Monetary Valuation of Insurance against Climate Change Risk

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Monetary Valuation of Insurance against Climate Change Risk"

Transcription

1 Monetary Valuation of Insurance against Climate Change Risk W.J.W. Botzen Institute for Environmental Studies Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam, The Netherlands and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh 1 ICREA and Institute of Environmental Science and Technology & Department of Economics and Economic History Autonomous University of Barcelona Spain jeroen.bergh@uab.es December Also affiliated with Faculty of Economics and Business Administration & Institute for Environmental Studies, Vrije Universiteit, Amsterdam. Fellow of NAKE and Tinbergen Institute.

2 Abstract Climate change is expected to increase the frequency and severity of certain natural catastrophes, such as flooding. This is likely to increase the willingness to pay (WTP) for natural catastrophe insurances, even though it is uncertain how large this effect will be. In various countries the public sector offers partial compensation of damage caused by natural catastrophes, which may reduce the need for private insurance coverage and hamper the development of insurance markets. We present a stated preference survey using choice modeling with mixed logit estimation methods to examine the effects of climate change and availability of government compensation on the demand for flood insurance by Dutch homeowners. Currently, insurance against flood damage is not offered in the Netherlands. We estimate the dependence of WTP on prior risk perceptions, actual measures of risk, risk aversion, and socio-economic characteristics. Results indicate that opportunities for a (partly) private flood insurance market exist. Keywords: Choice modeling, Flood insurance, Mixed logit, Public compensation scheme, Risk and uncertainty, The Netherlands. 1

3 1. Introduction Climate change is projected to increase the frequency and severity of weather extremes, which is likely to have considerable consequences for the insurance sector (IPCC, 2007). Several studies have examined the impact of climate change on insurance claims (e.g., Mills, 2005; Kunreuther and Michel-Kerjan, 2007; Dlugolecki, 2008). Few empirical studies have estimated the effect of climate change on the demand for natural catastrophe insurances. The willingness to pay (WTP) for insurance is expected to increase due to a rise in the probability of suffering weather-related damage, but it is uncertain how large this rise will be. Indeed, insight into the influence of climate change on WTP for disaster insurances is required so that insurers can assess the future profitability of offering coverage against damage caused by natural disasters. This is very relevant given that climate change is likely to continue in the coming decades due to committed radiative forcing by past emissions and rapid projected growth of emissions, notably in industrializing Asian economies (Pielke et al., 2007; Botzen et al., 2008a). Climate change projections for the Netherlands indicate an increase in flood risk due to more extreme precipitation and sea level rise (Middelkoop et al., 2001; Aerts et al., 2008a). Botzen and van den Bergh (2009) estimate risk premiums for flood insurance demand in the Netherlands under different climate change scenarios using prospect and rank dependent utility theories and parameters obtained from existing experimental studies. Their results indicate that rising flood probabilities from 1 in 1250 up to 1 in 550 cause WTP to increase more than the expected value of the loss. The representative agent assumption underling that study, which results in average WTP values, is relaxed here by estimating individual heterogeneity in WTP using a stated preference survey among homeowners with choice modelling and mixed logit estimation methods. A stated preference study is in order here since flood insurance is not available in the Netherlands, which implies that insurance demand cannot be analysed using data on revealed preferences. This study estimates demand for flood insurance under climate change scenarios with increasing flood probabilities. Apart from climate change, socio-economic developments, such as settlement in vulnerable areas as well as population and economic growth, are likely to increase damage of natural disasters (Bouwer et al., 2007), while investments in damage mitigation may limit rising trends in disaster losses (Botzen et al., 2

4 2009). Therefore, the influence of socio-economic developments on WTP for disaster insurance needs to be analyzed in addition to potential effects of climate change to arrive at reliable estimates of future demand. Botzen and van den Bergh (2008) examined the pros and cons of introducing flood insurance in the Netherlands. Advantages may be that insurance can be useful in efficiently spreading of risks, enhance households financial security, and provide incentives to policyholders to limit flood damage. For example, stimulating flood proofing of buildings in addition to investing in dikes may limit the occurrence of extremely large flood damages (Aerts et al., 2008b). The undertaking of these mitigation investments could for example be stimulated by providing premium discounts (Botzen et al., 2009). It was proposed to employ a public-private partnership for insuring flood risks, with a role for the government in covering extreme damages to overcome problems with correlated risks. A similar scheme has been suggested to insure weather-related risk in the USA (Kunreuther and Pauly, 2006). The absence of flood insurance in the Netherlands at this moment may be due to supply side problems, such as correlated risks, uncertainty of risks, adverse selection and moral hazard, or because of a lack of demand for insurance coverage (Freeman and Kunreuther, 2003). It will be examined here whether demand is the main impediment of the establishment of a partly private flood insurance market by estimating the level of WTP relative to the expected value of loss per policy. It has sometimes been suggested by Dutch insurers that problems with adverse selection may be severe in the case of offering flood insurance, because only individuals who live in unprotected areas with high flood risks would demand insurance (de Vries, 1998). Examining how WTP relates to actual risk derived from geographical characteristics will provide insight into potential problems with adverse selection. In addition, this study analyzes the effect of the current institutional setting, characterized by availability of government compensation of flood damage, on insurance demand. The Dutch government can grant partly compensation of damage caused by large-scale floods via the Calamities and Compensation Act (WTS), as is also the situation in several other countries (Crichton, 2008). Decisions about granting relief and its extent are a political decision. Experiences with flood damage in 1993 and

5 resulted in considerable relief payments via the WTS. As a consequence, households may expect that the government will compensate future flood damage unconditional on the risk they take. This may reduce the desirability of private insurance, which is often referred to as crowding out (Harrington, 2000). The main objectives of this valuation study are fourfold. First, it will estimate WTP for flood insurance in the Netherlands under the current institutional setting and climate conditions. This is of practical interest for insurers and the government in evaluating whether demand for flood insurance will be sufficiently high to make a private market viable. Second, the role of expectations about government compensation of disaster damage will be analyzed by comparing WTP with and without relief of flood damage by the government. This can aid the government in assessing what conditions need to be created to stimulate, or at least not hamper, the emergence of a market for flood insurance. Third, the effects of climate change and socio-economic developments on the demand for flood insurance will be assessed. This is accomplished by eliciting insurance demand under different scenarios of increased flood probabilities due to climate change and varying levels of expected flood damage. This provides insights into the risk characteristics of individuals faced with climate change risk, which allows for accurately prediction of behavioral responses to risk related to climate change and flooding. 2 Fourth, bid functions will be estimated to identify factors behind WTP using as explanatory variables perceptions of flood risk, actual measures of flood risk based on geographical characteristics, estimates of individual risk aversion, actual insurance purchase behavior, and socio-economic characteristics. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 explains the setup of the survey and its implementation. Section 3 explains the design of the choice experiment and the estimation methods. Section 4 provides the estimation results of logit and mixed logit models of the choice experiment. Section 5 concludes. 2. Explanation of the questionnaires 2.1. The commodity valued 2 Care must be taken in transferring the results to other contexts than insurance since it has been shown that in eliciting risk attitudes the insurance context may induce extra risk aversion (e.g., Hershey et al., 1982). 4

6 WTP for flood insurance is elicited by means of a choice experiment. The choice experiment values insurance with different levels of coverage in situations with varying flood probabilities and damages caused by river flooding on both homes and contents. Careful consideration is given to communicate these small flood probabilities in between the current safety standard of 1 in 1250 and increases in probabilities up to 1 in 100 due to climate change, as will be elaborated upon below Communicating small probabilities In general, individuals have difficulties to understand the likelihood of low-probability events and differences in probabilities (Viscusi, 1998). A large literature exists on valuation of small risk using surveys (Hammitt and Graham, 1999), especially on estimating the value of a statistical life by eliciting WTP for reductions in small health or accident risks (Vassanadumrongdee and Matsuoka, 2005; Alberini et al., 2004, 2006, 2007; Bhattacharya et al., 2007; Van Houtven, 2008). Risk ladders and square grids are commonly used as visual aids to improve respondents understanding of small probabilities and changes in probabilities. A risk ladder shows the current or baseline risk on a probability scale together with other risks that the respondent commonly faces (e.g., Hammitt, 1990; Vassanadumrongdee and Matsuoka, 2005). Changes in risk can be communicated by depicting both the baseline and the new probability on the risk ladder, and using an arrow to indicate the change in the probability. Such a risk ladder illustrates the size of the change and also how the new probability compares with the other risks. Square grids are often in the order of 10,000 or 100,000 squares on which risks are represented using colored squares (e.g., Jones-Lee et al., 1985; Krupnick et al., 2001; Alberini et al., 2004; Bhattacharya et al., 2007). Changes in probabilities can be presented on such a grid by increasing or decreasing the number of randomly filled squares. Risk ladders and square grids are likely to be suitable risk communication devices for this study. During the pilots of the survey we tested which device respondents perceive as the clearest and most useful Pre-tests 5

7 During the design of the survey, subsequent versions of the questionnaire were reviewed by experienced stated choice practitioners, economists, natural scientists, water management experts, and psychologists. After incorporating their comments, three pretests of the questionnaire were conducted between August and October 2007, using faceto-face interviews. Four trained and carefully instructed and supervised interviewers (2 male and 2 female) interviewed 88 households. Particular attention was paid to the comprehension of flood probabilities and the choice experiment. Different risk communication devices were tested, such as risk ladders, 10,000 square grids on which baseline risk and changes in risk are represented using colored squares, and a variety of textual explanations. The results indicated that the square grids were generally regarded as difficult and too abstract so that they are omitted from the final survey. The risk ladders were perceived as providing very clear and useful information. Textual comparisons of flood risks for different kinds of households with other risks, such as fire risk, have been tested, since they may increase comprehension as shown by Kunreuther et al. (2001). However, as these comparisons were not regarded to add much extra information to the risk ladders, they are excluded. We have tested a labeled experiment (one label per insurance type with labelspecific attributes) consisting of insurance options that cover flood damage on home contents, housing, both, and no insurance. The resulting choice experiment turned out to be overly complex. Instead, an experiment with generic (unlabeled) alternatives that values an insurance covering both damage on home contents and buildings was used in the final pre-tests and survey. This turned out to be easier for respondents. Both yearly and monthly premiums were provided in the choice experiment and their levels were derived from answers to open-ended WTP questions. A fourth and final pre-test was conducted to test the on-line implementation of the questionnaire, which resulted in minor adjustments in layout The structure of the questionnaires A description of the survey and an overview of the questions is given in Botzen et al. (2008b). The questionnaire opens with questions about the experience of the respondent with flooding, flood damage and evacuation because of flood threats and knowledge 6

8 about the causes of flooding. In addition, several questions address the perception of flood risks using both qualitative and quantitative answer categories. The answers to these risk perception questions are discussed in detail in Botzen et al. (2008c). These questions familiarize the respondents with flood probabilities. The assessed perceptions may be important in decision making under risk as several studies suggest (Viscusi, 1989) and serve as explanatory variables. Moreover, questions are included about risk aversion and actual insurance purchases. Whereas the previous questions were identical in all versions of the questionnaire, some subsequent explanations differ, giving rise to two versions. In version 1 the current regulation for compensating flood damage by the government is explained. In short, this states that the government may partly compensate damage caused by major floods, while this compensation is not granted for small flooding events. The uncertainty about receiving relief is mentioned and several recent examples of floods where damage has been partly compensated are given. The other version describes a scenario explaining that relief of flood damage by the government will no longer be granted, but that it is possible to purchase insurance coverage instead. Next, a short text is included about flood probabilities in all versions. It is explained why flood probabilities differ across regions, providing a comparison of risks in a textual context (see Hsee et al., 1999) and the idea of expressing probabilities in terms of return periods or frequencies is mentioned. In addition, estimated flood probabilities of an area not protected by dikes (1 in 100) are compared with flood probabilities of urban areas that are protected by dikes (1 in 1250). This explanation precedes our main risk communication device, which is a risk ladder on which flood risks are compared with other insurable risks commonly faced by Dutch citizens (see appendix A). All adverse events are expressed as yearly probabilities. Furthermore, risk ladders are shown that illustrate an increase in the flood probability from the current safety standard of 1 in 1250 to 1 in 600 and 1 in 400 as a result of climate change. Three contingent valuation questions with payment cards that elicit WTP for flood insurance under flood probabilities of 1 in 1250, 1 in 600 and 1 in 400 are included before the choice experiment. These changes in risk are communicated by stating the probability and frequency of the new risk, as well as the proportional changes relative to the baseline 7

9 probability ( doubled or tripled ) in order to facilitate comprehension (e.g., McDaniels, 1992). The results of these questions are not discussed in detail in this paper, which focuses on the valuation of flood insurance with a choice experiment. The choice experiment values flood insurance with varying coverage levels in situations with different flood probabilities and expected damages (see appendix B for an attribute and level overview). An unlabelled experiment is used where respondents choose between insurance Situation A, Situation B or an opt out (see appendix B). It is explained that flood probabilities differ due to the uncertain effect of climate change on flood risk and flood damage relates to the severity of the flood. Individuals are instructed to choose the opt out in case they do not want insurance or find the insurance in both situations unattractive. The experiment starts with an example practice choice card that is carefully explained in the text. Subsequently, respondents are asked their preferences at three random choice cards. Finally, a fixed card with a dominant option is shown to identify respondents who have trouble to understand the experiment. Follow-up questions ask for the main reasoning behind the choices made and the perceived difficulty of the experiment. In the valuation questions respondents are asked to consider their budget constraint to avoid hypothetical bias. The questionnaire concludes with the usual socio-demographic questions Administration of the survey and sample characteristics The survey was administered over the Internet using Sawtooth CBC software. 3 This computer based method has the advantage that follow-up questions can be automated, high quality graphics can be included, a large underlying design for the choice model can be applied, interviewer effects can be avoided, and a geographically spread sample can be obtained at relatively low costs. Respondents were selected from the consumer panel of Multiscope and contacted by . 4 The sample consists of random draws of panel members that live in the river delta in the Netherlands with a common flood probability standard of 1 in The survey starts with a selection question and only respondents who own a house are allowed to continue. Renters are not included in the sample because 3 See 4 For more information see 8

10 the insurance valued covers damage on both home contents and buildings. For this reason, the levels of the damage and premium attributes in the choice experiment are representative for homeowners only. A total of 1140 respondents filled out the questionnaire while 982 observations remain after excluding respondents who live in flats higher than the first floor and who live outside the sample area. Our sample has slightly more male (58%) than female respondents. On average respondents are 46 years old. The proportion of respondents who are older than 60 years is about 11%, which is smaller than is the case in the actual Dutch population. Fewer older individuals are represented in the Internet sample, because they are generally less active on the Internet than younger people. We do not regard this as troublesome in this application since the increased flood risk posed by climate change is less applicable to older respondents since it will take several decades for the altered risk to become relevant. The median and average after-tax household income is the answer category between 2501 and 3000 per month, which is close to the average after-tax income of a household that owns a house in the Netherlands, namely 3025 per month (Statistics Netherlands, 2008). 3. Experimental design and estimation method 3.1. The experimental design The choice experiment entails a choice between two situations in which flood insurance is available with as attributes the flood probability, expected damage, the percentage of coverage, and the premium. An opt out option is included for respondents who do not want the insurance. Appendix B shows an example choice card and an overview of the levels of the attributes included in the experiment. We chose 75% as the lowest coverage level in our choice experiment since this equals the maximum allowed deductible in catastrophe insurance markets in several states of the USA (Kunreuther et al., 2008). The risk (probability and damage) is presented as scenarios that are exogenous to the individual. The expected flood damage of 70,000 is an estimate of the current average flood damage per household as has been computed as in Botzen and van den Bergh (2009), while the other two levels of the experiment ( 40,000 and 120,000) can be regarded as minimum and maximum estimates. The respondents indicate whether they 9

11 prefer to buy insurance and if yes which insurance policy they favour. Other studies have valued insurance in situations with varying risk using choice experiments. For example, Schneider and Zweifel (2004) examine demand for nuclear risk insurance in Switzerland using damage, coverage, and price as insurance attributes. The experiment used in this study tries to assess the factors of influence on the insurance decision. In particular, individuals decide whether to buy a certain degree of insurance coverage against a risk -probability and damage- for a certain price (premium). An advantage of the choice experiment over the contingent valuation method is that it provides more information about the factors that influence demand for flood insurance. The choice experiment allows for simultaneously examining effects of varying flood probabilities, expected damages, coverage levels, and premiums on choices for insurance. Furthermore, the experiment is closer to reality where respondents can choose between different insurance options without a need to state a maximum WTP amount, which may result in smaller biases. A statistically efficient design was used as it contributes to maximum accuracy of coefficient estimates (i.e. low standard errors) of the attributes (Ferrini and Scarpa, 2007). In total, 250 versions of the design have been generated to which respondents were randomly assigned. 5 This means that many combinations of the levels of the attributes appear in the experiment. The generated design has been checked for strictly dominant choices, which were then excluded from the final design. Each respondent answered three random choice cards. After removing protest responses, this resulted in a total of 2751 completed choices Estimation methods Choice models are based on the random utility model. In this model, the probability p ni of an individual n choosing alternative i is set equal to the probability that the utility of 5 The design has been generated by means of the software Sawtooth CBC using the efficient design module ( Balanced Overlap ). 6 In total 65 protesters were excluded. Such responses are motivated by individuals saying that they do not believe that flood damage is not already covered, do not believe or accept the stated flood probability, do not believe or accept the change in the flood probability, or do not believe that offering flood insurance is possible. In version 2 a protest response may result from individuals not accepting the abolishment of government compensation. 10

12 alternative i is greater than or equal to the utility associated with an alternative j for every alternative in the choice set (j = 1 J). This can be formalized as p ni = prob[( V + ε ) ( V + ε ) j j = 1,..., J; i j] (1) ni ni nj nj where V ni and ε ni are the observed and unobserved components of individual n s utility associated with alternative i, respectively. Different assumptions about the distribution of ε ni result in different choice models. The logit model The logit model is the most commonly used choice model. It is derived under the assumption that ε ni is iid extreme value distributed for all i. This means that the unobserved components of utility are independently and identically distributed across alternatives. Therefore, the unobserved factors are uncorrelated over alternatives and have the same variance for all alternatives. This independence assumption also applies to sequential choices made over time. The logit probability is given by the formula (McFadden, 1974) p ni = βxni e βx e j nj (2) The mixed logit model The independence assumption within the logit model is restrictive, because unobserved characteristics associated with alternatives in a choice situation may be similar. Moreover, unobserved factors that affect the choice in one choice situation (or choice card) may affect the choice in a subsequent choice situation, which induces dependence among choices over rime. The more general mixed logit model is very flexible and can overcome these problems by allowing for random taste variation, unrestricted substitution patterns and correlation in unobserved characteristics over different choice situations (McFadden and Train, 2000). Therefore, the mixed logit model may be better in describing choice behavior than logit (Rieskamp et al., 2006). The mixed logit probability is (Train, 2003) 11

13 p T βxnit e = = f ( β dβ βx t 1 njt e j ni ) Formula (3) shows that the mixed logit probability is a weighted average of the logit representation (4) evaluated at different values of β with weights given by the density f(β). The panel data structure is presented by the time subscript t and is explicitly modeled since respondents were asked to answer three sequential choice cards (so that T=3). Coefficients can be specified as random in the mixed logit model, meaning that they vary over decision makers. In this case, the model estimates the mean coefficients and standard deviations of the random parameters, which represent unobserved heterogeneity in preferences. The parameters are estimated using maximum simulated likelihood with Monte Carlo integration using 200 Halton draws, which are generally found to produce more precise results than random draws (e.g., Bhat, 2001). (3) Coding of the explanatory variables A detailed explanation of the explanatory variables and their descriptive statistics are given in appendix C. Different methods of coding categorical variables have been applied. Dummy variables are used for several categorical variables. Continuous variables are created from categorical variables that represent monetary classes, such as the value of the house as well as home contents (e.g., Blumenschein et al., 2008). A variable representing the total value of property is created by adding the home contents and house values. Ordinal qualitative variables 7, which are partitioned into J intervals, can be included using J-1 dummies or can be transformed into values on the real axis using an approach proposed by Terza (1986). An advantage of the dummy approach is that the interpretation of the coefficients is straightforward, but many variables are needed in case J is large. In this case, the transformation of Terza (1986) can result in gains in efficiency and bias. For this reason the latter approach has been applied in several studies (e.g., van Praag et al., The transformation (see appendix D) is used 7 These variables are characterized by a continuous unobservable ordinal latent index and each interval is ranked (1 through J) in increasing order according to its supremum (Terza, 1986). 12

14 here for variables with a large number of categories, which are the perceived risk of suffering flood damage and the risk seeking index. 4. Estimation results of the choice models for flood insurance demand The choice experiment is unlabelled, which implies that there is no reason to expect a general preference for one of the two situations with flood insurance shown to respondents. This is supported by the data, since both situations with insurance (A and B) were chosen about 19% of the time each, while the opt out or no insurance was chosen 62% of the time. The choice experiment was followed by a question that asks how difficult it was for respondents to make a choice, with the answer options very easy, easy, neutral, difficult, and very difficult. Only 2.7% of the respondents indicated that the choice experiment was very difficult and 14% indicated that it was difficult. The last choice card included a dominant option to check understanding of the experiment by respondents. The dominant option was chosen by only 2% of the respondents. Based on these answers and the pilot of the survey we are confident that the experiment was not too difficult for the large majority of respondents, despite the inclusion of the probability attribute and the unfamiliarity of Dutch homeowners with buying flood insurance in practice Results of a model for insurance demand without heterogeneity It is common practice in studies that value insurance coverage or health risk to use a general utility function in the retained attributes and not anchor the utility function in expected utility theory (e.g., Schneider and Zweifel, 2004; Goldberg and Roosen, 2007). A reason for this is that often expected utility theory provides a poor description of individual choices under risk (Camerer, 1998). Common violations of expected utility theory relevant to the insurance application at hand are that individuals may ignore low probabilities or weigh them in a non-linear fashion (Slovic et al., 1977; Schmeidler, 1989; Tversky and Kahneman, 1992; Mason et al., 2005). In addition, it is often found in insurance markets that individuals place a larger value on the level of coverage than predicted by expected utility theory (Doherty and Eeckhoudt, 1995). The following utility specification is used for the model that includes only the attributes of the experiment: 13

15 U Insurance = β1 * probability low + β 2 * probability middle + β 3 * probability high + β * damage + β * coverage + β * price U 4 No insuran ce β 8 * 6 7 = constant (4) The utility of having insurance is dependent on the expected flood damage, the probability of flooding, insurance coverage, and price. 8 The parameters of the attributes are the same for both scenarios because the experiment is unlabelled, i.e. there is no a priori reason to expect that the attributes have a different effect on the utility in the generic scenarios A or B. The utility of the option without insurance is modeled with a constant term. The three probability variables are dummy variables representing the low (1/600), middle (1/400) and high (1/100) flood probability. The current flood probability (1/1250) is excluded so that the coefficients β 2, β 3, and β 4 measure the effect relative to having insurance under the current flood probability. Using dummies for the probability variable allows us to examine non-linear effects without restricting the functional form of this non-linearity. Subsequently, an adequate functional form for a continuous probability variable can be derived from the coefficient estimates of the dummy variables. The two left columns of Table 1 show the estimation results (equation 4). The pseudo R 2 is 0.27, which indicates a good fit for this type of models. The coefficients of all attributes are statistically significant at the 1% level and of the expected sign. In particular, the utility of flood insurance increases with flood risk (probability and damage) and coverage level, while it decreases with price. The dummy variables of the flood probability indicate a monotonic and non-linear increase of utility when the probability rises. This relation is concave, which means that utility and WTP increase less than proportional with a decreasing slope in response to a probability increase. The specification with the probability variables coded as dummy variables provided useful insights about the non-linear shape of the relation between utility of insurance and flood probability. A disadvantage of the dummy specification is that it is 8 Individuals may value the insurance according to the monetary payoff (damage*coverage), as appeared to be the case in a choice experiment of nuclear risk insurance by Schneider and Zweifel (2004). This is examined by including an interaction between the coverage and damage attribute in equation 4. The coefficient of this interaction term is insignificant. Furthermore, non-linearity in the reaction to damage has been estimated by including damage 2 as explanatory variable in equation 4. The non-linear reaction is insignificant. It should be noted that coverage cannot be modeled in a non-linear fashion, since the choice experiment included no more than two levels of this attribute (75% and 100%) in order to reduce complexity of the choice decision for respondents. 14

16 only possible to evaluate insurance demand for the flood probability levels captured by the dummies, that is 1/600, 1/400, and 1/100, and not for the whole range of probabilities in between 1/1250 and 1/100. The flood probability is a continuous variable (between 0 and 1) and this property can be exploited by including it as a single variable in the utility specification. The non-linear relation between probability and utility of flood insurance observed in equation 4 can be approximated by specifying the utility function dependent on the square root of the probability. 9 This model can be written as: = β 1 * ( SQRT ( probability)) + β 2 * damage + β3 * coverage + β 4 * price = constant (5) U Insurance U No insuran ce β 5 * The results of this more parsimonious model (5) are shown in the two right columns of Table 1. Overall, results are very similar to the model (4), apart from the relation with the flood probability that is now captured by a single variable instead of the three dummies. Table 1. Results of logit models without heterogeneity Logit model (equation 4) Logit model (equation 5) Variable Coefficient Wald-statistic Coefficient Wald-statistic Flood probability low *** 2.63 n.a. n.a. Flood probability middle *** 3.97 n.a. n.a. Flood probability high *** 7.43 n.a. n.a. SQRT flood probability n.a. n.a *** 7.50 Flood damage *** *** 3.33 Insurance coverage *** *** 3.62 Insurance premium *** *** Constant *** *** 5.67 Number of observations Log likelihood Pseudo R Notes. One, two and three stars (*) indicate respectively significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level and n.a. stands for not applicable. Estimations are performed with Limdeb software. 9 Non-linearity of continuous variables in choice experiments is often modeled by including a squared term of the variable in addition to its level. Main results are rather similar if the squared of the flood probability and the flood probability level are included instead of the square root of the probability (equation 5) or the dummies (equation 4). The coefficient of the level is significant and positive and the coefficient of the squared term is negative and significant. An unrealistic characteristic of such a specification in this application is that the utility of insurance declines if the probability rises for very large probabilities. We further experimented with modeling the probability variable with the logarithm of the probability. Overall results are rather similar again. Specification 5 is preferred as it stays close to the results of specification 4. 15

17 4.2. Results of a model for insurance demand with observed and unobserved heterogeneity Insights into individual heterogeneity in flood insurance demand are of interest to insurers for two main reasons. First, this provides information about what groups of costumers insurers could target. Second, it is very useful to know how demand for flood insurance relates to risk characteristics of individuals to determine pricing strategies, i.e. premium differentiation, and to assess potential problems with adverse selection. Adverse selection could hamper the development of flood insurance markets if mainly high risk individuals who live in unprotected areas are interested in purchasing insurance and insurers are unable to adequately distinguish low from high risk customers and charge the latter a higher (risk based) premium. Examining heterogeneity further provides relevant insights into risk characteristics of individuals faced with low-probability, high-impact climate risk. Observed heterogeneity in demand for flood insurance is examined by including explanatory variables in the logit model (5) about individual risk perceptions, experiences with flooding, individual risk aversion, and geographic as well as socio-economic characteristics. In addition, a variable is included about the availability of compensation of flood damage via the government to estimate differences in insurance demand between the two questionnaire versions. Unobserved heterogeneity is examined by specifying the coefficient of the probability variable as random using a mixed logit model, because the behavioral economics literature indicates that individuals can react in very different ways to probabilistic information. Explanatory variables representing personal characteristics that are constant across the choice alternatives can be included in two ways in our model. Such variables are either interacted with the attributes that vary in the alternatives with flood insurance or they are interacted with the constant of the no insurance alternative in equation 5. These variables can only be included in this manner since random utility models measure differences in utility between alternatives (equation 1). In this application, it is estimated whether the utility of insurance coverage is related to actual risk faced by the respondent by including an interaction with the coverage attribute and a variable representing individuals who live close to a main river and are more likely to suffer large flood 16

18 damage. Moreover, an interaction variable between price and a variable representing the high-income category is included to test for diminishing marginal utility in income. Other explanatory variables are included in the utility specification of the alternative without insurance so that they capture the utility difference between the insurance alternatives versus no insurance. This results in the following model: U Insurance = β * SQRT( probability) + β * damage + β * coverage + β * (coverage* close to main river) + β * price + β *( price* high income) U No insurance = β 7 * constant + β k * xn (6) where x n represents variables for availability of government relief, individual perceptions about the flood probability and damage, experience with floods, insurance purchases, risk aversion, (other) geographical characteristics, and socio-economic characteristics. The mixed logit model includes a random parameter for the square root of the flood probability to capture unobserved individual heterogeneity in the response to probability. A triangular distribution is specified for the coefficient of probability with the standard deviation set equal to the mean value of the coefficient. This distribution is particularly useful for two reasons. First, it is behaviorally plausible since coefficients are positive for all individuals, meaning that WTP for insurance increases for all individuals if the probability of suffering damage rises. Second, it prevents problems with the long tail of the lognormal distribution, which has been applied in some studies and may cause unrealistically large WTP estimates (Hensher and Greene, 2003). We note that similar results are obtained with specifications with normal and triangular distributions with various constraints on the variance, which indicates robustness of our findings. Table 2 below provides the estimation results of the logit and a mixed logit model of equation (6). The fit of the model improves considerably compared with model (5) without heterogeneity as reflected by the increase in log likelihood and pseudo R 2. The standard deviation of the random coefficient is statistically significant. This indicates that individual preference heterogeneity exists in the coefficient of the probability attribute around the mean coefficient and that the mixed logit specification is preferred to logit. The log likelihood increases from 2061 for the logit model to 2027 for the mixed logit, which confirms that the logit specification can be rejected based on the likelihood ratio test with χ 2 = 34 and 1 degree of freedom (McFadden and Train, 2000). The overall fit

19 of the mixed logit model is very good as the pseudo R 2 statistic of 0.33 indicates (see appendix D), which is similar to a linear R 2 of approximately 0.7 (Domencich and McFadden, 1975; Louviere et al., 2000). The attributes of the choice experiment determine the utility of having insurance (U Insurance in equation 6) so that a positive coefficient indicates a positive relation between the attribute and the value placed on flood insurance. The coefficients of the attributes are statistically significant and have the expected sign: the utility of insurance increases with flood probability and damage as well as coverage level, while it decreases with the insurance premium. The coefficient of the probability variable is about 80% larger in the mixed logit specification than in the logit specification. This indicates that the mean relation between the utility of insurance and the flood probability is considerably underestimated if the coefficient is mistakenly specified as fixed instead of random. Coefficients of other variables are very similar between the logit and mixed models. The interaction variable of insurance coverage and individuals living close to a main river has a positive and significant coefficient, which implies that high-risk individuals place a larger value on flood insurance coverage than individuals who face a lower flood risk. The interaction variable between the insurance premium and the high-income category is significant and positive. High-income individuals worry less about the price and have a higher WTP for flood insurance as can be expected from consumer theory. It is noted that the other explanatory variables determine the utility of having no insurance (U No insurance in equation 6) so that a positive coefficient indicates a negative relation between the variable and the value placed on flood insurance. Table 2 shows that the probability of choosing for insurance is lower if compensation of flood damage by the government is available, implying that government relief crowds out demand for private insurance. Perceptions of the risk of flooding are important determinants in the choice for flood insurance. In particular, the probability of choosing for flood insurance is positively related to a respondent s perceptions that climate change increases flood risk, the expected probability of flooding and the expected flood damage. The probability of choosing for flood insurance is lower if individuals expect that their flood risk is lower than an average resident and if it is expected that the return period of flooding equals zero. A variable that represents the expected return period of flooding of individuals who 18

20 stated a non-zero return period is of the expected sign but not significant. Respondents who indicate causes of flooding that are beyond their or water managers direct control, such as extreme weather events or climate change, are less likely to buy insurance. This is consistent with studies showing that individuals have lower flood risk perceptions if they regard floods as natural phenomena (e.g., Brilly and Polic, 2005). Individuals who have experienced a flood and have been evacuated for a threat of flooding are more likely to demand flood insurance. This is consistent with findings that individuals with a personal experience of a risk have a higher risk perception and are more likely to purchase insurance (e.g., Michel-Kerjan and Kousky, 2008). Actual insurance purchases of the individual may be a good indicator of risk aversion since they represent revealed preferences for financial protection. An insurance index has been derived from eleven potential insurance purchases of the respondent (see Table C1 in appendix C). 10 Results indicate that individuals with many actual insurance purchases are also more likely to purchase flood insurance. A risk seeking index has been derived by asking individuals how well they correspond to a risk averse individual who prefers to be well insured. The probability of buying insurance relates to this risk seeking index in the expected way, i.e. more risk seeking individuals are less likely to insure. Actual flood risks in the Netherlands are strongly related to geographic characteristics and the presence of dike infrastructure (Aerts et al., 2008a). Such geographical characteristics are included as explanatory variables in our insurance demand model. These data are obtained with the use of Geographical Information Systems (GIS) maps, which are related to the respondent s zip codes. 11 A variable has been constructed that represents the difference between the elevation of the zip code area of the individual and the height of the potential water level of a flood. 12 This variable is an indicator of the height of the water level at the individual s home once a flood occurs. 10 It is not possible to include separate variables for these actual insurance purchases in the model because they are highly correlated. These correlations arise because risk averse individuals are more likely to purchase many insurance policies. Another advantage of including insurance purchases as a single variable is that this saves on degrees of freedom. 11 This data is based on zip code numbers and letters for 950 respondents, which is highly accurate because the GIS data can be obtained on street level. The data for 32 respondents are based on zip code numbers only because letters are incomplete. 12 Adjustments have been made for respondents who live in flats on the first floor by adding 2.5 meter to the height of the area. 19

21 The positive coefficient indicates that the higher the house is situated above potential water level, the less likely will the individual purchase flood insurance. Moreover, respondents in rural areas are more likely to demand flood insurance. It is also examined whether respondents who live in areas unprotected by dikes have a larger demand for flood insurance. A variable that represents respondents living in unprotected areas is statistically insignificant, which suggests that demand for flood insurance is not higher in these high-risk areas. Statistical analyses of the variables indicating individual risk perceptions show that individuals in unprotected areas do not have higher perceptions of flood risk than individuals who live in protected areas (Botzen et al., 2008c). This suggests minor problems with averse selection if flood insurance markets were to emerge. The socio-economic variables indicate that the probability of choosing for flood insurance relates negatively to being female and age of the respondent. It has often been observed that older individuals have a lower risk perception and purchase less insurance. However, the opposite effect is usually found for females, which is contrary to our results (Slovic, 2000). A possible explanation is that females have less monetary resources to spend on insurance since being female correlates negatively to reported values of income and value of home contents and homes in our data. It may further be that females have a lower perception of flood risk and therefore demand less flood insurance. 13 Individuals with a higher value of property are more likely to self-insure and demand less flood insurance. Households with more children and individuals with a high education value flood insurance more than smaller families and individuals with a low education. 13 We find that relations between gender and perceptions of the probability of flooding are insignificant, while a negative and significant relation exists between being female and the expected flood damage variable (Botzen et al., 2008c). 20

22 Table 2. Estimation results of the choice experiment Logit model Mixed logit Variable Coefficient Wald-statistic Coefficient Wald-statistic Attributes and interactions (U Insurance): Flood probability *** *** Flood damage *** *** 3.72 Insurance coverage ** ** 2.36 Insurance coverage * Close to main river *** *** 2.59 Insurance premium *** *** Insurance premium * High income *** *** 3.60 Government compensation (U No insurance): Government relief of damage is available *** *** 4.27 Risk perception and experience (U No insurance): Climate change causes higher flood risk *** *** Risk of suffering flood damage *** *** Lower flood risk than average resident *** *** 3.83 Expected flood damage *** *** Zero expected return period flood *** *** 4.12 Return period flood Flooding is exogenous to human control *** *** 3.70 Experience with flooding and evacuation *** *** Individual risk aversion (U No insurance): Insurance purchase index ** ** Risk seeking index *** *** 4.35 Geographical characteristics (U No insurance): Elevation of house relative to water level ** ** 1.93 Area is not protected by dikes Rural area *** *** Socio economic characteristics (U No insurance): Age ** ** 1.95 Female *** *** 3.23 Value of property *** *** 3.91 Children *** *** University degree *** *** Standard deviation flood probability n.a. n.a *** Constant * *** 2.70 Number of observations Log likelihood Pseudo R Notes. One, two and three stars (*) indicate respectively significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level and n.a. stands for not applicable. Estimations are performed with Limdeb software. 21

Evaluation of influential factors in the choice of micro-generation solar devices

Evaluation of influential factors in the choice of micro-generation solar devices Evaluation of influential factors in the choice of micro-generation solar devices by Mehrshad Radmehr, PhD in Energy Economics, Newcastle University, Email: m.radmehr@ncl.ac.uk Abstract This paper explores

More information

Evaluation of influential factors in the choice of micro-generation solar devices: a case study in Cyprus

Evaluation of influential factors in the choice of micro-generation solar devices: a case study in Cyprus Evaluation of influential factors in the choice of micro-generation solar devices: a case study in Cyprus Mehrshad Radmehr, PhD, Newcastle University 33 rd USAEE/IAEE Conference, Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania

More information

Individual Flood Preparedness Decisions During Hurricane Sandy in New York City By prof.dr. Wouter Botzen

Individual Flood Preparedness Decisions During Hurricane Sandy in New York City By prof.dr. Wouter Botzen Individual Flood Preparedness Decisions During Hurricane Sandy in New York City By prof.dr. Wouter Botzen Agenda 1. Context: Individual adaptation measures in flood risk management 2. Flood risk management

More information

Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity

Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity Anders Karlsson and Lars Nordén 1 Department of Corporate Finance, School of Business, Stockholm University, S-106 91 Stockholm, Sweden Abstract

More information

PRE CONFERENCE WORKSHOP 3

PRE CONFERENCE WORKSHOP 3 PRE CONFERENCE WORKSHOP 3 Stress testing operational risk for capital planning and capital adequacy PART 2: Monday, March 18th, 2013, New York Presenter: Alexander Cavallo, NORTHERN TRUST 1 Disclaimer

More information

Divergence between individual perceptions and objective indicators of tail risks: Evidence from floodplain residents in New York City

Divergence between individual perceptions and objective indicators of tail risks: Evidence from floodplain residents in New York City Judgment and Decision Making, Vol. 10, No. 4, July 2015, pp. 365 385 Divergence between individual perceptions and objective indicators of tail risks: Evidence from floodplain residents in New York City

More information

the display, exploration and transformation of the data are demonstrated and biases typically encountered are highlighted.

the display, exploration and transformation of the data are demonstrated and biases typically encountered are highlighted. 1 Insurance data Generalized linear modeling is a methodology for modeling relationships between variables. It generalizes the classical normal linear model, by relaxing some of its restrictive assumptions,

More information

Estimating Mixed Logit Models with Large Choice Sets. Roger H. von Haefen, NC State & NBER Adam Domanski, NOAA July 2013

Estimating Mixed Logit Models with Large Choice Sets. Roger H. von Haefen, NC State & NBER Adam Domanski, NOAA July 2013 Estimating Mixed Logit Models with Large Choice Sets Roger H. von Haefen, NC State & NBER Adam Domanski, NOAA July 2013 Motivation Bayer et al. (JPE, 2007) Sorting modeling / housing choice 250,000 individuals

More information

Data Appendix. A.1. The 2007 survey

Data Appendix. A.1. The 2007 survey Data Appendix A.1. The 2007 survey The survey data used draw on a sample of Italian clients of a large Italian bank. The survey was conducted between June and September 2007 and elicited detailed financial

More information

Internet Appendix. The survey data relies on a sample of Italian clients of a large Italian bank. The survey,

Internet Appendix. The survey data relies on a sample of Italian clients of a large Italian bank. The survey, Internet Appendix A1. The 2007 survey The survey data relies on a sample of Italian clients of a large Italian bank. The survey, conducted between June and September 2007, provides detailed financial and

More information

Choice Probabilities. Logit Choice Probabilities Derivation. Choice Probabilities. Basic Econometrics in Transportation.

Choice Probabilities. Logit Choice Probabilities Derivation. Choice Probabilities. Basic Econometrics in Transportation. 1/31 Choice Probabilities Basic Econometrics in Transportation Logit Models Amir Samimi Civil Engineering Department Sharif University of Technology Primary Source: Discrete Choice Methods with Simulation

More information

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* Sónia Costa** Luísa Farinha** 133 Abstract The analysis of the Portuguese households

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS

CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS This chapter presents the results of the study and its analysis in order to meet the objectives. These results confirm the presence and impact of the biases taken into consideration,

More information

Modelling risk adaptation and mitigation behaviour under different climate change scenarios

Modelling risk adaptation and mitigation behaviour under different climate change scenarios Climatic Change (2013) 117:11 29 DOI 10.1007/s10584-012-0534-1 Modelling risk adaptation and mitigation behaviour under different climate change scenarios Roy Brouwer & Marije Schaafsma Received: 24 November

More information

Valuing Environmental Impacts: Practical Guidelines for the Use of Value Transfer in Policy and Project Appraisal

Valuing Environmental Impacts: Practical Guidelines for the Use of Value Transfer in Policy and Project Appraisal Valuing Environmental Impacts: Practical Guidelines for the Use of Value Transfer in Policy and Project Appraisal Annex 3 Glossary of Econometric Terminology Submitted to Department for Environment, Food

More information

Mixed Logit or Random Parameter Logit Model

Mixed Logit or Random Parameter Logit Model Mixed Logit or Random Parameter Logit Model Mixed Logit Model Very flexible model that can approximate any random utility model. This model when compared to standard logit model overcomes the Taste variation

More information

Analyzing the Determinants of Project Success: A Probit Regression Approach

Analyzing the Determinants of Project Success: A Probit Regression Approach 2016 Annual Evaluation Review, Linked Document D 1 Analyzing the Determinants of Project Success: A Probit Regression Approach 1. This regression analysis aims to ascertain the factors that determine development

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings Upjohn Institute Policy Papers Upjohn Research home page 2011 The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings Leslie A. Muller Hope College

More information

Stochastic Analysis Of Long Term Multiple-Decrement Contracts

Stochastic Analysis Of Long Term Multiple-Decrement Contracts Stochastic Analysis Of Long Term Multiple-Decrement Contracts Matthew Clark, FSA, MAAA and Chad Runchey, FSA, MAAA Ernst & Young LLP January 2008 Table of Contents Executive Summary...3 Introduction...6

More information

Adoption of Individual Flood Damage Mitigation Measures in New York City: An Extension of Protection Motivation Theory

Adoption of Individual Flood Damage Mitigation Measures in New York City: An Extension of Protection Motivation Theory Adoption of Individual Flood Damage Mitigation Measures in New York City: An Extension of Protection Motivation Theory W.J. Wouter Botzen Institute for Environmental Studies, VU University, Amsterdam,

More information

The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis

The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis Oktay Akkus Department of Economics University of Chicago Ali Hortacsu Department of Economics University of Chicago VERY Preliminary Draft:

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

Scope Sensitivity Tests in CV and DCE: An Application using WTP for Mortality and Morbidity Risk Reductions

Scope Sensitivity Tests in CV and DCE: An Application using WTP for Mortality and Morbidity Risk Reductions Valuing the Health Impacts of Chemicals ECHE Helsinki, January 12, 2016 Scope Sensitivity Tests in CV and DCE: An Application using WTP for Mortality and Morbidity Risk Reductions Henrik Andersson (TSE,

More information

Contents. Part I Getting started 1. xxii xxix. List of tables Preface

Contents. Part I Getting started 1. xxii xxix. List of tables Preface Table of List of figures List of tables Preface page xvii xxii xxix Part I Getting started 1 1 In the beginning 3 1.1 Choosing as a common event 3 1.2 A brief history of choice modeling 6 1.3 The journey

More information

Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction of the Riester Scheme in Germany

Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction of the Riester Scheme in Germany Modern Economy, 2016, 7, 1198-1222 http://www.scirp.org/journal/me ISSN Online: 2152-7261 ISSN Print: 2152-7245 Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction

More information

Getting Beyond Ordinary MANAGING PLAN COSTS IN AUTOMATIC PROGRAMS

Getting Beyond Ordinary MANAGING PLAN COSTS IN AUTOMATIC PROGRAMS PRICE PERSPECTIVE In-depth analysis and insights to inform your decision-making. Getting Beyond Ordinary MANAGING PLAN COSTS IN AUTOMATIC PROGRAMS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Plan sponsors today are faced with unprecedented

More information

Motif Capital Horizon Models: A robust asset allocation framework

Motif Capital Horizon Models: A robust asset allocation framework Motif Capital Horizon Models: A robust asset allocation framework Executive Summary By some estimates, over 93% of the variation in a portfolio s returns can be attributed to the allocation to broad asset

More information

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Addison-Wesley.

Copyright 2011 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Addison-Wesley. Appendix: Statistics in Action Part I Financial Time Series 1. These data show the effects of stock splits. If you investigate further, you ll find that most of these splits (such as in May 1970) are 3-for-1

More information

9. Logit and Probit Models For Dichotomous Data

9. Logit and Probit Models For Dichotomous Data Sociology 740 John Fox Lecture Notes 9. Logit and Probit Models For Dichotomous Data Copyright 2014 by John Fox Logit and Probit Models for Dichotomous Responses 1 1. Goals: I To show how models similar

More information

Using Halton Sequences. in Random Parameters Logit Models

Using Halton Sequences. in Random Parameters Logit Models Journal of Statistical and Econometric Methods, vol.5, no.1, 2016, 59-86 ISSN: 1792-6602 (print), 1792-6939 (online) Scienpress Ltd, 2016 Using Halton Sequences in Random Parameters Logit Models Tong Zeng

More information

How exogenous is exogenous income? A longitudinal study of lottery winners in the UK

How exogenous is exogenous income? A longitudinal study of lottery winners in the UK How exogenous is exogenous income? A longitudinal study of lottery winners in the UK Dita Eckardt London School of Economics Nattavudh Powdthavee CEP, London School of Economics and MIASER, University

More information

Online Appendix (Not For Publication)

Online Appendix (Not For Publication) A Online Appendix (Not For Publication) Contents of the Appendix 1. The Village Democracy Survey (VDS) sample Figure A1: A map of counties where sample villages are located 2. Robustness checks for the

More information

sociology SO5032 Quantitative Research Methods Brendan Halpin, Sociology, University of Limerick Spring 2018 SO5032 Quantitative Research Methods

sociology SO5032 Quantitative Research Methods Brendan Halpin, Sociology, University of Limerick Spring 2018 SO5032 Quantitative Research Methods 1 SO5032 Quantitative Research Methods Brendan Halpin, Sociology, University of Limerick Spring 2018 Lecture 10: Multinomial regression baseline category extension of binary What if we have multiple possible

More information

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer? AEA Papers and Proceedings 2018, 108: 401 406 https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20181116 In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer? By Barbara A. Butrica and Nadia S. Karamcheva*

More information

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? October 19, 2009 Ulrike Malmendier, UC Berkeley (joint work with Stefan Nagel, Stanford) 1 The Tale of Depression Babies I don t know

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 3 Fall 1997 CORPORATE MANAGERS RISKY BEHAVIOR: RISK TAKING OR AVOIDING?

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 3 Fall 1997 CORPORATE MANAGERS RISKY BEHAVIOR: RISK TAKING OR AVOIDING? Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 3 Fall 1997 CORPORATE MANAGERS RISKY BEHAVIOR: RISK TAKING OR AVOIDING? Kathryn Sullivan* Abstract This study reports on five experiments that

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Inflation Expectations and Behavior: Do Survey Respondents Act on their Beliefs? October Wilbert van der Klaauw

Inflation Expectations and Behavior: Do Survey Respondents Act on their Beliefs? October Wilbert van der Klaauw Inflation Expectations and Behavior: Do Survey Respondents Act on their Beliefs? October 16 2014 Wilbert van der Klaauw The views presented here are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those

More information

UPDATED IAA EDUCATION SYLLABUS

UPDATED IAA EDUCATION SYLLABUS II. UPDATED IAA EDUCATION SYLLABUS A. Supporting Learning Areas 1. STATISTICS Aim: To enable students to apply core statistical techniques to actuarial applications in insurance, pensions and emerging

More information

Willingness to Pay for Green Electricity in Tianjin, China: Based on Contingent Valuation Method

Willingness to Pay for Green Electricity in Tianjin, China: Based on Contingent Valuation Method Willingness to Pay for Green Electricity in Tianjin, China: Based on Contingent Valuation Method Li-Qiu Liu College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University the 40 th June 20, 2017, IAEE, Singapore

More information

School of Economic Sciences

School of Economic Sciences School of Economic Sciences Working Paper Series WP 2010-7 We Know What You Choose! External Validity of Discrete Choice Models By R. Karina Gallardo and Jaebong Chang April 2010 Working paper, please

More information

February 2010 Office of the Deputy Assistant Secretary of the Army for Cost & Economics (ODASA-CE)

February 2010 Office of the Deputy Assistant Secretary of the Army for Cost & Economics (ODASA-CE) U.S. ARMY COST ANALYSIS HANDBOOK SECTION 12 COST RISK AND UNCERTAINTY ANALYSIS February 2010 Office of the Deputy Assistant Secretary of the Army for Cost & Economics (ODASA-CE) TABLE OF CONTENTS 12.1

More information

Learning Objectives = = where X i is the i t h outcome of a decision, p i is the probability of the i t h

Learning Objectives = = where X i is the i t h outcome of a decision, p i is the probability of the i t h Learning Objectives After reading Chapter 15 and working the problems for Chapter 15 in the textbook and in this Workbook, you should be able to: Distinguish between decision making under uncertainty and

More information

ONLINE APPENDIX (NOT FOR PUBLICATION) Appendix A: Appendix Figures and Tables

ONLINE APPENDIX (NOT FOR PUBLICATION) Appendix A: Appendix Figures and Tables ONLINE APPENDIX (NOT FOR PUBLICATION) Appendix A: Appendix Figures and Tables 34 Figure A.1: First Page of the Standard Layout 35 Figure A.2: Second Page of the Credit Card Statement 36 Figure A.3: First

More information

2007 Minnesota Department of Revenue Taxpayer Satisfaction with the Filing Process

2007 Minnesota Department of Revenue Taxpayer Satisfaction with the Filing Process 2007 Minnesota Department of Revenue Taxpayer Satisfaction with the Filing Process Prepared for: The Minnesota Department of Revenue July 2007 2007 Minnesota Department of Revenue Taxpayer Satisfaction

More information

Decision Support Methods for Climate Change Adaption

Decision Support Methods for Climate Change Adaption Decision Support Methods for Climate Change Adaption 5 Summary of Methods and Case Study Examples from the MEDIATION Project Key Messages There is increasing interest in the appraisal of options, as adaptation

More information

Beliefs in Technology and Support for Environmental Taxes: An Empirical Investigation

Beliefs in Technology and Support for Environmental Taxes: An Empirical Investigation Beliefs in Technology and Support for Environmental Taxes: An Empirical Investigation Estefania Santacreu-Vasut and Jose Vives-Rego ESSEC Business School and THEMA France; Universitat de Barcelona 29/01/2015

More information

Presented at the 2012 SCEA/ISPA Joint Annual Conference and Training Workshop -

Presented at the 2012 SCEA/ISPA Joint Annual Conference and Training Workshop - Applying the Pareto Principle to Distribution Assignment in Cost Risk and Uncertainty Analysis James Glenn, Computer Sciences Corporation Christian Smart, Missile Defense Agency Hetal Patel, Missile Defense

More information

Valuation of Ambiguity Effect on Earthquake Retrofit on Willingness to Pay

Valuation of Ambiguity Effect on Earthquake Retrofit on Willingness to Pay Valuation of Ambiguity Effect on Earthquake Retrofit on Willingness to Pay Toshio Fujimi, Graduate School of Science and Technology, Kumamoto University fujimi@kumamoto-u.ac.jp Hirokazu Tatano, Disaster

More information

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade The Time Cost of Documents to Trade Mohammad Amin* May, 2011 The paper shows that the number of documents required to export and import tend to increase the time cost of shipments. However, this relationship

More information

A MODIFIED MULTINOMIAL LOGIT MODEL OF ROUTE CHOICE FOR DRIVERS USING THE TRANSPORTATION INFORMATION SYSTEM

A MODIFIED MULTINOMIAL LOGIT MODEL OF ROUTE CHOICE FOR DRIVERS USING THE TRANSPORTATION INFORMATION SYSTEM A MODIFIED MULTINOMIAL LOGIT MODEL OF ROUTE CHOICE FOR DRIVERS USING THE TRANSPORTATION INFORMATION SYSTEM Hing-Po Lo and Wendy S P Lam Department of Management Sciences City University of Hong ong EXTENDED

More information

RISK MANAGEMENT. Budgeting, d) Timing, e) Risk Categories,(RBS) f) 4. EEF. Definitions of risk probability and impact, g) 5. OPA

RISK MANAGEMENT. Budgeting, d) Timing, e) Risk Categories,(RBS) f) 4. EEF. Definitions of risk probability and impact, g) 5. OPA RISK MANAGEMENT 11.1 Plan Risk Management: The process of DEFINING HOW to conduct risk management activities for a project. In Plan Risk Management, the remaining FIVE risk management processes are PLANNED

More information

PARAMETRIC AND NON-PARAMETRIC BOOTSTRAP: A SIMULATION STUDY FOR A LINEAR REGRESSION WITH RESIDUALS FROM A MIXTURE OF LAPLACE DISTRIBUTIONS

PARAMETRIC AND NON-PARAMETRIC BOOTSTRAP: A SIMULATION STUDY FOR A LINEAR REGRESSION WITH RESIDUALS FROM A MIXTURE OF LAPLACE DISTRIBUTIONS PARAMETRIC AND NON-PARAMETRIC BOOTSTRAP: A SIMULATION STUDY FOR A LINEAR REGRESSION WITH RESIDUALS FROM A MIXTURE OF LAPLACE DISTRIBUTIONS Melfi Alrasheedi School of Business, King Faisal University, Saudi

More information

An Analysis of the Factors Affecting Preferences for Rental Houses in Istanbul Using Mixed Logit Model: A Comparison of European and Asian Side

An Analysis of the Factors Affecting Preferences for Rental Houses in Istanbul Using Mixed Logit Model: A Comparison of European and Asian Side The Empirical Economics Letters, 15(9): (September 2016) ISSN 1681 8997 An Analysis of the Factors Affecting Preferences for Rental Houses in Istanbul Using Mixed Logit Model: A Comparison of European

More information

Lecture 1: Logit. Quantitative Methods for Economic Analysis. Seyed Ali Madani Zadeh and Hosein Joshaghani. Sharif University of Technology

Lecture 1: Logit. Quantitative Methods for Economic Analysis. Seyed Ali Madani Zadeh and Hosein Joshaghani. Sharif University of Technology Lecture 1: Logit Quantitative Methods for Economic Analysis Seyed Ali Madani Zadeh and Hosein Joshaghani Sharif University of Technology February 2017 1 / 38 Road map 1. Discrete Choice Models 2. Binary

More information

Homeowners Ratemaking Revisited

Homeowners Ratemaking Revisited Why Modeling? For lines of business with catastrophe potential, we don t know how much past insurance experience is needed to represent possible future outcomes and how much weight should be assigned to

More information

Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare Statistics and Information Department

Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare Statistics and Information Department Special Report on the Longitudinal Survey of Newborns in the 21st Century and the Longitudinal Survey of Adults in the 21st Century: Ten-Year Follow-up, 2001 2011 Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare

More information

THE CODING OF OUTCOMES IN TAXPAYERS REPORTING DECISIONS. A. Schepanski The University of Iowa

THE CODING OF OUTCOMES IN TAXPAYERS REPORTING DECISIONS. A. Schepanski The University of Iowa THE CODING OF OUTCOMES IN TAXPAYERS REPORTING DECISIONS A. Schepanski The University of Iowa May 2001 The author thanks Teri Shearer and the participants of The University of Iowa Judgment and Decision-Making

More information

WC-5 Just How Credible Is That Employer? Exploring GLMs and Multilevel Modeling for NCCI s Excess Loss Factor Methodology

WC-5 Just How Credible Is That Employer? Exploring GLMs and Multilevel Modeling for NCCI s Excess Loss Factor Methodology Antitrust Notice The Casualty Actuarial Society is committed to adhering strictly to the letter and spirit of the antitrust laws. Seminars conducted under the auspices of the CAS are designed solely to

More information

The Impact of Hurricane Harvey Survey 2, Summer 2018

The Impact of Hurricane Harvey Survey 2, Summer 2018 The Impact of Hurricane Harvey Survey 2, Summer 2018 The Impact of Hurricane Harvey One Year Later Hurricane Harvey was a massive flood event, with devastating consequences for the greater Houston area.

More information

Econometrics is. The estimation of relationships suggested by economic theory

Econometrics is. The estimation of relationships suggested by economic theory Econometrics is Econometrics is The estimation of relationships suggested by economic theory Econometrics is The estimation of relationships suggested by economic theory The application of mathematical

More information

Econometric Methods for Valuation Analysis

Econometric Methods for Valuation Analysis Econometric Methods for Valuation Analysis Margarita Genius Dept of Economics M. Genius (Univ. of Crete) Econometric Methods for Valuation Analysis Cagliari, 2017 1 / 25 Outline We will consider econometric

More information

Cross-Sectional Distribution of GARCH Coefficients across S&P 500 Constituents : Time-Variation over the Period

Cross-Sectional Distribution of GARCH Coefficients across S&P 500 Constituents : Time-Variation over the Period Cahier de recherche/working Paper 13-13 Cross-Sectional Distribution of GARCH Coefficients across S&P 500 Constituents : Time-Variation over the Period 2000-2012 David Ardia Lennart F. Hoogerheide Mai/May

More information

Online Appendix for Does mobile money affect saving behavior? Evidence from a developing country Journal of African Economies

Online Appendix for Does mobile money affect saving behavior? Evidence from a developing country Journal of African Economies Online Appendix for Does mobile money affect saving behavior? Evidence from a developing country Journal of African Economies Serge Ky, Clovis Rugemintwari and Alain Sauviat In this document we report

More information

IJSE 41,5. Abstract. The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at

IJSE 41,5. Abstract. The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at www.emeraldinsight.com/0306-8293.htm IJSE 41,5 362 Received 17 January 2013 Revised 8 July 2013 Accepted 16 July 2013 Does minimum

More information

Choosing between subsidized or unsubsidized private pension schemes: a random parameters bivariate probit analysis

Choosing between subsidized or unsubsidized private pension schemes: a random parameters bivariate probit analysis Universität Bayreuth Rechts- und Wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Fakultät Wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Diskussionspapiere Choosing between subsidized or unsubsidized private pension schemes: a random parameters

More information

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 17 Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 Luísa Farinha Pedro Prego 2 Abstract The analysis of liquidity management decisions by firms has recently been used as a tool to investigate the

More information

Statistical Modeling Techniques for Reserve Ranges: A Simulation Approach

Statistical Modeling Techniques for Reserve Ranges: A Simulation Approach Statistical Modeling Techniques for Reserve Ranges: A Simulation Approach by Chandu C. Patel, FCAS, MAAA KPMG Peat Marwick LLP Alfred Raws III, ACAS, FSA, MAAA KPMG Peat Marwick LLP STATISTICAL MODELING

More information

Protecting Against Disaster Risks: Why Insurance and Prevention May Be Complements

Protecting Against Disaster Risks: Why Insurance and Prevention May Be Complements Protecting Against Disaster Risks: Why Insurance and Prevention May Be Complements W.J. Wouter Botzen Institute for Environmental Studies, VU University Howard Kunreuther The Wharton School University

More information

TOURISM GENERATION ANALYSIS BASED ON A SCOBIT MODEL * Lingling, WU **, Junyi ZHANG ***, and Akimasa FUJIWARA ****

TOURISM GENERATION ANALYSIS BASED ON A SCOBIT MODEL * Lingling, WU **, Junyi ZHANG ***, and Akimasa FUJIWARA **** TOURISM GENERATION ANALYSIS BASED ON A SCOBIT MODEL * Lingling, WU **, Junyi ZHANG ***, and Akimasa FUJIWARA ****. Introduction Tourism generation (or participation) is one of the most important aspects

More information

Indian Households Finance: An analysis of Stocks vs. Flows- Extended Abstract

Indian Households Finance: An analysis of Stocks vs. Flows- Extended Abstract Indian Households Finance: An analysis of Stocks vs. Flows- Extended Abstract Pawan Gopalakrishnan S. K. Ritadhi Shekhar Tomar September 15, 2018 Abstract How do households allocate their income across

More information

Insurance Against Climate Change and Flooding in the Netherlands: Present, Future, and Comparison with Other Countries

Insurance Against Climate Change and Flooding in the Netherlands: Present, Future, and Comparison with Other Countries Risk Analysis, Vol. 28, No. 2, 2008 DOI: 10.1111/j.1539-6924.2008.01035.x Insurance Against Climate Change and Flooding in the Netherlands: Present, Future, and Comparison with Other Countries W. J. W.

More information

STATISTICAL FLOOD STANDARDS

STATISTICAL FLOOD STANDARDS STATISTICAL FLOOD STANDARDS SF-1 Flood Modeled Results and Goodness-of-Fit A. The use of historical data in developing the flood model shall be supported by rigorous methods published in currently accepted

More information

CHAPTER 12 EXAMPLES: MONTE CARLO SIMULATION STUDIES

CHAPTER 12 EXAMPLES: MONTE CARLO SIMULATION STUDIES Examples: Monte Carlo Simulation Studies CHAPTER 12 EXAMPLES: MONTE CARLO SIMULATION STUDIES Monte Carlo simulation studies are often used for methodological investigations of the performance of statistical

More information

MODELLING OF INCOME AND WAGE DISTRIBUTION USING THE METHOD OF L-MOMENTS OF PARAMETER ESTIMATION

MODELLING OF INCOME AND WAGE DISTRIBUTION USING THE METHOD OF L-MOMENTS OF PARAMETER ESTIMATION International Days of Statistics and Economics, Prague, September -3, MODELLING OF INCOME AND WAGE DISTRIBUTION USING THE METHOD OF L-MOMENTS OF PARAMETER ESTIMATION Diana Bílková Abstract Using L-moments

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Interpretation issues in heteroscedastic conditional logit models

Interpretation issues in heteroscedastic conditional logit models Interpretation issues in heteroscedastic conditional logit models Michael Burton a,b,*, Katrina J. Davis a,c, and Marit E. Kragt a a School of Agricultural and Resource Economics, The University of Western

More information

Willingness to pay for accommodating job attributes when returning to work after cancer treatment:

Willingness to pay for accommodating job attributes when returning to work after cancer treatment: Willingness to pay for accommodating job attributes when returning to work after cancer treatment: A discrete choice experiment with Danish breast cancer survivors Anna Kollerup Iversen a,b and Jacob Ladenburg

More information

Gender wage gaps in formal and informal jobs, evidence from Brazil.

Gender wage gaps in formal and informal jobs, evidence from Brazil. Gender wage gaps in formal and informal jobs, evidence from Brazil. Sarra Ben Yahmed May, 2013 Very preliminary version, please do not circulate Keywords: Informality, Gender Wage gaps, Selection. JEL

More information

Obesity, Disability, and Movement onto the DI Rolls

Obesity, Disability, and Movement onto the DI Rolls Obesity, Disability, and Movement onto the DI Rolls John Cawley Cornell University Richard V. Burkhauser Cornell University Prepared for the Sixth Annual Conference of Retirement Research Consortium The

More information

Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data

Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data by Peter A Groothuis Professor Appalachian State University Boone, NC and James Richard Hill Professor Central Michigan University

More information

Using Stated Preferences Data to Analyze Preferences for Full and Partial Retirement. Arthur van Soest, RAND and Tilburg University 1

Using Stated Preferences Data to Analyze Preferences for Full and Partial Retirement. Arthur van Soest, RAND and Tilburg University 1 Using Stated Preferences Data to Analyze Preferences for Full and Partial Retirement Arthur van Soest, RAND and Tilburg University 1 Arie Kapteyn, RAND Julie Zissimopoulos, RAND Preliminary and Incomplete

More information

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication.

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication. Online Appendix Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle Not intended for publication Alexander Bick Arizona State University Sekyu Choi Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona,

More information

Recreational Boater Willingness to Pay for an Atlantic Intracoastal Waterway Dredging. and Maintenance Program 1. John C.

Recreational Boater Willingness to Pay for an Atlantic Intracoastal Waterway Dredging. and Maintenance Program 1. John C. Recreational Boater Willingness to Pay for an Atlantic Intracoastal Waterway Dredging and Maintenance Program 1 John C. Whitehead Department of Economics Appalachian State University Boone, North Carolina

More information

Using Monte Carlo Analysis in Ecological Risk Assessments

Using Monte Carlo Analysis in Ecological Risk Assessments 10/27/00 Page 1 of 15 Using Monte Carlo Analysis in Ecological Risk Assessments Argonne National Laboratory Abstract Monte Carlo analysis is a statistical technique for risk assessors to evaluate the uncertainty

More information

SELECTION BIAS REDUCTION IN CREDIT SCORING MODELS

SELECTION BIAS REDUCTION IN CREDIT SCORING MODELS SELECTION BIAS REDUCTION IN CREDIT SCORING MODELS Josef Ditrich Abstract Credit risk refers to the potential of the borrower to not be able to pay back to investors the amount of money that was loaned.

More information

Available online at ScienceDirect. Procedia Environmental Sciences 22 (2014 )

Available online at   ScienceDirect. Procedia Environmental Sciences 22 (2014 ) Available online at www.sciencedirect.com ScienceDirect Procedia Environmental Sciences 22 (2014 ) 414 422 12th International Conference on Design and Decision Support Systems in Architecture and Urban

More information

Capturing Risk Interdependencies: The CONVOI Method

Capturing Risk Interdependencies: The CONVOI Method Capturing Risk Interdependencies: The CONVOI Method Blake Boswell Mike Manchisi Eric Druker 1 Table Of Contents Introduction The CONVOI Process Case Study Consistency Verification Conditional Odds Integration

More information

Contract Nonperformance Risk and Ambiguity in Insurance Markets

Contract Nonperformance Risk and Ambiguity in Insurance Markets Contract Nonperformance Risk and in Insurance Markets Christian Biener, Martin Eling (University of St. Gallen) Andreas Landmann, Maria Isabel Santana (University of Mannheim) 11 th Microinsurance Conference

More information

Investment Decisions and Negative Interest Rates

Investment Decisions and Negative Interest Rates Investment Decisions and Negative Interest Rates No. 16-23 Anat Bracha Abstract: While the current European Central Bank deposit rate and 2-year German government bond yields are negative, the U.S. 2-year

More information

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20135 Theory of Finance, Part I (Sept. October) Fall 2014 Outline and objectives The backward, three-step solution

More information

Energy Price Processes

Energy Price Processes Energy Processes Used for Derivatives Pricing & Risk Management In this first of three articles, we will describe the most commonly used process, Geometric Brownian Motion, and in the second and third

More information

WORKING P A P E R. Using Stated Preferences Data to Analyze Preferences for Full and Partial Retirement

WORKING P A P E R. Using Stated Preferences Data to Analyze Preferences for Full and Partial Retirement WORKING P A P E R Using Stated Preferences Data to Analyze Preferences for Full and Partial Retirement ARTHUR VAN SOEST ARIE KAPTEYN JULIE ZISSIMOPOULOS WR-345 February 2006 This product is part of the

More information

EVALUATING OPTIMAL STRATEGIES TO IMPROVE EARTHQUAKE PERFORMANCE FOR COMMUNITIES

EVALUATING OPTIMAL STRATEGIES TO IMPROVE EARTHQUAKE PERFORMANCE FOR COMMUNITIES EVALUATING OPTIMAL STRATEGIES TO IMPROVE EARTHQUAKE PERFORMANCE FOR COMMUNITIES Anju GUPTA 1 SUMMARY This paper describes a new multi-benefit based strategy evaluation methodology to will help stakeholders

More information

1. Logit and Linear Probability Models

1. Logit and Linear Probability Models INTERNET APPENDIX 1. Logit and Linear Probability Models Table 1 Leverage and the Likelihood of a Union Strike (Logit Models) This table presents estimation results of logit models of union strikes during

More information

*9-BES2_Logistic Regression - Social Economics & Public Policies Marcelo Neri

*9-BES2_Logistic Regression - Social Economics & Public Policies Marcelo Neri Econometric Techniques and Estimated Models *9 (continues in the website) This text details the different statistical techniques used in the analysis, such as logistic regression, applied to discrete variables

More information

Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz

Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz Abstract: This paper is an analysis of the mortality rates of beneficiaries of charitable gift annuities. Observed

More information

Chapter 2 Uncertainty Analysis and Sampling Techniques

Chapter 2 Uncertainty Analysis and Sampling Techniques Chapter 2 Uncertainty Analysis and Sampling Techniques The probabilistic or stochastic modeling (Fig. 2.) iterative loop in the stochastic optimization procedure (Fig..4 in Chap. ) involves:. Specifying

More information