Debt and Consumption in The United Kingdom After The Crisis

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Debt and Consumption in The United Kingdom After The Crisis"

Transcription

1 Debt and Consumption in The United Kingdom After The Crisis Agnes Kovacs, May Rostom, Phil Bunn Preliminary - Do not circulate without authors permission: 4 Sept 2016 Abstract This paper investigates the relationship between mortgage leverage and consumption growth around the 2008 financial crisis. Using data from the UK s Family Expenditure Survey (FES), we first show that more indebted households made larger cuts to consumption following the financial crisis, and that this was largely driven by younger households. Second, using a life-cycle framework, we investigate the channels by which highly indebted households may have reduced consumption by more than other groups. Our key finding is that our empirical observation is most likely driven by income shocks at 2008 as well as the increased uncertainty around labor income after 2008, the effect of which varies depending on the size of household leverage. Keywords: life-cycle models, consumption, household leverage, debt, financial crisis JEL classification: D10; D11; D14; E21 Kovacs: University of Oxford; Rostom: University College London and Bank of England; Bunn: Bank of England. The authors would like to thank Orazio Attanasio, Richard Blundell, Antonio Guarino and Lars Nesheim for helpful comments and advice on this paper. Any views expressed are solely those of the author(s) and so cannot be taken to represent those of the Bank of England or to state Bank of England policy. This paper does not necessarily represent the views of the Bank of England or members of the Monetary Policy Committee or Financial Policy Committee. All errors are our own. 1

2 1 Introduction The 2008/2009 financial crisis in the UK has been characterized by a large drop in household consumption 1 and mortgage takeout at the same time. In this paper we focus on understanding how mortgage status affects households consumption behavior in the recent crisis. Using household-level data from the UK s Family Expenditure Survey (FES), we first show in our empirical model that households with a mortgage cut their consumption by more than households with no mortgage. In aggregate, we calculate that almost half of the fall in household consumption in 2009/10 was due to households who had a mortgage. Moreover, the higher the household s mortgage to income ratio (leverage) going into the crisis, the more they cut consumption afterward. In summary, households with higher levels of leverage contributed to the weakness in consumption growth more than households with lower levels of leverage. Having documented these empirical observations, we then simulate a life-cycle model with a realistic mortgage market in order to get a better understanding of the different mechanisms that drive indebted households to cut their consumption by more than other households after the 2008 crisis. Following Alan, Crossley, and Low (2012) we consider four definitions of what recession may have meant for households: a fall in the level of income, rising uncertainty around future income, a reduction in the supply of credit and a decline in house prices. The first channel works through a negative shock to income. When households face a fall in their income level, they cut back their consumption. But the size of the cutback would differ across households depending, among other things, on where they are in their life-cycle. Young households, for example, have typically had bigger falls in their income during the Great Recession than older households (they were more likely to be made unemployed). They also tend to have higher levels of secured debt than middle-aged households. If they are in a commitment contract to continue making mortgage payments, one may observe a bigger cut in consumption for these highly indebted households, as they substitute away from consumption towards meeting their mortgage obligations. The second channel plays a role when the recession is associated with higher uncertainty around future income. As uncertainty increases, households increase their precautionary savings, hence consuming less. Again, depending on where the households are at their life-cycle and consequently what their leverage is they could behave quantitatively very differently. 1 Throughout the paper, we use the term household consumption for households non-housing consumption 2

3 The third channel works through an exogenous reduction in the supply of credit. Since the crisis, banks decreased the acceptable leverages significantly, which made it increasingly difficult for households to finance consumption from topping up mortgages. This change may affect highly indebted households the most, since they are not able to withdraw additional equity from their housing at all 2. Therefore, their consumption may fall by much more than other households. The final channel we consider is a fall in house prices, which is very similar to the credit supply channel. As house prices fall, mortgagors face a reduction in their housing wealth, which increases their loan-to-value (LTV) ratios. This rise in leverage would lead to a decline in consumption in two different ways. First, in the event that the household needs to refinance (e.g. because they are moving house), they would be faced with much higher mortgage payments. To keep up with these higher payments, they would have to reduce their consumption. Second, heavily leveraged households would be unable to withdraw additional equity from their house that they would have used to maintain a certain level of consumption. As a result, heavily leveraged households may have to decrease their consumption by more than other households. Our focus is on how the differences in consumption cuts between high and lowleveraged households can be explained with the mechanisms detailed above. Using simulations we show that the observed pattern of consumption drops in the recent recession is best explained by a model in which the recession is associated either with a permanent income shock or an income uncertainty shock. Models with recessions led by a fall in credit supply or a fall in house prices do not predict differences in consumption behavior between high and low-leveraged households. The literature only has a limited number of papers analyzing the relationship between mortgages and consumption behavior. Dynan (2012) uses household level data to show that households with high leverages have experienced larger declines in spending between 2007 and 2009, after controlling for wealth effects and other factors. Mian, Rao, and Sufi (2013) show that the decline in US consumption following the crisis was greater in counties with higher leverage prior to the crisis. Baker (2013) finds that spending by highly indebted households has been more sensitive to income fluctuations and that is likely to have increased the depth of the recent recession. In the empirical sections we give detailed empirical evidence for the relationship between mortgage status and the consumption reaction of households to the 2008 crisis. More specifically we show that households with higher debt experience a much bigger drop in their consumption over the period of the crisis. This is the feature of the data which we would like to understand better. In our life-cycle model, we attempt to find 2 It would also affect first time buyers. Whereas before the crisis, first time buyers only needed to save 5% of the value of the house, the required down-payments increased significantly after the crisis. 3

4 the main driving forces behind the difference in households consumption reactions over the crisis. In order to do so, we develop a dynamic structural model, which can be used for testing the existence of these different channels. 4

5 2 Consumption Growth and Leverage Aggregate consumption data from the Office of National Statistics (ONS) show that household spending was growing at an annual rate of 3.5% per year in the decade running up to the crisis before collapsing in 2008, remaining at below historical averages until recently (Figure 1). Figure 1: Annual growth in household spending Yet these aggregate data mask a large degree of heterogeneity across households. In Figure 2 we plot annual consumption growth for households with different housing tenures. Figure 2: Non-housing consumption growth The green line plots owner occupiers (with no mortgage debt); the yellow line plots households who have mortgage debt of less than twice their income; and the navy line plots households who have a high mortgage debt to income ratio of two or more. While 5

6 households across different types of home ownership reduced their consumption, the biggest adjustment came from those with a mortgage debt to income ratios above two. Our goal in this paper is to understand Figure 2 better, understand the mechanisms that lead high-leveraged households to cut their consumption by much more than lowleveraged ones. In this and the following section we focus on a deeper empirical analysis of the data available. 2.1 Data We use data from the Family Expenditure Survey (FES), a micro dataset containing detailed information on household expenditure of 5,000 to 6,000 households per year. A two-week expenditure diary accompanies the questionnaire. It therefore provides the best household-level consumption data in the United Kingdom. The FES also contains information on outstanding levels of mortgage debt from However, our main analysis predominantly covers the pre and post Great Recession period, i.e. from We focus on households of working age, where the head is aged between 21 and 69. Waves of the FES also switch between calendar and fiscal year collection multiple times, so to maintain consistency, we convert all data to calendar years. We use weekly non-housing expenditure as our measure of consumption because the methodology for calculating housing consumption in the FES is not consistent with that used in the National Accounts. For homeowners, the FES only measures mortgage payments rather than using a measure of imputed rents like that of the National Accounts. All data are deflated using the National Accounts consumption deflator. We focus only on secured debt as the FES has, at best, only scant data on unsecured debt. As secured debt accounts for the majority (80%) of all debt, we would not expect excluding unsecured debt to change the big picture results. The Survey contains no information on assets. To address this, we merge the FES with data from the Wealth and Assets Survey (WAS) at the cohort level. The WAS is a panel survey covering 20-30,000 households in each wave. The survey began in 2006 and has three waves available: Wave 1 from mid to mid-2008, Wave 2 from mid-2008 to mid-2010 and Wave 3 from mid-2010 to mid Specifically, we merge in mean values of real housing wealth and real gross non-housing financial wealth (excluding deposits). Unfortunately, the FES are an annual time-series of cross-sections, meaning we cannot control for individual-level heterogeneity or track changes over time. Instead, we 3 While the time periods from the WAS wave do not exactly match the calendar time periods in our analysis, they nonetheless provide a reasonable approximation, given that assets tend to change slowly. Using data from part of a WAS wave risks the data not being fully representative. 6

7 construct a synthetic panel, using date of birth, as first suggested in Deaton (1985b) and in line with what others using the FES have done in the past (see Attanasio and Weber (1994), Attanasio, Banks, and Tanner (2002), or Campbell and Cocco (2007) as examples). This method allows us to condition debt at its pre-crisis levels and to track changes in consumption over time, but it comes at the expense of reducing the degree of heterogeneity that are otherwise available at the household level. When converting data into a synthetic panel, there exists a trade-off between the number of cohorts and the number of data points to create each cohort observation. A greater number of cohorts increases the degree of heterogeneity within the dataset, but uses fewer data points to create each cohort observation, reducing the reliability of those estimates. Vice versa, fewer cohorts mean less variation between cohorts, but more reliable cohort level estimates. [do we need this paragraph?] Firstly, we pool two years together when defining pre and post crisis periods. We define as the pre-crisis period and as the post crisis year (we later extend the analysis to too). This pooling makes the time periods of the data more comparable to the WAS waves, where each wave also spans two years. It also allows us to increase the number of data points used to create each cohort level data point. Secondly, we use three different cohort definitions to ensure the reliability of our results. The first definition uses single birth-year cohorts. For example, everybody born in 1956 belongs to one cohort. Birth years are the cleanest definition of a cohort because it is a deterministic variable: people cannot move between different cohorts over time. However, they also combine people with and without mortgage debt making it harder to identify the relationship between debt and spending decisions. To discriminate between groups that do and do not have a mortgage, we consider a second cohort definition, splitting each birth year by mortgage status. The third definition also splits the sample by mortgage status but pools birth years into 5-year buckets. This definition allows the mean number of observations in each bucket to be larger than in the second definition - creating less volatility in the mean values - but it comes at the expense of having fewer observations in total. The main disadvantage of the second and third cohort definitions is that the sample is split by mortgage status, a choice variable (one decides whether or not to buy a house). The results may suffer from selection bias. We discuss our approach to dealing with this in Section??. 7

8 2.2 Descriptive Statistics The amount of debt a household have vary over their life-cycle. Households tend to accumulate debt when young converting them to assets as they age. Even so, there are changes over time and across different generations driven by factors such as rapid changes in house prices, the availability of cheap credit or macroeconomic factors, such as GDP growth. As levels of debt are negatively correlated with age, one might expect that younger households may be the predominant drivers of the navy line in Figure 2. For this reason, it is important to examine how debt, income and consumption have evolved over the life-cycle for different birth cohorts. Figure?? plots these three key variables of interest between (a) Real outstanding mortgage debt (b) Real weekly household income (c) Real weekly non-housing consumption Figure 3: Life-cycle behaviors of key variables by age across cohorts Each line represents a 10-year date of birth cohort, e.g. the pink line plots the cohort born between 1941 and One can see from Panel (a) that mortgage debt has been accumulating at a much faster rate than incomes for younger cohorts. Panel (b) shows that real incomes were growing at a much faster rate for younger groups in 8

9 the earlier years before starting to flat line. It is possible that the younger households were expecting their income to recover and grow at the same trajectory it did when they entered the workforce. If they were systematically over-estimating their income growth, then they may have also been comfortable taking on large levels of debt relative to their incomes. The financial liberalization of the 1990 s, which made credit more readily available, may have also played a role in the increase of debt among younger households. Panel (c) shows that consumption of younger groups has been growing much more slowly than for other groups before the crisis. This is unsurprising as incomes had also been slowing. The rapid accumulation of debt for younger generations has been predominantly driven by the increase in house prices relative to real incomes in the run up to the financial crisis. Panel (a) in Figure 4 shows that between 1995 and 2005, younger groups took the lion s share of this increase in debt. This stands in stark contrast to wealth accumulation (Panel (b)), where the biggest winners over the last decade have been the older generations. Panel (a) of Figure 4 also shows that the level of debt of younger groups has decreased since the crisis. This can be interpreted as evidence of younger households deleveraging. (a) Real outstanding mortgage debt (b) Real housing wealth Figure 4: Average household debt and housing wealth by age across years We report summary statistics from the FES and WAS in the Appendix. 3 A Simple Regression Analysis In this section, we are interested in exploring whether levels of leverage before the crisis are correlated with the weakness of consumption growth after the crisis. We are interested in two definitions of leverage: loan-to-income (LTI) and loan-to-value (LTV). 9

10 We specify 2006/07 as the period before the Great Recession and 2009/10 as the period after. Although we later also extend the analysis to 2011/12 to show that this effect is persistent. More specifically, we are interested in how households with leverage at different points in their life-cycle may have differentially affected consumption growth. 3.1 Baseline Estimations In our baseline estimation, we are interested in whether the level of loan-to-income (LTI) before the crisis (2006/07) had an effect on consumption growth after the crisis (2009/10). We estimate the following cross-sectional equation at the cohort level: c it = α 0 + α 1 LT I it 1 + α 2 y it + α 3 w it + α 4 x it + e it (1) Where c it is the change in log of non-housing consumption for cohort i, between , denoted by t, and the pre-crisis period, , denoted by (t 1). Our main variable of interest, LT I it 1, is the ratio of outstanding mortgage debt to net (post-tax) income in 2006/7, or the pre-crisis loan-to-income ratio. y it is the change in log net income; w it is a vector for the change in log of housing and financial wealth, taken from the WAS. The wealth variables allow us to control for developments on the asset side of the balance sheet. Finally, x it is a vector of additional controls, such as change in household composition. This equation is similar to Dynan (2012). Table 1 reports results from Equation 1. Each column represents one of the cohort definitions as specified in Section 2.1. Across all columns, the coefficients on the precrisis debt to income ratio are negative and statistically significant. They are also broadly similar in magnitude across all definitions. On average, we find that cohorts with a one unit higher LTI (e.g. 3 instead of 2) reduced their consumption by an extra % between 2006/7 and 2009/10. 4 The effect of increased leverage through LTI works not just via an increase in the numerator, but also through a fall in income. Households who were hit with a negative income shock would see an increase in their leverage, as measured by LTI. If the Great Recession was disproportionately unkind to younger households where they were more likely to become unemployed and experience bigger drops in their incomes then we would expect α 1 to be more negative for them. But leverage may also be affected by changes in house prices although those would only be indirectly captured by changes in loan-to-income ratios. A more direct way of 4 In most cases, the coefficients on the wealth variables are not clearly identified. That may be because the small sample sizes make it difficult to estimate these coefficient precisely. Nevertheless, these results are in line with some in the literature that show that changes in housing wealth do not determine household spending (Attanasio and Weber (1994)) 10

11 capturing how falls in house prices would affect leverage is through loan-to-values (LTV), the more commonly used definition of leverage. Cohort definition Single birth year Single birth year, 5 birth year, mortgagor mortgagor Dependent variable: C t [1] [2] [3] Y t 0.675*** 0.599*** 0.766*** (0.122) (0.118) (0.123) LT I t ** *** ** (0.014) (0.007) (0.009) Housing wealth t (0.070) (0.036) (0.059) F inancial wealth t *** (0.020) (0.023) (0.021) Constant ** ** (0.023) (0.012) (0.013) Controls Yes Yes Yes Observations Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Dependent variable is the change in log of non-housing consumption from 2006/07 to 2009/10. Y is the change in posttax income, net of mortgage interest payments between 2006/007 & 2009/10. Housing wealth and F inancial wealth are also for the same time period. LT I 06/07 is the ratio of outstanding mortgage debt to annual net income in 2006/07. Controls are the change in the number of adults and children between 2006/07 and 2009/10. Each column represents a synthetic panel regression from 2 pooled years, using one of four cohort definitions: using single birth years, single birth years, split by whether the household is a mortgagor or a non-mortgagor; 5-year birth buckets, split by mortgagor status and 10 year birth buckets, split by UK Government Office Region. Table 1: Baseline results (Loan-to-Income) Using the housing wealth data from WAS, we construct loan-to-values and estimate 11

12 the same equation as above but substituting LTIs with LTVs: c it = β 0 + β 1 LT V it 1 + β 2 y it + β 3 w it + β 4 x it + e it (2) This specification allows us to compare our results to other studies as the literature typically uses LTV as a measure of leverag, but it also serves as a useful cross-check to equation 1. The results are reported in Table 2. We find a statistically significant effect: for each 10% increase in LTV, consumption is reduced by % between 2006/7 and 2009/10. A fall in house prices would increase LTVs making it harder (or more expensive) to refinance. It also makes it harder to move on to or up the housing ladder, as it would require saving for a bigger deposit. If younger households are more highly leveraged (i.e. have larger loans) compared to households of an older generation (because of the rapid rise in house prices), then a fall in house prices would increase LTVs for those younger households by more than older, less-leveraged households. If, after the crisis, the availability of credit requires achieving higher credit scores than what was acceptable before the crisis then we would expect a more negative β 1 coefficient for younger households, who because of their shorter financial histories have weaker credit scores. To simplify matters we use only one cohort definition for the remainder of the analysis. We prefer to use single birth years split by mortgagor status for three reasons. One, given that we are analyzing the effect of household debt on spending, it makes sense to have a pseudo panel that groups households by mortgagor/non-mortgagor status. Second, the coefficient sizes for pre-crisis LTI and LTV using that definition falls in between the other two cohort definitions. Third, this definition yields the largest number of observations, which will come in quite handy when we split the sample by age. The main criticism of using this cohort definition is that mortgagor status is a choice variable, so the construction of the panel does not just rely on deterministic variables. Following Attanasio, Banks, and Tanner (2002), we use predicted mortgagor status (instead of actual status) to construct the an alternative panel specification 5. We get the same results using predicted variables as we would actual variables. The detailed method and results are discussed in Appendix A We also use predicted debt for the LTI ratio. 12

13 Cohort definition Single birth year Single birth year, 5 birth year mortgagor mortgagor Dependent variable: C t [1] [2] [3] Y t 0.743*** 0.607*** 0.857*** (0.124) (0.117) (0.130) LT V t * *** ** (0.064) (0.038) (0.054) Housing wealth t (0.096) (0.036) (0.061) F inancial wealth t *** (0.020) (0.023) (0.021) Constant ** ** (0.029) (0.012) (0.013) Controls Yes Yes Yes Observations Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Dependent variable is the change in log of non-housing consumption from 2006/07 to 2009/10. Y is the change in post-tax income, net of mortgage interest payments between 2006/007 & 2009/10. Housing wealth and F inancial wealth are also for the same time period. LT V 06/07 is the ratio of outstanding mortgage debt to housing wealth in 2006/07. Controls are the change in the number of adults and children between 2006/07 and 2009/10. Each column represents a synthetic panel regression from one of four cohort definitions: using single birth years, single birth years, split by whether the household is a mortgagor or a non-mortgagor; 5-year birth buckets, split by mortgagor status and 10 year birth buckets, split by UK Government Office Region. Table 2: Baseline results (Loan-to-Value) 3.2 Effect by age Household debt accumulation is disproportionately skewed towards younger households, paying it down as they grow older. But there is also evidence to suggest that the Great 13

14 Recession was harsher for younger households than older household: they had bigger falls in their income and more were more likely to become unemployed. It may also be that they experienced tighter conditions accessing credit than older households. Sample split: Young Old Dependent variable: C t [1] [2] [3] [4] Y t *** 0.708*** (0.302) (0.317) (0.133) (0.134) LT I t *** ** (0.012) (0.008) LT V t *** ** (0.054) (0.045) Housing wealth t 0.097* 0.101* (0.044) (0.047) (0.063) (0.062) F inancial wealth t (0.039) (0.041) (0.025) (0.025) Constant ** ** (0.065) (0.069) (0.014) (0.014) Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations Robust standard errors in parentheses, *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. TBD Table 3: Age split To check if there was a differential effect on consumption between young and old households, we split the sample by age those who are older than 35 and those 35 years or less. The results, reported in Table 3, indicate that the biggest cuts to consumption were driven by the younger households the coefficients on LT I t 1 and LT V t 1 are about three times larger for younger than for older households. 3.3 Robustness We test out different specifications to check the robustness of our results. We summarize those below, but details of all robustness tests can be found in the Appendix??. First, 14

15 we show that defining cohorts using mortgagor status is not particularly problematic. Over long periods of time, households will move between different housing tenures. Data from the WAS suggest that around 90% of the households who had a mortgage in the first wave of the survey, between mid-2006 and mid-2008, still had a mortgage two years later. We can therefore assume that over shorter periods - such as when looking at changes over the financial crisis period - mortgage level is fixed. Nevertheless, we cross-check our results by also using predicted, rather than actual, mortgagor status, as suggested by Moffitt (1993). We get the same results. Second, we extend the time period to 2011/2012 to check for persistence. We find that extending out estimation period does little to change the size and significance of the LTI and LTV coefficients, suggesting that the larger cuts in spending by leveraged households had not dissipated, at least up to Third, we test for non-linearities in leverage by checking whether households with higher loan-to-incomes cut their spending by more than those with lower values. We find that households who have an LTI of greater than 4 or more cut their consumption by 41% more than households who had an LTI of 4 or less. These effects are also persistent: we find a similar coefficient if the analysis is extended to 2011/12. The final check we do is test for spuriousness of our results. We do this by running placebo regressions for two alternative time periods, in place of the pre-crisis base year of 2006/07. The first time period we use is between and ; and the second time period is between and We find no effect using those two alternative time-periods: the coefficients are very small and statistically insignificant. 4 Life-Cycle Model with Mortgages In a regression analysis it is impossible to disentangle how consumption cuts of high and low- leveraged households were affected by different shocks around the recession. We can not test wether the empirical connection between the size of the consumption cut and the leverage can be better understood with income shocks, credit market shocks or house price shocks. For this reason, in this section we build a theoretical model and simulate the behavior of a large number of households. In this way we are able to analyze counterfactuals and identify the most likely recession scenarios. We start with a simple model of life-cycle consumption and savings in a dynamic stochastic framework. Households maximize their present discounted lifetime utility, which depends on nondurable consumption and the consumption of a flow of housing services. They can move resources between periods by investing in either a fully liquid asset equivalent to a one-period bond or less liquid housing, which also provides a flow 15

16 of housing services. We only allow households to have collateralized debt, where housing could serve as collateral. Households face uncertainty in two dimensions: idiosyncratic uncertainty over labor income and aggregate uncertainty over the house price. We do not consider bequest motives and an uncertain end of life. 4.1 Model structure The problem of the households can be written as subject to V t (Ω t ) = max U(C t, S t ) + βe t V t+1 (Ω t+1 ) (3) {C t,i t,ξ t,ϑ t} X t+1 = R X (X t C t Q t I t Θ t ξ t + ϑ t ) + Y t+1 (4) Households get utility from nondurable consumption, C t and housing services, S t. Ω t is the vector of state variables, Ω t = (X t, H t, M t, Q t, Yt P ). Households start any period t with a given amount of wealth and receive uncertain labor income, Y t, that add up to cash-on-hand, X t. Given the amount of cash-on-hand, households decide how much to consume, C t, how much to invest in an illiquid housing, I t at unit price Q t, how much repayment to make on the existing mortgage, ξ t and how much new mortgage to take out, ϑ t. Depending on the size of housing adjustment, households have to pay a cost, Θ t. Yt P denotes permanent income, which we discuss later. Utility function. We use a CRRA utility function in the composite good. Nondurable consumption and housing services are aggregated with a Cobb-Douglas technology into the composite good. u(c t, S t ) = ( ) C α t St 1 α 1 ρ 1 ρ where α is the weight on nondurable consumption in the utility function, ρ is the inverse of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution (for the composite good). Housing. Housing investment, I t, adds to the existing housing, H t. Hence the law of motion for the housing is (5) H t+1 = H t + I t, H 0 > 0 (6) The purchase of housing may often be associated with significant cost such as time spent looking for the preferred house or contractual costs. To capture such types of costs, we allow for non-convex adjustment costs Θ(I t ) 0, which we assume to depend on the 16

17 value of housing investment Θ(I t ) = δq t I t (7) Housing generates housing services, S t. We assume a linear technology between housing and housing services. Since there is no rental market in our model housing services are only acquired by owning. S t = bh t (8) Housing can be used as collateral for mortgage loans. Households can get collateralized debt at a constant price of R M up to a given fraction, 1 ψ, of the value of housing. At the moment of the first mortgage take-out, the following inequality has to hold M t (1 ψ)q t H t (9) where ψ can be interpreted as the down-payment requirement. Financial markets. We only allow households to have collateralized debt. Other types of debt are not available. This is not an unreasonable assumption as mortgages constitute the vast majority of loans in the household sector in the UK. Consequently this means that households have an incentive to take out a mortgage even if the mortgage rate is higher than the risk-free rate. Households with an existing mortgage, M t can apply for a new mortgage, ϑ t, although they have to keep repaying the existing mortgage, ξ t. The law of motion for the mortgage stock is as follows M t+1 = R M M t + ϑ t ξ t (10) Next period s mortgage equals the existing mortgage with its interest, R M, 6 plus the new mortgage taken out minus the repayment on the existing mortgage. We assume that repayment on the existing mortgage is bounded from below. Households have to pay at least the interest on the value of the mortgage in each period. Also there is a natural upper bound for repayment, which is paying back all the mortgage with all its interest. r M M t ξ t R M M t (11) As highlighted earlier, households are assumed to face a constraint on the level of mortgage they can take out. The maximum amount of mortgage they can have is a constant 6 R M is the gross real mortgage rate, R M = 1 + r M 17

18 fraction of the value of their housing. { (1 ψ)q t H t R M M t if (1 ψ)q t H t > R M M t ϑ t = 0 else (12) It is important to see from equation (12), that the restriction on the mortgage relative to the value of housing is only enforced at the moment of taking out new mortgage. As house prices do fluctuate, the constraint can be violated for households with an existing mortgage as there is no mechanism through which households could insure themselves against this uncertainty. In this manner, whenever the existing mortgage exceeds the maximum possible mortgage take-out, households can not apply for a new mortgage. Whenever households borrow they are also subject to the terminal condition, M T = 0, which prevents them from borrowing more than they can repay with certainty by the end of their life. Uncertainty. In our baseline model households face uncertainty in two dimensions: idiosyncratic uncertainty over labor income and aggregate uncertainty over house prices. Following Zeldes (1989), labor income Y t at any time before retirement is exogenously described by a combination of deterministic and random components Y t = Y P t Z t log(z t ) N( 0.5σ 2 z, σ 2 z) (13) where Yt P is the permanent component and Z t is the transitory component. Furthermore we assume that the permanent component can be described as Y P t = G t Y P t 1N t log(n t ) N( 0.5σ 2 n, σ 2 n) (14) with G t being a deterministic function of age and N t is the innovation. We also assume that the shocks (N t and Z t ) are independent. Labour income Y t at any time after retirement is a constant fraction a of the last working year s permanent labor income. Y t = ayw P (15) The log of the house price is assumed to be determined by a random walk process with drift. In Section 4.3 we show that this assumption is consistent with the UK house price data. log Q t+1 = d 0 + log Q t + log ε t log(ε t ) N( 0.5σε, 2 σε) 2 (16) It is important to highlight that the log-normality assumption about the idiosyncratic shocks to labour income, Z t and N t, and about the aggregate shocks to house prices, ε t, 18

19 is only relevant in our baseline specification. When we 4.2 Solution and Simulation The life-cycle problem can not be solved analytically, we therefore apply numerical techniques. Given the finite nature of the problem, a solution exists and can be obtained by approximating optimal policy functions with backward induction technique. We use the backward induction over the normalized value function of the households to obtain the optimal policy functions. Expectations in the model refer to uncertain incomes and house prices, while they are evaluated by using the Gauss-Hermite approximation. Since shocks to incomes and prices, Z t+1, N t+1 and ε t+1 are log-normally distributed random variables in each period, we are able to use a three-dimensional Gauss-Hermite quadrature to approximate the expectations as follows E t V t+1 (ω t+1 ) = = 1 π V t+1 1 i j π wgh i k ) V t+1 (ω t+1 (Z, N, ε) df (Z)dF (N)dF (ε) ( ω t+1 ( 2σ Z Z, 2σ N N, ) 2σ ε ε) e (Z2 +N 2 +ε 2 ) ( wj GH wk GH V t+1 ω t+1 ( 2σ Z Z GH where ω t+1 is the vector of normalized state variables, Z GH i Gauss-Hermite nodes and wi GH, wj GH and wk GH backward induction, we get the optimal policy functions. i, 2σ N Nj GH, ) 2σ ε ε GH k ) (17) s, Nj GH s and ε GH k s are the are the corresponding weights. Using Having the optimal policy functions calculated, we simulate the behavior of households over the life-cycle. For each simulation we draw realizations for the two individual shocks, the permanent income shock and the transitory income shock and realizations for the aggregate house price shocks which are identical for all the households. As we disregard from any kind of bequest motive households start their life with zero wealth, and they get labor income. 4.3 Model Calibration Most of the parameter values for the life-cycle model presented above are adapted from the existing literature. Here we only discuss the values of parameters, which we estimate from different data sources. Income process. To obtain the age-specific component of the life-cycle income profiles (G), we fit a second-order age polynomial to the logarithm of cohort income data 19

20 gathered from the Family Expenditure Survey between 1996 and ln y c t = γ 0 + γ 1 age c,t + γ 2 age 2 c,t 10 (18) where c refers to cohort averages. The regression results are presented in Table 4. Age Age 2 Constant log y c (0.003) (0.000) (0.058) Observations 945 R-squared Standard errors are in parenthesis. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1 Table 4: INCOME PROCESS House price process. We estimate the house price process based on Nationwide s House Price Index adjusted for retail prices (using the Office for National Statistics Retail Price Index) for quarters 1996q1-2015q2. We estimate an AR(1) process with linear trend for the logarithm of the real house price index. log Q t+1 = q 0 + q 1 t + ρ h log Q t + log ε t (19) The result of the estimation is in Table 5. The persistence parameter ρ h of the log real house price is estimated to be very close to one and the unit root tests do not reject the null hypothesis that this parameter is actually 1. It implies that the log real house price process can be approximated by a random walk. The estimated quarterly variance of the house price shock, σε, 2 equals , which corresponds to at an annual frequency. The benchmark model parameters are collected in Table 6. Cohorts. We define different groups of households, and simulate their behaviour separately, taking into account that different cohorts experience aggregate shocks at different ages. Altogether we define 6 cohorts between ages 20 and 80 (10-year age interval each) and simulate 1000 households in each cohort. 20

21 log Q t (0.0000) log Q (-1) (0.012) constrained Constant (0.137) (0.002) σε Observations R-squared Standard errors are in parenthesis. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1 Table 5: HOUSE PRICE PROCESS Parameter Value Source T Number of years as adult 60 W Number of years as worker 45 β Discount factor 0.95 ρ Risk aversion parameter 1.5 Blundell, Browning, and Meghir (1994) Constant Age-specific income, constant Own calculations, FES Age Age-specific income, linear trend Own calculations, FES Age 2 /10 Age-specific income, quadratic trend Own calculations, FES a Replacement rate 0.72 Own calculations, FES σ n Std.dev.permanent income shock Carroll and Samwick (1997) σ z Std.dev.transitory income shock 0.21 Carroll and Samwick (1997) σ ε Std.dev.house price shock Own calculation, Nationwide ρ h Persistence parameter for house price 1 Own calculation, Nationwide R X Liquid asset return 1.02 Gourinchas and Parker (2002) R M Mortgage rate 1.03 α Weight of durables in composite good 0.83? b Housing service technology 0.06? δ Adjustment cost 0.05 ψ Down-payment requirement 0.2 Table 6: PARAMETERS FOR THE BENCHMARK MODEL 21

22 5 Simulation Results In this section we present results from the numerical simulation. Similarly to the empirical part, in the simulation we define two groups of households: high-leveraged and low-leveraged households. Households with mortgage-to-income ratio above 2.5 are defined as high-leveraged households, while households with mortgage-to-income ratio below 2.5 as low-leveraged households. We present our results separately for high- and low-leveraged households. First, in our baseline simulation, we disregard of the 2008/2009 recession. Then, we extend our analysis and model the recession in four different ways. Our aim with this exercisse is to identify the main driving forces behind our empirical observation discussed in Section 2: high-leveraged households cut their consumption by much more than low-leveraged households in response to the crisis. Following Alan, Crossley, and Low (2012) we consider four different sources of the 2008/2009 recession: negative shock to income, increased uncertainty around future income, reduction in the credit supply and fall in house prices (i.e. reduction in housing wealth). 5.1 Baseline In our baseline specification we analyse the model without considering the recession in It means that we do not take into account big house price or income shocks around Therefore, we simulate households according to the model described in the previous section. Figure 5 shows the simulated level of the average consumption between 1992 and Even though the average consumption is calculated over all the cohorts, there is a steady increase in consumption over the observed period. This moderate increase in average consumption can be rationalized by the model assumption in equation (16): the level of house prices are increasing over time only with small disturbances around its trend. This leads to a constant increase in housing wealth, therefore a constant increase in consumption. The vertical black line corresponds to year

23 Baseline year Figure 5: LEVEL OF CONSUMPTION In Figure 6 we disaggregate the simulated consumption data by cohorts and by the level of indebtedness. First, we define two broad groups: households in the three youngest cohorts out of the six cohorts are labelled as young, while the rest of the households are labelled as old. As it is visible from Figure 6 young households experience a sharp increase in their consumption between 1992 and Moreover, the increase is much sharper than the one for the aggregate consumption shown in Figure 5. The reason behind is that young households are liquidity constrained: at the beginning of their life-cycle they adjust their consumption to their quickly increasing income. The consumption of old households are steady over the same period. Second, we categorize households into two different groups by a leverage criteria: households whose mortgage-to-income ratio is below 2.5 at year 2007 are labelled as low-leveraged households, while the ones above the 2.5 threshold are labelled as highleveraged households. 23

24 year year Young Old High Leverage Low Leverage Figure 6: LEVEL OF CONSUMPTION FOR DIFFERENT GROUPS High-leveraged households only have slightly lower levels of consumption in 1992 than low-leveraged ones, while this gap is broadening over the observed time period. Therefore, on average high-leveraged households have lower consumption over their lifecycle. Figure 7 similarly to Figure 2 shows the year-to-year consumption growth separately for households with high- and with low leverages for the period of Consumption growth of households with high leverages are in general lower than that of households with low leverages. The only exception is around 2009/2010. Recall that in our baseline model specification there is no mechanism to generate the 2008 recession. Hence, it is just a coincidence that the time series for high-leveraged households deviates from its trend exactly around the the years associated with the great recession in the real world. 24

25 Baseline year High Leverage Low Leverage Figure 7: NO RECESSION CONSUMPTION GROWTH 5.2 Different Models of Recession In this part of the paper we analyse different models of recession and discuss wether they could explain the empirical fact that high-leveraged households have cut their consumption by more than low-leveraged ones in the 2008 recession. In the following, we consider four alternative shocks that could have caused the 2008 recession, or what households may have thought of what has happened. Permanent Income. A recession may occur when all the households face a negative income shock at the same time. We model this scenario by assuming that the expected value of the permanent income shock, N t, decreases from 1 to 0.8 for one period in More precisely, N 2008 = 0.8N 2007 for each household and the rest of the shocks are drawn from the same lognormal distribution we have introduced in Section 4.1, log(n t ) N( 0.5σ 2 n, σ 2 n). Variance of the Permanent Income. The other alternative cause of recession is that from 2008 onwards households experience a higher level of uncertainty about their future labor income. We simulate this situation by considering an increase in the variance of 25

26 the permanent shocks to income. log(n t ) N( 0.5σ 2 n, σ 2 n) if t < 2008 log(n t ) N( σ 2 n, 2σ 2 n) if t 2008 Note that in order to keep the expected value of the shock fixed, E(N t ) = 1, doubling the variance of the lognormal distribution needs doubling the mean of it as well. Downpayment Requirement. We can think of the recession as a period with decreased supply of credit. In fact, banks changed their credit conditions dramatically after 2008 and most importantly they increased their downpayment requirements. Instead of, on average, 10% down-payment they have started to demand around 20% down-payment. In our model down-payment requirement is led by a single parameter, ψ, as seen in equation (9). Hence in our simulations we set: ψ = 0.1 if t < 2008 ψ = 0.2 if t 2008 House Prices. The last alternative we consider is the collapse of the house prices after Instead of the estimated house price process in Table 5, we feed the model with the observed house price data. 7 After simulating these alternative scenarios, we are able to compare the effect of different types of shocks to the baseline, no recession scenario. We are concerned about consumption growth, therefore we calculate how the consumption growth of different models deviates from the no recession case. In Figure 8 we present the results for all the simulated households in the sample - aged 20 to 80. We again separate high and low-leveraged households according to the 2.5 mortgage-to-income-ratio criteria. The numbers of the y-axises should be interpreted as percentage points deviations in consumption growth from the no recession case. Four facts are worth noticing here. First, only permanent income drop and the increase in the down-payment requirement can lead to a sudden drop in consumption in Second, both of these shocks generate higher consumption cuts for highly indebted households, which is consistent with our empirical observation. Third, the increase in the variance of the permanent income shock only has long-term effects. As we can see in Figure 8, both the high- and low-leveraged households decrease their consumption persistently after And fourth, house price evolution can not account for the immediate cut of 7 See the graph of observed house prices in the UK in the Appendix 26

27 consumption in WHY???!!!! Permanent Income Drop Increase in Permanent Income Variance year year Increase in Downpayment Requirement Observed House Price year year High Leverage Low Leverage Figure 8: DEVIATION IN CONSUMPTION GROWTH FROM NO RECESSION 5.3 Young versus Middle-Aged In the previous section we have identified two types of shocks that could generate differences in consumption cuts between low- and high-leveraged households: the permanent income shock and the shock to the credit supply. In this section we investigate the effects of these two shocks further by disaggregating the simulated data. As, by assumption, permanent income shocks do not affect retired households, we only focus on households between age 20 and 60 (4 simulated cohorts) in each scenarios. We define two groups: households between 20 and 40 years of age are selected into the group of young households, while households between ages 40 and 60 into the group of middle-aged households. In Figure 9 we show consumption growth over time under the scenario, when the recession is interpreted as a sudden drop in the permanent income of households. Both young and middle age households experience a sudden drop in consumption in 2008, while there is a significant difference between consumption cuts of high- and low-leveraged households for each age group. Middle-aged households make bigger adjustments to their 27

Consumption Response to Aggregate Shocks and the Role of Leverage

Consumption Response to Aggregate Shocks and the Role of Leverage Consumption Response to Aggregate Shocks and the Role of Leverage Agnes Kovacs, May Rostom, Philip Bunn July 11, 2018 Abstract This paper investigates the relationship between mortgage leverage and consumption

More information

Household debt and spending in the United Kingdom

Household debt and spending in the United Kingdom Household debt and spending in the United Kingdom Philip Bunn and May Rostom Bank of England Fourth ECB conference on household finance and consumption 17 December 2015 1 Outline Motivation Literature/theory

More information

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel Martin Eichenbaum, Sergio Rebelo, and Arlene Wong May 2018 Motivation In the US, bulk of household borrowing is in fixed rate mortgages with

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

The Coincident Cycles of House Prices and Consumption in the U.K.: Do House Prices Drive Consumption Growth?

The Coincident Cycles of House Prices and Consumption in the U.K.: Do House Prices Drive Consumption Growth? The Coincident Cycles of House Prices and Consumption in the U.K.: Do House Prices Drive Consumption Growth? Orazio Attanasio (Institute for Fiscal Studies, University College, London, NBER and CEPR) Andrew

More information

Consumption and House Prices in the Great Recession: Model Meets Evidence

Consumption and House Prices in the Great Recession: Model Meets Evidence Consumption and House Prices in the Great Recession: Model Meets Evidence Greg Kaplan Kurt Mitman Gianluca Violante MFM 9-10 March, 2017 Outline 1. Overview 2. Model 3. Questions Q1: What shock(s) drove

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

The role of debt in UK household spending decisions

The role of debt in UK household spending decisions Working Paper No. The role of debt in UK household spending decisions Philip Bunn (1) and May Rostom (2) PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE Abstract Household debt rose sharply in the

More information

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation Internet Appendix A. Participation constraint In evaluating when the participation constraint binds, we consider three

More information

Leverage, Re-leveraging, and Household Spending

Leverage, Re-leveraging, and Household Spending Leverage, Re-leveraging, and Household Spending Thomas Crossley (Essex) Peter Levell (IFS) Hamish Low (Cambridge) NIESR March 2018 1 / 35 Introduction How does borrowing and spending of more leveraged

More information

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Matthias Doepke UCLA Martin Schneider NYU and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Abstract This paper shows that a zero-sum redistribution

More information

The Financial Labor Supply Accelerator

The Financial Labor Supply Accelerator The Financial Labor Supply Accelerator Jeffrey R. Campbell and Zvi Hercowitz June 16, 2009 Abstract When minimum equity stakes in durable goods constrain a household s debt, a persistent wage increase

More information

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Advanced Macroeconomics II Professor Lorenza Rossi/Jordi Gali T.A. Daniël van Schoot, daniel.vanschoot@upf.edu Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model Schedule: 28th of May (seminar 4): Exercises 1, 2 and

More information

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication.

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication. Online Appendix Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle Not intended for publication Alexander Bick Arizona State University Sekyu Choi Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona,

More information

The marginal propensity to consume out of a tax rebate: the case of Italy

The marginal propensity to consume out of a tax rebate: the case of Italy The marginal propensity to consume out of a tax rebate: the case of Italy Andrea Neri 1 Concetta Rondinelli 2 Filippo Scoccianti 3 Bank of Italy 1 Statistical Analysis Directorate 2 Economic Outlook and

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

Saving, wealth and consumption

Saving, wealth and consumption By Melissa Davey of the Bank s Structural Economic Analysis Division. The UK household saving ratio has recently fallen to its lowest level since 19. A key influence has been the large increase in the

More information

Household Finance in China

Household Finance in China Household Finance in China Russell Cooper 1 and Guozhong Zhu 2 October 22, 2016 1 Department of Economics, the Pennsylvania State University and NBER, russellcoop@gmail.com 2 School of Business, University

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

What Can a Life-Cycle Model Tell Us About Household Responses to the Financial Crisis?

What Can a Life-Cycle Model Tell Us About Household Responses to the Financial Crisis? What Can a Life-Cycle Model Tell Us About Household Responses to the Financial Crisis? Sule Alan 1 Thomas Crossley 1 Hamish Low 1 1 University of Cambridge and Institute for Fiscal Studies March 2010 Data:

More information

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings Upjohn Institute Policy Papers Upjohn Research home page 2011 The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings Leslie A. Muller Hope College

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* Sónia Costa** Luísa Farinha** 133 Abstract The analysis of the Portuguese households

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Relating Income to Consumption Part 1

Relating Income to Consumption Part 1 Part 1 Extract from Earnings, Consumption and Lifecycle Choices by Costas Meghir and Luigi Pistaferri. Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 4b, Ch. 9. (2011). James J. Heckman University of Chicago AEA Continuing

More information

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho Beggar-thy-parents? A Lifecycle Model of Intergenerational Altruism Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho University of New South Wales March 2009 Motivation & Question Since Becker (1974), several studies analyzing

More information

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 17 Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 Luísa Farinha Pedro Prego 2 Abstract The analysis of liquidity management decisions by firms has recently been used as a tool to investigate the

More information

How Do House Prices Affect Consumption? Evidence from Micro Data

How Do House Prices Affect Consumption? Evidence from Micro Data How Do House Prices Affect Consumption? Evidence from Micro Data The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation Published

More information

ON THE ASSET ALLOCATION OF A DEFAULT PENSION FUND

ON THE ASSET ALLOCATION OF A DEFAULT PENSION FUND ON THE ASSET ALLOCATION OF A DEFAULT PENSION FUND Magnus Dahlquist 1 Ofer Setty 2 Roine Vestman 3 1 Stockholm School of Economics and CEPR 2 Tel Aviv University 3 Stockholm University and Swedish House

More information

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Yan Bai University of Rochester NBER Dan Lu University of Rochester Xu Tian University of Rochester February

More information

Wealth Accumulation in the US: Do Inheritances and Bequests Play a Significant Role

Wealth Accumulation in the US: Do Inheritances and Bequests Play a Significant Role Wealth Accumulation in the US: Do Inheritances and Bequests Play a Significant Role John Laitner January 26, 2015 The author gratefully acknowledges support from the U.S. Social Security Administration

More information

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits Day Manoli UCLA Andrea Weber University of Mannheim February 29, 2012 Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence

More information

Pension Funds Performance Evaluation: a Utility Based Approach

Pension Funds Performance Evaluation: a Utility Based Approach Pension Funds Performance Evaluation: a Utility Based Approach Carolina Fugazza Fabio Bagliano Giovanna Nicodano CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto and University of of Turin CeRP 10 Anniversary Conference Motivation

More information

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge By Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Elena Pastorino This paper is motivated by the strong correlation between changes in household debt and employment across regions

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt WORKING PAPER NO. 08-15 THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt Keith Kuester Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Final version

More information

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models?

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models? How Much Insurance in Bewley Models? Greg Kaplan New York University Gianluca Violante New York University, CEPR, IFS and NBER Boston University Macroeconomics Seminar Lunch Kaplan-Violante, Insurance

More information

Euler Equations, Subjective Expectations and Income Shocks

Euler Equations, Subjective Expectations and Income Shocks Euler Equations, Subjective Expectations and Income Shocks Orazio Attanasio Agnes Kovacs Krisztina Molnar May 19, 2017 Abstract In this paper, we make three substantive contributions: first, we use elicited

More information

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination Arvind Magesan and Jordi Mondria January 31, 2011 Abstract In this paper we study the economic and strategic incentives for a country to financially liberalize

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World Nicolas Coeurdacier (SciencesPo & CEPR) Helene Rey (LBS & NBER & CEPR) Pablo Winant (PSE) Barcelona June 2013 Coeurdacier, Rey, Winant Financial Integration...

More information

When Interest Rates Go Up, What Will This Mean For the Mortgage Market and the Wider Economy?

When Interest Rates Go Up, What Will This Mean For the Mortgage Market and the Wider Economy? SIEPR policy brief Stanford University October 2015 Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research on the web: http://siepr.stanford.edu When Interest Rates Go Up, What Will This Mean For the Mortgage

More information

Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership

Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership Kamila Sommer Paul Sullivan August 2017 Federal Reserve Board of Governors, email: kv28@georgetown.edu American

More information

The Lost Generation of the Great Recession

The Lost Generation of the Great Recession The Lost Generation of the Great Recession Sewon Hur University of Pittsburgh January 21, 2016 Introduction What are the distributional consequences of the Great Recession? Introduction What are the distributional

More information

Consumption and House Prices in the Great Recession: Model Meets Evidence

Consumption and House Prices in the Great Recession: Model Meets Evidence : Model Meets Evidence Greg Kaplan Princeton University and NBER Kurt Mitman IIES Giovanni L. Violante New York University, CEPR, and NBER Extended Abstract One of the distinctive features of the Great

More information

Euler Equations, Subjective Expectations and Income Shocks

Euler Equations, Subjective Expectations and Income Shocks Euler Equations, Subjective Expectations and Income Shocks Orazio Attanasio Agnes Kovacs Krisztina Molnar October 26, 2017 Abstract In this paper, we make three substantive contributions: first, we use

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

BOOMS AND BUSTS: CONSUMPTION, HOUSE PRICES AND EXPECTATIONS

BOOMS AND BUSTS: CONSUMPTION, HOUSE PRICES AND EXPECTATIONS BOOMS AND BUSTS: CONSUMPTION, HOUSE PRICES AND EXPECTATIONS Orazio P. Attanasio Laura Blow Robert Hamilton Andrew Leicester THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES WP05/24 Booms and Busts: Consumption, house

More information

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions Mario Meier 1 & Andrea Weber 2 1 University of Mannheim 2 Vienna University of Economics and Business, CEPR, IZA Meier & Weber (2016) Peers in Retirement 1 / 35 Motivation

More information

Household finance in Europe 1

Household finance in Europe 1 IFC-National Bank of Belgium Workshop on "Data needs and Statistics compilation for macroprudential analysis" Brussels, Belgium, 18-19 May 2017 Household finance in Europe 1 Miguel Ampudia, European Central

More information

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier Faculty of Social Sciences Jeppe Druedahl (Ph.d. Student) Department of Economics 16th of December 2013 Slide 1/29 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 16th of December 2013 Slide 2/29 The For Today 1 Some 2 A Benchmark

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Petra Gerlach-Kristen Hong Kong Institute of Economics and Business Strategy May, Abstract This paper uses unobserved components analysis to estimate

More information

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound Timothy Hills Taisuke Nakata Sebastian Schmidt New York University Federal Reserve Board European Central Bank 1 September 2016 1 The views expressed

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University March 2013 Idiosyncratic risk and the business cycle How much and what types

More information

A Quantitative Evaluation of. the Housing Provident Fund Program in China

A Quantitative Evaluation of. the Housing Provident Fund Program in China A Quantitative Evaluation of the Housing Provident Fund Program in China Xiaoqing Zhou Bank of Canada December 6, 217 Abstract The Housing Provident Fund (HPF) is the largest public housing program in

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

Are Americans Saving Optimally for Retirement?

Are Americans Saving Optimally for Retirement? Figure : Median DB Pension Wealth, Social Security Wealth, and Net Worth (excluding DB Pensions) by Lifetime Income, (99 dollars) 400,000 Are Americans Saving Optimally for Retirement? 350,000 300,000

More information

Macroeconomics Field Exam August 2017 Department of Economics UC Berkeley. (3 hours)

Macroeconomics Field Exam August 2017 Department of Economics UC Berkeley. (3 hours) Macroeconomics Field Exam August 2017 Department of Economics UC Berkeley (3 hours) 236B-related material: Amir Kermani and Benjamin Schoefer. Macro field exam 2017. 1 Housing Wealth and Consumption in

More information

Movements on the Price of Houses

Movements on the Price of Houses Movements on the Price of Houses José-Víctor Ríos-Rull Penn, CAERP Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Universidad de Cantabria, Penn Tue Dec 14 13:00:57 2004 So Preliminary, There is Really Nothing Conference on

More information

Credit and hiring. Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, visiting EIEF Qi Sun University of Southern California.

Credit and hiring. Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, visiting EIEF Qi Sun University of Southern California. Credit and hiring Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, visiting EIEF Qi Sun University of Southern California November 14, 2013 CREDIT AND EMPLOYMENT LINKS When credit is tight, employers

More information

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007 Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert February 15, 2007 Abstract In this paper we use a simple model with a single Cobb Douglas firm and a consumer with

More information

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Vipin Arora Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Junsang Lee U.S. EIA Deakin Univ. SKKU December 16, 2013 GRIPS Junsang Lee (SKKU) Oil Price Dynamics in

More information

Model Construction & Forecast Based Portfolio Allocation:

Model Construction & Forecast Based Portfolio Allocation: QBUS6830 Financial Time Series and Forecasting Model Construction & Forecast Based Portfolio Allocation: Is Quantitative Method Worth It? Members: Bowei Li (303083) Wenjian Xu (308077237) Xiaoyun Lu (3295347)

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 207 Introduction This note works through some simple two-period consumption-saving problems. In

More information

Financial Wealth, Consumption Smoothing, and Income Shocks due to Job Loss

Financial Wealth, Consumption Smoothing, and Income Shocks due to Job Loss Financial Wealth, Consumption Smoothing, and Income Shocks due to Job Loss Hans G. Bloemen * and Elena G. F. Stancanelli ** Working Paper N o 2003-09 December 2003 *** * Free University Amsterdam, Department

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Kenichi Ueda* *The University of Tokyo PRI-ADBI Joint Workshop January 13, 2017 The views are those of the author and should not be attributed

More information

Robustness Appendix for Deconstructing Lifecycle Expenditure Mark Aguiar and Erik Hurst

Robustness Appendix for Deconstructing Lifecycle Expenditure Mark Aguiar and Erik Hurst Robustness Appendix for Deconstructing Lifecycle Expenditure Mark Aguiar and Erik Hurst This appendix shows a variety of additional results that accompany our paper "Deconstructing Lifecycle Expenditure,"

More information

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013 Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak November 2013 Well known that policymakers face important tradeoffs between equity and efficiency in the design of the tax system The issue we address in this paper informs

More information

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes Syed M. Hussain Samreen Malik May 9,. Online Appendix.. Anticipated versus Unanticipated Tax changes Comparing our estimates with the estimates

More information

1. Suppose that instead of a lump sum tax the government introduced a proportional income tax such that:

1. Suppose that instead of a lump sum tax the government introduced a proportional income tax such that: hapter Review Questions. Suppose that instead of a lump sum tax the government introduced a proportional income tax such that: T = t where t is the marginal tax rate. a. What is the new relationship between

More information

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE Macroeconomic Dynamics, (9), 55 55. Printed in the United States of America. doi:.7/s6559895 ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE KEVIN X.D. HUANG Vanderbilt

More information

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014 External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ali Shourideh Wharton Ariel Zetlin-Jones CMU - Tepper November 7, 2014 Introduction Question: How

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Permanent versus Transitory Income Shocks over the Business Cycle

Permanent versus Transitory Income Shocks over the Business Cycle Permanent versus Transitory Income Shocks over the Business Cycle Agnes Kovacs Concetta Rondinelli Serena Trucchi August 21, 2018 Abstract This paper investigates the role of subjective income expectations

More information

The Employment and Output Effects of Short-Time Work in Germany

The Employment and Output Effects of Short-Time Work in Germany The Employment and Output Effects of Short-Time Work in Germany Russell Cooper Moritz Meyer 2 Immo Schott 3 Penn State 2 The World Bank 3 Université de Montréal Social Statistics and Population Dynamics

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates at the effective lower bound for interest rates Bank of England 12 March 2010 Plan Introduction The model The policy problem Results Summary & conclusions Plan Introduction Motivation Aims and scope The

More information

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default Private Leverage and Sovereign Default Cristina Arellano Yan Bai Luigi Bocola FRB Minneapolis University of Rochester Northwestern University Economic Policy and Financial Frictions November 2015 1 / 37

More information

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

Nonlinear Persistence and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID

Nonlinear Persistence and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID AEA Papers and Proceedings 28, 8: 7 https://doi.org/.257/pandp.2849 Nonlinear and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID By Manuel Arellano, Richard Blundell, and Stephane Bonhomme*

More information

Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap

Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap Peter N Bell University of Victoria 12. April 2012 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/38347/ MPRA Paper

More information

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy Mitsuru Katagiri International Monetary Fund October 24, 2017 @Keio University 1 / 42 Disclaimer The views expressed here are those of

More information

Notes for Econ202A: Consumption

Notes for Econ202A: Consumption Notes for Econ22A: Consumption Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas UC Berkeley Fall 215 c Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, 215, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. Disclaimer: These notes are riddled with inconsistencies, typos and

More information

Home Ownership, Savings and Mobility Over The Life Cycle

Home Ownership, Savings and Mobility Over The Life Cycle Introduction Model Results Home Ownership, Savings and Mobility Over The Life Cycle Jonathan Halket Gopal Vasudev NYU January 28, 2009 Jonathan Halket, Gopal Vasudev To Rent or To Own Introduction 30 percent

More information

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Minchung Hsu Pei-Ju Liao GRIPS Academia Sinica October 15, 2010 Abstract This paper aims to discover the impacts

More information

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon Ziemowit Bednarek, Pratish Patel and Cyrus Ramezani December 8, 2014 ABSTRACT Both building blocks of the Sharpe ratio the expected return and the expected volatility

More information

Household Debt and Defaults from 2000 to 2010: The Credit Supply View Online Appendix

Household Debt and Defaults from 2000 to 2010: The Credit Supply View Online Appendix Household Debt and Defaults from 2000 to 2010: The Credit Supply View Online Appendix Atif Mian Princeton University and NBER Amir Sufi University of Chicago Booth School of Business and NBER May 2, 2016

More information

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? October 19, 2009 Ulrike Malmendier, UC Berkeley (joint work with Stefan Nagel, Stanford) 1 The Tale of Depression Babies I don t know

More information

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame Consumption ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2018 1 / 27 Readings GLS Ch. 8 2 / 27 Microeconomics of Macro We now move from the long run (decades

More information

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho Beggar-thy-parents? A Lifecycle Model of Intergenerational Altruism Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho University of New South Wales, Sydney July 2009, CEF Conference Motivation & Question Since Becker (1974), several

More information

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis University of Western Ontario February 2013 Question Main Question: what is the welfare cost/gain of US social safety

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System Shinichi Nishiyama Department of Risk Management and Insurance Georgia State University November 17, 2008 Abstract We extend a standard overlapping-generations

More information