Earnings Precision and the Relations Between Earnings and Returns

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Earnings Precision and the Relations Between Earnings and Returns"

Transcription

1 Earnings Precision and the Relations Between Earnings and Returns Presented by Dr David Burgstahler Julius A Roller Professor of Accounting University of Washington #2017/18-11 The views and opinions expressed in this working paper are those of the author(s) and not necessarily those of the School of Accountancy, Singapore Management University.

2 Earnings Precision and the Relations Between Earnings and Returns* David Burgstahler Julius A. Roller Professor of Accounting University of Washington Elizabeth Chuk University of California - Irvine September 7, 2017 * We appreciate helpful comments on earlier drafts from Bill Beaver, Darren Bernard, Phil Berger, Sunhwa Choi, Dan Collins, Dan Dhaliwal, Ilia Dichev, Michael Eames, Robert Freeman, Weili Ge, Christi Gleason, Michelle Hanlon, Thomas Hemmer, Frank Hodge, Bill Kinney, Bill Lanen, Roby Lehavy, Christian Leuz, Feng Li, Russell Lundholm, Roger Martin, Dawn Matsumoto, Terry Shevlin, Mark Soliman, K.R. Subramanyam, John Wertz and workshop participants at Santa Clara University, Southern Methodist University, Sungkyunkwan University, University of Technology Sydney, and the Universities of Chicago, Houston, Iowa, Michigan, Tennessee, and Washington.

3 Earnings Precision and the Relations Between Earnings and Returns Abstract The low estimates of earnings response coefficients (hereafter, ERCs) reported in the literature have sometimes been interpreted as indicating that earnings information is relatively unimportant (Beaver, Lambert, and Morse 1980; Lev 1989). Prior literature typically documents ERCs in the range of 1 to 3 (Kothari 2001), which is an order of magnitude lower than theoretically plausible annual earnings capitalization factors (hereafter, ECFs) in the range of 10 to 30. This paper uses a simple Bayesian model to highlight and explain differences between the coefficient relating security returns to observable unexpected earnings (i.e., the ERC) versus the coefficient relating changes in firm value to unobservable revisions in expected earnings (i.e., the ECF). In this model, the ERC is the product of a Bayesian weight and the ECF, which implies that the ERC is lower than the ECF and that variation in the relative precision of the earnings signal translates directly into variation in the ERCs. Results for a large sample of widely followed firms from show that proxies for precision explain a broad empirical range of relations between earnings and returns. In fact, we find that the highest precision subsamples have ERCs in the range of 10 to 30. Thus, our model and results reconcile the large gap between typical empirical estimates of ERCs versus plausible values for ECFs, and suggest that earnings information is much more important than the low ERCs in the prior literature would seem to imply. JEL classification: G14, M40 Key Words: Earnings precision, earnings response coefficients, analyst forecasts, uncertainty

4 1. Introduction The vast literature on earnings response coefficients (hereafter, ERCs) examines the relation between stock returns and current-period earnings (Kothari 2001). The magnitude of the return associated with an earnings signal depends on the importance of the information contained in the earnings signal relative to existing information prior to the signal. If the earnings signal is relatively important, then the earnings signal leads to greater revisions in the market s expectations of future earnings and therefore larger price changes. Prior studies typically document ERCs in the range of 1 to 3 (Kothari 2001), which is an order of magnitude lower than theoretically plausible earnings capitalization factors (hereafter, ECFs) in the range of 10 to 30. The low values of empirical ERCs have sometimes been interpreted as indicating that earnings information is relatively unimportant (Beaver, Lambert, and Morse 1980; Lev 1989; Amir and Lev 1996; Lev and Sougiannis 1996; Aboody and Lev 1998; Lev and Zarowin 1999). The objective of our paper is two-fold. First, we model how the relative importance of new versus prior information affects the magnitude of the ERC, the coefficient relating returns and unexpected earnings. Second, we use the model and empirical proxies for the relative importance of new earnings information to reconcile the order-of-magnitude gap between empirical ERCs (in the range of 1 to 3) and theoretical ECFs (in the range of 10 to 30). To discuss the gap between the ECF and the ERC, we invoke a simple Bayesian model similar to the models in Subramanyam (1996), Holthausen and Verrechia (1988), or DeGroot (1970). In the Bayesian model, revised beliefs about expected future earnings after an earnings announcement can be described as a relative weighting of prior information versus new information in the announcement, where the weight on the new earnings information depends on the precision of the new information relative to the precision of the prior information. We define precision of new information contained in the earnings signal in an equity valuation decision Page 1

5 context, such that a higher-precision signal provides higher-quality and more accurate information about expected future earnings. Higher precision earnings signals provide more information about expected future earnings, leading to a higher Bayesian weight on the new information. As explained in more detail in Section 3, the unobservable revision of expected earnings is the product of the Bayesian weight and the observable difference between realized and expected earnings. As a consequence, the ERC, the coefficient on the observable new earnings information, is the product of (i) the Bayesian weight and (ii) the ECF, the coefficient on the unobservable revision of expected earnings. Thus, our decomposition shows how the gap between the ERC and the ECF depends on the precision of the earnings signal. In summary, we show that earnings information is much more important than the low ERCs in the prior literature would seem to imply. The model and results provide several important contributions to the accounting literature. First, the model and results show that the combination of ex ante and ex post precision proxies explains a more substantial range of relations between earnings and returns than previously documented in the literature. In the model, the coefficient on observable unexpected earnings (the ERC) is a fraction of the coefficient on unobservable earnings revision (the ECF), where the fraction is determined by the relative precision of the earnings signal. Results show that when our two proxies for the statistical precision of earnings are high, accounting quality, which we infer from the ERC, is high and when the proxies for precision are low, accounting quality is low. For instance, for observations where both our ex post and ex ante proxies simultaneously indicate high precision, estimated ERCs range as high as 17 to 27, much higher than the ERCs typically reported in the previous literature. For observations where both proxies indicate low precision, Page 2

6 estimated ERCs are near zero. Thus, precision proxies explain much more variation than other empirical determinants of earnings quality previously considered in the literature. 1 Second, we demonstrate that the substantial range in ERCs that we document (as described above) becomes compressed into a low point estimate by research design choices typically employed in the prior literature. When we apply regression consistent with approaches in prior literature (i.e., using a pooled sample without conditioning on precision), the ERC for our sample is low and consistent with the estimates reported in prior studies. However, we demonstrate how the low ERC for the pooled sample is explained by the mechanics of leastsquares regression combined with the strong inverse relation between the magnitude of unexpected earnings, our ex post proxy for precision, and the Bayesian weight on new earnings information. Third, the Bayesian model provides a framework for conjectures about plausible values for the weights that determine ERCs to explain why ERCs documented in the literature are so low. The weights on new versus prior information are relative, so a high weight on new information implies a low weight on prior information. Because the set of information available prior to the announcement of earnings is almost always rich and broad, the plausible relative weight on new information is almost always far below 100%. For example, we conjecture that even high precision fourth-quarter earnings signals have a relative weight no higher than the weight on the rich set of all prior information, which includes earnings from all previous quarters as well as all previously available non-earnings information. This conjecture implies the relative weights on even high precision earnings signals are likely to be no greater than half (i.e., 50%) and, for lower precision earnings, weights are likely to be far lower than 50%. The weights implied by our 1 For example, Ali and Zarowin 1992; Choi and Jeter 1992; and Wilson 2008 document much smaller ranges of ERCs explained, respectively, by earnings persistence; the issuance of qualified audit reports; and earnings restatements. Page 3

7 empirical results are consistent with these conjectures. For the highest precision subsamples (where estimated ERCs are as high as 17 to 27), we find that the implied relative weight on new earnings information is on the order of 40%. For lower precision subsamples, we find that the implied weights are much lower and, for the lowest precision subsamples the implied weights approach 0%. Thus, the model illustrates how differences in precision lead to a wide range of plausible values for Bayesian weights, which in turn lead to a wide range of ERCs that extend from as high as 40% of theoretical ECFs to as low as the low ERCs consistently documented in prior literature. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides background. Section 3 uses a Bayesian model to characterize the effect of relative precision of the earnings signal on the relation between unexpected earnings and returns. Section 4 develops empirical proxies and predictions. Section 5 provides results and discussion, and Section 6 concludes. 2. Background A variety of models express firm value as a function of the stream of future earnings. 2 It is often further assumed that expectations about the stream of future earnings can be summarized in a scalar expected earnings number where firm value can be expressed as an ECF, c, multiplied by the scalar expected earnings. 3 In these earnings capitalization models, the change in value in response to new information is equal to c times the revision in expected earnings in response to new information. The accounting concept of earnings quality corresponds directly to the statistical concept of precision of the earnings signal. In an equity valuation decision context, earnings quality focuses on the amount of information that current earnings provide about future earnings, and 2 See, for example, Beaver 1968, Kormendi and Lipe 1986, or Ohlson See, for example, Miller and Modigliani 1966, Ramakrishnan and Thomas 1998, or Easton et al Page 4

8 hence about firm value. 4 For example, Dechow and Schrand (2004, Chapter 2) define earnings quality in terms of how well current earnings represents the scalar expected earnings: "We define earnings to be of high quality when the earnings number accurately annuitizes the intrinsic value of the firm." In a more abstract model of the relation between an accounting signal and prices, Holthausen and Verrecchia (1988, p. 83) characterize the "quality" of the signal in terms of the variance of the error in the signal (the inverse of its precision): "The potential usefulness of the information is determined, in part, by the variance of its error term (its 'quality')." Earnings quality is determined by both the accounting processes used to measure earnings and by the fundamental economics of earnings processes. Accounting measures that capture more persistent (or more permanent) components of earnings result in a more informative signal about future earnings. 5 In contrast, transitory components of the economic earnings process (such as temporary fluctuations in input or output prices or other non-recurring events such as one-time gains and losses) and transitory components of the accounting measurement process (such as random accounting errors) make current earnings less informative about future earnings and hence less informative about firm value. Despite the theoretical importance of earnings information in determining firm value, the ERC estimates documented in the prior literature appear to suggest that current-period earnings innovations contain little relevant information to market participants. Our study offers a modelbased reconciliation of the inconsistency between the theoretical versus empirical importance of earnings information. The reconciliation hinges on the conceptual distinction between two related 4 Dechow, Ge, and Schrand (2010) provide a comprehensive review of the recent literature on earnings quality. DGS summarize evidence on ten proxies for, and eighteen determinants of, earnings quality in a variety of decision contexts. Earnings response coefficients are directly related to one of these decision contexts, equity valuation decisions. 5 Kormendi and Lipe (1987) develop and test the hypothesis that the coefficient relating earnings to returns is related to persistence assessed based on the parameters from a moving-average time-series model. While they find a statistically significant relation between time-series properties and the magnitude of ERCs, their estimated ERCs remain far below the range of plausible earnings capitalization factors. Page 5

9 concepts. First, the ECF relates firm value to the theoretical construct of expected future earnings, and changes in firm value to changes in expected future earnings. Second, the ERC relates changes in firm value to empirical measures of unexpected earnings. There is an order-ofmagnitude gap between plausible values for the ECF, in the range of 10 to 30, versus empirical estimates of the ERC, which have frequently been in the range of 1 to 3. 6 In the model discussed in Section 3 below, the key insight into why the large gap exists relies the conceptual distinction between the ECF and the ERC, where the ERC can be decomposed into (i) a Bayesian weight and (ii) the ECF Model In this section, we interpret the typical operationalization of the empirical ERC model in the framework of the theoretical Bayesian model of belief revision. Consider a Bayesian model of the revision of beliefs about annuitized future earnings in response to the announcement of earnings. 8 Let pre-announcement beliefs about future earnings be summarized by the mean, m', of a normal prior distribution with precision I', where precision is the inverse of the variance of the prior distribution over firm value. Let the earnings signal, m, be generated by a normal distribution with known precision I, the inverse of the noise component of the signal that current earnings provides about expected future earnings. The predictive distribution for m is normal with expectation equal to the prior expectation of firm value, m', and variance equal to the sum of the variances of the prior distribution and the distribution of the earnings signal. 6 See Kothari and Sloan (1992, p. 144) or Kothari (2001) section for a more extensive review and discussion. 7 Another consideration, explained in more detail later, is that the ECF also depends on the length of the period over which earnings are measured. For example, in the absence of seasonality or other complicating factors, the ECF for quarterly earnings should be roughly four times as large as for annual earnings. As a result, the ERC for unexpected quarterly earnings should be on the order of 4 times larger than the ERC for unexpected earnings for a full year. 8 We use a generic Bayesian revision mechanism and notation from Winkler (1972, pp ) but the model is also consistent with DeGroot (1970) Section 9.5 and other similar discussions of Bayesian revision. Page 6

10 Post-announcement beliefs about annuitized future earnings are described by the posterior distribution, where the posterior mean, m", is a weighted average of the prior mean, m', and the signal, m, where the weight reflects the relative precisions of the prior and the signal: 9 m" (I m I' m') (I I'). (3.1) Equation (3.1) implies the revision in beliefs due to the earnings signal (i.e., the change from the prior belief m' to the posterior belief m") is m" m' I (I I') (m m. (3.2) The revision is the product of two terms: 1) a weight, defined as w = I / (I+I'), and 2) the difference between the realized earnings signal and its expectation (m m'). To convert equation (3.2) from units of expected and realized earnings to units of firm value, each term is multiplied by the ECF, c. The left side becomes the change in market value due to belief revision while the right side is the product of the weight, the ECF, and the deviation of the realized signal from its expectation. 10 cm" cm = w c (m m ). (3.3) 3.1 ERC operationalization of the Bayesian model The standard ERC regression model can be interpreted as an empirical version of the theoretical Bayesian revision represented in equation (3.3). First, divide both sides by market value prior to the announcement of earnings, cm. The left side becomes the return attributable to the earnings signal, operationalized as the announcement period return. The right side becomes the product of w, c, and the deviation of the signal from its expectation scaled by prior market value. This scaled deviation is operationalized as the standard ERC unexpected earnings variable, 9 Equations (3.1) and (3.2) also correspond to equations for the revision of price in period 1 in the model of Holthausen and Verrecchi (1988, pp ). 10 This operation assumes the announcement of earnings does not result in a change in the ECF, c. Page 7

11 announced earnings minus forecast earnings scaled by beginning market value, denoted below by UE. Finally, adding an intercept term, β0, to allow for the possibility of a non-zero expected return during the announcement period and an error term, eit, to allow for the effects of non-earnings information related to firm i during the announcement period, we have the familiar ERC relation for firm i during earnings announcement period t: Rit = β0 + wit c UEit + eit. (3.4) The key insight from Equation (3.4) is that the ERC can be decomposed into two individual components: (i) the Bayesian weight, w, and (ii) the ECF, c. The weight is less than or equal to one and varies with the precision of the earnings signal relative to the precision of the prior information. Consequently, the ERC, the coefficient on UE in (3.4), is a fraction of the ECF, where the fraction is the Bayesian relative weight. The ERC is near zero when the precision of the earnings signal is low relative to the precision of the prior (where the weight is near zero) and increases as the precision of the earnings signal relative to the precision of the prior increases. The low ERCs previously reported in the literature might seem to imply that the weights on new information are consistently small across all observations. However, the results below show that proxies for precision explain substantial empirical variation in ERCs. Specifically, the results suggest that while there are some observations where the weights on new earnings information and the corresponding ERCs are low, there are even more observations for which the weights on new earnings information and the corresponding ERCs are remarkably high. 3.2 Numeric example to illustrate the effect of the Bayesian weight on the ECF Equation (3.4) defines the ERC as the product of a weight and the ECF. In this section, we illustrate the weights implied by ERC estimates for a stylized example assuming an annual ECF common to all observations equal to 15, which 1) is approximately the long-run average priceearnings ratio for the S&P 500 and 2) provides a convenient, round parameter for the numerical Page 8

12 example that illustrates the weights. 11 In the absence of seasonality in earnings, the quarterly ECF is about four times the annual ECF so the assumed annual ECF of 15 translates into a quarterly ECF of 60. The following example illustrates the intuition for the implied weights. Consider a firm with expected annual earnings of $4.00 per share (i.e., expected quarterly earnings of $1.00 per share, assuming no seasonality in earnings) and an annual ECF of 15 (i.e., a quarterly ECF of 60, again assuming no seasonality), which implies a pre-announcement market value of $60.00 per share. 12 Assume announced fourth quarter earnings is $1.50. The $.50 surprise can be variously interpreted as 50% of expected fourth quarter earnings of $1.00 or as 12.5% of expected annual earnings of $ The posterior price, after the announcement of earnings, is the product of the ECF and the posterior belief about expected future earnings, which in turn depends on the relative weight on new earnings information. Therefore, the price, return, and ERC that result from the $.50 surprise also depend on the relative weight. The table below illustrates the posterior beliefs, prices, returns, and ERCs that correspond to five examples of weights in Column II, which range between the extremes of 0% and 100%. Note that the weight on new information in Column II and the weight on prior information in Column III are relative, such that they always add to 100%. At one extreme where the weight on new earnings information is 0% (in the first row), posterior beliefs are unchanged from the prior 11 The assumption of a single ECF common to all observations ignores any inter-temporal or cross-sectional variation in the ECF. However, it is easy to extend the example to consider variation in ECFs and the weight we derive for an assumed ECF of 15 can be easily converted to the weight for alternative values of the ECF. For example, doubling the assumed ECF to 30 implies half the weight implied by an ECF of 15 while cutting the assumed ECF in half to 7.5 implies a weight double the weight implied by an ECF of This example is constructed so that expected quarterly earnings of $1.00 serves as a convenient numeraire. However, conclusions do not depend on the per share amounts the substance of the example is no different when the example is rescaled for expected quarterly earnings equal to $.10 per share, $10.00 per share, or any positive amount per share. 13 To place this example in the context of price-scaled earnings surprise reported later in Table 3 (the scaling that is also frequently used in the previous literature), the implied $.50 earnings surprise represents of market value of $60, which falls in the middle ES magnitude range of ±.01 in Table 3. Page 9

13 beliefs of $1.00 (Column IV) and the posterior price is unchanged from the prior price of $60.00 (Column VII). At the other extreme where the weight on new earnings information is 100% (in the last row), posterior beliefs effectively ignore prior information and are revised completely to the new earnings information, or $1.50 (Column IV), and the posterior price is revised to $90.00 (Column VII). Between these two extremes, the three examples of weights on new information of 20%, 50%, and 80% (in the second, third, and fourth rows, respectively) illustrate cases that result in posterior beliefs between the prior beliefs and the new information. (I) (II) (III) (IV) (V) (VI) (VII) (VIII) (IX) ECF Weight on new information Weight on prior information Posterior expected quarterly earnings % change in expected earnings Prior price Posterior price Return ERC % 100.0% % % % 80.0% % % % 50.0% % % % 20.0% % % % 0.0% % % 60 Columns VII, VIII, and IX of the table summarize how the revision of beliefs translates into price, return, and the ERC. The posterior prices (Column VII) translate into announcement returns that correspond exactly to the percentage change in expected future earnings (Column V), ranging from 0% to 50%. The returns translate into ERCs ranging from 0 (for a weight on new information of 0% in the first row) to 60, the ECF (for a weight on new information of 100% in the last row). Thus, consistent with equation (3.4), the ERC is the product of (i) the quarterly ECF in Column I and (ii) the weight on new information in Column II). In the example, the weight (Column II) determines the posterior expected earnings (Column IV) which, together with the ECF (Column I), implies the posterior price (Column VII) and return (Column VIII). In empirical applications, we use the observed price and return together Page 10

14 with the assumed ECF to infer the posterior expected earnings and the weight on new earnings information. Using the numbers from the second row of the table to illustrate the inference, an observed return of 10% (Column VIII) implies a weight on the new earnings information of 20% (Column II), which is the ratio of the ERC (Column IX) to the quarterly ECF (Column I) Empirical Proxies In this section, we develop proxies for precision based on two conjectures: (1) lower precision earnings processes tend to generate larger magnitude unexpected earnings and (2) lower precision earnings processes tend to be accompanied by greater dispersion among analyst forecasts. These two conjectures lead to proxies based on either (1) realized deviations of earnings from expectations, or (2) variation among analyst earnings forecasts. The first conjecture is consistent with both prior empirical evidence and with formal models. There is a long stream of empirical evidence showing an S-shaped aggregate relation between unexpected earnings and security market returns, consistent with a negative relation between the magnitude of unexpected earnings and precision. Beaver, Clarke, and Wright (1979) report an S-shaped relation for the average returns for portfolios formed on the magnitude of unexpected annual earnings. Freeman and Tse (1992) examine the relation for unexpected quarterly earnings and fit an S-shaped functional form based on the arctangent function. Kinney, Burgstahler, and Martin (2002) use a portfolio approach that extends the original Beaver, Clarke, and Wright methodology, and also report strong visual and statistical evidence of the S-shape. The formal model in Subramanyam (1996) illustrates how precision of the earnings signal is inferred from the magnitude of unexpected earnings, which leads to an S-shaped relation that is more steeply-sloped for smaller magnitude unexpected earnings and flatter for larger magnitude 14 The weight of 20% can also be interpreted as the ratio 10%/50%, i.e., the ratio of the percentage revision of expected quarterly earnings (10%) divided by the earnings surprise as a percentage of expected quarterly earnings, 50% (=$.50/$1.00) Page 11

15 unexpected earnings. Subramanyam (1996) outlines reasons to believe that precision is inferred from the magnitude of unexpected earnings: (A)n examination of institutional features and the information environment reveals that the market is unlikely to have perfect knowledge of the signal precision ex ante. For example, in the case of an earnings announcement, a number of the determinants of information accuracy--such as the proportion of transitory cash flows and other non-recurring items, and the effect of changes in accounting methods--are specific to each announcement, and the market is unlikely to have perfect a priori knowledge of them. In addition, accrual earnings incorporates estimates of future events, but managers rarely report the precision of those estimates. Therefore, a descriptively richer analysis is one which incorporates ex ante uncertainty regarding signal precision. Note that uncertain precision does not imply that the market has no ex ante information regarding signal quality, it merely implies that the market does not have perfect ex ante information. (p. 208) The second conjecture is based on evidence in Kinney, Burgstahler, and Martin (2002, hereafter KBM) for a sample of First Call forecasts from 1992 through The results show that the S-shape relation between returns and magnitude of unexpected earnings is steeper and more pronounced among observations with lower forecast dispersion and flatter and more nearly linear among observations with higher dispersion, consistent with the conjecture that forecast dispersion is inversely related to relative precision of the earnings signal. However, forecast dispersion is affected by a number of factors other than precision, and these factors potentially affect dispersion as a proxy for precision. For example, dispersion reflects differences in analysts priors that result from heterogeneity of information or information processing skill among analysts (Barron et al. 1998) and analysts incentives to herd (Trueman 1994), so forecast dispersion may include noise unrelated to precision. Dieter, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002) consider a variety of possible interpretations for forecast dispersion. They conclude that dispersion is a proxy for differences in opinion among investors, though differences of opinion might also result from other factors that have little or nothing to do with relative precision. Finally, Yeung (2009) suggests forecast dispersion could be positively related to the relative precision of the current earnings signal if higher forecast dispersion proxies for lower Page 12

16 precision of prior information. In sum, the KBM conjecture that lower forecast dispersion may proxy for higher precision of the earnings signal remains an open empirical question. Based on these two conjectures, we develop the following proxies for precision: 1. Magnitude of current unexpected earnings: The first proxy, the magnitude of current unexpected earnings, is only observable ex post (i.e., after realization of the earnings signal). The ex post proxy is based on extensive empirical evidence of an S-shaped relation between unexpected earning and returns and on the theoretical model in Subramanyam (1996). 2. Dispersion of current analyst forecasts: The second proxy, analyst forecast dispersion, is observable ex ante (i.e., prior to realization of the earnings signal). The ex ante proxy is motivated by the empirical evidence and conjecture in KBM and by the Dieter, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002) conjecture that dispersion may proxy for differences in opinion among investors. In order to have meaningful measures of standard deviation, the analysis based on this proxy is restricted to observations where there are four or more analyst forecasts. In the next section, we present evidence on the relations between these proxies and the relation between the proxies and ERCs. Our predictions are as follows. First, we expect a positive relation between precision and ERCs, as higher-precision earnings information is expected to lead to larger revisions in beliefs about firm value. 15 Second, because the ex ante and ex post proxies are separate measures of precision, they potentially each provide incremental information about ERCs. For example, holding the value of the ex post proxy constant, subsamples with higher ex ante precision are likely to have higher ERCs than subsamples with lower ex ante precision. Third, because both are proxies for the same construct (i.e., precision), we expect them to be positively correlated. Finally, to the extent that precision is a stable characteristic resulting from the accounting and economic processes that create earnings quality, we also expect the proxies to be positively autocorrelated. 15 Statements about the relation can be confusing because lower values of the precision proxies (i.e., smaller magnitude unexpected earnings or smaller forecast dispersion) indicate higher precision. To minimize the potential for confusion, we refer to the theoretical construct as precision and each empirical measure as a precision proxy. Using this terminological convention, we expect a positive relation between precision and ERCs but a negative relation between each precision proxy and ERCs. Page 13

17 5. Data and Results We obtain data from the IBES database for the 23-year period We measure the following variables from IBES: earnings surprise (defined as actual EPS minus the consensus forecast as of the last update before the announcement of earnings for the year, where the consensus forecast serves as the measure of expected earnings), the number of analyst forecasts used in computing the consensus forecast, and forecast dispersion (defined as the standard deviation of analyst forecasts). 16 Accounting and stock return data are obtained from Compustat and CRSP. We measure announcement period returns as raw return minus the value-weighted market return accumulated over a 22-day window extending from day -20 to +1 relative to the day of the announcement of earnings. 17 We scale earnings surprise and forecast dispersion by price at the end of the fiscal year (Compustat data item PRCC_F), which is typically shortly before the beginning of the return period. Table 1 provides descriptive statistics for the final sample of firm-years with the necessary IBES analyst forecast, accounting, and stock return data and where price-scaled earnings surprise is in the range between and The descriptive statistics are generally comparable to the older and smaller sample in KBM. Panel A shows that all four size measures have rightskewed distributions with means greater than the 75 th percentile. Panel B provides descriptive 16 Payne and Thomas (2003) report that versions of IBES data adjusted for stock splits and then rounded to the nearest penny sometimes incorrectly include zero forecast error for firms with stock splits even when the actual forecast error is non-zero. Also, the standard deviation of analyst forecasts computed using the split-adjusted and rounded forecasts is mechanically reduced for firms with stock splits. However, because we use the unadjusted IBES data, our measures of earnings surprise and dispersion of analyst forecasts should not be affected by these issues. 17 We also computed our primary results 1) using raw returns minus the equally-weighted market return, and 2) using a shorter 3-day return window extending only from day -1 to +1. Results using the equally-weighted market return are similar to those reported here. Results using 3-day returns are similar to the reported results except that the magnitude of the return reactions and the associated ERCs are reduced by as much as 50% for the 3-day return window, consistent with previous evidence that a substantial portion of earnings information "leaks" to market participants during days -20 to -2 prior to the actual announcement. 18 Although the range in figures later in the paper is similarly restricted to the range between -.02 and +.02, subsequent tables generally include results for the entire unrestricted range of earnings surprise. Page 14

18 statistics showing some changes in sample properties over time such as growth in the number of analyst forecast observations available and decreases in the mean and median forecast dispersion. The statistics do not highlight any important differences from samples commonly used to examine the relation between returns and earnings. Similar to many previous ERC samples, this sample should not be construed as representative of the entire population of Compustat firms because it is conditioned on analyst coverage and specifically excludes firms not covered by analysts. At the same time, this conditional sample covers a large proportion of the total market value of firms in the entire Compustat population, as shown in the last few lines of Panel B. In most years, the proportion of market value represented by firms followed by 2 or more analysts is between 72% and 81% of the total market value of the population of firms on Compustat and the proportion represented by firms followed by 4 or more analysts is between 56% and 72% of total market value. 5.1 Effect of Ex Post Proxy Figure 1 plots statistics describing the distribution of returns corresponding to portfolios of 1,000 observations formed on the ex post proxy, magnitude of earnings surprise. Consistent with previous results in KBM (2002), Freeman and Tse (1992), and Beaver, Clarke, and Wright (1979), and consistent with the Subramanyam (1996) model where the magnitude of earnings surprise proxies for precision of the earnings signal, the relation exhibits a pronounced S-shape. 19 This S- shape is reflected in all of the return distribution statistics (mean, median, 25 th, and 75 th percentile 19 For earnings surprise beyond the range plotted in Figure 1, the S-shape turns back toward zero for more extreme earnings surprise, consistent with the Subramanyam model. Note also that there is no evidence in Figure 1 (nor later in Figure 3) of an asymmetrically larger effect for slightly negative earnings surprise than for slightly positive earnings surprise. In fact, unreported statistical tests suggest that the coefficient on small positive earnings surprise is usually significantly larger than the coefficient on small negative earnings surprise. Thus, the "torpedo effect" reported in Skinner and Sloan (2002) for a subsample of high growth firms does not generalize to our broad sample of firms. Page 15

19 returns) so the S-shape reflects broad distributional effects, and not the influence of a few unusual observations ERC Estimates We next turn to estimated ERCs and tests of statistical significance corresponding to Figure 1. Table 2 shows estimates of the ERC, β1, for different values of the ex post proxy, beginning with the estimate for unrestricted magnitude of earnings surprise, followed successively by estimates for earnings surprise restricted to the ranges ±.02, ±.01, ±.005, and finally ± Panel A provides results for the total sample of 96,745 observations while Panels B and C provide results for two subsamples. Panel B comprises observations with 4 or more analyst forecasts (for which our ex ante proxy is defined) and Panel C includes the remaining observations with less than 4 analyst forecasts. For the total sample in Panel A, the ERC, corresponding to witc in equation (3.4), for the unrestricted range of earnings surprise is essentially zero. However, as ex post precision increases (i.e., as the magnitude of earnings surprise decreases), the estimated ERCs grow. When the magnitude of earnings surprise is limited to the range ±.02, the ERC increases to about 3 and when the magnitude is successively cut in half to ±.01, then ±.005, and finally ±.0025, the ERC increases to about 5, then 8, and finally Successive narrowing of the included range of earnings surprise reduces the sample size but even the narrowest range includes almost half (about 46%) of the original entire sample in Panel A and more than half (about 60%) of the original defined-dispersion subsample in Panel B. 20 The results reported here are qualitatively consistent with the results for the smaller sample in KBM except 1) the rate of increase in the ERC as the range of earnings surprise is narrowed is smaller for our larger, more recent sample, and 2) KBM report continued substantial increases in ERCs as the range is narrowed even further than ± We do not report results for the much narrower ranges considered in KBM because these ranges comprise smaller and smaller subsets of the overall sample as well as smaller and smaller surprises. For our sample, unreported results show a continued increase in ERCs for the next narrower range of earnings surprise (.00125) though the increase is smaller than in KBM. Page 16

20 The product of an earnings surprise and the corresponding estimated ERC implies a predicted percentage return and percentage revision in expected earnings. 21 For example, a surprise equal to.0025 multiplied by the corresponding ERC of implies a predicted return and percentage revision in expected earnings of.0025 x = 3.30%. However, because the ERC is smaller for larger surprises, larger surprises do not imply proportionally higher revisions in expected earnings. For example, a surprise that is twice as large, equal to.005, multiplied by the smaller ERC of for these smaller surprises implies a predicted return and percentage revision in expected earnings that is less than twice as large, namely.005 x = 4.15%. Further doubling of the magnitude, for surprises equal to.01 or.02, similarly imply predicted returns (and percentage revisions in expected earnings) that do not increase proportional to the surprise, but instead increase to only 5.11% or 6.25%, respectively. Thus, because the ERC decreases as the largest earnings surprise in each successive range doubles, the corresponding return and percentage revision in expected earnings does not double, but rather increases at a much slower rate. Returning to the numeric example in Section 3.2, we can calculate the weight implied by the ratio of the ERC and the assumed quarterly ECF of 60 for any of the earnings surprise ranges in Table 2 Panel A. For example, the ERC for the unrestricted range implies a weight of approximately 0% =.001/60. As precision increases for increasingly narrow ranges of earnings surprise, the implied weight increases to 5.2% = 3.126/60, then 8.5% = 5.111/60, then 13.8% = 8.303/60, and finally, for surprises in the narrowest range ±.0025, to 22% = / Thus, the ex post precision proxy by itself identifies substantial variation in the ERC and in the implied 21 The equivalence of the percentage return and percentage revision in expected earnings follows from the assumption that equity value is the product of expected earnings and the ECF combined with the assumption that the ECF is not affected by the earnings announcement. 22 While the narrowest range of earnings surprise appears numerically small, it 1) includes a large proportion (44,416 / 96,475 = 46%) of all observations, and 2) is not limited to only trivial earnings surprises it includes surprises up to 15% of expected quarterly earnings. Page 17

21 weight on new earnings information. Results in Section 5.2 below show that by partitioning on both the ex post proxy and an ex ante proxy, we can identify subsamples with even higher precision and larger implied weights on new earnings information Evidence of another proxy for precision: analyst coverage Finally, before we turn to exploration of the role of specific ex ante proxies for precision, the results in Table 2 Panels B and C provide evidence of another variable related to precision: analyst coverage. There is evidence in the literature that analysts are less likely to cover firms with earnings that are more difficult to forecast (Stickel 1992 and Mikhail, Walther, and Willis 1999). As a result, analyst coverage may be another ex ante proxy for precision, i.e., firms covered by fewer analysts may have lower precision than firms covered by more analysts. The results in Table 2 are consistent with this conjecture. The ERCs (and the implied weights on new information) for the subsample of 52,388 observations with 4 or more analyst forecasts in Panel B are generally substantially larger than the corresponding ERCs for the subsample of 44,357 observations with fewer than 4 forecasts in Panel C. For each of the restricted ranges of earnings surprise, the ERCs in Panel B range from 56% to 82% larger than in Panel C. For the unrestricted range of earnings surprise, the relative difference is even larger, as the ERC for the subsample covered by more analysts is several hundred percent larger. 5.2 Effect of Specific Ex Ante Proxies We next evaluate the incremental effect of an ex ante proxy relative to the ex post proxy, to examine whether the ex ante proxy provides incremental information about ERCs. In Sections through 5.2.4, we focus on the ex ante proxy defined in Section 4. Then, in Section we present results for two alternative ex ante proxies Incremental Effect of the Ex Ante Proxy To condition on precision using the ex ante proxy, we sort observations with at least four analyst forecasts into three approximately equal-sized subsets based on the price-scaled standard Page 18

22 deviation of contemporaneous analyst forecasts. The three subsets comprise 17,464 high precision observations, 17,458 medium precision observations, and 17,466 low precision observations. Figure 2 provides evidence on the relation between the ex ante proxy and the ex post proxy by plotting distributions of price-scaled earnings surprise for subsets defined by low, medium, and high forecast dispersion. The low dispersion subset includes mainly small magnitude earnings surprise, tightly concentrated around zero. As we move to higher dispersion subsets, the proportion of larger magnitude earnings surprise increases. 23 Thus, Figure 2 illustrates two important facts: First, the ex post and ex ante precision proxies are strongly positively correlated, as expected if the proxies measure the same construct. 24 Second, because the correlation between the two proxies is less than perfect, there is the potential for the proxies to be empirical complements, where each proxy may provide information incremental to the other. We next depict the relation between returns and earnings surprise within each of the ex ante precision groups, using an approach that corresponds to Figure 1. For each of the three forecast dispersion subsets, Figure 3 shows a plot of the return distribution statistics for portfolios of 500 observations formed on scaled earnings surprise. Lower dispersion observations are predicted to have higher ERCs due to higher precision and the resulting higher weight on the current earnings signal. Consistent with this prediction, the slope of the relation is much steeper for the low dispersion subset in Panel A than for the high dispersion subset in Panel C, with the slope for the medium dispersion subset in Panel B falling between the slopes for the low and high dispersion subsets. 23 The vertical bars at the endpoints of the earnings surprise axis represent the combined frequency of all observations that fall beyond the limits of the horizontal axis. For instance, in the high dispersion subset, the height of the bar at the extreme earnings surprise of indicates there are more than 2,000 observations with earnings surprise less than In each histogram, the checkered bar represents the frequency of exact zero earnings surprise. Also note that each histogram exhibits a pronounced discontinuity at zero earnings surprise, consistent with prior research (e.g., Burgstahler and Eames 2006). 24 The Spearman (Pearson) correlation coefficient between the two proxies is 0.60 (0.54), where the Pearson correlation is computed after winsorizing at the 1 st and 99 th percentiles. Page 19

23 Within each of the subsets conditioned on forecast dispersion, the overall relation is also more nearly linear than in the unconditional relation in Figure 1, as expected if the partitioning based on forecast dispersion yields subsets where precision is more homogeneous within each precision group than in the three groups combined. 25 The conditional relations for the subsets in the three panels also provide a visual explanation as to how the more pronounced S-shape arises in the unconditional relation in Figure 1. Because of the strong correlation between forecast dispersion and earnings surprise magnitude shown in Figure 2, most of the small magnitude earnings surprise observations correspond to the more-steeply-sloped relation in Figure 3 Panel A, forming the more-steeply-sloped center of the S-shape, while most of the large magnitude earnings surprise observations correspond to the less-steeply-sloped relation in Panel C, forming the lesssteeply-sloped tails of the S-shape ERC Estimates and Tests of Significance Table 3 reports estimated ERCs and tests of statistical significance. The ex ante precision proxy based on the dispersion of contemporaneous analyst forecasts has significant explanatory power, both by itself and incremental to the ex post proxy. By itself, the ex ante proxy has significant explanatory power. Comparing ERCs without taking the ex post proxy into account (i.e. comparing results for the unrestricted range of earnings surprise across the three panels), the ERC for the high ex ante precision group is significantly higher than the ERC for either the medium or low precision group. Incremental to the ex post proxy, the ex ante proxy again has 25 Unless precision within each subset is strictly homogeneous, the earnings-return relations within the three ex ante precision subsets are expected to be more linear but still S-shaped. The individual precision subsets are not likely to reflect strictly homogeneous precision, both because the partitioning variable is subject to proxy error and because each of the three partitions includes a range, rather than a single value, of the precision proxy. 26 Note that Figure 1 is not simply the aggregation of the 52,388 observations represented in the three panels of Figure 3 because Figure 1 includes an additional 44,357 undefined dispersion observations with three or fewer analyst forecasts. The decision by analysts to produce forecasts for a firm is not random, so undefined dispersion observations are likely to differ systematically from defined dispersion observations, as noted in the discussion of Table 2 above. Page 20

Earnings Precision and the Relations Between Earnings and Returns*

Earnings Precision and the Relations Between Earnings and Returns* Earnings Precision and the Relations Between Earnings and Returns* David Burgstahler Julius A. Roller Professor of Accounting University of Washington Elizabeth Chuk University of Southern California December

More information

DETERMINING THE EFFECT OF POST-EARNINGS-ANNOUNCEMENT DRIFT ON VARYING DEGREES OF EARNINGS SURPRISE MAGNITUDE TOM SCHNEIDER ( ) Abstract

DETERMINING THE EFFECT OF POST-EARNINGS-ANNOUNCEMENT DRIFT ON VARYING DEGREES OF EARNINGS SURPRISE MAGNITUDE TOM SCHNEIDER ( ) Abstract DETERMINING THE EFFECT OF POST-EARNINGS-ANNOUNCEMENT DRIFT ON VARYING DEGREES OF EARNINGS SURPRISE MAGNITUDE TOM SCHNEIDER (20157803) Abstract In this paper I explore signal detection theory (SDT) as an

More information

Earnings Surprise Materiality as Measured by Stock Returns

Earnings Surprise Materiality as Measured by Stock Returns Journal of Accounting Research Vol. 40 No. 5 December 2002 Printed in U.S.A. Earnings Surprise Materiality as Measured by Stock Returns WILLIAM KINNEY, DAVID BURGSTAHLER, AND ROGER MARTIN Received 3 January

More information

The Decreasing Trend in Cash Effective Tax Rates. Alexander Edwards Rotman School of Management University of Toronto

The Decreasing Trend in Cash Effective Tax Rates. Alexander Edwards Rotman School of Management University of Toronto The Decreasing Trend in Cash Effective Tax Rates Alexander Edwards Rotman School of Management University of Toronto alex.edwards@rotman.utoronto.ca Adrian Kubata University of Münster, Germany adrian.kubata@wiwi.uni-muenster.de

More information

Valuation of tax expense

Valuation of tax expense Valuation of tax expense Jacob Thomas Yale University School of Management (203) 432-5977 jake.thomas@yale.edu Frank Zhang Yale University School of Management (203) 432-7938 frank.zhang@yale.edu August

More information

MIT Sloan School of Management

MIT Sloan School of Management MIT Sloan School of Management Working Paper 4262-02 September 2002 Reporting Conservatism, Loss Reversals, and Earnings-based Valuation Peter R. Joos, George A. Plesko 2002 by Peter R. Joos, George A.

More information

The Impact of Analysts Forecast Errors and Forecast Revisions on Stock Prices

The Impact of Analysts Forecast Errors and Forecast Revisions on Stock Prices The Impact of Analysts Forecast Errors and Forecast Revisions on Stock Prices William Beaver, 1 Bradford Cornell, 2 Wayne R. Landsman, 3 and Stephen R. Stubben 3 April 2007 1. Graduate School of Business,

More information

What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium?

What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium? What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium? Hae mi Choi Loyola University Chicago This study investigates what drives the earnings announcement premium. Prior studies have offered various explanations

More information

Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence

Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence Joshua Livnat Department of Accounting Stern School of Business Administration New York University 311 Tisch Hall

More information

The Effect of Matching on Firm Earnings Components

The Effect of Matching on Firm Earnings Components Scientific Annals of Economics and Business 64 (4), 2017, 513-524 DOI: 10.1515/saeb-2017-0033 The Effect of Matching on Firm Earnings Components Joong-Seok Cho *, Hyung Ju Park ** Abstract Using a sample

More information

Margaret Kim of School of Accountancy

Margaret Kim of School of Accountancy Distinguished Lecture Series School of Accountancy W. P. Carey School of Business Arizona State University Margaret Kim of School of Accountancy W.P. Carey School of Business Arizona State University will

More information

Investor Uncertainty and the Earnings-Return Relation

Investor Uncertainty and the Earnings-Return Relation Investor Uncertainty and the Earnings-Return Relation Dissertation Proposal Defended: December 3, 2004 Kenneth J. Reichelt Ph.D. Candidate School of Accountancy University of Missouri Columbia Columbia,

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

The Impact of Analysts Forecast Errors and Forecast Revisions on Stock Prices

The Impact of Analysts Forecast Errors and Forecast Revisions on Stock Prices The Impact of Analysts Forecast Errors and Forecast Revisions on Stock Prices William Beaver, 1 Bradford Cornell, 2 Wayne R. Landsman, 3 and Stephen R. Stubben 1 First Draft: October, 2004 Current Draft:

More information

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LVI, NO. 6 DEC. 2001 Dividend Changes and Future Profitability DORON NISSIM and AMIR ZIV* ABSTRACT We investigate the relation between dividend changes and future profitability,

More information

Tests of Investor Learning Models Using Earnings Innovations and Implied Volatilities

Tests of Investor Learning Models Using Earnings Innovations and Implied Volatilities Tests of Investor Learning Models Using Earnings Innovations and Implied Volatilities Thaddeus Neururer Boston University Edward J. Riedl * Boston University October 2014 Abstract: This paper investigates

More information

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality DORON NISSIM* Corporate disclosures are an important source of information for investors. Many studies have documented strong price

More information

Very preliminary. Comments welcome. Value-relevant properties of smoothed earnings. December, 2002

Very preliminary. Comments welcome. Value-relevant properties of smoothed earnings. December, 2002 Very preliminary. Comments welcome. Value-relevant properties of smoothed earnings December, 2002 by Jacob K. Thomas (JKT1@columbia.edu) and Huai Zhang (huaiz@uic.edu) Columbia Business School, New York,

More information

Assessing the reliability of regression-based estimates of risk

Assessing the reliability of regression-based estimates of risk Assessing the reliability of regression-based estimates of risk 17 June 2013 Stephen Gray and Jason Hall, SFG Consulting Contents 1. PREPARATION OF THIS REPORT... 1 2. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY... 2 3. INTRODUCTION...

More information

Increased Information Content of Earnings Announcements in the 21st Century: An Empirical Investigation

Increased Information Content of Earnings Announcements in the 21st Century: An Empirical Investigation Increased Information Content of Earnings Announcements in the 21st Century: An Empirical Investigation William H. Beaver Joan E. Horngren Professor (Emeritus) Graduate School of Business, Stanford University,

More information

The cross section of expected stock returns

The cross section of expected stock returns The cross section of expected stock returns Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER This version: March 2013 First draft: October 2010 Tel: 603-646-8650; email: jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu. I am grateful

More information

Do the Market Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors Matter with Earnings Management in the U.S. Banking Industry?

Do the Market Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors Matter with Earnings Management in the U.S. Banking Industry? Min-Lee Chan Kai-Li Wang & Pin-Shiuan Chen o the Market Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors Matter with Earnings Management in the U.S. Banking Industry? (Received Sep 30 2008; First Revision Jan 15 2009;

More information

The predictive qualities of earnings volatility and earnings uncertainty

The predictive qualities of earnings volatility and earnings uncertainty The predictive qualities of earnings volatility and earnings uncertainty Dain C. Donelson McCombs School of Business, University of Texas at Austin 2110 Speedway Avenue, B6400 Austin, TX 78712 dain.donelson@mccombs.utexas.edu

More information

Journal of Applied Business Research Volume 20, Number 4

Journal of Applied Business Research Volume 20, Number 4 Management Compensation And Project Life Charles I. Harter, (E-mail: charles.harter@ndsu.nodak.edu), North Dakota State University T. Harikumar, New Mexico State University Abstract The goal of this paper

More information

Do Investors Fully Understand the Implications of the Persistence of Revenue and Expense Surprises for Future Prices?

Do Investors Fully Understand the Implications of the Persistence of Revenue and Expense Surprises for Future Prices? Do Investors Fully Understand the Implications of the Persistence of Revenue and Expense Surprises for Future Prices? Narasimhan Jegadeesh Dean s Distinguished Professor Goizueta Business School Emory

More information

Errors in Estimating Unexpected Accruals in the Presence of. Large Changes in Net External Financing

Errors in Estimating Unexpected Accruals in the Presence of. Large Changes in Net External Financing Errors in Estimating Unexpected Accruals in the Presence of Large Changes in Net External Financing Yaowen Shan (University of Technology, Sydney) Stephen Taylor* (University of Technology, Sydney) Terry

More information

Research Methods in Accounting

Research Methods in Accounting 01130591 Research Methods in Accounting Capital Markets Research in Accounting Dr Polwat Lerskullawat: fbuspwl@ku.ac.th Dr Suthawan Prukumpai: fbusswp@ku.ac.th Assoc Prof Tipparat Laohavichien: fbustrl@ku.ac.th

More information

THE OPTION MARKET S ANTICIPATION OF INFORMATION CONTENT IN EARNINGS ANNOUNCEMENTS

THE OPTION MARKET S ANTICIPATION OF INFORMATION CONTENT IN EARNINGS ANNOUNCEMENTS THE OPTION MARKET S ANTICIPATION OF INFORMATION CONTENT IN EARNINGS ANNOUNCEMENTS - New York University Robert Jennings - Indiana University October 23, 2010 Research question How does information content

More information

The Implications of Using Stock-Split Adjusted I/B/E/S Data in Empirical Research

The Implications of Using Stock-Split Adjusted I/B/E/S Data in Empirical Research The Implications of Using Stock-Split Adjusted I/B/E/S Data in Empirical Research Jeff L. Payne Gatton College of Business and Economics University of Kentucky Lexington, KY 40507, USA and Wayne B. Thomas

More information

The Reconciling Role of Earnings in Equity Valuation

The Reconciling Role of Earnings in Equity Valuation The Reconciling Role of Earnings in Equity Valuation Bixia Xu Assistant Professor School of Business Wilfrid Laurier University Waterloo, Ontario, N2L 3C5 (519) 884-0710 ext. 2659; Fax: (519) 884.0201;

More information

Surprising absence of scale for forecast error magnitudes and forecast dispersion. Foong Soon Cheong Rutgers University

Surprising absence of scale for forecast error magnitudes and forecast dispersion. Foong Soon Cheong Rutgers University Surprising absence of scale for forecast error magnitudes and forecast dispersion Foong Soon Cheong Rutgers University fscheong@rutgers.edu Jacob Thomas Yale University jake.thomas@yale.edu Current Version:

More information

A Synthesis of Accrual Quality and Abnormal Accrual Models: An Empirical Implementation

A Synthesis of Accrual Quality and Abnormal Accrual Models: An Empirical Implementation A Synthesis of Accrual Quality and Abnormal Accrual Models: An Empirical Implementation Jinhan Pae a* a Korea University Abstract Dechow and Dichev s (2002) accrual quality model suggests that the Jones

More information

Accounting Conservatism and the Relation Between Returns and Accounting Data

Accounting Conservatism and the Relation Between Returns and Accounting Data Review of Accounting Studies, 9, 495 521, 2004 Ó 2004 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Manufactured in The Netherlands. Accounting Conservatism and the Relation Between Returns and Accounting Data PETER EASTON*

More information

Internal versus external equity funding sources and earnings response coefficients

Internal versus external equity funding sources and earnings response coefficients Title Internal versus external equity funding sources and earnings response coefficients Author(s) Park, CW; Pincus, M Citation Review Of Quantitative Finance And Accounting, 2001, v. 16 n. 1, p. 33-52

More information

The Effects of Shared-opinion Audit Reports on Perceptions of Audit Quality

The Effects of Shared-opinion Audit Reports on Perceptions of Audit Quality The Effects of Shared-opinion Audit Reports on Perceptions of Audit Quality Yan-Jie Yang, Yuan Ze University, College of Management, Taiwan. Email: yanie@saturn.yzu.edu.tw Qian Long Kweh, Universiti Tenaga

More information

J. Account. Public Policy

J. Account. Public Policy J. Account. Public Policy 28 (2009) 16 32 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect J. Account. Public Policy journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jaccpubpol The value relevance of R&D across profit

More information

Adrian Kubata University of Muenster, Germany

Adrian Kubata University of Muenster, Germany A Rxamination of the Associations betwn Earnings Innovations, Persistence of Expected Earnings, Price-to-Earnings Ratios, and Earnings Response Coefficients Adrian Kubata University of Muenster, Germany

More information

Core CFO and Future Performance. Abstract

Core CFO and Future Performance. Abstract Core CFO and Future Performance Rodrigo S. Verdi Sloan School of Management Massachusetts Institute of Technology 50 Memorial Drive E52-403A Cambridge, MA 02142 rverdi@mit.edu Abstract This paper investigates

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

Why Returns on Earnings Announcement Days are More Informative than Other Days

Why Returns on Earnings Announcement Days are More Informative than Other Days Why Returns on Earnings Announcement Days are More Informative than Other Days Jeffery Abarbanell Kenan-Flagler Business School University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Jeffery_Abarbanell@unc.edu Sangwan

More information

Interactions between Analyst and Management Earnings Forecasts: The Roles of Financial and Non-Financial Information

Interactions between Analyst and Management Earnings Forecasts: The Roles of Financial and Non-Financial Information Interactions between Analyst and Management Earnings Forecasts: The Roles of Financial and Non-Financial Information Lawrence D. Brown Seymour Wolfbein Distinguished Professor Department of Accounting

More information

The Role of Accounting Accruals in Chinese Firms *

The Role of Accounting Accruals in Chinese Firms * 10.7603/s40570-014-0011-5 148 2014 年 6 月第 16 卷第 2 期 中国会计与财务研究 C h i n a A c c o u n t i n g a n d F i n a n c e R e v i e w Volume 16, Number 2 June 2014 The Role of Accounting Accruals in Chinese Firms

More information

Management of reported and forecast EPS and the extent to which investors adjust. Foong Soon Cheong NYU Shanghai

Management of reported and forecast EPS and the extent to which investors adjust. Foong Soon Cheong NYU Shanghai Management of reported and forecast EPS and the extent to which investors adjust Foong Soon Cheong NYU Shanghai fscheong@nyu.edu Jacob Thomas Yale University jake.thomas@yale.edu Current Version: June

More information

Does R&D Influence Revisions in Earnings Forecasts as it does with Forecast Errors?: Evidence from the UK. Seraina C.

Does R&D Influence Revisions in Earnings Forecasts as it does with Forecast Errors?: Evidence from the UK. Seraina C. Does R&D Influence Revisions in Earnings Forecasts as it does with Forecast Errors?: Evidence from the UK Seraina C. Anagnostopoulou Athens University of Economics and Business Department of Accounting

More information

Historical Trends in the Degree of Federal Income Tax Progressivity in the United States

Historical Trends in the Degree of Federal Income Tax Progressivity in the United States Kennesaw State University DigitalCommons@Kennesaw State University Faculty Publications 5-14-2012 Historical Trends in the Degree of Federal Income Tax Progressivity in the United States Timothy Mathews

More information

The predictive power of investment and accruals

The predictive power of investment and accruals The predictive power of investment and accruals Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu Robert J. Resutek Dartmouth College robert.j.resutek@dartmouth.edu This version:

More information

The Vasicek adjustment to beta estimates in the Capital Asset Pricing Model

The Vasicek adjustment to beta estimates in the Capital Asset Pricing Model The Vasicek adjustment to beta estimates in the Capital Asset Pricing Model 17 June 2013 Contents 1. Preparation of this report... 1 2. Executive summary... 2 3. Issue and evaluation approach... 4 3.1.

More information

Random Variables and Probability Distributions

Random Variables and Probability Distributions Chapter 3 Random Variables and Probability Distributions Chapter Three Random Variables and Probability Distributions 3. Introduction An event is defined as the possible outcome of an experiment. In engineering

More information

Information in Accruals about the Quality of Earnings*

Information in Accruals about the Quality of Earnings* Information in Accruals about the Quality of Earnings* Scott Richardson a Richard G. Sloan a Mark Soliman a and Irem Tuna a First Version: July 2001 * We acknowledge the helpful comments of Patricia Dechow.

More information

Pricing and Mispricing in the Cross Section

Pricing and Mispricing in the Cross Section Pricing and Mispricing in the Cross Section D. Craig Nichols Whitman School of Management Syracuse University James M. Wahlen Kelley School of Business Indiana University Matthew M. Wieland J.M. Tull School

More information

SCHOOL OF FINANCE AND ECONOMICS

SCHOOL OF FINANCE AND ECONOMICS SCHOOL OF FINANCE AND ECONOMICS UTS:BUSINESS WORKING PAPER NO. 116 APRIL, 2002 Solving the Price-Earnings Puzzle Carl Chiarella Shenhuai Gao ISSN: 1036-7373 http://www.business.uts.edu.au/finance/ Working

More information

Management Science Letters

Management Science Letters Management Science Letters 3 (2013) 2039 2048 Contents lists available at GrowingScience Management Science Letters homepage: www.growingscience.com/msl A study on relationship between investment opportunities

More information

Higher ERC or Higher Future ERC from Income Smoothness? The Role of Information Environment

Higher ERC or Higher Future ERC from Income Smoothness? The Role of Information Environment Higher ERC or Higher Future ERC from Income Smoothness? The Role of Information Environment ABSTRACT We examine the differential effects of income smoothness on value-relevance of current future earnings

More information

Does Meeting Expectations Matter? Evidence from Analyst Forecast Revisions and Share Prices

Does Meeting Expectations Matter? Evidence from Analyst Forecast Revisions and Share Prices Does Meeting Expectations Matter? Evidence from Analyst Forecast Revisions and Share Prices Ron Kasznik Graduate School of Business Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305 (650) 725-9740 Fax: (650) 725-6152

More information

Detecting Earnings Management Using Discontinuity Evidence*

Detecting Earnings Management Using Discontinuity Evidence* Detecting Earnings Management Using Discontinuity Evidence* David Burgstahler Julius A. Roller Professor of Accounting University of Washington/Seattle Elizabeth Chuk Assistant Professor University of

More information

Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts

Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts We replicate Tables 1-4 of the paper relating quarterly earnings forecasts (QEFs) and long-term growth forecasts (LTGFs)

More information

Evidence of conditional conservatism: fact or artifact? Panos N. Patatoukas Yale University

Evidence of conditional conservatism: fact or artifact? Panos N. Patatoukas Yale University Evidence of conditional conservatism: fact or artifact? Panos N. Patatoukas Yale University panagiotis.patatoukas@yale.edu Jacob Thomas Yale University jake.thomas@yale.edu Current Version: October 5,

More information

Morningstar Style Box TM Methodology

Morningstar Style Box TM Methodology Morningstar Style Box TM Methodology Morningstar Methodology Paper 28 February 208 2008 Morningstar, Inc. All rights reserved. The information in this document is the property of Morningstar, Inc. Reproduction

More information

Shareholder-Level Capitalization of Dividend Taxes: Additional Evidence from Earnings Announcement Period Returns

Shareholder-Level Capitalization of Dividend Taxes: Additional Evidence from Earnings Announcement Period Returns Shareholder-Level Capitalization of Dividend Taxes: Additional Evidence from Earnings Announcement Period Returns John D. Schatzberg * University of New Mexico Craig G. White University of New Mexico Robert

More information

Financial Statement Comparability and Investor Responsiveness to Earnings News

Financial Statement Comparability and Investor Responsiveness to Earnings News University of St. Thomas, Minnesota UST Research Online Accounting Faculty Publications Accounting 2017 Financial Statement Comparability and Investor Responsiveness to Earnings News Matthew Stallings

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

Earnings Response Coefficients and Default Risk: Case of Korean Firms

Earnings Response Coefficients and Default Risk: Case of Korean Firms Earnings Response Coefficients and Default Risk: Case of Korean Firms Yohan An Department of Finance and Accounting, Tongmyoung University, Busan, South Korea Correspondence: Dr. Yohan An, Assistant Professor,

More information

The Use of Special Items to Inflate Core Earnings *

The Use of Special Items to Inflate Core Earnings * The Use of Special Items to Inflate Core Earnings * Sarah E. McVay University of Michigan Business School 701 Tappan Street Ann Arbor, MI 48109 email: smcvay@umich.edu January 2004 ABSTRACT Investors place

More information

The Changing Landscape of Accrual Accounting

The Changing Landscape of Accrual Accounting DOI: 10.1111/1475-679X.12100 Journal of Accounting Research Vol. 54 No. 1 March 2016 Printed in U.S.A. The Changing Landscape of Accrual Accounting ROBERT M. BUSHMAN, ALINA LERMAN, AND X. FRANK ZHANG Received

More information

A Study of Relationship between Accruals and Managerial Operating Decisions over Firm Life Cycle among Listed Firms in Tehran Stock Exchange

A Study of Relationship between Accruals and Managerial Operating Decisions over Firm Life Cycle among Listed Firms in Tehran Stock Exchange A Study of Relationship between Accruals and Managerial Operating Decisions over Firm Life Cycle among Listed Firms in Tehran Stock Exchange Vahideh Jouyban Young Researchers Club, Borujerd Branch, Islamic

More information

The Pennsylvania State University. The Graduate School. The Mary Jean and Frank P. Smeal College of Business Administration

The Pennsylvania State University. The Graduate School. The Mary Jean and Frank P. Smeal College of Business Administration The Pennsylvania State University The Graduate School The Mary Jean and Frank P. Smeal College of Business Administration IS THE VALUE RELEVCE OF EARNINGS REALLY DECREASING OVER TIME A Thesis in Business

More information

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore.

This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore. This document is downloaded from DR-NTU, Nanyang Technological University Library, Singapore. Title Rounding-up in reported EPS, behavioral thresholds, and earnings management Author(s) Das, Somnath; Zhang,

More information

Evidence That Management Earnings Forecasts Do Not Fully Incorporate Information in Prior Forecast Errors

Evidence That Management Earnings Forecasts Do Not Fully Incorporate Information in Prior Forecast Errors Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 36(7) & (8), 822 837, September/October 2009, 0306-686X doi: 10.1111/j.1468-5957.2009.02152.x Evidence That Management Earnings Forecasts Do Not Fully Incorporate

More information

Accrual reversals and cash conversion

Accrual reversals and cash conversion Accrual reversals and cash conversion Matt Bloomfield 1, Joseph Gerakos 1 and Andrei Kovrijnykh 2 1 University of Chicago Booth School of Business 2 W. P. Carey School of Business, Arizona State University

More information

Identifying unexpected accruals: a comparison of current approaches

Identifying unexpected accruals: a comparison of current approaches Identifying unexpected accruals: a comparison of current approaches Jacob Thomas and Xiao-jun Zhang Journal of Accounting and Public Policy (Winter 2000): 347-376 Jacob Thomas is Ernst & Young Professor

More information

Comparison of OLS and LAD regression techniques for estimating beta

Comparison of OLS and LAD regression techniques for estimating beta Comparison of OLS and LAD regression techniques for estimating beta 26 June 2013 Contents 1. Preparation of this report... 1 2. Executive summary... 2 3. Issue and evaluation approach... 4 4. Data... 6

More information

Effect of Earnings Growth Strategy on Earnings Response Coefficient and Earnings Sustainability

Effect of Earnings Growth Strategy on Earnings Response Coefficient and Earnings Sustainability European Online Journal of Natural and Social Sciences 2015; www.european-science.com Vol.4, No.1 Special Issue on New Dimensions in Economics, Accounting and Management ISSN 1805-3602 Effect of Earnings

More information

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck

More information

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel Appendix to: Why Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down? AMoreElaborateModel Antti Petajisto Yale School of Management February 2004 1 A More Elaborate Model 1.1 Motivation Our earlier model provides a

More information

Conflict in Whispers and Analyst Forecasts: Which One Should Be Your Guide?

Conflict in Whispers and Analyst Forecasts: Which One Should Be Your Guide? Abstract Conflict in Whispers and Analyst Forecasts: Which One Should Be Your Guide? Janis K. Zaima and Maretno Agus Harjoto * San Jose State University This study examines the market reaction to conflicts

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 1 Spring 1994 INSTITUTIONAL INVESTMENT ACROSS MARKET ANOMALIES. Thomas M.

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 1 Spring 1994 INSTITUTIONAL INVESTMENT ACROSS MARKET ANOMALIES. Thomas M. Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 1 Spring 1994 INSTITUTIONAL INVESTMENT ACROSS MARKET ANOMALIES Thomas M. Krueger * Abstract If a small firm effect exists, one would expect

More information

Properties of implied cost of capital using analysts forecasts

Properties of implied cost of capital using analysts forecasts Article Properties of implied cost of capital using analysts forecasts Australian Journal of Management 36(2) 125 149 The Author(s) 2011 Reprints and permission: sagepub. co.uk/journalspermissions.nav

More information

Eli Amir ab, Eti Einhorn a & Itay Kama a a Recanati Graduate School of Business Administration,

Eli Amir ab, Eti Einhorn a & Itay Kama a a Recanati Graduate School of Business Administration, This article was downloaded by: [Tel Aviv University] On: 18 December 2013, At: 02:20 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer

More information

Earnings Announcements, Analyst Forecasts, and Trading Volume *

Earnings Announcements, Analyst Forecasts, and Trading Volume * Seoul Journal of Business Volume 19, Number 2 (December 2013) Earnings Announcements, Analyst Forecasts, and Trading Volume * Minsup Song **1) Sogang Business School Sogang University Abstract Empirical

More information

The Rational Modeling Hypothesis for Analyst Underreaction to Earnings News*

The Rational Modeling Hypothesis for Analyst Underreaction to Earnings News* The Rational Modeling Hypothesis for Analyst Underreaction to Earnings News* Philip G. Berger Booth School of Business, University of Chicago, 5807 S. Woodlawn Ave., Chicago, IL 60637 and Zachary R. Kaplan

More information

Using Mechanical Earnings and Residual Income Forecasts In Equity Valuation

Using Mechanical Earnings and Residual Income Forecasts In Equity Valuation Using Mechanical Earnings and Residual Income Forecasts In Equity Valuation Jennifer Francis (Duke University) Per Olsson (University of Wisconsin) Dennis R. Oswald (London Business School) Revised: April

More information

Earnings Guidance and Market Uncertainty *

Earnings Guidance and Market Uncertainty * Earnings Guidance and Market Uncertainty * Jonathan L. Rogers Graduate School of Business The University of Chicago Douglas J. Skinner Graduate School of Business The University of Chicago Andrew Van Buskirk

More information

Why do EPS forecast error and dispersion not vary with scale? Implications for analyst and managerial behavior.

Why do EPS forecast error and dispersion not vary with scale? Implications for analyst and managerial behavior. Why do EPS forecast error and dispersion not vary with scale? Implications for analyst and managerial behavior. Foong Soon Cheong Rutgers University fscheong@rutgers.edu Jacob Thomas Yale University jake.thomas@yale.edu

More information

Earnings Surprises and Uncertainty: Theory and Evidence from Option Implied Volatility

Earnings Surprises and Uncertainty: Theory and Evidence from Option Implied Volatility Earnings Surprises and Uncertainty: Theory and Evidence from Option Implied Volatility Presented by Dr K R Subramanyam KPMG Foundation Professor of Accounting University of Southern California Cheng Tsang

More information

Who, if Anyone, Reacts to Accrual Information? Robert H. Battalio, Notre Dame Alina Lerman, NYU Joshua Livnat, NYU Richard R. Mendenhall, Notre Dame

Who, if Anyone, Reacts to Accrual Information? Robert H. Battalio, Notre Dame Alina Lerman, NYU Joshua Livnat, NYU Richard R. Mendenhall, Notre Dame Who, if Anyone, Reacts to Accrual Information? Robert H. Battalio, Notre Dame Alina Lerman, NYU Joshua Livnat, NYU Richard R. Mendenhall, Notre Dame 1 Overview Objectives: Can accruals add information

More information

Pricing and Mispricing Effects of SFAS 131

Pricing and Mispricing Effects of SFAS 131 Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 35(3) & (4), 281 306, April/May 2008, 0306-686X doi: 10.1111/j.1468-5957.2007.02071.x Pricing and Mispricing Effects of SFAS 131 Ole-Kristian Hope, Tony Kang,

More information

Detecting Earnings Management Using Discontinuity Evidence*

Detecting Earnings Management Using Discontinuity Evidence* Detecting Earnings Management Using Discontinuity Evidence* David Burgstahler Julius A. Roller Professor of Accounting University of Washington/Seattle Elizabeth Chuk Assistant Professor University of

More information

Investor protection and the information content of annual earnings announcements: International evidence

Investor protection and the information content of annual earnings announcements: International evidence Investor protection and the information content of annual earnings announcements: International evidence Pages 37-67 Mark DeFond, Mingyi Hung and Robert Trezevant Abstract We draw on the investor protection

More information

Of the tools in the technician's arsenal, the moving average is one of the most popular. It is used to

Of the tools in the technician's arsenal, the moving average is one of the most popular. It is used to Building A Variable-Length Moving Average by George R. Arrington, Ph.D. Of the tools in the technician's arsenal, the moving average is one of the most popular. It is used to eliminate minor fluctuations

More information

Earnings Management and Earnings Surprises: Stock Price Reactions to Earnings Components * Larry L. DuCharme. Yang Liu. Paul H.

Earnings Management and Earnings Surprises: Stock Price Reactions to Earnings Components * Larry L. DuCharme. Yang Liu. Paul H. Earnings Management and Earnings Surprises: Stock Price Reactions to Earnings Components * Larry L. DuCharme Yang Liu Paul H. Malatesta University of Washington School of Business Box 353200 Seattle, WA

More information

The Separate Valuation Relevance of Earnings, Book Value and their Components in Profit and Loss Making Firms: UK Evidence

The Separate Valuation Relevance of Earnings, Book Value and their Components in Profit and Loss Making Firms: UK Evidence MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Separate Valuation Relevance of Earnings, Book Value and their Components in Profit and Loss Making Firms: UK Evidence S Akbar The University of Liverpool 2007 Online

More information

Investor Trading and Book-Tax Differences

Investor Trading and Book-Tax Differences Investor Trading and Book-Tax Differences Benjamin C. Ayers University of Georgia (706) 542-3772 Bayers@terry.uga.edu Stacie K. Laplante University of Georgia (706) 542-3620 Slaplante@terry.uga.edu Oliver

More information

Earnings Response Coefficient as a Measure of Market Expectations: Evidence from Tunis Stock Exchange

Earnings Response Coefficient as a Measure of Market Expectations: Evidence from Tunis Stock Exchange International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues ISSN: 2146-4138 available at http: www.econjournals.com International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues, 2015, 5(2), 377-389. Earnings Response

More information

INVESTMENT OPPORTUNITIES AND THE VALUE-RELEVANCE OF EARNINGS, CASH FLOWS AND ACCRUALS

INVESTMENT OPPORTUNITIES AND THE VALUE-RELEVANCE OF EARNINGS, CASH FLOWS AND ACCRUALS INVESTMENT OPPORTUNITIES AND THE VALUE-RELEVANCE OF EARNINGS, CASH FLOWS AND ACCRUALS Gopal V. Krishnan Department of Accountancy City University of Hong Kong, Kowloon, Hong Kong acgk@cityu.edu.hk and

More information

Chapter 3. Numerical Descriptive Measures. Copyright 2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. Chapter 3, Slide 1

Chapter 3. Numerical Descriptive Measures. Copyright 2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. Chapter 3, Slide 1 Chapter 3 Numerical Descriptive Measures Copyright 2016 Pearson Education, Ltd. Chapter 3, Slide 1 Objectives In this chapter, you learn to: Describe the properties of central tendency, variation, and

More information

Voluntary disclosure of balance sheet information in quarterly earnings announcements $

Voluntary disclosure of balance sheet information in quarterly earnings announcements $ Journal of Accounting and Economics 33 (2002) 229 251 Voluntary disclosure of balance sheet information in quarterly earnings announcements $ Shuping Chen a, Mark L. DeFond b, *, Chul W. Park c a School

More information

What Have We Learned About Earnings Management? Correcting Disinformation about Discontinuities*

What Have We Learned About Earnings Management? Correcting Disinformation about Discontinuities* What Have We Learned About Earnings Management? Correcting Disinformation about Discontinuities* David Burgstahler Julius A. Roller Professor of Accounting University of Washington/Seattle Elizabeth Chuk

More information

CEO Cash Compensation and Earnings Quality

CEO Cash Compensation and Earnings Quality CEO Cash Compensation and Earnings Quality Item Type text; Electronic Thesis Authors Chen, Zhimin Publisher The University of Arizona. Rights Copyright is held by the author. Digital access to this material

More information

What Makes Stock Prices Move? Fundamentals vs. Investor Recognition

What Makes Stock Prices Move? Fundamentals vs. Investor Recognition Volume 68 Number 2 2012 CFA Institute What Makes Stock Prices Move? Fundamentals vs. Investor Recognition Scott Richardson, Richard Sloan, and Haifeng You, CFA The authors synthesized and extended recent

More information