How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO?

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO?"

Transcription

1 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? Bruce A. Babcock and Chad E. Hart Briefing Paper 05-BP 48 November 2005 Center for Agricultural and Rural Development Iowa State University Ames, Iowa Bruce Babcock is professor of economics and director of the Center for Agricultural and Rural Development (CARD) at Iowa State University and Chad Hart is a research scientist and U.S. policy and insurance analyst at CARD. This paper is available online on the CARD Web site: Permission is granted to reproduce this information with appropriate attribution to the authors. Questions or comments about the contents of this paper should be directed to Bruce Babcock, 578 Heady Hall, Iowa State University, Ames, IA ; Ph: (515) ; Fax: (515) ; babcock@iastate.edu. Iowa State University does not discriminate on the basis of race, color, age, religion, national origin, sexual orientation, gender identity, sex, marital status, disability, or status as a U.S. veteran. Inquiries can be directed to the Director of Equal Opportunity and Diversity, 3680 Beardshear Hall, (515)

2 Executive Summary Critics of the U.S. proposal to the World Trade Organization (WTO) made in October 2005 are correct when they argue that adoption of the proposal would significantly reduce available support under the current farm program structure. Using historical prices and yields from 1980 to 2004, we estimate that loan rates would have to drop by 9 percent and target prices would have to drop by 10 percent in order to meet the proposed aggregate Amber Box and Blue Box limits. While this finding should cheer those who think that reform of U.S. farm programs is long overdue, it alarms those who want to maintain a strong safety net for U.S. agriculture. The dilemma of needing to reform farm programs while maintaining a strong safety net could be resolved by redesigning programs so that they target revenue rather than price. Building on a base of 70 percent Green Box income insurance, a program that provides a crop-specific revenue guarantee equal to 98 percent of the product of the current effective target price and expected county yield would fit into the proposed aggregate Amber and Blue Box limits. Payments would be triggered whenever the product of the season-average price and county average yield fell below this 98 percent revenue guarantee. Adding the proposed crop-specific constraints lowers the coverage level to 95 percent. Moving from programs that target price to ones that target revenue would eliminate the rationale for ad hoc disaster payments. Program payments would automatically arrive whenever significant crop losses or economic losses caused by low prices occurred. Also, much of the need for the complicated mechanism (the Standard Reinsurance Agreement) that transfers most risk of the U.S. crop insurance to the federal government would be eliminated because the federal government would directly assume the risk through farm programs. Changing the focus of federal farm programs from price targeting to revenue targeting would not be easy. Farmers have long relied on price supports and the knowledge that crop losses are often adequately covered by heavily subsidized crop insurance or by ad hoc disaster payments. Farmers and their leaders would only be willing to support a change to revenue targeting if they see that the current system is untenable in an era of tight federal budgets and WTO limits. Keywords: farm safety net, revenue targeting, U.S. farm programs, WTO.

3 HOW MUCH SAFETY IS AVAILABLE UNDER THE U.S. PROPOSAL TO THE WTO? In an effort to jump-start the Doha round negotiations in the World Trade Organization (WTO), the United States proposed new limits on trade-distorting domestic subsidies. While it remains to be seen whether this proposal will ultimately be successful in furthering the negotiations, it has already caused some alarm in the U.S. Congress and among farm groups because of the size of the cuts in subsidy levels that would need to take place under the proposal. For example, in a public letter to the secretary of agriculture, Senator Chambliss, the chair of the Senate Agriculture Committee, requested that there be no net reduction in the agricultural safety net. 1 And the proposal was criticized by Larry Mitchell, chief executive of the American Corn Growers Association, as yet another in a series of policy decisions by the present administration to unravel the safety net for the nation s farm families. The administration s decision to slash our essential domestic farm program benefits by 50 to 60 percent is ill advised, irresponsible and ill timed. 2 These two statements support the notion that the purpose of U.S. farm subsidies is to create a safety net for U.S. agriculture. Such a purpose implies that subsidies should increase when financial stress increases. But countercyclical aid to farmers is generally considered to be trade distorting because it reduces the supply contracting incentives of low prices or unsuitable growing conditions. Decoupled support, such as U.S. direct payments and E.U. single farm payments, is generally considered to be non-trade distorting because it does not change in response to income levels, prices, crop yields, or farmers planting decisions. The dilemma for U.S. trade negotiators is that they need to assure the world that the U.S. proposal would result in meaningful reductions in U.S. domestic support while simultaneously assuring Congress that the proposal would provide adequate flexibility to maintain an adequate agricultural safety net for U.S. farmers. Is it possible to reform U.S.

4 2 / Babcock and Hart farm programs to make them less trade distorting while simultaneously maintaining effective countercyclical safety net protection for U.S. farmers? We provide insight into this question by estimating the extent of the cuts that will have to be made in current program parameters in order to meet the U.S.-proposed limits. We demonstrate that the size of the cuts that are required would indeed make the current set of farm programs less trade distorting. But the size of the cuts needed would also significantly lower the amount of safety provided by the U.S. program. We then estimate the extent to which a redesign of U.S. farm programs to maximize countercyclical support could provide an adequate safety net. Using prices and detrended yields (not acreage or production) over the period from 1980 to 2004, we estimate that a program with the following three components would meet the proposed U.S. limits on trade-distorting subsidies with a high degree of probability: 1. Individual farmer crop revenue is guaranteed not to fall below 70 percent of the Olympic average of the previous five years of crop revenue. 2. If the product of national season-average price and county-average yield falls below 85 percent of the product of expected county yield and the effective target price (as defined in the 2002 U.S. farm bill), then all farmers in a county will receive the difference on each planted acre. Such payments are capped at 15 percent of the product of expected county yield and the effective target price. 3. If the product of national season-average price and county-average yield falls below 95 percent of the product of expected county yield and the effective target price, then all farmers in a county will receive the difference on each base acre that is assigned to their farm. Such payments are capped at 10 percent of the product of expected county yield and the effective target price. We report how we derived these estimates in the remainder of the paper. The U.S. Proposal for Agricultural Domestic Support In October 2005, the United States made a proposal for the next WTO agreement on agriculture that included significant changes for all three pillars of the agricultural negotiations: domestic support, market access, and export competition. The domestic support pillar deals with programs in the U.S. farm bill. Under the current WTO

5 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? / 3 agriculture agreement, agricultural support programs are divided into three boxes : Green, Blue, and Amber. Green Box programs are considered the least trade distorting and are not constrained. There is a specific set of guidelines a program must meet in order for it to be considered Green Box. Conservation programs are an example of Green Box programs. Blue Box programs are thought to be more trade distorting, but production limits or fixed payment bases are to be put in place to limit the amount of distortion. Currently, Blue Box programs do not face spending limits. The pre-1996 farm bill deficiency payment program is an example of a Blue Box program. Amber Box programs are thought to be the most trade distorting, and these are the programs that are most constrained under the agricultural agreements. Programs that go into the Amber Box are subcategorized depending on two factors: the targeting of the program to one or many products (product versus non-product specific) and the financial size of the amount of support. Once the programs are sorted into the product-specific and non-productspecific groups, the value of the support is compared to 5 percent of the value of agricultural production for the product (in the case of product-specific support) or for all agricultural products (in the case of non-product-specific support). If the value of support is less (more) than the 5 percent rule, then the support does not (does) count against the Amber Box spending limits. This rule is called the de minimis rule, exempting small amounts of agricultural support from the Amber Box limits. In July 2004, members of the WTO agreed to a framework for the next agricultural agreement. The agreement included a cap of 5 percent of the value of agricultural production on Blue Box support, a reduction in the de minimis percentage, productspecific limits on Amber Box support, a reduction in the Amber Box support limit, and a reduction of the amount of support from the combination of the Blue and Amber boxes and de minimis programs. The U.S. proposal further built upon this agreement in several ways. Support limits would be lowered over a five-year period. Blue Box support would be capped at 2.5 percent of the value of agricultural production. The Amber Box support limit would be cut by 60 percent (from $19.10 billion to $7.64 billion). Product-specific caps would be based on support levels for the product. The de minimis percentage would be reduced to 2.5 percent. The total amount of allowable support under

6 4 / Babcock and Hart the combination of the Blue and Amber boxes and de minimis programs would fall by 53 percent (Office of the United States Trade Representative). Table 1 shows the amounts of product-specific Amber Box support the U.S. reported during the period. Dairy, soybeans, corn, cotton, and sugar had the largest amounts of support. Beef and pork had no reported support during the period. If we use the average level of support as the product-specific cap (the proposal does not state an exact definition of the cap), then the sum of the product-specific caps is $16.13 billion. This greatly exceeds the overall Amber Box proposed limit of $7.64 billion, so not all of the commodities could be supported to the maximum level at the same time. Thus, it is likely that the United States would find that the overall Amber Box limit and some of the product-specific limits would be binding under current U.S. farm programs. Fitting Current Programs into the U.S. Proposal Current programs use two different prices to determine if a payment is to be received. The countercyclical payment (CCP) program uses the national season-average price whereas the marketing loan program uses posted county prices that vary each day. The selection of which of these two prices to use will determine the level of protection that can be offered to farmers. The idea of the marketing loan program is to provide farmers with an absolute guarantee that the price they receive for their crop will be no lower than the loan rate in their county. The idea is that if the local market price is less than the loan rate on the day that a farmer sells a crop, then a payment is made to compensate for the difference. This requires that daily prices be calculated. However, many farmers speculate with the marketing loan program by taking a loan deficiency payment (LDP) when they estimate that the gap between the loan rate and local market prices is widest: that is, when market prices are at their low point after harvest. This typically occurs for most regions right after harvest. To illustrate why the choice of price matters, we calculated the average price gap between the season-average farm price and the price indicated by average LDP rates historically when average LDP rates are positive. The season-average farm price is the average price received by farmers. Positive LDP rates indicate prices are below the loan

7 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? / 5 TABLE 1. Reported Amber Box support by product, Product Average ($ Million) Dairy 4,660 5,070 4,483 4,738 Soybeans 2,856 3,606 3,610 3,358 Corn 2,554 2,757 1,270 2,193 Cotton 2,353 1,050 2,810 2,071 Sugar 1,207 1,177 1,061 1,149 Wheat Rice Tobacco Peanuts Sunflower Apples Sorghum Canola Barley Oats Flaxseed Sheep and Lamb Wool Potatoes Honey Cranberries Onions Tomatoes Peaches Safflower Mohair Crambe Pears Apricots Mustard Seed Rapeseed Sesame Beef and Veal Hogs and Pigs Rye

8 6 / Babcock and Hart rate at some point during the crop year, and this can occur even when the season-average price is above the loan rate. Given average LDP rates for each year, we can back out a national price representing the average price when LDPs are taken. This is equal to the national loan rate less the average LDP rate. Comparing these prices to the seasonaverage prices for each year, we compute the price difference between the two and average this difference across all years. Table 2 shows the calculation of the corn LDP price gap. We subtract this price gap from the 2005 projected prices to calculate projected prices for LDP utilization. We then subtract these projected prices from the national crop loan rates to determine 2005 projected average LDP rates. Projected LDP expenditures are equal to projected production times the projected average LDP rate. Table 3 shows the calculated LDP price gap by crop. For rice and cotton, the price gap is calculated from the U.S. season-average prices and not the adjusted world prices actually used in the marketing loan program. As shown, all farmers have used the LDP price gap to their advantage. The typical farmer takes an LDP just after harvest and then successfully markets his crop at a significantly higher price later in the year. The LDP program therefore overcompensates farmers in most low-price years in that, on average, farmers market their crop for a price greater than the guaranteed price, which is the county loan rate. This suggests that use of the season average price would provide more targeted countercyclical support, and because it would lower program costs, use of the season-average price would allow target revenues to be higher than they would be if the posted county price were used. TABLE 2. Corn LDP price gap calculation Year Season-Average Price National Loan Rate Average LDP Rate LDP Price Gap ($ per bushel) Average 0.26

9 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? / 7 TABLE 3. LDP price gap by commodity Crop LDP Price Gap ($ per bushel) Barley* 0.78 Corn 0.26 Oats 0.23 Sorghum 0.22 Soybeans 0.56 Wheat 0.48 ($ per pound) Cotton Peanuts ($ per hundredweight) Rice 2.01 *Price gap calculated from the all-barley price. To see how the policy prices under the current programs would have to be changed to fit the U.S. proposed WTO limits, we computed what CCP and LDP expenditures would have been over the 1980 to 2004 period had the two programs been in place. This historical analysis will give us a general idea about the magnitude of the changes that would be required to meet the proposed limits. Finer detail would require a forwardlooking analysis. For the computation, we used the actual prices during the period, but we updated acreage to 2004 levels and yields as shown in the equation below. Actual Yieldt Adjusted Yieldt = Trend Yield2004 * Trend Yieldt where t is the crop year. To compute the WTO limits, we assumed a total value of U.S. agricultural production of $230 billion. This results in a Blue Box cap of $5.75 billion. Given this and the Amber Box limit of $7.64 billion, we allocated $750 million of Blue Box support and $1.04 billion in Amber Box support to commodities not covered by our analysis (mainly dairy and sugar), leaving $5 billion in Blue Box support and $6.6 billion in Amber Box support for the nine commodities examined here. We then computed the loan rates and target prices that would have resulted in support exceeding the new WTO support limits 4 percent of the time (1 year out of the 25 years examined). The 4 percent target was chosen to reflect a couple of points. First, any

10 8 / Babcock and Hart countercyclical program has a stochastic payout stream that will rise and fall over time. Thus, such a program could exceed any given bound if left unchecked. Second, the United States has shown a willingness to live with the possibility of exceeding WTO support limits (see the FAPRI 2002 U.S. Baseline Briefing Book discussion on WTO issues). To begin, we assumed that all commodities would face the same proportional reductions in the loan rate and target price to reach the limits of $6.6 billion for Amber Box support and $5 billion for Blue Box support for the commodities covered. Given the price and yield pattern seen from 1980 to 2004, a 9 percent reduction in loan rates is needed to reduce marketing loan support to the U.S. proposed Amber Box limit. Table 4 shows the adjusted loan rates. Table 5 shows the estimated historical Amber Box support at the adjusted loan rates. The 1986 crop year was the one year in which the limit was exceeded (by a large margin). We estimate that $10.26 billion would have flowed out through the marketing loan program, with corn receiving the lion s share at $6.45 billion. Corn s season-average price for 1986 was $1.50 per bushel, well below even the lowered loan rate of $1.77. Two other years nearly hit the limit. The 1999 and 2001 crop years also exhibited low commodity prices and high marketing loan support. Corn would have received the most support in 1999; cotton and soybeans would have received the most support in To meet the $5 billion Blue Box limit, given the reduced loan rates and the current direct payment rates, target prices would need to be reduced by 10 percent. TABLE 4. Impact of U.S. WTO proposal on commodity loan rates Crop Units Current Loan Rate Adjusted Loan Rate Barley ($/bushel) Corn ($/bushel) Cotton ($/pound) Oats ($/bushel) Peanuts ($/pound) Rice ($/hundredweight) Sorghum ($/bushel) Soybeans ($/bushel) Wheat ($/bushel)

11 TABLE 5. Estimated historical Amber Box support at adjusted loan rates Year Wheat Oats Rice Cotton Corn Sorghum Peanut Soybean Barley Total ($ million) , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , ,226 Limit ,071 2, , ,600 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? / 9

12 10 / Babcock and Hart Table 6 shows the current and adjusted target prices. Table 7 shows the resulting estimated historical CCP expenditures by commodity and in total for the period. The 1999 crop year was the year that exceeded the Blue Box limit. Seven of the nine crops had season-average prices low enough to trigger CCP payments. The 1986 and 2000 crop years also approached the $5 billion limit, with seven of the nine crops receiving CCP payments. So given proportional cuts of 10 percent in the target prices and 9 percent in the loan rates, the United States could meet, with a high degree of confidence, the proposed limits in Amber Box and Blue Box support. However, the proposal also includes productspecific limits on Amber Box support as well. If we compare the product-specific limits outlined in Table 1 to the commodity-specific support estimated in Table 5, we see that while the overall Amber Box limit was met, the product-specific limits were not met in several cases. We returned to the historical analysis and calculated the loan rates required to meet the product-specific limits. For cotton, peanuts, and soybeans, no reduction in loan rates is needed. For corn, a 10 percent reduction in the loan rate is needed to reduce marketing loan support to meet the limit. For the other crops, the loan rate reduction needed is on the order of 17 to 25 percent. These results also show that the United States could be bound by both the overall limits and the product-specific limits and that proportional reductions may not work. TABLE 6. Impact of U.S. WTO proposal on commodity target prices Crop Units Current Target Price Adjusted Target Price Barley ($/bushel) Corn ($/bushel) Cotton ($/pound) Oats ($/bushel) Peanuts ($/pound) Rice ($/hundredweight) Sorghum ($/bushel) Soybeans ($/bushel) Wheat ($/bushel)

13 TABLE 7. Estimated historical Blue Box support at adjusted target prices and loan rates Year Wheat Oats Rice Cotton Corn Sorghum Peanut Soybean Barley Total ($ million) , , , , , , , , , , ,117 2, , , , , , , , ,117 1, ,418 Limit 5,000 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? / 11

14 12 / Babcock and Hart Reductions of this magnitude would be seen by many agricultural groups as creating a sizable hole in the U.S. agricultural safety net. Whereas the combination of the CCP and marketing loan protected producers against corn prices below $2.35, soybean prices below $5.36, and wheat prices below $3.40, the new levels would be $2.09, $4.78, and $3.01, respectively. Also, the CCP and marketing loan programs do not respond to yield disasters. As Table 8 illustrates, in the drought years of 1983 and 1988 and the flood year of 1993 very little support would have been given to U.S. agriculture under these programs, while in the bumper crop year of 2004 significant payments were given. TABLE 8. Estimated historical combined support Year LDP CCP Total ($ million) ,261 4,894 15, ,427 2,368 4, ,203 1,009 2, , ,636 2,191 4, ,232 5,121 11, ,403 4,406 9, ,169 3,232 9, ,591 1,433 3, ,226 2,418 4,643

15 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? / 13 Redesign of U.S. Farm Policy The motivation for our proposed redesign of U.S. farm policy is illustrated nicely in Figure 1. Average per-acre market revenue for Iowa corn farmers from 1980 to 2004 peaked in 1995, hit a minimum in 1993, and from 1998 to 2001 hovered around $250 per acre. Had the current CCP and LDP programs been in place over this period, $100 peracre payments would have occurred during the period from 1998 to 2001, and they did occur during 2004 and No payments would have occurred during Peak afterpayment revenue occurred in 2004 (with 2005 close behind). Note that 2004 market revenue was about the same as market revenue in 1997, but Iowa farmers received no payments in The explanation for the mismatch between farm revenue and payments is that the current set of U.S. programs targets low prices rather than low revenue. In 2004, low prices triggered large payments even though per-acre income levels appear adequate. This illustrates that low prices are not synonymous with financial stress because high yields can bolster farm income. Similarly, high corn prices in 1993 clearly were not an indicator of financial health because Iowa corn farmers had only half a crop to sell $/acre Market Revenue CCP+LDP Market Revenue Plus LDP and CCP FIGURE 1. Average Iowa corn revenue with and without current subsidies

16 14 / Babcock and Hart Redirecting U.S. farm programs toward hitting a revenue target rather than a price target could reduce aggregate expenditures while simultaneously reducing the years in which farm income fell to unacceptable levels, as occurred in Iowa in The cost savings accrue from two sources. First, overcompensation would be reduced in highyield, low-price years by accounting for the fact that farmers have more production to sell in these years. Second, although payments from a revenue-targeting program would be greater when yields are low such as occurred in 1993 in Iowa the probability that low yields would trigger payments to all states and regions is close to zero because crop yields are not perfectly correlated across the country. For example, 1993 corn yields in Illinois did not suffer as they did in Iowa. The foregoing discussion suggests that moving U.S. farm programs to a countercyclical program that targets revenue instead of price could reduce aggregate expenditures while simultaneously improving the farm safety net. If this combination is possible, then this is exactly what is needed to assuage concerns that the U.S. proposal would unravel U.S. farm support. Key Design Aspects Moving to a program that targets revenue instead of price is just the first step in designing a new farm program. The extent to which such a program would actually improve the safety net while reducing expenditures depends on three program attributes: (1) individual versus area guarantees; (2) if an area guarantee is chosen, which area yield to use; and (3) the choice of which price to use. Individual vs. Area Guarantee. What features would be embodied in an effective safety net program? Farmers preferences are simple: they prefer higher average payments, and if farmers value payments more when their income is low, then they would prefer that the payments arrive when their income is low. Expressed in the context of a farm program, these preferences mean that farmers would prefer a countercyclical program that makes large average payments. Furthermore, they would prefer that payments would arrive when their individual income was low. Abstracting from production costs, income is low when market revenue is low, which implies that farmers prefer revenue insurance plans such as Revenue Assurance, Income Protection, and Crop Revenue Coverage. Part of the preference for revenue insurance plans comes from the

17 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? / 15 preferences of bankers who loan farmers money. Bankers often use the revenue insurance policy as a guarantee for their production loan. The downside of providing farmers with high revenue guarantees at the individual farm level is that these guarantees would induce farmers to change their planting, crop management, and marketing decisions in response to the incentives in the program. That is, high government guarantees at the individual farm level would induce farmers to farm the program rather than make decisions based on market considerations. Such moral hazard considerations are why the U.S. crop insurance program limits the individual guarantees that are available to 85 percent of expected revenue. One approach that has been taken to reduce moral hazard problems of high coverage levels is to make payments when an indicator of farm income is low rather that when actual farm income is low. For example, Group Risk Income Protection (GRIP) in the U.S. crop insurance program makes indemnity payments when the average county revenue is less than a county revenue guarantee. Basing payments on area revenue rather than individual revenue will decrease moral hazard because farmers can influence the size of the payments only through their acreage decisions. Thus farmers will look to market signals when deciding on how to care for, harvest, and market their crops. Further decoupling of payments from production decisions can be accomplished by making payments on fixed base acres, much like what is done with the U.S. CCP program. The trade-off of moving to more decoupled countercyclical payments is more market orientation, resulting in a decrease in moral hazard but less individual income protection. Which Area Yield to Use? If moral hazard concerns lead us away from individual farm guarantees, then we must choose which area yield to use. GRIP uses the county yield. Former Congressman Stenholm s SIPP (Supplemental Income Protection Program) proposal used national yields. Other natural alternatives are state yields and crop reporting district yields. There are three considerations in this choice. The first is the degree of correlation between farm yields and the chosen area yields. A higher correlation implies a better safety net because payments will arrive more often when income is low. This consideration argues for a low level of aggregation, such as at the county level.

18 16 / Babcock and Hart The second consideration is cost. The greater is the variability in yield, the higher will be the expected cost of the program. Variability of yield decreases as the level of aggregation increases. This consideration argues for a high level of aggregation, such as national or state yields. The final consideration is the degree of spatial correlation between yields. Lower spatial correlation implies lower year-to-year variability in total program payments. Low temporal variability allows more safety to be built into a program that must meet a limit on yearly expenditures. To see why low variability helps, consider the following situation. Suppose the United States has agreed to limit payments to $5 billion per year and Congress is considering two program options. One option is projected to pay out the maximum of $5 billion with a probability of 20 percent, $1 billion with a probability of 20 percent, and nothing with a probability of 60 percent. The expected payout from this option is $1.2 billion. The other option pays out $4 billion with a probability of 20 percent, $2 billion with a probability of 20 percent, and nothing with a probability of 60 percent. The expected payout under this option is also $1.2 billion. Under the first program option there is no room for any increase in support because the $5 billion limit would be exceeded. However, the second option still has room for additional support because the maximum payout is still less than the limit. This simple example illustrates that programs that have lower variability in year-toyear payments can offer more average support than programs that have higher variability. By their very nature countercyclical programs must vary payments to individuals; otherwise, they would be fixed payments. But different countercyclical programs will differ in the variability of total payments made to all individuals. For example, compare the variability of aggregate payments in a safety net program that pays corn farmers when the corn price falls below a certain amount to a program that pays farmers when their yield falls below a certain amount. When price falls below the target price, every eligible farmer in the United States would receive a payment because for most commodities market prices are about the same across the country. Under the yield safety net program, only a portion of farmers would receive payments in a year because growing conditions are not perfectly correlated across the country. In other words, price risk is more systemic than yield risk.

19 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? / 17 Taking this example one step further, if there is a limit on aggregate payments, then the amount of protection that can be offered to each farmer under a program that protects against yield shortfalls will be much higher than a program that offers protection against price shortfalls. A program that protects revenue can offer an intermediate level of protection because revenue risk is more systemic than yield risk but less systemic than price risk. Furthermore, a revenue countercyclical program that pays off when national revenue is low will have greater variability than a program that pays off when individual farm revenue is low. Thus, this consideration argues for a low level of aggregation, such as at the county level. Which Price to Use? There are two choices concerning prices that need to be made. The first concerns what price to use to set the target revenue level. The second concerns what price to use to determine whether a payment should be made. Our current price support programs pay farmers if market price falls below a price trigger, the level of which is set by Congress in farm legislation. CCP payments flow when the season-average price falls below the fixed effective target price and marketing loan payments flow when the posted county price falls below the fixed loan rate. The advantage of this approach is that farmers are assured (barring subsequent congressional action) of a certain level of support for the life of the legislation. One disadvantage is that as the expected market price drops for a particular crop, farmers have no incentive to respond to the low price by cutting production. Thus, fixed support prices tend to perpetuate periods of low market prices. A market-based alternative would be to use futures prices to estimate expected price and then base the target revenue on this expected price. Thus, in low-price years, farmers would have more of an incentive to cut production. And in high-price years, farmers would have additional incentive to expand production. Crop revenue insurance plans provide market-based guarantees. For example, GRIP calculates expected revenue as the product of the average futures price over a period of days and expected county yields. The reason for using a market-based price to determine the guarantee is that crop insurance companies do not want to be in a position of having to offer a guarantee that is well above what markets project a crop is worth.

20 18 / Babcock and Hart Program Details The U.S. proposal anticipates that U.S. farm countercyclical support programs would fall into both the Amber Box and the Blue Box, with the current CCP program falling into the Blue Box and the marketing loan program falling into the Amber Box. Thus, we need to allocate new countercyclical revenue payments into both the Amber and Blue boxes in order to maximize the amount of support in the new safety net. However, before we turn to the details of new Amber and Blue box programs, we will present the base countercyclical revenue program that will not count against either Amber Box or Blue Box limits because it will fall into the Green Box. Green Box Program Countercyclical Support. Section 7 of Annex 2 of the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture spells out the criteria that an income insurance program must adhere to if it is to be considered as Green Box support: (a) Eligibility for such payments shall be determined by an income loss, taking into account only income derived from agriculture, which exceeds 30 percent of average gross income or the equivalent in net income terms (excluding any payments from the same or similar schemes) in the preceding three-year period or a three-year average based on the preceding fiveyear period, excluding the highest and the lowest entry. Any producer meeting this condition shall be eligible to receive the payments. (b) The amount of such payments shall compensate for less than 70 percent of the producer s income loss in the year the producer becomes eligible to receive this assistance. (c) The amount of any such payments shall relate solely to income; it shall not relate to the type or volume of production (including livestock units) undertaken by the producer; or to the prices, domestic or international, applying to such production; or to the factors of production employed. There is a bit of a contradiction in these statements in that payments can be made when farm income is low, but farm income is determined by the output price and production levels. That is, an income loss can only occur if either prices or production drop. Yet paragraph (c) indicates that the size of payments cannot depend on either production levels or prices. For our purposes here, we will focus attention on paragraphs (a) and (b), which imply that a guarantee that equals 70 percent of the Olympic average of the previous five

21 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? / 19 years of revenue can be considered as Green Box support. Hence, it will not count toward the limits in the Amber and Blue boxes. We also assume that such payments can be made on a crop-specific basis, if for no other reason than a farmer with a single crop would qualify for this type of payment. Another interpretation is that only whole-farm Green Box income insurance programs would be allowed, which would be similar to the Adjusted Gross Revenue (AGR) insurance offered in the U.S. crop insurance program. What this implies is that a base level of countercyclical revenue support can be given to U.S. farmers in the form of a 70 percent revenue guarantee. As shown in Figure 2, 70 percent revenue coverage is the most popular level of coverage for farmers who buy Revenue Assurance. Ironically, the Unites States reports all crop insurance subsidies as Amber Box support. Adopting a Green Box program at a 70 percent coverage level would thereby move a significant amount of Amber Box support over to the Green Box. A New Amber Box Program. The next revenue countercyclical program to be developed will build on the Green Box 70 percent base and will be designed to fit into the Amber Box. Amber Box spending is generally tied to production or price levels and is considered to be the most trade distorting. As discussed in the previous section, offering individual farm guarantees at high coverage levels will begin to affect farmers planting Million acres Coverage Level (%) FIGURE 2. Revenue Assurance insured acreage in 2005

22 20 / Babcock and Hart and crop management decisions. Given the 30 percent deductible built into the Green Box program, such distortions are likely minimal. But at higher coverage levels, such distortions will likely begin to come into play. As discussed, a partial decoupling of support from management decisions can be made by basing the next level of countercyclical support on area yields. Given that our objective is to design an effective farm-level safety net, and given the limited amount of spatial poolability from national or state yields, we choose to use county yields. Payments will be made whenever actual county revenue falls below the Amber Box trigger revenue level for each crop. To reduce the amount of change that would have to take place relative to current farm program structures, we propose to use fixed target prices to determine the trigger revenue levels rather than expected market prices. For lack of a better alternative, we will use the effective target prices that are in place for the 2005 crop year. Table 9 presents the levels. To maximize the amount of coverage that this program will provide, we calculate actual county revenue as the product of the season average price and county average yield. The trigger revenue level will equal some percentage of the product of expected county yield (the same yield used to determine trigger yield and revenue levels in Group Risk Plan and GRIP) and the effective target price. The optimization problem is to maximize the percentage the Amber Box coverage level such that the probability of total payments across all crops being greater than Amber Box limits does not exceed a certain level. Because this is a program designed to be designated as Amber Box, payments will be based on actual planted acreage. TABLE 9. Effective target prices for 2005 crop year Crop Units Effective Target Price Wheat ($/bushel) 3.40 Soybeans ($/bushel) 5.36 Peanuts ($/pound) Cotton ($/pound) Sorghum ($/bushel) 2.22 Corn ($/bushel) 2.35 Oats ($/bushel) Rice ($/hundredweight) 8.15 Barley ($/bushel) 2.00

23 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? / 21 A per-acre payment for a particular crop is given by the following formula: Amber Payment = min(max(0, α*etp*e[y c ] SAP* Y c ), (α 0.70)*ETP*E[Y c ]) where α > 0.70 is the Amber Box coverage level, ETP is the effective target price for a crop, E[Y c ] is the expected county yield, SAP is the season average price, and Y c is the actual county yield. The minimum operation takes place to reflect the 70 percent coverage offered by the Green Box program. A New Blue Box Program. Additional countercyclical revenue support can be provided with a program that can fit into the proposed Blue Box. Blue Box programs can base payments on actual prices and production levels if they are paid on a fixed acreage base. Therefore, our Blue Box program is similar to our Amber Box program except it will be paid on a fixed acreage base. In addition, it will build support on top of the Amber Box support so that the per-base-acre payment formula is Blue Payment = min(max(0, β*etp*e[y c ] SAP* Y c ), (β α)*etp*e[y c ]) where β is the Blue Box coverage level. To summarize, countercyclical support for farm income can most effectively be achieved by making payments when farm revenue is low. To determine the degree to which an agricultural safety net can be maintained given the limits on support proposed by the United States, we have designed a sequence of three tiered countercyclical programs. The base program provides individual farmers with a revenue guarantee equal to 70 percent of the Olympic average of the past five years of their revenue. Payments under this program would be declared as Green Box support. The second-tier program would provide support from 70 percent to 100*α percent of the product of the effective target price and expected county yield. This support would be paid on planted acreage so it would fall into the Amber Box. The third-tier program would provide support from 100*α percent to 100*β percent. Payments under this third-tier program would be based on base acres so this support could be declared as Blue Box. Solving for α and β To determine the settings for α and β, we again utilize an historical analysis. Using the same period that we used to estimate payments under the current program tools, we estimate payments under the revenue Amber Box and Blue Box programs. As

24 22 / Babcock and Hart with the earlier analysis, this historical analysis will give us a general idea about the magnitude of the changes that would be required to meet the proposed limits. Finer detail would require a forward-looking analysis. For the Amber Box program we used 2004 planted acreage and detrended (to 2004) yields. For the Blue Box program we set the base acreage equal to 2004 planted acreage for each of the crops, as this program would be a new program and not necessarily tied to the current base acreage structure. The yield and acreage data is at the county level. To start, suppose that we did not have to split the new safety net program into separate Amber and Blue boxes, and suppose that there were no product-specific limits. How high a coverage level (α) could we obtain and still meet the combined limit of the Amber and Blue boxes (support at or below $11.6 billion)? We estimate that a coverage level of 99 percent can be achieved while still meeting the combined limit in 24 out of the 25 years. That is, ignoring the Amber versus Blue Box split, as well as the productspecific limits, 99 percent of the current effective target price could be protected by a county revenue program while still meeting overall WTO limits as proposed by the United States. If we allocate coverage to meet both aggregate Amber and Blue Box limits, the top coverage level is 98 percent. These results suggest that moving to a program that targets revenue can provide a much higher amount of safety than does a program that targets price. Table 10 shows the outlays from such a 99 percent program. The 1986 crop year is the one year that exceeds the limit. Payments approached the limit for the 1999 and 2000 crop years. We can clearly see how targeting revenue creates a much different pattern of payments than the pattern that occurs when price is targeted. The revenue program would have provided significant payments in the drought year of 1988 and the flood year of 1993 whereas the current array of programs would not (compare Table 10 to Table 8). However, if we examine the product-specific limit, there would be several instances in which the support from a 99 percent program would exceed the allowed level. To find the parameters that allow the proposed revenue programs to fit all of the requirements (the overall limit, the Amber and Blue Box limits, and the product-specific limits), we estimated α and β such that any of the three limits is only exceeded once out of the 25 years in the historical analysis (a 4 percent chance). Because the Blue Box revenue

25 TABLE 10. Revenue support available at a 99 percent county revenue guarantee Year Wheat Oats Rice Cotton Corn Sorghum Peanut Soybean Barley Total ($ million) , , , , , , , , ,256 6, , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , ,651 5, , , , ,517 4, , , , ,728 3, , , ,616 2, , , , ,121 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? / 23

26 24 / Babcock and Hart / program is conditioned on both α and β, while the Amber Box revenue program depends only on α, we computed the setting for α and the Amber Box expenditures first. That is, we solved for the α such that both the product-specific limits and the Amber Box support limit of $6.6 billion was met for the nine commodities. As we did in the analysis of the current programs, we assumed that all of the commodities had the same parameter setting (the same α). Table 11 shows the historical results for the Amber Box revenue program for α = 0.85, the highest value that satisfies all of the constraints. For the Amber Box revenue program, the binding constraints were the product-specific limits for wheat, corn, and sorghum. If we ignored the product-specific caps in the U.S. proposal, then an α of 0.89 was possible. Thus, some of the product-specific limits were more binding than the overall limit. One major difference between the Amber Box revenue program and the marketing loan program is the year-to-year variability flow of payments. From Table 8, we can see that in five years (20 percent of the time) no payments would be made under the marketing loan program. The Amber Box revenue program would make payments every year. Thus, while both programs are constructed to the Amber Box constraints, the Amber Box revenue program provides a much steadier flow of payments over the years examined. The reason, of course, is that when revenue is targeted, payments will flow to farmers in counties that experience poor yields, whereas the current programs pay out only when price is low. Given an α of 0.85 and the $5 billion constraint on Blue Box support, we then estimated β, again assuming all crops receive the same β. Table 12 contains the estimated historical payments under a Blue Box revenue program with β = 0.95, the highest β possible given the constraints. As there are no product-specific limits in the Blue Box, the Blue Box revenue program need only meet the overall Blue Box limit. As with the Amber Box comparison, the Blue Box comparison between the current programs and the proposed revenue programs shows substantial differences. The Blue Box revenue program would pay out every year, whereas the CCP program would pay out in 17 of the 25 years. Also, the CCP program is based on 85 percent of the current base acreage and yields. The Blue Box revenue program is based on 100 percent of an updated base

27 TABLE 11. Amber Box revenue support Year Wheat Oats Rice Cotton Corn Sorghum Peanut Soybean Barley Total ($ million) , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , Limit ,071 2, , ,600 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? / 25

28 / TABLE 12. Blue Box revenue support Year Wheat Oats Rice Cotton Corn Sorghum Peanut Soybean Barley Total ($ million) , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , / Babcock and Hart Limit 5,000

29 How Much Safety Is Available under the U.S. Proposal to the WTO? / 27 acreage (2004 planted acreage) and yields (expected county yields). And finally, the CCP program is a program that pays on a national scale; all producers qualify for a CCP payment at the same time. The Blue Box revenue program is a county-level program; only producers for which actual county revenue falls below the revenue guarantee qualify for a payment. Table 13 shows the prices covered under the revenue programs when the yield coverage is set to 100 percent. The Amber Box revenue program can protect a slightly higher price (α*effective Target Price) than the adjusted loan rate shown in Table 4. The Blue Box covered price (β*effective Target Price) is 5 percent below the effective target price (the target price less the direct payment rate) for the current CCP program. Again, the revenue program can protect a higher price than the effective target price for the CCP program after being adjusted to meet the WTO limits. Another way to compare the two approaches is to examine the payment streams under each. Figures 3 and 4 show the total payments under the current programs and the proposed revenue programs, respectively. The current programs have a much more variable payment stream. In fact, the coefficient of variation (the ratio of the standard deviation to the mean) is nearly twice as high under the current programs as it is for the revenue programs. The LDP and CCP programs would not pay anything in several of the TABLE 13. Supported prices under the revenue programs with α = 0.85 and β = 0.95 Crop Units α*effective Target Price β*effective Target Price Barley ($/bushel) Corn ($/bushel) Cotton ($/pound) Oats ($/bushel) Peanuts ($/pound) Rice ($/hundredweight) Sorghum ($/bushel) Soybeans ($/bushel) Wheat ($/bushel)

30 28 / Babcock and Hart FIGURE 3. Payment stream under the current LDP and CCP programs with adjusted target price and loan rates to meet U.S. proposal limits FIGURE 4. Payment stream under the proposed revenue programs

Loan Deficiency Payments versus Countercyclical Payments: Do We Need Both for a Price Safety Net?

Loan Deficiency Payments versus Countercyclical Payments: Do We Need Both for a Price Safety Net? CARD Briefing Papers CARD Reports and Working Papers 2-2005 Loan Deficiency Payments versus Countercyclical Payments: Do We Need Both for a Price Safety Net? Chad E. Hart Iowa State University, chart@iastate.edu

More information

Counter-Cyclical Agricultural Program Payments: Is It Time to Look at Revenue?

Counter-Cyclical Agricultural Program Payments: Is It Time to Look at Revenue? Counter-Cyclical Agricultural Program Payments: Is It Time to Look at Revenue? Chad E. Hart and Bruce A. Babcock Briefing Paper 99-BP 28 December 2000 Revised Center for Agricultural and Rural Development

More information

U.S. Farm Policy and the World Trade Organization: How Do They Match Up?

U.S. Farm Policy and the World Trade Organization: How Do They Match Up? U.S. Farm Policy and the World Trade Organization: How Do They Match Up? Chad E. Hart and Bruce A. Babcock Working Paper 02-WP 294 February 2002 Center for Agricultural and Rural Development Iowa State

More information

Construction of a Green Box Countercyclical Program

Construction of a Green Box Countercyclical Program Construction of a Green Box Countercyclical Program Bruce A. Babcock and Chad E. Hart Briefing Paper 1-BP 36 October 1 Center for Agricultural and Rural Development Iowa State University Ames, Iowa 511-17

More information

Loan Deficiency Payments or the Loan Program?

Loan Deficiency Payments or the Loan Program? Loan Deficiency Payments or the Loan Program? Dermot J. Hayes and Bruce A. Babcock Briefing Paper 98-BP 19 September 1998 Center for Agricultural and Rural Development Iowa State University Ames, Iowa

More information

ARPA Subsidies, Unit Choice, and Reform of the U.S. Crop Insurance Program

ARPA Subsidies, Unit Choice, and Reform of the U.S. Crop Insurance Program CARD Briefing Papers CARD Reports and Working Papers 2-2005 ARPA Subsidies, Unit Choice, and Reform of the U.S. Crop Insurance Program Bruce A. Babcock Iowa State University, babcock@iastate.edu Chad E.

More information

Implications of the WTO on the Redesign of U.S. Farm Policy

Implications of the WTO on the Redesign of U.S. Farm Policy Implications of the WTO on the Redesign of U.S. Farm Policy Chad E. Hart and Bruce A. Babcock Briefing Paper 01-BP 32 May 2001 Center for Agricultural and Rural Development Iowa State University Ames,

More information

The Potential Budgetary Costs and WTO Implications of the New Farm Bill. Joseph Glauber and Pat Westhoff

The Potential Budgetary Costs and WTO Implications of the New Farm Bill. Joseph Glauber and Pat Westhoff The Potential Budgetary Costs and WTO Implications of the New Farm Bill Joseph Glauber and Pat Westhoff Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the International Agricultural Trade Research Consortium

More information

Background Information

Background Information March 1998 Revised March 19, 1998 Statutory Authority Sections 131 through 136 of the Federal Agriculture Improvement and Reform Act of 1996 (1996 Act), P.L. 104-127 (7 USC 7231-7236) require that a nonrecourse

More information

AGEC 429: AGRICULTURAL POLICY LECTURE 19: ANALYSIS OF THE 2014 FARM BILL I

AGEC 429: AGRICULTURAL POLICY LECTURE 19: ANALYSIS OF THE 2014 FARM BILL I AGEC 429: AGRICULTURAL POLICY LECTURE 19: ANALYSIS OF THE 2014 FARM BILL I Background AGEC 429 Lecture #19 ANALYSIS OF THE 2014 FARM BILL I The Agricultural Act of 2014 Right after the 2008 Farm Bill passed,

More information

Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress

Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Œ œ Ÿ This report examines U.S. commodity subsidy programs against an emerging set of criteria that test their potential vulnerability to challenge in the

More information

CRS Report for Congress

CRS Report for Congress Order Code RS21604 Updated December 15, 2004 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Marketing Loans, Loan Deficiency Payments, and Commodity Certificates Summary Jim Monke Analyst in Agricultural

More information

Counter-Cyclical Farm Safety Nets

Counter-Cyclical Farm Safety Nets Counter-Cyclical Farm Safety Nets AFPC Issue Paper 01-1 James W. Richardson Steven L. Klose Edward G. Smith Agricultural and Food Policy Center Department of Agricultural Economics Texas Agricultural Experiment

More information

2002 FSRIA. Farm Security & Rural Investment Act. (2002 Farm Bill) How much money is spent with the United States Department of Agriculture (USDA)?

2002 FSRIA. Farm Security & Rural Investment Act. (2002 Farm Bill) How much money is spent with the United States Department of Agriculture (USDA)? 2002 FSRIA Farm Security & Rural Investment Act (2002 Farm Bill) Some general background: How much money is spent with the United States Department of Agriculture (USDA)? How much money is spent on farm

More information

Supplemental Revenue Assistance Payments Program (SURE): Montana

Supplemental Revenue Assistance Payments Program (SURE): Montana Supplemental Revenue Assistance Payments Program (SURE): Montana Agricultural Marketing Policy Center Linfield Hall P.O. Box 172920 Montana State University Bozeman, MT 59717-2920 Tel: (406) 994-3511 Fax:

More information

Aligning U.S. Farm Policy With World Trade Commitments Farm income support and trade programs

Aligning U.S. Farm Policy With World Trade Commitments Farm income support and trade programs 12 Economic Research Service/USDA Agricultural Outlook/January-February 2002 Green box support is the least trade distorting. As such, it is exempt from support reduction commitments and thus not included

More information

The 2014 U.S. Farm Bill: DDA Implications of Increased Countercyclical Support and Reliance on Insurance

The 2014 U.S. Farm Bill: DDA Implications of Increased Countercyclical Support and Reliance on Insurance IFPRI The 2014 U.S. Farm Bill: DDA Implications of Increased Countercyclical Support and Reliance on Insurance David Orden Presented at the EC DG Trade Workshop US farm policy and its implications on the

More information

2008 FARM BILL: FOCUS ON ACRE

2008 FARM BILL: FOCUS ON ACRE 2008 FARM BILL: FOCUS ON ACRE (Average Crop Revenue Election) Carl Zulauf Ag. Economist, Ohio State University Updated: October 3, 2008, Presented to USDA Economists Group 1 Seminar Outline 1. Provide

More information

The Common Crop (COMBO) Policy

The Common Crop (COMBO) Policy The Common Crop (COMBO) Policy Agricultural Marketing Policy Center Linfield Hall P.O. Box 172920 Montana State University Bozeman, MT 59717-2920 Tel: (406) 994-3511 Fax: (406) 994-4838 Email: ampc@montana.edu

More information

Estimating the Costs of MPCI Under the 1994 Crop Insurance Reform Act

Estimating the Costs of MPCI Under the 1994 Crop Insurance Reform Act CARD Working Papers CARD Reports and Working Papers 3-1996 Estimating the Costs of MPCI Under the 1994 Crop Insurance Reform Act Chad E. Hart Iowa State University, chart@iastate.edu Darnell B. Smith Iowa

More information

Taxpayers, Crop Insurance, of environmental working group U Street. NW, Suite 100 Washington, DC

Taxpayers, Crop Insurance, of environmental working group U Street. NW, Suite 100 Washington, DC Taxpayers, Crop Insurance, and the Drought of 2012 environmental working group April 2013 www.ewg.org 1436 U Street. NW, Suite 100 Washington, DC 20009 Contents 3 Preface 4 Full Report 5 Crop Insurance

More information

Farm Safety Net. Dr. Alejandro Plastina Assistant Professor, Economics

Farm Safety Net. Dr. Alejandro Plastina Assistant Professor, Economics Farm Safety Net Dr. Alejandro Plastina Assistant Professor, Economics Invited Presentation to the Professional Agriculture Workers Conference Organized by Tuskegee University Opelika, Alabama December

More information

THE FARM BILL AND THE WESTERN HAY INDUSTRY. Western States Alfalfa and Forage Symposium November 29, 2017 Reno, Nevada

THE FARM BILL AND THE WESTERN HAY INDUSTRY. Western States Alfalfa and Forage Symposium November 29, 2017 Reno, Nevada THE FARM BILL AND THE WESTERN HAY INDUSTRY Western States Alfalfa and Forage Symposium November 29, 2017 Reno, Nevada Daniel A. Sumner and William A. Matthews University of California Agricultural Issues

More information

GAO. U.S. DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE Marketing Assistance Loan Program Should Better Reflect Market Conditions

GAO. U.S. DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE Marketing Assistance Loan Program Should Better Reflect Market Conditions GAO November 1999 United States General Accounting Office Report to the Ranking Minority Member, Subcommittee on Forestry, Conservation, and Rural Revitalization, Committee on Agriculture, Nutrition, and

More information

Impacts of Linking Wheat Countercyclical Payments to Prices for Classes of Wheat

Impacts of Linking Wheat Countercyclical Payments to Prices for Classes of Wheat June 2007 #19-07 Staff Report Impacts of Linking Wheat Countercyclical Payments to Prices for Classes of Wheat www.fapri.missouri.edu (573) 882-3576 Providing objective analysis for over twenty years Published

More information

2014 Actual Average County Yield. times. higher of: Month Market Year Average Price or National Loan Rate 86% times

2014 Actual Average County Yield. times. higher of: Month Market Year Average Price or National Loan Rate 86% times Cotton Transition, Price Loss Coverage, County Agricultural Risk Coverage, and Individual Agricultural Risk Coverage Diagram for the 2014 Crop Year May 15, 2014 Step 1: Producers on a farm must make a

More information

Crop Insurance Rates and the Laws of Probability

Crop Insurance Rates and the Laws of Probability CARD Working Papers CARD Reports and Working Papers 4-2002 Crop Insurance Rates and the Laws of Probability Bruce A. Babcock Iowa State University, babcock@iastate.edu Chad E. Hart Iowa State University,

More information

12/14/2009. Goals Today. Introduction. Crop Insurance, the SURE Disaster Assistance Program, and Farm Risk Management

12/14/2009. Goals Today. Introduction. Crop Insurance, the SURE Disaster Assistance Program, and Farm Risk Management Crop Insurance, the SURE Disaster Assistance Program, and Farm Risk Management Rod M. Rejesus Assistant Professor and Extension Specialist Dept. of Ag. and Resource Economics NC State University Goals

More information

2014 Farm Bill How does it affect you and your operation? Section 1: Overview, Base Reallocation, and Yield Updates

2014 Farm Bill How does it affect you and your operation? Section 1: Overview, Base Reallocation, and Yield Updates 2014 Farm Bill How does it affect you and your operation? Section 1: Overview, Base Reallocation, and Yield Updates 1 Dr. Jason Fewell Assistant Professor Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics

More information

2014 Farm Bill Provisions and WTO Compliance

2014 Farm Bill Provisions and WTO Compliance 2014 Farm Bill Provisions and WTO Compliance Randy Schnepf Specialist in Agricultural Policy December 8, 2014 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov R43817 Summary The enacted 2014 farm bill

More information

The current basis for multilateral negotiations of global agricultural trade is

The current basis for multilateral negotiations of global agricultural trade is Domestic Support in Agriculture: The Struggle for Meaningful Disciplines Harry de Gorter and J. Daniel Cook 7 The current basis for multilateral negotiations of global agricultural trade is the July 2004

More information

Adjusted Gross Revenue Pilot Insurance Program: Rating Procedure (Report prepared for the Risk Management Agency Board of Directors) J.

Adjusted Gross Revenue Pilot Insurance Program: Rating Procedure (Report prepared for the Risk Management Agency Board of Directors) J. Staff Paper Adjusted Gross Revenue Pilot Insurance Program: Rating Procedure (Report prepared for the Risk Management Agency Board of Directors) J. Roy Black Staff Paper 2000-51 December, 2000 Department

More information

Farm Bill Details and Decisions

Farm Bill Details and Decisions Farm Bill Details and Decisions Bradley D. Lubben, Ph.D. Extension Assistant Professor, Policy Specialist, and Director, North Central Extension Risk Management Education Center Department of Agricultural

More information

Should Basic Underwriting Rules be Applied to Average Crop Revenue Election and Supplemental Revenue?

Should Basic Underwriting Rules be Applied to Average Crop Revenue Election and Supplemental Revenue? Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, 42,3(August 2010):517 535 Ó 2010 Southern Agricultural Economics Association Should Basic Underwriting Rules be Applied to Average Crop Revenue Election and

More information

AFPC Crop Decision Aids Data Collection Form and Instructions

AFPC Crop Decision Aids Data Collection Form and Instructions AFPC Crop Decision Aids Data Collection Form and Instructions Use the form on the last page of this document to collect the data needed to enter for the AFPC Decision Aid. Use one data form for each farm

More information

NGFA Country Elevator Conference St. Louis, Missouri Dec. 9, 2013

NGFA Country Elevator Conference St. Louis, Missouri Dec. 9, 2013 Pat Westhoff (westhoffp@missouri.edu) Director, Food and Agricultural Policy Research Institute Professor, Agricultural and Applied Economics University of Missouri www.fapri.missouri.edu NGFA Country

More information

Valuing Counter-Cyclical Payments

Valuing Counter-Cyclical Payments United States Department of Agriculture Economic Research Service Economic Research Report Number 39 Valuing Counter-Cyclical Payments Implications for Producer Risk Management and Program Administration

More information

Farm Bill Details and Decisions

Farm Bill Details and Decisions Farm Bill Details and Decisions Bradley D. Lubben, Ph.D. Extension Assistant Professor, Policy Specialist, and Director, North Central Extension Risk Management Education Center Department of Agricultural

More information

Farm Safety Net Programs: Issues for the Next Farm Bill

Farm Safety Net Programs: Issues for the Next Farm Bill Farm Safety Net Programs: Issues for the Next Farm Bill Dennis A. Shields Specialist in Agricultural Policy Jim Monke Specialist in Agricultural Policy Randy Schnepf Specialist in Agricultural Policy September

More information

Presentation Outline

Presentation Outline The Current and Future Farm Policy Outlook for Corn and Soybeans Joe L. Outlaw Professor & Extension Economist Co-Director, AFPC Minnesota Crop Insurance Conference Mankato, MN September 12, 2013 Presentation

More information

Reinsuring Group Revenue Insurance with. Exchange-Provided Revenue Contracts. Bruce A. Babcock, Dermot J. Hayes, and Steven Griffin

Reinsuring Group Revenue Insurance with. Exchange-Provided Revenue Contracts. Bruce A. Babcock, Dermot J. Hayes, and Steven Griffin Reinsuring Group Revenue Insurance with Exchange-Provided Revenue Contracts Bruce A. Babcock, Dermot J. Hayes, and Steven Griffin CARD Working Paper 99-WP 212 Center for Agricultural and Rural Development

More information

Economic Aspects of Revenue- Based Commodity Support

Economic Aspects of Revenue- Based Commodity Support United States Department of Agriculture Economic Research Service Economic Research Report Number 72 Economic Aspects of Revenue- Based Commodity Support Joseph Cooper April 2009 ww w o Visit Our Website

More information

Farm Bill and Texas A&M Computer Training. Nebraska Innovation Campus Conference Center January 14, 2015

Farm Bill and Texas A&M Computer Training. Nebraska Innovation Campus Conference Center January 14, 2015 Farm Bill and Texas A&M Computer Training Nebraska Innovation Campus Conference Center January 14, 2015 Farm Bill Details and Decisions Bradley D. Lubben, Ph.D. Extension Assistant Professor, Policy Specialist,

More information

How Long Will Commodity Prices Remain High?

How Long Will Commodity Prices Remain High? CARD Policy Briefs CARD Reports and Working Papers 5-2013 How Long Will Commodity Prices Remain High? Dermot J. Hayes Iowa State University, dhayes@iastate.edu Lisha Li Iowa State University, lisa1107@iastate.edu

More information

RISK MANAGEMENT AND THE NEW 2014 FARM BILL

RISK MANAGEMENT AND THE NEW 2014 FARM BILL RISK MANAGEMENT AND THE NEW 2014 FARM BILL Paul D. Mitchell Associate Professor, Ag and Applied Economics March 11, 2014 Email pdmitchell@wisc.edu Office: 608-265-6514 http://www.aae.wisc.edu/pdmitchell/extension.htm

More information

A TAX INCENTIVE FOR CERTIFIED SEED: A BROADER ASSESSMENT

A TAX INCENTIVE FOR CERTIFIED SEED: A BROADER ASSESSMENT A TAX INCENTIVE FOR CERTIFIED SEED: A BROADER ASSESSMENT Prepared for: Canadian Seed Trade Association Attention: Patty Townsend Vice President (613) 829-9527 ptownsend@cdnseed.org Prepared by: Al Mussell,

More information

Crop Insurance and Disaster Assistance

Crop Insurance and Disaster Assistance Crop Insurance and Disaster Assistance Joy Harwood, Economic Research Service, USDA James L. Novak, Auburn University Background The 1996 Federal Agricultural Improvement and Reform (FAIR) Act implemented

More information

INTERNATIONAL COTTON ADVISORY COMMITTEE

INTERNATIONAL COTTON ADVISORY COMMITTEE INTERNATIONAL COTTON ADVISORY COMMITTEE Standing Committee Attachment III to SC-N-493 Washington, DC May 12, 2008 Government Support to the Cotton Industry Direct government subsidies currently provided

More information

11/14/2011. Bradley D. Lubben, Ph.D. Special thanks to: Federal Budget. Economy Farm & General Economy. Politics. Super Committee (more politics)

11/14/2011. Bradley D. Lubben, Ph.D. Special thanks to: Federal Budget. Economy Farm & General Economy. Politics. Super Committee (more politics) John Deering Agriculture and Specialist Colorado State University Extension Special thanks to: Bradley D. Lubben, Ph.D. Extension Assistant Professor, Policy Specialist t& Director, North Central Risk

More information

Agricultural Act of 2014

Agricultural Act of 2014 Farm Bill Cash Flow 2017 Outlook Conference for Agricultural Lenders Grand Forks Oct. 16 Fargo Oct. 31 Andrew Swenson Extension Farm Management Specialist Department of Agribusiness and Applied Economics

More information

Farm Bill Details and Decisions for 2014

Farm Bill Details and Decisions for 2014 Farm Bill Details and Decisions for 2014 Bradley D. Lubben, Ph.D. Extension Assistant Professor, Policy Specialist, and Director, North Central Risk Management Education Center Department of Agricultural

More information

Agricultural Risk Coverage County (ARC CO) vs. Price Loss Coverage (PLC)

Agricultural Risk Coverage County (ARC CO) vs. Price Loss Coverage (PLC) Agricultural Risk Coverage County (ARC CO) vs. Price Loss Coverage (PLC) Carl Zulauf, Ohio State University, November 2014 The 2014 farm bill gives Farm Service Agency (FSA) farms a 1 time opportunity

More information

Farm Bill Details and Decisions

Farm Bill Details and Decisions Farm Bill Details and Decisions Bradley D. Lubben, Ph.D. Extension Assistant Professor, Policy Specialist, and Director, North Central Risk Management Education Center Department of Agricultural Economics

More information

Commodity Programs in 2014 Farm Bill. Key Provisions

Commodity Programs in 2014 Farm Bill. Key Provisions Commodity Programs in 2014 Farm Bill Gary Schnitkey, Jonathan Coppess, Nick Paulson, and Carl Zulauf University of Illinois The Ohio State University (February 13, 2014) 1 Key Provisions Eliminates direct,

More information

Farm Policy: 2012 and Beyond

Farm Policy: 2012 and Beyond Farm Policy: 2012 and Beyond Carl Zulauf (Zulauf.1@osu.edu) Ag. Economist, Ohio State University December 3, 2012 Dean s Outlook Meeting Columbus, OH Outline Current Status of Farm Bill Process Shallow

More information

2014 FARM BILL COMMODITY PROGRAMS AND DECISION TOOLS

2014 FARM BILL COMMODITY PROGRAMS AND DECISION TOOLS 2014 FARM BILL COMMODITY PROGRAMS AND DECISION TOOLS Dr. Jody Campiche Dr. Eric DeVuyst OSU Extension Commodity Programs FSA Option to Reallocate Base Owners Option to Update Yields Owners Crop Insurance

More information

Pat Westhoff FAPRI-MU, University of Missouri

Pat Westhoff FAPRI-MU, University of Missouri Agricultural Lender meetings Dexter and Sikeston, MO December 1, 214 Pat Westhoff (westhoffp@missouri.edu) FAPRI-MU, University of Missouri www.fapri.missouri.edu Eliminates many existing farm programs

More information

The federal crop insurance program is ripe for reform: TWO CHANGES TO CROP INSURANCE TO IMPROVE EQUITY AND EFFICIENCY

The federal crop insurance program is ripe for reform: TWO CHANGES TO CROP INSURANCE TO IMPROVE EQUITY AND EFFICIENCY CONTENTS Introduction 1 Means-Testing Crop Insurance Subsidies 1 How Crop Insurance is Subsidized 2 The Crop Insurance Industry s Position 3 Impacts of Limiting Premium Subsidies 3 Eliminating Subsidies

More information

Risk Management Agency Dave Schumann

Risk Management Agency Dave Schumann Risk Management Agency Dave Schumann History In 1938 the Federal Crop Insurance Corporation, or FCIC, was created. In 1980, the FCIC act was amended to expand to all states and primary field crops. This

More information

Looking Out for the 2012 Farm Bill

Looking Out for the 2012 Farm Bill Looking Out for the 2012 Farm Bill, Ph.D. Extension Assistant Professor, Policy Specialist, and Director, North Central Risk Management Education Center Department of Agricultural Economics UNL Farm Bill

More information

Allan Gray and Luc Valentin. Purdue University

Allan Gray and Luc Valentin. Purdue University The 2008 Farm Bill Allan Gray and Luc Valentin Department of Agricultural Economics Purdue University Farm Bill Timeline May 13, 2002 Farm Security and Rural Investment Act of 2002 enacted. Commodity Futures

More information

The Economics of ARC vs. PLC

The Economics of ARC vs. PLC University of Nebraska - Lincoln DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln Cornhusker Economics Agricultural Economics Department 2-4-2015 The Economics of ARC vs. PLC Bradley D. Lubben University

More information

FACT SHEET. Fundamentally, risk management. A Primer on Crop Insurance AGRICULTURE & NATURAL RESOURCES JAN 2016 COLLEGE OF

FACT SHEET. Fundamentally, risk management. A Primer on Crop Insurance AGRICULTURE & NATURAL RESOURCES JAN 2016 COLLEGE OF COLLEGE OF AGRICULTURE & NATURAL RESOURCES FACT SHEET DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURAL AND RESOURCE ECONOMICS JAN 2016 A Primer on Crop Insurance Most crop insurance takes one of two forms: yield insurance pays

More information

Farm Level Impacts of a Revenue Based Policy in the 2007 Farm Bill

Farm Level Impacts of a Revenue Based Policy in the 2007 Farm Bill Farm Level Impacts of a Revenue Based Policy in the 27 Farm Bill Lindsey M. Higgins, James W. Richardson, Joe L. Outlaw, and J. Marc Raulston Department of Agricultural Economics Texas A&M University College

More information

Current Crop Insurance and Federal Policy Situation

Current Crop Insurance and Federal Policy Situation Current Crop Insurance and Federal Policy Situation Mil. acres Participation Growth 1981-2012 326 mil Premium support, then 2000 Act 1 1 % Source: USDA/RMA Summary of Business Percent of Total Premium

More information

The Agriculture Risk Coverage (ARC) Program of the 2014 Farm Bill

The Agriculture Risk Coverage (ARC) Program of the 2014 Farm Bill Staff Report No. 2014-11 July 2014 The Agriculture Risk Coverage () Program of the 2014 Farm Bill Michael A. Deliberto and Michael E. Salassi Department of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness Louisiana

More information

Discussion: What Have We Learned from the New Suite of Risk Management Programs of the Food, Conservation, and Energy Act of 2008?

Discussion: What Have We Learned from the New Suite of Risk Management Programs of the Food, Conservation, and Energy Act of 2008? Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, 42,3(August 2010):537 541 Ó 2010 Southern Agricultural Economics Association Discussion: What Have We Learned from the New Suite of Risk Management Programs

More information

Wyoming Barley Production: Opportunities to Manage Production, Quality and Revenue Risks

Wyoming Barley Production: Opportunities to Manage Production, Quality and Revenue Risks Wyoming Barley Production: Opportunities to Manage Production, Quality and Revenue Risks Agricultural Marketing Policy Center Linfield Hall P.O. Box 172920 Montana State University Bozeman, MT 59717-2920

More information

Seed Cotton Informational Meeting. Price Loss Coverage Program (PLC)

Seed Cotton Informational Meeting. Price Loss Coverage Program (PLC) Seed Cotton Informational Meeting Price Loss Coverage Program (PLC) PLC Overview PLC is an Income Support Program PLC payments are not dependent upon planting of the crop PLC is the default program election

More information

Delayed and Prevented Planting Provisions for Multiple Peril Crop Insurance

Delayed and Prevented Planting Provisions for Multiple Peril Crop Insurance Delayed and Prevented Planting Provisions for Multiple Peril Crop Insurance Most crop producers know that to achieve optimum yields it is important to plant early. Once the danger of a frost is past, the

More information

Farm Safety Net Provisions in a 2013 Farm Bill: S. 954 and H.R. 2642

Farm Safety Net Provisions in a 2013 Farm Bill: S. 954 and H.R. 2642 Farm Safety Net Provisions in a 2013 Farm Bill: S. 954 and H.R. 2642 Dennis A. Shields Specialist in Agricultural Policy Randy Schnepf Specialist in Agricultural Policy July 24, 2013 Congressional Research

More information

2014 Farm Bill Update. International Crop Expo February 19, 2015

2014 Farm Bill Update. International Crop Expo February 19, 2015 2014 Farm Bill Update International Crop Expo February 19, 2015 Decisions Operators and Owners Need to Make Yield Update Base Reallocation Choice of Safety Net Yield Update Everyone should attempt to update

More information

Title: The Economic Welfare Impacts of the new Agricultural Insurance and Shallow Loss Programs

Title: The Economic Welfare Impacts of the new Agricultural Insurance and Shallow Loss Programs Title: The Economic Welfare Impacts of the new Agricultural Insurance and Shallow Loss Programs Authors: Vincent H. Smith, Anton Bekkerman. Affiliations: Vincent Smith is a professor in the Department

More information

Farm Bill Principles and Commodity Program Proposals: A View from the House

Farm Bill Principles and Commodity Program Proposals: A View from the House Farm Bill Principles and Commodity Program Proposals: A View from the House A Presentation by Craig Jagger Chief Economist, Majority Staff House Committee on Agriculture Concurrent Session: Farm Policy

More information

Farm Safety Net Programs: Background and Issues

Farm Safety Net Programs: Background and Issues Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR Federal Publications Key Workplace Documents 8-21-2015 Farm Safety Net Programs: Background and Issues Dennis A. Shields Congressional Research Service

More information

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web

CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Order Code RS21642 October 14, 2003 Comparing Quota Buyout Payments for Peanuts and Tobacco Summary Jasper Womach Specialist in Agricultural Policy

More information

Marketing Assistance Loans, Loan Deficiency Payments and Marketing Loan Gains for Minor Oilseed and Pulse Crops

Marketing Assistance Loans, Loan Deficiency Payments and Marketing Loan Gains for Minor Oilseed and Pulse Crops Marketing Assistance Loans, Loan Deficiency Payments and Marketing Loan Gains for Minor Oilseed and Pulse Crops James B. Johnson Objective Analysis for Informed Decision Making Agricultural Marketing Policy

More information

Owning or operating corn Base Acres makes you eligible for corn direct payment No trigger for corn DP, just own or operate

Owning or operating corn Base Acres makes you eligible for corn direct payment No trigger for corn DP, just own or operate AAE 320 Spring 2012 Final Exam Name: 1) (20 pts. total, 2 pts. each) True or False? Mark your answer. a) T F Wisconsin s cranberry industry may be important in the state, but nationally it ranks quite

More information

Optimal Crop Insurance Options for Alabama Cotton-Peanut Producers: A Target-MOTAD Analysis

Optimal Crop Insurance Options for Alabama Cotton-Peanut Producers: A Target-MOTAD Analysis Optimal Crop Insurance Options for Alabama Cotton-Peanut Producers: A Target-MOTAD Analysis Marina Irimia-Vladu Graduate Research Assistant Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology Auburn

More information

Farm Bill Meeting Stoddard County

Farm Bill Meeting Stoddard County Farm Bill Meeting Stoddard County David Reinbott Agriculture Business Specialist P.O. Box 187 Benton, MO 63736 (573) 545-3516 http://extension.missouri.edu/scott/agriculture.aspx reinbottd@missouri.edu

More information

REPORTING PERIOD: Marketing Year Current Total Aggregate Measurement of Support

REPORTING PERIOD: Marketing Year Current Total Aggregate Measurement of Support Table DS:1 DOMESTIC SUPPORT: United States REPORTING PERIOD: Marketing Year 2012 Current Total Aggregate Measurement of Support Total AMS commitment level for period in question Currency Current Total

More information

Price-Risk Management in Grain Marketing

Price-Risk Management in Grain Marketing Price-Risk Management in Grain Marketing for North Carolina, South Carolina, and Georgia Nicholas E. Piggott George A. Shumaker, Charles E. Curtis Jr. North Carolina State University University of Georgia

More information

AGEC 429: AGRICULTURAL POLICY LECTURE 18: ANALYSIS OF PAST FARM BILL PROGRAMS III

AGEC 429: AGRICULTURAL POLICY LECTURE 18: ANALYSIS OF PAST FARM BILL PROGRAMS III AGEC 429: AGRICULTURAL POLICY LECTURE 18: ANALYSIS OF PAST FARM BILL PROGRAMS III AGEC 429 Lecture #18 ANALYSIS OF PAST FARM BILL PROGRAMS III Food Conservation and Energy Act (FCEA) of 2008 Background

More information

Estimated ARC and PLC Payments for 2016 Covered Commodities

Estimated ARC and PLC Payments for 2016 Covered Commodities AGECON-17-01 July 2017 Estimated ARC and PLC Payments for 2016 Covered Commodities Don Shurley and Adam N. Rabinowitz Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics University of Georgia The 2014 farm

More information

4Q 2017 Earnings Call. 22 November 2017

4Q 2017 Earnings Call. 22 November 2017 4Q 2017 Earnings Call 22 November 2017 1 Safe Harbor Statement & Disclosures The earnings call and accompanying material include forward-looking comments and information concerning the company s plans

More information

Eligibility: own or operate Base Acres. No trigger except owning /operating Base Acres.

Eligibility: own or operate Base Acres. No trigger except owning /operating Base Acres. AAE 320 Spring 2013 Final Exam Name: KEY 1) (20 pts. total, 2 pts. each) True or False? Mark your answer. a) T F Wisconsin s vegetable processing industry (green beans, sweet corn, potatoes) may be important

More information

Grain Stocks. Corn Stocks Up 11 Percent from March 2014 Soybean Stocks Up 34 Percent All Wheat Stocks Up 6 Percent

Grain Stocks. Corn Stocks Up 11 Percent from March 2014 Soybean Stocks Up 34 Percent All Wheat Stocks Up 6 Percent Grain Stocks ISSN: 1949-0925 Released March 31, 2015, by the National Agricultural Statistics Service (NASS), Agricultural Statistics Board, United s Department of Agriculture (USDA). Corn Stocks Up 11

More information

COMMENT ON THE EC-US JOINT PAPER ON AGRICULTURE IN WTO. By Martin Khor, Third World Network 14 August 2003

COMMENT ON THE EC-US JOINT PAPER ON AGRICULTURE IN WTO. By Martin Khor, Third World Network 14 August 2003 COMMENT ON THE EC-US JOINT PAPER ON AGRICULTURE IN WTO By Martin Khor, Third World Network 14 August 2003 1. GENERAL On 13 August the EC and US presented a joint Text on agriculture. It is meant to be

More information

GIVING IT AWAY FREE FREE CROP INSURANCE CAN SAVE MONEY AND STRENGTHEN THE FARM SAFETY NET

GIVING IT AWAY FREE FREE CROP INSURANCE CAN SAVE MONEY AND STRENGTHEN THE FARM SAFETY NET GIVING IT AWAY FREE FREE CROP INSURANCE CAN SAVE MONEY AND STRENGTHEN THE FARM SAFETY NET by Bruce Babcock Professor of Economics, Iowa State University Preface by Craig Cox Senior VP for Agriculture and

More information

u.s. FARM PROGRAM AND ITS 1988 PROVISIONS A Brief Explanation of the Basic Features Related to Grains and Soybeans HARVEY L. KISER

u.s. FARM PROGRAM AND ITS 1988 PROVISIONS A Brief Explanation of the Basic Features Related to Grains and Soybeans HARVEY L. KISER ,po Ytt:;:;. (0 u.s. FARM PROGRAM AND ITS 1988 PROVISIONS A Brief Explanation of the Basic Features Related to Grains and Soybeans HARVEY L. KISER APRIL 1988 No. 88-10 L Kansas State University..,... Department

More information

The Viability of a Crop Insurance Investment Account: The Case for Obion, County, Tennessee. Delton C. Gerloff, University of Tennessee

The Viability of a Crop Insurance Investment Account: The Case for Obion, County, Tennessee. Delton C. Gerloff, University of Tennessee The Viability of a Crop Insurance Investment Account: The Case for Obion, County, Tennessee Delton C. Gerloff, University of Tennessee Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the Southern Agricultural

More information

Agricultural Disaster Assistance

Agricultural Disaster Assistance University of Nebraska - Lincoln DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln Congressional Research Service Reports Congressional Research Service 2010 Agricultural Disaster Assistance Dennis A. Shields

More information

( ) Page: 1/26 NOTIFICATION. Revision

( ) Page: 1/26 NOTIFICATION. Revision G/AG/N/USA/00/Rev. February 07 (7-067) Page: /6 Committee on Agriculture Original: English NOTIFICATION Revision The following submission, dated December 06, is being circulated at the request of the Delegation

More information

2014 Farm Bill How does it affect you and your operation? Section II: PLC, SCO, ARC-C, and ARC-I

2014 Farm Bill How does it affect you and your operation? Section II: PLC, SCO, ARC-C, and ARC-I 1 2014 Farm Bill How does it affect you and your operation? Section II: PLC, SCO, ARC-C, and ARC-I 2014 Farm Bill: PLC, SCO, ARC-C, and ARC-I Dr. Aaron Smith Assistant Professor: Row Crop Marketing Specialist

More information

Farm Bill Meeting Scott County

Farm Bill Meeting Scott County Farm Bill Meeting Scott County David Reinbott Agriculture Business Specialist P.O. Box 187 Benton, MO 63736 (573) 545-3516 http://extension.missouri.edu/scott/agriculture.aspx reinbottd@missouri.edu 1.

More information

2014 FARM BILL DECISION AID

2014 FARM BILL DECISION AID USING THE WEB-BASED 2014 FARM BILL DECISION AID DATA COLLECTION FORM AND INSTRUCTIONS Use the form on the last page of this document to collect the data that you will need to enter to use the decision

More information

AAE 320 Spring 2013 Final Exam Name: 1) (20 pts. total, 2 pts. each) 2) (17 pts. total) 2a) (3 pts.) 2b) (3 pts.)

AAE 320 Spring 2013 Final Exam Name: 1) (20 pts. total, 2 pts. each) 2) (17 pts. total) 2a) (3 pts.) 2b) (3 pts.) AAE 320 Spring 2013 Final Exam Name: 1) (20 pts. total, 2 pts. each) True or False? Mark your answer. a) T F Wisconsin s vegetable processing industry (green beans, sweet corn, potatoes) may be important

More information

( ) Page: 1/10 TARIFF IMPLEMENTATION ISSUES COMMUNICATION FROM THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA

( ) Page: 1/10 TARIFF IMPLEMENTATION ISSUES COMMUNICATION FROM THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA 4 June 2014 (14-3252) Page: 1/10 Committee on Agriculture Original: English TARIFF IMPLEMENTATION ISSUES COMMUNICATION FROM THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA The following communication, received on 3 June

More information

National Crop Insurance Services

National Crop Insurance Services National Crop Insurance Services FEBRUARY 15, 2016 BRANDON WILLIS, ADMINISTRATOR USDA RISK MANAGEMENT AGENCY Market Penetration Crop Category Item 1990 2000 2011 2014 Principle Crops*** NASS Acres* 246,527,700

More information

2018 Farm Bill Economic Principles and Policy Challenges

2018 Farm Bill Economic Principles and Policy Challenges 2018 Farm Bill Economic Principles and Policy Challenges Bradley D. Lubben Ph.D. Extension Associate Professor, Policy Specialist, Faculty Fellow, Rural Futures Institute, and Director, North Central Extension

More information