice Probabilities. Logit Choice Probabilities Derivation. Choice Probabilities. Basic Econometrics in Transportation. 1/31 Choice Probabilities Basic Econometrics in Transportation Logit Models Amir Samimi Civil Engineering Department Sharif University of Technology Primary Source: Discrete Choice Methods with Simulation

More information

Resale Price and Cost-Plus Methods: The Expected Arm s Length Space of Coefficients

Resale Price and Cost-Plus Methods: The Expected Arm s Length Space of Coefficients International Alessio Rombolotti and Pietro Schipani* Resale Price and Cost-Plus Methods: The Expected Arm s Length Space of Coefficients In this article, the resale price and cost-plus methods are considered

More information

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains Maria-Augusta Miceli University of Rome Sapienza Claudia Nardone University of Rome Sapienza October 8, 06 Abstract We here want to analyze how the imperfect competition

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

How High A Hedge Is High Enough? An Empirical Test of NZSE10 Futures.

How High A Hedge Is High Enough? An Empirical Test of NZSE10 Futures. How High A Hedge Is High Enough? An Empirical Test of NZSE1 Futures. Liping Zou, William R. Wilson 1 and John F. Pinfold Massey University at Albany, Private Bag 1294, Auckland, New Zealand Abstract Undoubtedly,

More information

Impact of Weekdays on the Return Rate of Stock Price Index: Evidence from the Stock Exchange of Thailand

Impact of Weekdays on the Return Rate of Stock Price Index: Evidence from the Stock Exchange of Thailand Journal of Finance and Accounting 2018; 6(1): 35-41 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/jfa doi: 10.11648/j.jfa.20180601.15 ISSN: 2330-7331 (Print); ISSN: 2330-7323 (Online) Impact of Weekdays on the

More information

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati Module No. # 03 Illustrations of Nash Equilibrium Lecture No. # 02

More information

MEASURING PORTFOLIO RISKS USING CONDITIONAL COPULA-AR-GARCH MODEL

MEASURING PORTFOLIO RISKS USING CONDITIONAL COPULA-AR-GARCH MODEL MEASURING PORTFOLIO RISKS USING CONDITIONAL COPULA-AR-GARCH MODEL Isariya Suttakulpiboon MSc in Risk Management and Insurance Georgia State University, 30303 Atlanta, Georgia Email: suttakul.i@gmail.com,

More information

SHSU ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER

SHSU ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER Sam Houston State University Department of Economics and International Business Working Paper Series Controlling Pollution with Fixed Inspection Capacity Lirong Liu SHSU Economics & Intl. Business Working

More information

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory Chapter Microeconomics of Consumer Theory The two broad categories of decision-makers in an economy are consumers and firms. Each individual in each of these groups makes its decisions in order to achieve

More information

Bloomberg. Portfolio Value-at-Risk. Sridhar Gollamudi & Bryan Weber. September 22, Version 1.0

Bloomberg. Portfolio Value-at-Risk. Sridhar Gollamudi & Bryan Weber. September 22, Version 1.0 Portfolio Value-at-Risk Sridhar Gollamudi & Bryan Weber September 22, 2011 Version 1.0 Table of Contents 1 Portfolio Value-at-Risk 2 2 Fundamental Factor Models 3 3 Valuation methodology 5 3.1 Linear factor

More information

Online Appendix A: Verification of Employer Responses

Online Appendix A: Verification of Employer Responses Online Appendix for: Do Employer Pension Contributions Reflect Employee Preferences? Evidence from a Retirement Savings Reform in Denmark, by Itzik Fadlon, Jessica Laird, and Torben Heien Nielsen Online

More information

Online Appendix: Extensions

Online Appendix: Extensions B Online Appendix: Extensions In this online appendix we demonstrate that many important variations of the exact cost-basis LUL framework remain tractable. In particular, dual problem instances corresponding

More information

Reinsuring Group Revenue Insurance with. Exchange-Provided Revenue Contracts. Bruce A. Babcock, Dermot J. Hayes, and Steven Griffin

Reinsuring Group Revenue Insurance with. Exchange-Provided Revenue Contracts. Bruce A. Babcock, Dermot J. Hayes, and Steven Griffin Reinsuring Group Revenue Insurance with Exchange-Provided Revenue Contracts Bruce A. Babcock, Dermot J. Hayes, and Steven Griffin CARD Working Paper 99-WP 212 Center for Agricultural and Rural Development

More information

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions

PRISONER S DILEMMA. Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions ECO 300 Fall 2005 November 22 OLIGOPOLY PART 2 PRISONER S DILEMMA Example from P-R p. 455; also 476-7, 481-2 Price-setting (Bertrand) duopoly Demand functions X = 12 2 P + P, X = 12 2 P + P 1 1 2 2 2 1

More information

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination Arvind Magesan and Jordi Mondria January 31, 2011 Abstract In this paper we study the economic and strategic incentives for a country to financially liberalize

More information

Problem 3,a. ds 1 (s 2 ) ds 2 < 0. = (1+t)

Problem 3,a. ds 1 (s 2 ) ds 2 < 0. = (1+t) Problem Set 3. Pay-off functions are given for the following continuous games, where the players simultaneously choose strategies s and s. Find the players best-response functions and graph them. Find

More information

Mixed Logit or Random Parameter Logit Model

Mixed Logit or Random Parameter Logit Model Mixed Logit or Random Parameter Logit Model Mixed Logit Model Very flexible model that can approximate any random utility model. This model when compared to standard logit model overcomes the Taste variation

More information

Working Party No. 3 on Co-operation and Enforcement

Working Party No. 3 on Co-operation and Enforcement For Official Use DAF/COMP/WP3/WD(2008)20 DAF/COMP/WP3/WD(2008)20 For Official Use Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Économiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 03-Mar-2008

More information

Point Estimation. Some General Concepts of Point Estimation. Example. Estimator quality

Point Estimation. Some General Concepts of Point Estimation. Example. Estimator quality Point Estimation Some General Concepts of Point Estimation Statistical inference = conclusions about parameters Parameters == population characteristics A point estimate of a parameter is a value (based

More information

Working Paper: Cost of Regulatory Error when Establishing a Price Cap

Working Paper: Cost of Regulatory Error when Establishing a Price Cap Working Paper: Cost of Regulatory Error when Establishing a Price Cap January 2016-1 - Europe Economics is registered in England No. 3477100. Registered offices at Chancery House, 53-64 Chancery Lane,

More information

Conover Test of Variances (Simulation)

Conover Test of Variances (Simulation) Chapter 561 Conover Test of Variances (Simulation) Introduction This procedure analyzes the power and significance level of the Conover homogeneity test. This test is used to test whether two or more population

More information

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium Online Appendix to Partnerships versus Corporations: Moral Hazard, Sorting and Ownership Structure Ayca Kaya and Galina Vereshchagina Appendix A formally defines an equilibrium in our model, Appendix B

More information

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals. Chapter 3 Oligopoly Oligopoly is an industry where there are relatively few sellers. The product may be standardized (steel) or differentiated (automobiles). The firms have a high degree of interdependence.

More information

Budget Setting Strategies for the Company s Divisions

Budget Setting Strategies for the Company s Divisions Budget Setting Strategies for the Company s Divisions Menachem Berg Ruud Brekelmans Anja De Waegenaere November 14, 1997 Abstract The paper deals with the issue of budget setting to the divisions of a

More information

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination Carl E. Walsh March 8, 017 Contents 1 Policy Coordination 1 1.1 The Basic Model..................................... 1. Equilibrium with Coordination.............................

More information

ROBUST OPTIMIZATION OF MULTI-PERIOD PRODUCTION PLANNING UNDER DEMAND UNCERTAINTY. A. Ben-Tal, B. Golany and M. Rozenblit

ROBUST OPTIMIZATION OF MULTI-PERIOD PRODUCTION PLANNING UNDER DEMAND UNCERTAINTY. A. Ben-Tal, B. Golany and M. Rozenblit ROBUST OPTIMIZATION OF MULTI-PERIOD PRODUCTION PLANNING UNDER DEMAND UNCERTAINTY A. Ben-Tal, B. Golany and M. Rozenblit Faculty of Industrial Engineering and Management, Technion, Haifa 32000, Israel ABSTRACT

More information

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS ECO410H: Practice Questions SOLUTIONS 1. (a) The unique Nash equilibrium strategy profile is s = (M, M). (b) The unique Nash equilibrium strategy profile is s = (R4, C3). (c) The two Nash equilibria are

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Putnam Institute JUne 2011 Optimal Asset Allocation in : A Downside Perspective W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT Once an individual has retired, asset allocation becomes a critical

More information

Measuring the Amount of Asymmetric Information in the Foreign Exchange Market

Measuring the Amount of Asymmetric Information in the Foreign Exchange Market Measuring the Amount of Asymmetric Information in the Foreign Exchange Market Esen Onur 1 and Ufuk Devrim Demirel 2 September 2009 VERY PRELIMINARY & INCOMPLETE PLEASE DO NOT CITE WITHOUT AUTHORS PERMISSION

More information

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture X: Introduction to Game Theory

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture X: Introduction to Game Theory Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture X: Introduction to Game Theory Kai Hao Yang 11/14/2017 1 Introduction and Basic Definition of Game So far we have been studying environments where the economic

More information

Contrarian Trades and Disposition Effect: Evidence from Online Trade Data. Abstract

Contrarian Trades and Disposition Effect: Evidence from Online Trade Data. Abstract Contrarian Trades and Disposition Effect: Evidence from Online Trade Data Hayato Komai a Ryota Koyano b Daisuke Miyakawa c Abstract Using online stock trading records in Japan for 461 individual investors

More information

13.1 Infinitely Repeated Cournot Oligopoly

13.1 Infinitely Repeated Cournot Oligopoly Chapter 13 Application: Implicit Cartels This chapter discusses many important subgame-perfect equilibrium strategies in optimal cartel, using the linear Cournot oligopoly as the stage game. For game theory

More information

THEORY & PRACTICE FOR FUND MANAGERS. SPRING 2011 Volume 20 Number 1 RISK. special section PARITY. The Voices of Influence iijournals.

THEORY & PRACTICE FOR FUND MANAGERS. SPRING 2011 Volume 20 Number 1 RISK. special section PARITY. The Voices of Influence iijournals. T H E J O U R N A L O F THEORY & PRACTICE FOR FUND MANAGERS SPRING 0 Volume 0 Number RISK special section PARITY The Voices of Influence iijournals.com Risk Parity and Diversification EDWARD QIAN EDWARD

More information

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Addison-Wesley.

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Addison-Wesley. Appendix: Statistics in Action Part I Financial Time Series 1. These data show the effects of stock splits. If you investigate further, you ll find that most of these splits (such as in May 1970) are 3-for-1

More information

On the Use of Stock Index Returns from Economic Scenario Generators in ERM Modeling

On the Use of Stock Index Returns from Economic Scenario Generators in ERM Modeling On the Use of Stock Index Returns from Economic Scenario Generators in ERM Modeling Michael G. Wacek, FCAS, CERA, MAAA Abstract The modeling of insurance company enterprise risks requires correlated forecasts

More information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 in the first Blue Book and Problems 2, 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A Final

More information

Econometrics and Economic Data

Econometrics and Economic Data Econometrics and Economic Data Chapter 1 What is a regression? By using the regression model, we can evaluate the magnitude of change in one variable due to a certain change in another variable. For example,

More information

Is a Binomial Process Bayesian?

Is a Binomial Process Bayesian? Is a Binomial Process Bayesian? Robert L. Andrews, Virginia Commonwealth University Department of Management, Richmond, VA. 23284-4000 804-828-7101, rlandrew@vcu.edu Jonathan A. Andrews, United States

More information

Chapter 8 Estimation

Chapter 8 Estimation Chapter 8 Estimation There are two important forms of statistical inference: estimation (Confidence Intervals) Hypothesis Testing Statistical Inference drawing conclusions about populations based on samples

More information

Upward Pricing Pressure formulations with logit demand and endogenous partial acquisitions

Upward Pricing Pressure formulations with logit demand and endogenous partial acquisitions Upward Pricing Pressure formulations with logit demand and endogenous partial acquisitions Panagiotis N. Fotis Michael L. Polemis y Konstantinos Eleftheriou y Abstract The aim of this paper is to derive

More information

Lesson Plan for Simulation with Spreadsheets (8/31/11 & 9/7/11)

Lesson Plan for Simulation with Spreadsheets (8/31/11 & 9/7/11) Jeremy Tejada ISE 441 - Introduction to Simulation Learning Outcomes: Lesson Plan for Simulation with Spreadsheets (8/31/11 & 9/7/11) 1. Students will be able to list and define the different components

More information

Bias in Reduced-Form Estimates of Pass-through

Bias in Reduced-Form Estimates of Pass-through Bias in Reduced-Form Estimates of Pass-through Alexander MacKay University of Chicago Marc Remer Department of Justice Nathan H. Miller Georgetown University Gloria Sheu Department of Justice February

More information

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University April 12, 2008 Abstract A model of mixed oligopoly is constructed in which a Home public firm

More information

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy Yangbo Song Economics Department, UCLA June 30, 2014 Yangbo Song UCLA June 30, 2014 1 / 31 Game theory Game theory is a methodology used to analyze strategic situations in

More information

Best Reply Behavior. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

Best Reply Behavior. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013 Best Reply Behavior Michael Peters December 27, 2013 1 Introduction So far, we have concentrated on individual optimization. This unified way of thinking about individual behavior makes it possible to

More information

GN47: Stochastic Modelling of Economic Risks in Life Insurance

GN47: Stochastic Modelling of Economic Risks in Life Insurance GN47: Stochastic Modelling of Economic Risks in Life Insurance Classification Recommended Practice MEMBERS ARE REMINDED THAT THEY MUST ALWAYS COMPLY WITH THE PROFESSIONAL CONDUCT STANDARDS (PCS) AND THAT

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Presented at the 2012 SCEA/ISPA Joint Annual Conference and Training Workshop -

Presented at the 2012 SCEA/ISPA Joint Annual Conference and Training Workshop - Applying the Pareto Principle to Distribution Assignment in Cost Risk and Uncertainty Analysis James Glenn, Computer Sciences Corporation Christian Smart, Missile Defense Agency Hetal Patel, Missile Defense

More information

PRICING CHALLENGES A CONTINUOUSLY CHANGING MARKET +34 (0) (0)

PRICING CHALLENGES A CONTINUOUSLY CHANGING MARKET +34 (0) (0) PRICING CHALLENGES IN A CONTINUOUSLY CHANGING MARKET Michaël Noack Senior consultant, ADDACTIS Ibérica michael.noack@addactis.com Ming Roest CEO, ADDACTIS Netherlands ming.roest@addactis.com +31 (0)203

More information

The Baumol-Tobin and the Tobin Mean-Variance Models of the Demand

The Baumol-Tobin and the Tobin Mean-Variance Models of the Demand Appendix 1 to chapter 19 A p p e n d i x t o c h a p t e r An Overview of the Financial System 1 The Baumol-Tobin and the Tobin Mean-Variance Models of the Demand for Money The Baumol-Tobin Model of Transactions

More information

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions? March 3, 215 Steven A. Matthews, A Technical Primer on Auction Theory I: Independent Private Values, Northwestern University CMSEMS Discussion Paper No. 196, May, 1995. This paper is posted on the course

More information

An Empirical Examination of the Electric Utilities Industry. December 19, Regulatory Induced Risk Aversion in. Contracting Behavior

An Empirical Examination of the Electric Utilities Industry. December 19, Regulatory Induced Risk Aversion in. Contracting Behavior An Empirical Examination of the Electric Utilities Industry December 19, 2011 The Puzzle Why do price-regulated firms purchase input coal through both contract Figure and 1(a): spot Contract transactions,

More information

Diversion Ratio Based Merger Analysis: Avoiding Systematic Assessment Bias

Diversion Ratio Based Merger Analysis: Avoiding Systematic Assessment Bias Diversion Ratio Based Merger Analysis: Avoiding Systematic Assessment Bias Kai-Uwe Kűhn University of Michigan 1 Introduction In many cases merger analysis heavily relies on the analysis of so-called "diversion

More information

Statistics 431 Spring 2007 P. Shaman. Preliminaries

Statistics 431 Spring 2007 P. Shaman. Preliminaries Statistics 4 Spring 007 P. Shaman The Binomial Distribution Preliminaries A binomial experiment is defined by the following conditions: A sequence of n trials is conducted, with each trial having two possible

More information

Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity *

Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity * Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity * Index Section 1: High bargaining power of the small firm Page 1 Section 2: Analysis of Multiple Small Firms and 1 Large

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks The historical data on financial asset returns show that one dollar invested in the Dow- Jones yields 6 times more than one dollar invested in U.S. Treasury bonds. The return

More information

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives Department of Mathematics MA408 Mathematics of Financial Derivatives Thursday 15th January, 2009 2pm 4pm Duration: 2 hours Attempt THREE questions MA408 Page 1 of 5 1. (a) Suppose 0 < E 1 < E 3 and E 2

More information

1 Excess burden of taxation

1 Excess burden of taxation 1 Excess burden of taxation 1. In a competitive economy without externalities (and with convex preferences and production technologies) we know from the 1. Welfare Theorem that there exists a decentralized

More information

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

1 Two Period Exchange Economy University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 502) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout # 2 1 Two Period Exchange Economy We shall start our exploration of dynamic economies with

More information

Lecture 14. Multinational Firms. 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies

Lecture 14. Multinational Firms. 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies Lecture 14 Multinational Firms 1. Review of empirical evidence 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies 3. A model with endogenous multinationals 4. Pattern of trade in goods

More information

Portfolio Construction Research by

Portfolio Construction Research by Portfolio Construction Research by Real World Case Studies in Portfolio Construction Using Robust Optimization By Anthony Renshaw, PhD Director, Applied Research July 2008 Copyright, Axioma, Inc. 2008

More information

Ideal Bootstrapping and Exact Recombination: Applications to Auction Experiments

Ideal Bootstrapping and Exact Recombination: Applications to Auction Experiments Ideal Bootstrapping and Exact Recombination: Applications to Auction Experiments Carl T. Bergstrom University of Washington, Seattle, WA Theodore C. Bergstrom University of California, Santa Barbara Rodney

More information

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior

Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior Relative Performance and Stability of Collusive Behavior Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, the University of Tokyo and Noriaki Matsushima Graduate School of Business Administration, Kobe

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

Comparative Study between Linear and Graphical Methods in Solving Optimization Problems

Comparative Study between Linear and Graphical Methods in Solving Optimization Problems Comparative Study between Linear and Graphical Methods in Solving Optimization Problems Mona M Abd El-Kareem Abstract The main target of this paper is to establish a comparative study between the performance

More information

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS 247 16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS Let us associate each state S with a numeric utility U(S), which expresses the desirability of the state A nondeterministic action A will have possible outcome states Result

More information

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies Chapter 5 Regret Minimization and Security Strategies Until now we implicitly adopted a view that a Nash equilibrium is a desirable outcome of a strategic game. In this chapter we consider two alternative

More information

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis EC 202 Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I George Symeonidis Oligopoly When only a small number of firms compete in the same market, each firm has some market power. Moreover, their interactions cannot be ignored.

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A BRAZILIAN DEBT-CRISIS MODEL. Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A BRAZILIAN DEBT-CRISIS MODEL. Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A BRAZILIAN DEBT-CRISIS MODEL Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka Working Paper 9211 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9211 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

ECO220Y, Term Test #2

ECO220Y, Term Test #2 ECO220Y, Term Test #2 December 4, 2015, 9:10 11:00 am U of T e-mail: @mail.utoronto.ca Surname (last name): Given name (first name): UTORID: (e.g. lihao8) Instructions: You have 110 minutes. Keep these

More information

Target Date Glide Paths: BALANCING PLAN SPONSOR GOALS 1

Target Date Glide Paths: BALANCING PLAN SPONSOR GOALS 1 PRICE PERSPECTIVE In-depth analysis and insights to inform your decision-making. Target Date Glide Paths: BALANCING PLAN SPONSOR GOALS 1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY We believe that target date portfolios are well

More information