A New Informativeness Principle: Managerial Incentives Decline in Stock Price Informativness * Version: May 24, 2012 Brandon Chen. Peter L.

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A New Informativeness Principle: Managerial Incentives Decline in Stock Price Informativness * Version: May 24, 2012 Brandon Chen. Peter L."

Transcription

1 A New Informativeness Principle: Managerial Incentives Decline in Stock Price Informativness * Version: May 4, 01 Brandon Chen Peter L. Swan Abstract Holmstrom (1979) established the informativeness principle when he showed that even very imperfect information can be used to improve the welfare of the principal and agent. Holmstrom and Tirole (1993) appears to show that use of price-based incentives should increase when stock prices become more informative about managerial action such as when firm scale is greater. To the contrary, we show that the sum of price and non-price incentives must always fall with increased informativeness, explaining why larger firms are less reliant on incentives. Moreover, the price sensitivity always falls if the precision of the price signal of performance exceeds that of the accounting signal. We empirically confirm our model s prediction to show that the use of equity-based incentives actually falls when institutional traders impound more information in stock prices. In other words, monitoring and incentives are substitutes. Despite the lower use of equity-based incentives and the even lower still use of bonus incentives, the CEO works harder and her total compensation increases. Our paper not only redresses previous confusion about managerial incentives and price efficiency due to informed trading, but also utilizes a new way to infer price informativeness from the number of institutional informed traders as well as the magnitude of their trades from a swing measure of informed trading. In its first application to the United States, we show that the swing measure can be inferred from SEC 13f filings and is robust to a number of tests. JEL Classification: D8, G14, G3, G3 Keywords: Informativeness, Incentives, Substitutes, CEO pay, Institutional monitoring, Governance through Trading. * We thank Renée Adams, Rajesh K. Aggarwal, Anat Admati, Riccardo Calcagno, especially Alex Edmans, David Feldman, Daniel Ferreira, Florian Heider, Bengt Holmstrom to whom we owe special thanks, Albert (Pete) Kyle, Pedro Matos, Paul Pfleiderer, Jaeyoung Sung, Jean Tirole, Terry Walter, and seminar participants at University of New South Wales, La Trobe University, 010 Giblin Workshop, 010 FIRS Conference, 010 China International Conference in Finance, 010 ISB CAF Summer Research Conference in Finance, 010 Econometric Society World Congress and 01 American Finance Association participants for comments on earlier versions and the Australian Research Council (ARC) for financial support. We also thank Kai Li, our discussant at the 01 AFA Conference in Chicago for comments. School of Economics and Finance, Victoria University of Wellington, New Zealand. brandon.chen@vuw.ac.nz. School of Banking and Finance, Australian School of Business, University of New South Wales, Sydney, NSW 05 Australia. peter.swan@unsw.edu.au.

2 In his famous paper, Holmstom (1979) formulated the informativeness principle as to how sharing relationships such as agency can be improved. In a world with moral hazard, even imperfect additional information about the agent s unobservable actions makes both the principal and agent better off. Holmstrom reprises his seminal contribution in Holmstrom and Tirole (1993) (hereafter, HT) where they conclude (pp ) that manager stock price incentives increase absolutely (i.e. incentives are more high-powered) as stock price becomes more informative. They argue that larger stocks (i.e. increased firm scale) trading in more liquid markets will have more informative stock prices since informed traders (i.e. speculators ) can hide more effectively in the crowd as in Kyle (1984, 1985), giving rise to more high-powered incentives. Conversely, if control considerations give rise to some form of vertical integration with weaker performance information in the stock price then lowerpowered incentives will be used (HT p.698). These model findings seem peculiar as practically every study of pay for performance sensitivity shows that sensitivity falls rather than rises with increases in firm size and that high-powered contract (e.g. MacDonald s franchise contracts) usage occurs in vertical relationships when there is less informative stock price information. Sensitivity is typically high in start-ups with highly uncertain stock market valuations. We show that these counterintuitive predictions are not due to technical error in the HS model itself but rather are simply a consequence of their redefinition of price incentives from the proportion of shares allocated to the manager into a measure of equity performance by multiplying by informativeness itself. They do this to help simplify and sign their comparative-static findings but forget to translate back again into their original units when interpreting results. 4 Once this problem is 4 HT (p. 695) state that their transformed equity incentive term, i.e., ' b' ˆ p ˆ, where ˆ p ˆ is the equity share allocated to the manager that they (incorrectly) interpret as their price-based incentive, will fall with increases in their observational error term, i.e., ' ', that worsens the informational content of price (HT, p. 69). In their framework, after retransforming units, a fall in the observational error that improves the informational content of price will generally (but not always) result in a fall in the equity incentive, not a rise. In

3 corrected we find that pay for performance sensitivity falls absolutely with a more informative stock price on the reasonable supposition that the price signal has greater precision for many firms than the non-price signal utilizing accounting numbers. Thus, from the perspective of our findings, young firms with high inside ownership and low liquidity have low precision of the price signal and thus relatively high precision of the accounting signal. The ineffectiveness of market monitoring means that management needs high share ownership and pay for performance sensitivity to create alignment of interests in order to compensate for the weakness of stock price informativeness. HT point out that, relative to its benefits, the costs of informed traders earning large profits comes ultimately as an expense borne by insiders is it depresses stock price. Such relatively illiquid stocks may be more valuable as part of a conglomerate with no trading of divisional shares and almost complete reliance on accounting numbers. The large fall in managerial shareholdings following acquisition and conversion to a conglomerate division need not indicate any sizeable change in market monitoring. The discontinuous fall in managerial share ownership with acquisition may be largely irrelevant with negligible change in the already low level of market monitoring. This theory also explains why most small businesses and a number of large businesses remain unlisted. If these companies were to list creating relatively illiquid stocks and thus the need for high-powered incentives, the gains in terms of better motivating the manager relative to just accounting performance may not outweigh the losses incurred by noise traders. Empirically, we find that sensitivity always declines with respect to both informativeness and firm scale, the latter being a proxy for informativeness. In the limiting theoretical case in which non-price incentives are irrelevant, we show that it is always the case that incentives correspondence with us, Bengt Holmstrom has acknowledged the problem and hence the misleading nature of their results. 3

4 are less high-powered the more informative is stock price. By following the Wall Street Rule or taking the Wall Street walk, dubbed Governance through Trading (GTT) by Gallagher, Gardner, and Swan (011) (hereafter, GGS), informed traders can considerably remove extraneous information that disguises managerial actions in stock prices. They accomplish this by driving price toward fundamental value determined by managerial action. The resulting greater sensitivity of stock price to managerial action stock price informativeness makes a non-performing manager more vulnerable to the decline in stock prices and thus ensures that the manager exerts appropriate costly effort ex ante. Edmans and Manso (011) (hereafter, EM) establish this as a theoretical proposition with the manager s equity allocation taken as given exogenously since their concern is not with the manager s contract. 5 GGS show empirically that informed trades, particularly those taking an aggressive form dubbed swing trades akin to stock turnover but with three legs such as buy-sell-buy or sell-buy-sell, results in subsequent firm outperformance consistent with higher managerial effort. They show using the daily trades of investment managers that swing trades are profitable after transaction costs, indicating that they are informed. Profitability is also improving at a diminishing rate in initial portfolio holdings up to an optimal holdings level. This indicates that long-only institutional investors invest more in acquiring information in a stock the higher are their holdings, as predicted by Edmans (009). Diminishing liquidity with increased information about future stock value predicates an optimal holdings level for trading purposes. Profitability is also declining in the number of fund managers swing trading simultaneously, indicating that fund managers observe correlated signals of future value. 5 Their assumption rules out endogenous sale of the firm to the manager, a corner solution that could arise in the context of a risk-neutral manager. 4

5 In this paper, we empirically implement GTT s swing trades using quarterly 13f filing data. Since GTT boosts the efficiency of the equity performance incentive, a smaller level of CEO equity incentives does the same or better job. Despite reduced use of incentives, the CEO works harder and, empirically, her total compensation increases. In our setting, stock price based incentives (equity allocation) is neither exogenous nor increasing in stock price informativeness. Rather, it is a substitute for institutional monitoring based on GTT and thus diminishes the more effective is GTT. We take a simple analogy based on the idea that, since incentives are expensive to create, a more efficient incentive due to GTT should result in a smaller outlay on the incentive: 6 the introduction of an automobile with a diesel engine that is more fuel-efficient (institutional informed trading, or GTT, introduced) than an equivalent automobile with a gasoline engine (no GTT). To keep it simple, the price of a gallon of diesel and gasoline are identical and do not vary. One might expect that the diesel automobile would use less fuel each week (equity allocation lower) because of its greater fuel efficiency even if driven further each week due to its greater fuel economy (the agent works harder). That is, the technological fuel efficiency improvement (GTT) and the number of gallons of fuel purchased each week (equity allocation) are likely to be substitutable, not complementary, but we cannot rule out complementarity on theoretical grounds alone. 7 Our new informativeness theory is on stronger ground when it comes to the more general question of monitoring versus incentives. Incentives are always substitutable for informed 6 We thank Gerald Garvey for this analogy. 7 That is, a priori we cannot rule out the possibility that the automobile uses more gallons of diesel each week (equity allocation increases) if the driving mileage response to the lower effective cost of fuel is sufficiently elastic with respect to the diesel innovation. This complementary relationship is more likely, the fewer are the initial gasoline-miles with the owner preferring to use more efficient public transport running on gasoline (analogous to the use of accounting-based bonus incentives within a conglomerate with negligible divisional equity) when private gasoline costs are too high (since equity is highly inefficient prior to GTT, accounting incentives dominate). If the productivity gain with diesel is sufficiently high, private diesel mileage replaces both private gasoline mileage and gasoline-based public transport such that diesel usage is now higher (under GTT, the equity allocation increases as a conglomerate s division is separately floated). 5

6 trader monitoring. We establish a new and quite general result: the sum of equity and nonprice (bonus) incentives unambiguously fall in response to better monitoring. This represents our surprising informativeness principle: the more effective is a mechanism such as stock price in disciplining management because it contains more performance information, the less its use in optimal agency contracts. The substitutability-complementarity issue cannot be resolved empirically under the HT framework, as the (single) informed trader s effort to increase price informativeness by investing in a better signal is unobservable unless proxied by an increased firm scale. By extending our corrected version of HT s model to multiple informed traders, however, we are able to construct proxies for institutional informed trading and empirically investigate its relation with the use of managerial incentives. In our extended set up, price informativeness is proportional to the number of informed traders as well as their trade aggressiveness as measured by the magnitude of swing trades and informed trader informational advantage: the price is least informative when there is merely one informed trader (pure monopoly, as in HT), and it becomes more informative as the number of informed traders increases (as in Cournot competition and EM). 8 By analyzing institutional investors actual trading data recorded in the Thomson Reuter s 13f filing database, we are able to infer from their trading patterns the magnitude of informed trading via the size of swings and the number of informed traders, both of which make stock prices more informative. Our regression results show that the use of equity-based incentives actually falls as stock price informativeness increases. In other words, these two governance mechanisms are substitutes. While our (and reinterpreted HT) model is consistent with substitutability in a weak form; empirically, the substitutes relation exists in a strong form. We also demonstrate, 8 To keep things simple, we abstract from the multi-period nature of the HT model. This simplified HT model is a special case of ours with the number of informed traders set equal to one, but only after HT s equity incentive is measured correctly (see below). 6

7 based on a sample consisting of 77% of S&P 1500 stocks, , that increased informativeness not only reduces equity-based incentives and the sum of equity and bonus incentives (as it must do), but also raises the level of total CEO pay because empirically higher managerial productivity outweighs the fall in the use of incentives. To put our model and findings into context, traditional theories argue that concentrated ownership helps alleviate the agency problem embedded in the manager-shareholder relationship in a firm, because only large shareholders have incentives to monitor the manager through direct intervention, or voice, as termed by Hirshman (1970). Recent research shows the possibility of an alternative channel through which multiple blockholders may still exert effective governance despite the power of using voice being reduced. In terms of theory, both Admati and Pfleiderer (009) and Edmans (009) focus on a single blockholder that exerts governance through trading. In addition, many empirical works note this alternative monitoring mechanism of institutional trading. For example, Parrino, Sias and Starks (003) show that some institutional investors engage in the biggest sell-off in a firm four quarters immediately before CEO firing occurs. Sias, Starks and Titman (006) provide evidence that institutional investors possess information that affects prices permanently. With a different focus but in a similar vein, Chen, Harford and Li (007) show that some institutional investors will sell their stakes in a firm when they anticipate a large enough value reduction. Gopalan (008) finds evidence that institutional selling is a predictor of subsequent poor performance and firm takeover. A survey conducted by McCahery, Saunter and Starks (011) finds that a high proportion (80%) of responding institutional investors is willing to use GTT as a governance mechanism. 9 9 In addition, Yan and Zhang (009) find that short-term trading by institutional investors forecast future returns. Ferreira, Ferreira and Raposa (011) find that stock price informativeness is associated with board structure. Boehmer and Kelley (009) show that institutional trading is associated with greater pricing efficiency. Ferreira, Laux and Markarian (009) find that managerial equity-based incentives are a substitute for institutional trading. 7

8 The organization of the paper is as follows. Section I presents the theoretical framework that forms the basis of our empirical analysis. Section II discusses our data source and the construction of several institutional investor- and manager-related variables. Section III provides the rationale of using the buy-sell-buy and sell-buy-sell trade sequence as the proxy for the institutional informed trading, or Governance through Trading. We present our empirical tests in Section IV. Section V concludes. I. Optimal Contracting with Informed Traders A. Incentives and Price-(and Non-price-) based Signals As in EM s model, we view a blockholder simply as a shareholder who has greater information than the market and do not require her to hold a certain proportion (e.g., 5%) of a firm. Our model refers to informed investors or traders, not blockholders per se. We introduce an optimal managerial contract for a risk-averse manager whose reward depends on both stock price and non-price performance measures. The model is a two-stage game. In the first stage the manager is hired by firm owners (inside shareholders) and takes actions a[0, ) that affect firm (terminal) value, v : v a ( 1) Nature determines a (terminal) value v for the firm s equity from a normally distributed value v Ɲ a,. The higher the variance, the more valuable is the receipt of this signal to informed traders 10 but the harder it is to infer managerial actions from stock price movements. Random shocks represented by not only garble the managerial actions but also raise the risk borne by the risk-averse manager. Thus, it is desirable to eliminate the impact of these shocks from a contracting perspective. 10 This is what EM refer to as the trader s informational advantage parameter since if there were no variance in the signal there would be no point in trading. 8

9 The manager s total income, I, consists of three parts: a fixed salary, 0, plus the cash equivalent of an equity allocation of shares granted by insiders to the manager that is evaluated at the equilibrium market clearing price 11 at the rate, p, and an allocation, y, in the form of a cash payment based on the residual terminal value, paid by inside stockholders to the manager at the time of termination. CEO total pay has the following representation: I p y ( ) 0 p y, where denotes the cash reward based on the (observable) stock price, p, and y y can be p p viewed as the CEO s terminating bonus, based on a non-price (e.g., accounting) performance measure of the firm s terminal value, y, that is imperfectly related to the actual terminal value, v. Specifically, yv, with ~ Ɲ(0, ) that is normally distributed denoting the independent non-price observational error term (accounting valuation term). Here we follow Calcagno and Heider (009) by adopting a more general specification of the non-price signal than HT who by contrast adopt a more complicated three-period model with short- and longterm bonus and incentive effects. Our manager can depart at any time (so long as there is a non-price signal) whereas the HT manager must depart at a pre-specified date. The manager is paid an amount in cash that is directly related to stock price performance, 0 p p, plus an amount in expectation of yy E v 0 pp y, p in the form of the net cash equivalent of shares at the terminal date. We view the term ( v0 p p) as the net liquidation value of the firm and y y as the projection (i.e., linear regression) of the terminal bonus jointly on the accounting signal y and stock price p. 11 This is what HT call stock appreciation rights in their formulation of the problem in a three period setting. 9

10 The risk-averse manager s exponential CARA utility function depends on the manager s U I, a exp I 1 a income less her cost of effort,, where is the manager s coefficient of constant absolute risk aversion (CARA) and 1 a is the manager s quadratic cost of effort function. The total number of shares in the firm is normalized to 1, made up of shares retained by insiders with the residual number sold to liquidity traders. There are N symmetric risk-neutral informed traders and each trade 1 shares. Free float is fixed and N plays no role, as in EM. B. Trading Demand of Informed Investors and Price Informativeness The equilibrium price is determined in the second stage of the game. We adopt Kyle s (1984, 1985) model and extend Admati and Pfleiderer (1988), EM, HT, and Calcagno and Heider (Appendix A, 009) in modeling N separate individual signals received by informed traders in our analysis of trading demands. Each informed trader submits a market order, x s, after observing an imperfect heterogeneous signal of the true (common) value of the firm, si v i, where i is an independent and normally distributed observational error term with i i N 1 1 s s v N N i i Ɲ a, i1 N i1 and 1 N i1 i Ɲ 0, representing the N individual trader mean signal and error terms, respectively. 1 The trading strategy of each informed trader is a linear function of the imperfect signal: x s, where denotes Kyle s (1985) trade aggressiveness, and some constant. Uninformed risk-neutral (noise) traders as a group submit market orders u ~ Ɲ (0, u ) i i with mean zero and variance, u. The 1 Our assumption here differs from the model in the body of Calcagno and Heider (009) since in their model there is no collective error in the signals when summed up over all traders. We believe that this is the first time our problem with multiple investors and independent observational errors has been posed and solved. 10

11 market-clearing price that is not fully revealing of the actions of informed traders is then set by a competitive market maker who observes only the total order flow, N z x u, made i1 i up of both the informed trader and uninformed trader demands. Note that in our study we normalize the price and incentive contract to place it on a gross (i.e., pre-managerial compensation) basis as in HT and Calcagno and Heider (008). 13 This normalization procedure results in the definition of the gross (normalized) share price as pˆ 0 1 p p; the corresponding normalized manager income becomes: I ˆ ˆ pˆ ˆ y. ( 3) 0 pˆ y We solve this two-stage game by backward induction. We start from the second stage, taking the efforts of the manager as given to solve for the equilibrium (normalized) price. We then move back to the first stage and solve for the optimal managerial effort as well as firm owners contracting parameters. Proposition 1: The equilibrium normalized price is: * 1 ˆ N p 1 a a, i 1 i u ( 4) N where Kyle s lambda, N ( 1) u N, ( 5) which simplifies to the HT (equation (11) expression u, 1 when N=1. 13 In the context of different models, both HT and Calcagno and Heider (009) recognize the need to normalize by grossing up to remove the direct effects of pay from the stock price. The relation between the observed price, p, (which is measured net of managerial cash outlays) and the gross price undistorted by incentive payments, pˆ, is as follows: p pˆ 0 p p. 11

12 and the informativeness coefficient is N N, N 1 ( 6) N where. N 1 Informativeness is increasing in the number of informed traders, 0, N N N 1 and as the magnitude of the observational error term is reduced, 0, as in the original HT model. These relationships mean that we need only consider the impact of a change in informativeness,, on incentive allocations and performance rather than its various components. Since informed traders are likely to know more about larger stocks trading in more liquid markets, one expects this observational error term to diminish in firm size, as HT originally proposed. Informativeness is also increasing in trader informational advantage,, conditional on the reasonable supposition that there is observational error term. Note that N and N N 1 when each informed trader s signal is perfect and 1, HT s, exactly as in equation (11) of HT when trade aggressiveness summed over all informed participants is:. Aggregate informed N N u, ( 7) HT ' s u which corresponds to HT s trade aggressiveness parameter with only one informed investor. 1

13 Proof : See Appendix A. Hence, systematically profitable trade sequences that by definition are informed are indicative of a strong trader informational advantage. The second effort term in the normalized price (equation ( 4)) represents out-of-equilibrium effort, a. In equilibrium, a * a and thus the terms in equation ( 4), a * and a, cancel out, leaving the equilibrium price dependent on equilibrium effort, a *, plus informative effects. Aggregate trade aggressiveness given by N in equation ( 7) provides an additional rationale for our proxy for institutional trader monitoring based on actual trading data (introduced in section III). It is increasing in the number of informed traders. It is also higher the smaller is the magnitude of the variance of the informed trader observational error,, as in HT. Moreover, it is increasing in the volatility of noise trading, u, and diminishing in the magnitude of the trader informational advantage,. C. The Manager s Actions and Incentives We now explore the manager s effort level and her incentives in the first stage of the game. Since the utility function of the risk-averse CEO takes the negative exponential form, her optimizing problem can be expressed as: 1 a * arg max EI Var I a ( 8) a The first-order condition yields the optimal managerial effort level: ˆ ˆ. ( 9) * a pˆ y Before we solve the firm owners optimization problem for the absolute weights of equitybased pay allocation, ˆ p, and non-equity-based pay allocation, ˆ y, to determine the value of 13

14 the manager s optimal effort, we first consider the relative weight placed on equity-based pay allocation. In our structure with both CARA preferences and normally distributed returns, the optimal contract must minimize the total income risk faced by the risk-averse manager. Therefore, the firm owners (i.e. inside shareholders ) objective is to choose the best combination of ˆ p ˆ and ˆ y that minimize the variance of managerial income Var I subject to effort level being optimal for the manager (equation( 9)). We state the following result: Proposition : The ratio of equity-based to non-equity-based compensation becomes ˆ. pˆ ˆ y 1 ( 10) Substituting the ratios from ( 10) into the optimal effort expression, ( 9) above, we obtain: * 1 * ˆ ˆ pˆ a and y a, ( 11) 1 1 where and The manager s normalized equity allocation increases relative to the bonus share allocation the greater is the measurement error of the non-price (accounting) signal,, and the larger the number of informed traders ( ). Also, it increases the smaller is the informational advantage of informed traders,, and the smaller the observational error term, In the special case corresponding to HT s assumption of an informational monopolist, we obtain ˆ pˆ 1 ; ; and ˆ y u 14 which is equivalent to eqs. (30)-(3) of HT (1993, p. 695). In comparing our results with HT it is important to note that HT do not utilize the ratio of equity ˆ pˆ and bonus incentives,, in their comparative-statics following their eq.(4) (1993, p. 693) but, as an ˆ y (unintended) consequence of variable transformation, use what they refer to as the incentive ratio ˆ pˆ 1, where in HT s terminology, HT ' s ' v' and ˆ pˆ HT ' s ' b', implicitly holding ˆ y

15 Proof: See Appendix A. Having examined the relative weight on equity and bonus-based pay allocation, we now solve the firm owners optimization problem for the absolute weights of the share and bonus ˆ p ˆ allocations, and ˆ y. The risk-neutral firm owners choose the parameters of the manager s incentive contract to maximize the expected value of the firm net of the manager s income, max E ˆ p, ˆ y v I, ( 1) subject to the manager s incentive compatibility and participation constraints. The first order conditions yields the following proposition: Proposition 3: The respective optimal incentives are: ˆ 1 * * pˆ a * * ˆ y a. and ( 13) Substituting these optimal solutions into the expression for the optimal effort level (equation ( 9)) and simplifying yields: a * ( 14) Proof: See Appendix A. constant the terms and that go to make up stock price informativeness,, when the same terms are varied on the other side of the equation. Thus HT s sign condition for an increase in the informed trader s measurement error in observing terminal value to reduce the relative use of equity incentive is ˆ p Sign ˆ Sign ˆ pˆ 4, whereas it should read Sign ˆ Sign. Fortunately, both y ˆ y sign conditions are negative so that the comparative-static results based on sign here are similar for HT s transformed incentive ratio and the actual ratio but, in principle, they differ. 15

16 The terms involving the CARA coefficient, 0, in the optimal incentive values given by equation ( 13) and optimal effort (equation ( 14)) reflect second-best contracting considerations with a risk-averse manager such that all incentives are less high-powered and effort lower the more risk-averse the agent. Conversely, having the agent s preferences approach risk-neutrality (i.e. 0) achieves full efficiency but can make informed investor monitoring less relevant if high-powered incentives can be used in franchise contracts (i.e. sell the firm to the manager). Nonetheless, if there are constraints on the ability to eliminate agency problems by selling the firm to the manager, then there is still a role for informed trading to improve manager monitoring. We now get to the core of the paper by examining the effect of higher price informativeness on ˆ p ˆ and ˆ y due to increasing the number of informed traders, N, or smaller observational error volatility,, perhaps due to increased firm scale, although larger more liquid stocks benefit with respect to both elements. We examine the comparative-statics of the equity allocation, equation ( 13) with respect to informativeness,, as this represents either more informed traders or a smaller error volatility term: Proposition 4: A sufficient condition for the equity allocation (i.e pay-performance sensitivity) to fall with increased stock price informativeness is that the precision of the stock price signal exceed that of the non-price (i.e. accounting signal). Proof: See Appendix A. Intuitively, this finding makes a great deal of sense: the more accurate is the information in the stock price relative to alternative signals such as accounting information, the more productive is equity (i.e. pay-performance sensitivity) as an incentive device. Hence, the less of their own equity (i.e. wealth) insiders have to give away to the manager. 16

17 Nonetheless, HT prove the following proposition that, on the face of it, contradicts Proposition 4: Proposition 4 (HT Version): The (transformed) equity allocation is always rising in stock price informativeness and thus incentives must become more high-powered as liquidity and informativeness rise with firm scale. In fact, HT state explicitly that their transformed equity allocation ˆ p ˆ falls in response to an increase in the error volatility term, ( in HT s notation). 15 In fact, there is no contradiction due to HT s transformation of the equity incentive into a measure of equity s effectiveness and their only lapse is in failing to transform it back prior to analysis. Thus, as Proposition 4 shows, in general it is not possible to sign the impact of more informed traders on the equity allocation unequivocally on theoretical grounds alone because the relative magnitudes of parameters of interest are latent when both equity and bonus payment incentives are utilized. Hence, we need to rely on the empirical evidence as presented in Section IV. This empirical evidence in turn provides information about the relevant latent variables. A potentially empirically relevant case arises when non-price incentives are weak, i.e. stock price precision is high relative to (say) accounting precision. One easily shows in this case that a corner solution pertains with no non-price incentives: 1 ˆ, pˆ ( 15) 15 Note that as Bengt Holmstrom points out in correspondence, there are no technical errors in the proofs in HT as all the comparative-static results are reported for the transformed equity share incentive variable that is in reality the incentive due to equity and bears little relationship to the equity allocation itself. It is only in their verbal interpretation of the model that he refers to as misleading as this transformed equity share incentive is treated as being the actual equity allocation whereas it is not. 17

18 with a * ˆ p ˆ and, obviously, the equity allocation is always falling in stock price informativeness,. Note that in this case, HT mistake ˆ p ˆ. * a for their original equity allocation Proposition 5: The impact of higher stock price informativeness on the non-price incentive allocation is always negative. With more efficient informed trader monitoring due to greater price informativeness, the requirement to provide non-price incentives (i.e. accounting-based bonus payments) always reduces. Proof: See Appendix A. Proposition 6: The risk-averse manager s effort and thus firm performance is always increasing in stock price informativeness. Proof: See Appendix A. Hence, the effort of the risk-averse manager, and therefore firm performance, is always increasing in the number of informed traders and reductions in the observational error term. Increased stock price informativeness due to more traders or a smaller observational error term must always increase managerial effort except in the limiting case in which effort is already at first best. Combined with the results in Proposition, multiple informed traders lead to higher trading volume and more intense trade aggressiveness, causing greater price informativeness and an increase in firm value accordingly. 16 Hence, in more informationally rich markets with more aggressive informed traders we should observe both higher asset values and lower stock returns. We now obtain a general result on the substitutability of equity and bonus incentives for informed trader monitoring. 16 In our setting, as in the EM and HT framework, firm value and managerial effort has no bearing on informed traders trading profits. 18

19 Proposition 7: The sum of price (equity) and non-price (i.e. accounting bonus) incentives is always diminishing in stock price informativeness. Proof: See Appendix A. It is important to recognize that this striking result holds regardless of whether the equitybased incentive is increasing in informativeness. Hence, we obtain an exceedingly strong result in terms of the general substitutability of managerial incentives for informed trader monitoring. It makes intuitive sense, as it is expensive for shareholders to incentivize riskaverse managers. The more effectively stock price informativeness reveals the manager s own actions and thus the more she is self-motivated to perform, the lower the cost burden placed on shareholders. We now examine the impact of increased informativeness on the manager s expected ˆ ˆ ˆ a since the expected values of ˆp and y are given by income, * E I equilibrium managerial productivity, 0 pˆ y * a. Proposition 8: In general, expected managerial income cannot be signed unambiguously with respect to stock price informativeness induced by either a larger number of informed traders or more informed traders as incentives are reduced while both performance and performance pay rises, depending on how risk-averse is the manager. It is thus an empirical issue. Proof: See Appendix A. To recover the weights placed on equity-based and non-equity-based pay in the original managerial incentive contract, equation ( ) from the normalized ones in equation ( 3), we present the following proposition: 19

20 Proposition 9: Following the general approach of Calcagno and Heider (009) but with a quite different specification, the transformed components of the manager s contract can be expressed in terms of its original components: 1 1p 1 ˆ ˆ ˆ 0 0, pˆ,, and. y y 1 p 1 p 1 1 ( 16) Proof: See Appendix A. II. Data and Descriptive Statistics We merge CRSP/Compustat database with Standard & Poor s (S&P) ExecuComp database (from 199 to 007) to calculate CEO incentives. The institutional trading and shareholdings data are sourced from Thomson Reuter s 13f filing database. 17 All the firm-level accounting and stock price data are from Compustat and CRSP, respectively. A. CEO Incentives Data The ExecuComp database covers about 1,500 firms in the S&P It contains valuable compensation-related information for the top five (sometimes more) executives of each firm including total amounts of salary, bonus, long-term incentive plan, restricted stock grants and stock option grants. In this study, we focus only on CEO compensation because we expect the CEO alone to have the greatest power in a firm s decision-making process and to be the focus of institutional investor monitoring. We compute the pay-for-performance sensitivity (PPS) of CEO s total equity-based compensation as our proxy for equity-based pay allocation in the text. PPS as a proper proxy can be easily motivated since higher PPS indicates a closer alignment of interests between the CEO and the shareholders as posited by Jensen and Murphy (1990) and Hall and Liebman 17 Institutions with more than $100 million of securities under management are required to report to the SEC. The Thomson Reuter s 13f filing database contains the aggregate shareholdings for each institution on the quarterly basis. Disclosure is required for all positions greater than 10,000 shares or $00,000. 0

21 (1998). Our PPS measure consists of two parts: PPS_Cum_Option and PPS_CEO_Shares. The former is calculated as per Yermack (1995) and Core and Guay (00) 18 and is used to measure the dollar change in value of CEO option holdings for every $1,000 change in the value of the firm (shareholders value). The latter is used to measure the dollar change in CEO shareholdings (including restricted stock) for every $1,000 change in the firm value. The combined PPS measure is termed PPS_Total. It is worth noting that PPS_Cum_Option comprises the value of all outstanding options, as we believe the value of unexercised stock options granted in previous years also provides incentives that will influence CEOs actions (e.g. Jensen and Murphy (1990)). We also include CEO total compensation and other pay components (salary, bonus, and equity-based incentives) in our sample. Total compensation is the total direct compensation data derived from ExecuComp, defined as the sum of salary, bonus, total value of restricted stock granted, total (Black-Scholes) value of stock options granted, long-term incentive pay, and other annual payouts (including pension and health benefits, perquisites, etc). In Panel A of Table I we can see that on average, PPS_Total is about $35 per $1,000 change in shareholder value. Around 67% of PPS_Total can be attributed to CEO shareholdings (including restricted shares), and the remaining part to CEO option grants. The average CEO s total compensation is $4.9 million in 006 dollars. Of this amount, salary averages $760,000 and bonus $784,000. We also aggregate all equity-based components 19 and the sum averages $.97 million. All the CEO pay measures are right-skewed. <<Insert Table I>> 18 In particular, we compute PPS_Cum_Option by dividing the share equivalent of CEO cumulative option holdings by the total number of shares outstanding at the beginning of the fiscal year. Whereas the share equivalent of CEO option holdings is the product of the delta (i.e. the hedge ratio, based on the Black-Scholes formula adjusted for dividends) and the number of options granted in current and previous years. We apply the same method to compute PPS_CEO_Shares (note that hedge ratio of shares is 1). We then multiply PPS by 1000 to reflect the dollar change in CEO option grants for every $1,000 change in the firm value. 19 Equity-based components include CEO s restricted stock grants, stock option grants, and long-term incentive pay (LTIP). LTIP is included because it is mostly equity-based in public listed firms. 1

22 B. Institutional Trading and Ownership Measures We identify informed institutional investors by verifying whether they engage in a specific trading pattern. We make necessary adjustments suggested by the database provider (WRDS) before constructing variables related to institutional holdings. 0 B.1. Institutional Ownership Measures For each stock, we aggregate shares held across all institutions and divide it by the total number of shares outstanding at the end of each quarter to construct the institutional ownership measure (IO). We also construct the Top5_shrout measure by summing up the holdings of the five largest institutional investors for each firm and scale it by the total number of shares outstanding at the end of each quarter. These ownership concentration measures, as per Chen, Harford, and Li (007), are proxies for voice of institutional investors but differ from the concentration measure used by Hartzell and Starks (003) that ignores share ownership. Smith and Swan (01) shows that their findings are either insignificant or reversed when one uses a more reasonable size proxy based on the logarithm of market capitalization. B.. Institutional Trading Pattern and Turnover We analyze all institutional trades in a year (four quarters). We split up all trades in a year into several trading patterns based on the sign of change in the quarterly holdings of a particular stock. Hence, a trading pattern represents how an institution investor trades a particular stock within a year. Since Thomson Reuter s data fix the report date for a year at every March, June, September and December, we take every December of the previous year as the starting point and calculate the quarterly change of shareholdings of an institutional 0 To make sure that all shares in the 13f reports are adjusted for splits and special distributions we merge the 13f reports with CRSP monthly stock file dataset and use FDATE (file date in Thomson 13f dataset) and CRSP cumulative adjustment factors to make the adjustment. We also make similar adjustments for total number of shares outstanding and price sourced from CRSP.

23 investor for a particular stock for the next four quarters. We identify the following eight mutually exclusive trading patterns: (i) Buy-Sell-Buy (BSB), (ii) Sell-Buy-Sell (SBS), (iii) Sell-Buy (SB), (iv) Buy-Sell (BS), 1 (v) Hold-Hold-Hold (HHH), (vi) Buy-Buy-Buy (BBB), (vii) Sell-Sell-Sell (SSS), and finally (viii) Others (one occurrence of either Sell or Buy in the sequence). We require an institutional investor to hold the stock for four consecutive quarters for her trade sequence to be valid. For each stock, we calculate turnover ratio of each trading pattern identified in a year. The details are as follows: we firstly compute the annual trading volume of an institutional investor by summing the absolute value of the quarterly change in holding within a year (i.e., four quarters). Then for each stock, we aggregate the trading volume across all institutional investors engaging in a particular trading pattern, scaling it by the total number of shares outstanding at the end of each September (because we start with each December of the previous year, the ending quarter is September of each year). We repeat the same process for all the trading patterns and finally arrive at a dataset containing the turnover rate of each of the seven trading patterns for each stock, totaling 4,679 firm-years (covering 16 years from 199 to 007). We also construct a measure called InstTrade that represents the total institutional turnover by aggregating all the trading volume annually (regardless of the trading patterns) across all institutions, scaling it by its total number of shares outstanding. Panel B of Table I shows the average institutional ownership of the 13f institutions is about 60% in the year range, which is seven percentage point higher than a decade ago reported in Hartzel and Starks (003), using data. The ownership concentration of the top five institutions averages 4%, which is only slightly higher than a decade ago. The mean of total institutional turnover is about 3.5% with a standard deviation 1 Pattern (3) also includes both Sell-Buy-Hold and Hold-Sell-Buy sequences; pattern (4) also includes Buy- Sell-Hold and Hold-Buy-Sell sequences. We exclude the trading pattern, HHH, because there is no change in holdings, hence no turnover rate. 3

24 of 13% and the mean turnover of all the trading patterns is 3.5%, varying from 0.17% (the Sell-Buy pattern) to 11.7% (the Others pattern). B.3. Other Control Variables We include control variables widely used in the literature on managerial compensation. Ln_MktCap is the natural log of market value of equity, measured as the product of the number of shares outstanding and share price, both of which we source from CRSP. Firm size measured in this way is highly negatively associated with pay-performance sensitivity. While not surprising, it is actually support for the major prediction of the original HT model after correcting for HT s confusion between pay-performance sensitivity and performance due to equity (i.e. the difference between Proposition 4 and Proposition 4 (HT Version) above). The difference of MktCap between year t and year t-1, ΔMktCap, and the lagged value of ΔMktCap are included as per Hartzell and Starks (003) to control for change in shareholder value. We also include Debt_Ratio, computed as the ratio of total liabilities to total assets, for debt has been widely viewed as an alternative monitoring mechanism in principal-agent theory, and therefore can affect CEO incentives. Tobin_Q, defined as the ratio of the market value of assets 3 to the book value of total assets, is included as a popular proxy for the firm s growth opportunities in the literature. We compute the above two firm-level controls based on the Compustat dataset. We also include both the yearly buy-and-hold cumulative returns (CumRet) and standard deviation of market capitalization (Dol_Volat) because the former deals with the potential association between the firm s performance and CEO pay whereas the latter is highly related to the talent of CEO as per Sung and Swan (009). We compute both of them from CRSP. All the price level-related variables are CPI deflated (006 = 100). In all of our analyses, we also control for year and industry effects. Year dummy variables allow both PPS and other CEO pay component to vary year by year. They also control for 3 See Sung and Swan (009) for more details on the calculation of the market values of assets. 4

25 exogenous factors that may influence PPS and other CEO pay component, such as the overall market condition. Industry dummy variables act as fixed effects at the industry level. Our final unified dataset covers more than 77% of the firms in ExecuComp from 199 to 007, totaling 17,946 firm-years. We winsorize all the continuous variables at the 1% and 99% levels to mitigate the effect of extreme observations. 4 As can be seen from Panel C of Table I, the average annual stock return (buy-and-hold) is 17.7% with a standard deviation of nearly 49%. The standard deviation of market capitalization averages $,10 million. The debt ratio of all the firms in our sample is about one quarter and Tobin s Q is 1.8 on average. Finally, the mean (median) firm size is about $7.4 billion ($1.8 billion). III. Following Governance through Trading BSB and SBS as Swing Trades We follow GGS to identify institutional investors aiming to make trading profits rather than to extract private benefits from acquiring control of the firm or to gain from better governance of the firm. Of all the eight trading patterns, the sequence of a Buy, followed by a Sell, then a Buy ( BSB sequence) or a Sell, followed by a Buy, then a Sell ( SBS sequence) in a stock fits the characteristics of institutional investor monitoring best. Indeed, GGS show that these are profitable sequences even after transaction costs. These two sequences involve large swings (defined as the distance from the peak to trough in the holdings), suggesting institutional investors engaging in such trading are either constantly monitoring the CEO or are receiving strong signals regarding future firm value for other reasons. Either way, they are likely to have a strong trader informational advantage. Greater swing also implies higher trade aggressiveness as shown in equation ( 6) above, which in turn 4 There is a potential overlapping issue in merging CEO incentives-related data with institutional trading/ownership data and firm-level control variables, since ExcuComp is fiscal-year-based annual dataset (same as Compustat) and the Thomson 13f reports are a calendar-year-based quarterly dataset. We avoid this by selecting firms with fiscal year-end month in September, October, November, and December only. See Appendix B for further details. 5

Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring?

Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring? Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring? Peter L. Swan ACE Conference, July 13, 2018, Canberra UNSW Business School, Sydney Australia July 13, 2018 UNSW Australia, Sydney, Australia 1 /

More information

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Miguel Antón, Florian Ederer, Mireia Giné, and Martin Schmalz August 13, 2016 Abstract This internet appendix provides

More information

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Minh Vo Metropolitan State University Abstract This paper develops a model of financing with informational feedback effect that jointly determines a firm s capital

More information

The Role of Stock Liquidity and Stock Return Volatility in Executive Compensation: Risk versus Information

The Role of Stock Liquidity and Stock Return Volatility in Executive Compensation: Risk versus Information The Role of Stock Liquidity and Stock Return Volatility in Executive Compensation: Risk versus Information Sudarshan Jayaraman and Todd Milbourn Draft Date: July 1, 2009 Abstract We examine how managerial

More information

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria and Rational Expectations Equilibria 1 Basic Setup Two periods: 0 and 1 One riskless asset with interest rate r One risky asset which pays a normally distributed

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK Scott J. Wallsten * Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research 579 Serra Mall at Galvez St. Stanford, CA 94305 650-724-4371 wallsten@stanford.edu

More information

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models Preliminary Lecture Notes Hongbin Cai and Xi Weng Department of Applied Economics, Guanghua School of Management Peking University November 2014 Contents 1 Static Moral Hazard

More information

Liability, Insurance and the Incentive to Obtain Information About Risk. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University

Liability, Insurance and the Incentive to Obtain Information About Risk. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University \ins\liab\liabinfo.v3d 12-05-08 Liability, Insurance and the Incentive to Obtain Information About Risk Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University Paul Thistle University of Nevada Las Vegas December

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 in the first Blue Book and Problems 2, 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A Final

More information

THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND THE LINK BETWEEN EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND FIRM PERFORMANCE CHNG BEY FEN

THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND THE LINK BETWEEN EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND FIRM PERFORMANCE CHNG BEY FEN THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND THE LINK BETWEEN EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND FIRM PERFORMANCE CHNG BEY FEN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE 2001 THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring Holmstrom and Tirole (JPE, 1993) The main idea A firm would like to issue shares in the capital market because once these shares are publicly traded, speculators

More information

The Effect of Speculative Monitoring on Shareholder Activism

The Effect of Speculative Monitoring on Shareholder Activism The Effect of Speculative Monitoring on Shareholder Activism Günter Strobl April 13, 016 Preliminary Draft. Please do not circulate. Abstract This paper investigates how informed trading in financial markets

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

The Role of Stock Liquidity in Executive Compensation

The Role of Stock Liquidity in Executive Compensation The Role of Stock Liquidity in Executive Compensation Sudarshan Jayaraman Olin Business School Washington University in St. Louis Campus Box 1133 St. Louis, MO 63130 jayaraman@wustl.edu Todd Milbourn Olin

More information

Weak Governance by Informed Large. Shareholders

Weak Governance by Informed Large. Shareholders Weak Governance by Informed Large Shareholders Eitan Goldman and Wenyu Wang June 15, 2016 Abstract A commonly held belief is that better informed large shareholders with greater influence improve corporate

More information

The Determinants of CEO Inside Debt and Its Components *

The Determinants of CEO Inside Debt and Its Components * The Determinants of CEO Inside Debt and Its Components * Wei Cen** Peking University HSBC Business School [Preliminary version] 1 * This paper is a part of my PhD dissertation at Cornell University. I

More information

Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson

Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options Joshua D. Anderson jdanders@mit.edu (617) 253-7974 John E. Core* jcore@mit.edu (617) 715-4819 Abstract We measure

More information

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Journal of Financial Economics 47 (1998) 219 239 Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Anup Agrawal*, Charles R. Knoeber College of Management, North Carolina State University, Raleigh, NC

More information

Liquidity and the cost of market-based compensation in informationally efficient markets

Liquidity and the cost of market-based compensation in informationally efficient markets Liquidity and the cost of market-based compensation in informationally efficient markets Riccardo Calcagno Florian Heider February 205 Abstract We provide a model which adresses the problem of compensating

More information

Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion. Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b

Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion. Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b a Department of Finance, Spears School of Business, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, OK

More information

research paper series

research paper series research paper series Research Paper 00/9 Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market by A. Mukherjee The Centre acknowledges financial support from The

More information

Journal of Corporate Finance

Journal of Corporate Finance Journal of Corporate Finance 14 (2008) 484 498 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Corporate Finance journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jcorpfin Stock trading, information production,

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

Information-Based Stock Trading, Executive Incentives, and the Principal-Agent Problem

Information-Based Stock Trading, Executive Incentives, and the Principal-Agent Problem Information-Based Stock Trading, Executive Incentives, and the Principal-Agent Problem Qiang Kang University of Miami Qiao Liu University of Hong Kong This Draft: November 2009 Abstract We examine the

More information

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem Jin Yong Jung We analyze how the wealth of an agent and its distribution affect the profit of the principal by considering the simple

More information

Lectures on Trading with Information Competitive Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium (Grossman and Stiglitz AER (1980))

Lectures on Trading with Information Competitive Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium (Grossman and Stiglitz AER (1980)) Lectures on Trading with Information Competitive Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium (Grossman and Stiglitz AER (980)) Assumptions (A) Two Assets: Trading in the asset market involves a risky asset

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

Discussion Paper No. 593

Discussion Paper No. 593 Discussion Paper No. 593 MANAGEMENT OWNERSHIP AND FIRM S VALUE: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS USING PANEL DATA Sang-Mook Lee and Keunkwan Ryu September 2003 The Institute of Social and Economic Research Osaka

More information

Does Insider Ownership Matter for Financial Decisions and Firm Performance: Evidence from Manufacturing Sector of Pakistan

Does Insider Ownership Matter for Financial Decisions and Firm Performance: Evidence from Manufacturing Sector of Pakistan Does Insider Ownership Matter for Financial Decisions and Firm Performance: Evidence from Manufacturing Sector of Pakistan Haris Arshad & Attiya Yasmin Javid INTRODUCTION In an emerging economy like Pakistan,

More information

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland The International Journal of Business and Finance Research Volume 6 Number 2 2012 AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University

More information

Internet Appendix to. Glued to the TV: Distracted Noise Traders and Stock Market Liquidity

Internet Appendix to. Glued to the TV: Distracted Noise Traders and Stock Market Liquidity Internet Appendix to Glued to the TV: Distracted Noise Traders and Stock Market Liquidity Joel PERESS & Daniel SCHMIDT 6 October 2018 1 Table of Contents Internet Appendix A: The Implications of Distraction

More information

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility and Coordination Failures What makes financial systems fragile? What causes crises

More information

Making Money out of Publicly Available Information

Making Money out of Publicly Available Information Making Money out of Publicly Available Information Forthcoming, Economics Letters Alan D. Morrison Saïd Business School, University of Oxford and CEPR Nir Vulkan Saïd Business School, University of Oxford

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality DORON NISSIM* Corporate disclosures are an important source of information for investors. Many studies have documented strong price

More information

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 26/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008 Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008 There are two questions on the exam, representing Asset Pricing (236D = 234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Executive Compensation, Financial Constraint and Product Market Strategies

Executive Compensation, Financial Constraint and Product Market Strategies Executive Compensation, Financial Constraint and Product Market Strategies Jaideep Chowdhury January 17, 01 Abstract In this paper, we provide an additional factor that can explain a firm s product market

More information

Incentives in Executive Compensation Contracts: An Examination of Pay-for-Performance

Incentives in Executive Compensation Contracts: An Examination of Pay-for-Performance Incentives in Executive Compensation Contracts: An Examination of Pay-for-Performance Alaina George April 2003 I would like to thank my advisor, Professor Miles Cahill, for his encouragement, direction,

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Economics 101A (Lecture 25) Stefano DellaVigna

Economics 101A (Lecture 25) Stefano DellaVigna Economics 101A (Lecture 25) Stefano DellaVigna April 28, 2015 Outline 1. Asymmetric Information: Introduction 2. Hidden Action (Moral Hazard) 3. The Takeover Game 1 Asymmetric Information: Introduction

More information

Agency Problems are Ameliorated by Stock Market Liquidity: Monitoring, Information and the Use of Stock- Based Compensation

Agency Problems are Ameliorated by Stock Market Liquidity: Monitoring, Information and the Use of Stock- Based Compensation Agency Problems are Ameliorated by Stock Market Liquidity: Monitoring, Information and the Use of Stock- Based Compensation Version February 12, 2002 Gerald T. Garvey and Peter L. Swan ξ Abstract Recent

More information

Monopoly Power with a Short Selling Constraint

Monopoly Power with a Short Selling Constraint Monopoly Power with a Short Selling Constraint Robert Baumann College of the Holy Cross Bryan Engelhardt College of the Holy Cross September 24, 2012 David L. Fuller Concordia University Abstract We show

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Strategic Trading of Informed Trader with Monopoly on Shortand Long-Lived Information

Strategic Trading of Informed Trader with Monopoly on Shortand Long-Lived Information ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 10-, 351 365 (009) Strategic Trading of Informed Trader with Monopoly on Shortand Long-Lived Information Chanwoo Noh Department of Mathematics, Pohang University of Science

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

Book Review of The Theory of Corporate Finance

Book Review of The Theory of Corporate Finance Cahier de recherche/working Paper 11-20 Book Review of The Theory of Corporate Finance Georges Dionne Juillet/July 2011 Dionne: Canada Research Chair in Risk Management and Finance Department, HEC Montreal,

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage Jin-Chuan Duan * and Yun Li (First draft: April 12, 2006) (This version: May 16, 2006) Abstract This paper identifies a key cause for the documented diversification

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry Lin, Journal of International and Global Economic Studies, 7(2), December 2014, 17-31 17 Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically

More information

Durable Goods Price Cycles: Theory and Evidence from the Textbook Market. By Eric W. Bond and Toshiaki Iizuka

Durable Goods Price Cycles: Theory and Evidence from the Textbook Market. By Eric W. Bond and Toshiaki Iizuka Durable Goods Price Cycles: Theory and Evidence from the Textbook Market By Eric W. Bond and Toshiaki Iizuka June 2005 Abstract: We develop a model of the monopoly pricing of a durable good when there

More information

Market based compensation, trading and liquidity

Market based compensation, trading and liquidity Market based compensation, trading and liquidity Riccardo Calcagno Florian Heider January 004 Abstract This paper examines the role of trading and liquidity in a large competitive market with dispersed

More information

Does the Equity Market affect Economic Growth?

Does the Equity Market affect Economic Growth? The Macalester Review Volume 2 Issue 2 Article 1 8-5-2012 Does the Equity Market affect Economic Growth? Kwame D. Fynn Macalester College, kwamefynn@gmail.com Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.macalester.edu/macreview

More information

Do Mutual Fund Managers Monitor Executive Compensation?

Do Mutual Fund Managers Monitor Executive Compensation? Do Mutual Fund Managers Monitor Executive Compensation? David R. Gallagher Gavin Smith a Peter Swan Current Draft: 7 June 2005 School of Banking Finance, University of New South Wales, Sydney, N.S.W. 2052

More information

Internet Appendix for Back-Running: Seeking and Hiding Fundamental Information in Order Flows

Internet Appendix for Back-Running: Seeking and Hiding Fundamental Information in Order Flows Internet Appendix for Back-Running: Seeking and Hiding Fundamental Information in Order Flows Liyan Yang Haoxiang Zhu July 4, 017 In Yang and Zhu (017), we have taken the information of the fundamental

More information

Master Thesis Finance

Master Thesis Finance Master Thesis Finance Anr: 120255 Name: Toby Verlouw Subject: Managerial incentives and CEO compensation Study program: Finance Supervisor: Dr. M.F. Penas 2 Managerial incentives: Does Stock Option Compensation

More information

Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin. The allocation of authority under limited liability

Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin. The allocation of authority under limited liability Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin Nr. 2005/25 VOLKSWIRTSCHAFTLICHE REIHE The allocation of authority under limited liability Kerstin Puschke ISBN

More information

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Definition of Incomplete Contracts Definition of Incomplete Contracts Susheng Wang 1 2 nd edition 2 July 2016 This note defines incomplete contracts and explains simple contracts. Although widely used in practice, incomplete contracts have

More information

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics ISSN 974-40 (on line edition) ISSN 594-7645 (print edition) WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY

More information

Transactions with Hidden Action: Part 1. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Transactions with Hidden Action: Part 1. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Transactions with Hidden Action: Part 1 Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2015 Transactions with hidden action A risk-neutral principal (P) delegates performance of a task to an agent (A) Key features

More information

IS TAX SHARING OPTIMAL? AN ANALYSIS IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT FRAMEWORK

IS TAX SHARING OPTIMAL? AN ANALYSIS IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT FRAMEWORK IS TAX SHARING OPTIMAL? AN ANALYSIS IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT FRAMEWORK BARNALI GUPTA AND CHRISTELLE VIAUROUX ABSTRACT. We study the effects of a statutory wage tax sharing rule in a principal - agent framework

More information

Growth Options, Incentives, and Pay-for-Performance: Theory and Evidence

Growth Options, Incentives, and Pay-for-Performance: Theory and Evidence Growth Options, Incentives, and Pay-for-Performance: Theory and Evidence Sebastian Gryglewicz (Erasmus) Barney Hartman-Glaser (UCLA Anderson) Geoffery Zheng (UCLA Anderson) June 17, 2016 How do growth

More information

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW 2.1 Background on capital structure Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set of assumptions, capital structure is irrelevant. This

More information

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation Internet Appendix A. Participation constraint In evaluating when the participation constraint binds, we consider three

More information

Sensex Realized Volatility Index (REALVOL)

Sensex Realized Volatility Index (REALVOL) Sensex Realized Volatility Index (REALVOL) Introduction Volatility modelling has traditionally relied on complex econometric procedures in order to accommodate the inherent latent character of volatility.

More information

Research Article Managerial risk reduction, incentives and firm value

Research Article Managerial risk reduction, incentives and firm value Economic Theory, (2005) DOI: 10.1007/s00199-004-0569-2 Red.Nr.1077 Research Article Managerial risk reduction, incentives and firm value Saltuk Ozerturk Department of Economics, Southern Methodist University,

More information

JACOBS LEVY CONCEPTS FOR PROFITABLE EQUITY INVESTING

JACOBS LEVY CONCEPTS FOR PROFITABLE EQUITY INVESTING JACOBS LEVY CONCEPTS FOR PROFITABLE EQUITY INVESTING Our investment philosophy is built upon over 30 years of groundbreaking equity research. Many of the concepts derived from that research have now become

More information

Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market

Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market Meng-Wei Chen Department of Economics, Indiana University at Bloomington April 21, 2011 Abstract This paper studies the information transmission

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012. Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012. You have 3 hours to answer the questions in the final exam. We will collect the exams at 2.30 sharp. Show your work, and good luck! Problem 1. Utility Maximization.

More information

Loss-leader pricing and upgrades

Loss-leader pricing and upgrades Loss-leader pricing and upgrades Younghwan In and Julian Wright This version: August 2013 Abstract A new theory of loss-leader pricing is provided in which firms advertise low below cost) prices for certain

More information

Citation for published version (APA): Oosterhof, C. M. (2006). Essays on corporate risk management and optimal hedging s.n.

Citation for published version (APA): Oosterhof, C. M. (2006). Essays on corporate risk management and optimal hedging s.n. University of Groningen Essays on corporate risk management and optimal hedging Oosterhof, Casper Martijn IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish

More information

Monitoring, Contractual Incentive Pay, and the Structure of CEO Equity-Based Compensation. Fan Yu. A dissertation

Monitoring, Contractual Incentive Pay, and the Structure of CEO Equity-Based Compensation. Fan Yu. A dissertation Monitoring, Contractual Incentive Pay, and the Structure of CEO Equity-Based Compensation Fan Yu A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

EFFICIENT MARKETS HYPOTHESIS

EFFICIENT MARKETS HYPOTHESIS EFFICIENT MARKETS HYPOTHESIS when economists speak of capital markets as being efficient, they usually consider asset prices and returns as being determined as the outcome of supply and demand in a competitive

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency. Problem

Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency. Problem Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency Problem Anthony M. Marino Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Los Angeles, CA 90089-1422 E-mail: amarino@usc.edu May 8,

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector

Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector Bengt Holmstrom and Jean Tirole April 3, 2017 Holmstrom and Tirole Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and The Real Sector April 3, 2017

More information

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract In this paper we study the market reaction to capital expenditure announcements in the backdrop

More information

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence A The infinite horizon model This section defines the equilibrium of the infinity horizon model described in Section III of the paper and characterizes

More information

Contrarian Trades and Disposition Effect: Evidence from Online Trade Data. Abstract

Contrarian Trades and Disposition Effect: Evidence from Online Trade Data. Abstract Contrarian Trades and Disposition Effect: Evidence from Online Trade Data Hayato Komai a Ryota Koyano b Daisuke Miyakawa c Abstract Using online stock trading records in Japan for 461 individual investors

More information

A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales

A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance Volume 8 Issue 1 Spring 2003 Article 7 12-2003 A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales Robert Dubil San Jose State University Follow this and additional

More information

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Jian Liu ** University of Exeter This draft: August 2016 Abstract We examine

More information

Are CEOs Charged for Stock-Based Pay? An Instrumental Variable Analysis

Are CEOs Charged for Stock-Based Pay? An Instrumental Variable Analysis Are CEOs Charged for Stock-Based Pay? An Instrumental Variable Analysis Nina Baranchuk School of Management University of Texas - Dallas P.O. BOX 830688 SM31 Richardson, TX 75083-0688 E-mail: nina.baranchuk@utdallas.edu

More information

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Mehmet E. Akbulut 1 Department of Finance College of Business and Economics California State University Fullerton Abstract This paper examines whether managers

More information

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure Corporate Financial Management Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure As we discussed in previous lectures, two extreme results, namely the irrelevance of capital structure and 100 percent

More information

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Appendices A A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Given the structure of venture capital financing just described, the potential mechanisms by which shocks might propagate across companies in

More information

FISCAL FEDERALISM WITH A SINGLE INSTRUMENT TO FINANCE GOVERNMENT. Carlos Maravall Rodríguez 1

FISCAL FEDERALISM WITH A SINGLE INSTRUMENT TO FINANCE GOVERNMENT. Carlos Maravall Rodríguez 1 Working Paper 05-22 Economics Series 13 April 2005 Departamento de Economía Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Calle Madrid, 126 28903 Getafe (Spain) Fax (34) 91 624 98 75 FISCAL FEDERALISM WITH A SINGLE

More information

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Zhangkai Huang * and Xingzhong Xu Guanghua School of Management Peking University Abstract Unlike in other countries, negotiated block shares have

More information

Socially responsible mutual fund activism evidence from socially. responsible mutual fund proxy voting and exit behavior

Socially responsible mutual fund activism evidence from socially. responsible mutual fund proxy voting and exit behavior Stockholm School of Economics Master Thesis Department of Accounting & Financial Management Spring 2017 Socially responsible mutual fund activism evidence from socially responsible mutual fund proxy voting

More information

Academic Editor: Emiliano A. Valdez, Albert Cohen and Nick Costanzino

Academic Editor: Emiliano A. Valdez, Albert Cohen and Nick Costanzino Risks 2015, 3, 543-552; doi:10.3390/risks3040543 Article Production Flexibility and Hedging OPEN ACCESS risks ISSN 2227-9091 www.mdpi.com/journal/risks Georges Dionne 1, * and Marc Santugini 2 1 Department

More information

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel Appendix to: Why Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down? AMoreElaborateModel Antti Petajisto Yale School of Management February 2004 1 A More Elaborate Model 1.1 Motivation Our earlier model provides a

More information

Executive Compensation and Firm Leverage

Executive Compensation and Firm Leverage Executive Compensation and Firm Leverage Michael Albert Fisher College of Business Ohio State University November 10, 2013 ** Preliminary and Incomplete ** Abstract This work explores the role of executive

More information

Hostile Corporate Governance and Stock Liquidity

Hostile Corporate Governance and Stock Liquidity Hostile Corporate Governance and Stock Liquidity Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign EFMA 2014 Panel Session on Hedge Fund Activism Vyacheslav (Slava) Fos, UIUC Hostile Corporate

More information

Executive Compensation and Short-Termism

Executive Compensation and Short-Termism Executive Compensation and Short-Termism Alessio Piccolo University of Oxford December 16, 018 Click here for the most updated version Abstract The stock market is widely believed to pressure executives

More information