Ownership, Governance and Investment *

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Ownership, Governance and Investment *"

Transcription

1 Ownership, Governance and Investment * Germán Gutiérrez and Thomas Philippon March 2017 Preliminary Abstract The US business sector has under-invested relative to Tobin's Q since the early 2000s; and the under-investment appears to be explained by decreasing competition (due to both increasing concentration and common ownership) and tight or short-termist governance [Gutiérrez and Philippon, 2016]. In this paper, we use a combination of natural experiments and instrumental variables to establish a causal relationship between increased quasi-indexer institutional ownership and decreased investment. In particular, we use the Russell index threshold as a natural experiment, and lagged quasi-indexer ownership as an IV. We nd that higher quasi-indexer ownership leads to higher buybacks and less investment. We then study the interaction between governance and competition in causing under-investment and nd contrasting results. At the rm-level, governance matters most for rms in non-competitive industries: they tend to buyback more shares and invest less. At the industry-level, anti-competitive eects of common ownership disproportionately aect industries that `appear' competitive according to traditional measures but actually are not (due to common ownership). In Gutiérrez and Philippon [2016], we show that investment is weak relative to measures of profitability and valuation, and that this weakness starts in the early 2000s. We argue that investment is not low because Q is low, but rather despite high Q; which rules out a long list of potential explanations such as low expected growth. We then use a mix of industry- and rm-level data to test whether under-investment relative to Q is driven by (i) nancial frictions, (ii) measurement error (due to the rise of intangibles, globalization, etc), (iii) decreased competition (due to technology, regulation or common ownership), or (iv) tightened governance and/or increased short-termism. We nd that proxies for competition and ownership explain the bulk of the investment gap, across * We are grateful to Janice Eberly, Olivier Blanchard, René Stulz, Boyan Jovanovic, Tano Santos, Charles Calomiris, Glenn Hubbard, Holger Mueller, Alexi Savov, Philipp Schnabl, Ralph Koijen, Ricardo Caballero, Emmanuel Farhi, Viral Acharya, and seminar participants at Columbia University and New York University for stimulating discussions. New York University New York University, CEPR and NBER 1

2 industries and across rms. Controlling for current market conditions, industries with less entry and more concentration (traditional or due to common ownership) invest less. Within each industryyear, the investment gap is driven by rms owned by quasi-indexers and located in industries with more concentration/more common ownership. These rms spend a disproportionate amount of free cash ows buying back their shares. The conclusions in Gutiérrez and Philippon [2016] are supported by discussions in policy and industry circles. 1 However, they are based on simple regressions and therefore cannot establish causality between competition, ownership and investment. In this paper, we (i) test the causality of increased quasi-indexer ownership on investment; and (ii) study the interaction between governance and competition in causing under-investment. A companion paper studies the causality between increased competition and investment [Gutiérrez and Philippon, 2017]. From a theoretical perspective, ownership can aect management incentives in three main ways: (i) by aecting the investment horizon of managers (i.e., by inducing short-termism); (ii) by tightening governance, leading to less over-investment; and (iii) by inducing anti-competitive eects through common ownership. We develop a simple model of Dynamic Competition to clarify these dynamics, to show that these three mechanisms aect investment in very dierent ways: improved governance aligns the (manager's) maximization problem with that of the shareholder's, thereby increasing the focus on long term value. Increased short-termism shifts the objective function of the maximization towards short-term value. Increased common ownership reduces incentives to compete. We are able to dierentiate the rst two from the third empirically; as common ownership diers from institutional ownership in the cross-section. However, we are unable to dierentiate between short-termism and governance. Improvements in governance reduce managerial entrenchment and require managers to continuously demonstrate strong performance, just as increased short-termism would. We simply test whether increases in (passive) institutional ownership lead to higher payouts and lower investment. We use largely the same dataset as Gutiérrez and Philippon [2016], which includes a mixture of rm- and industry-level data. These data are sourced (primarily) from Compustat, SEC (13f) lings, and the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). We aim to explain aggregate-level underinvestment, which requires clean identication as well as external validity. As a result, we start by discussing Crane et al. [2016], which exploits a discontinuity in institutional ownership around the Russell index thresholds to establish a causal relationship between ownership and payouts. Crane et al. [2016] provides clean identication, but applies only to a limited set of (smaller) rms close to 1 For instance, the decline in investment and associated decrease in competition is discussed in Furman [2015] and CEA [2016], among others. In particular, CEA [2016] argues that several indicators suggest that competition may be decreasing in many economic sectors, including the decades-long decline in new business formation and increases in industry-specic measures of concentration. The rise of buybacks and associated implications for investment have been discussed by senior executives of major asset management companies, as well as the media. For instance, in his March 2016 letter to the executives of S&P 500 rms, Laurence Fink (BlackRock CEO) states that in the wake of the nancial crisis, many companies have shied away from investing in the future growth of their companies. Too many companies have cut capital expenditure and even increased debt to boost dividends and increase share buybacks. See also As Activism Rises, U.S. Firms Spend More on Buybacks Than Factories, The Wall Street Journal, May 26, 2015; The repurchase revolution and Corporate cocaine, The Economist, September 13, 2014, among others. 2

3 the index threshold. To gain external validity, we then use pre-2000 quasi-indexer ownership as an instrumental variable for post-2000 buybacks and investment, controlling for rm fundamentals. We nd that higher (pre-2000) quasi-indexer ownership indeed leads to higher (post-2000) buybacks. This approach is supported by the very high persistence of quasi-indexer ownership, even after controlling for rm characteristics such as market capitalization, protability, Q, etc. Next, we study the interaction between competition, ownership and investment, which yields two conclusions. First, anti-competitive eects of common ownership disproportionately aect industries that `appear' competitive according to traditional measures (e.g., have low Herndahls) but actually are not (because of common ownership). In other words, common ownership has a limited eect on industries that are noncompetitive according to traditional measures; but a substantial eect on industries that appear competitive according to traditional measures but have large amounts of common ownership. Second, the impact of ownership on governance and short-termism is most material for rms in noncompetitive industries (consistent with Giroud and Mueller [2010, 2011], among others). The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 1 presents four recent trends in ownership and investment that drive our analysis. Section 2 discusses the mechanisms through which ownership may aect investment; as well as the interaction between ownership and competition. In doing so, we also review the relevant literature for the interaction of ownership, competition and investment. For a complete literature review, please refer to Gutiérrez and Philippon [2016]. Section 3 introduces a simple model of competition, with governance, short-termism and common ownership. We use this model to discuss and clarify the discussion in Section 2. Section 4 discusses the dataset used for empirical tests. Section 4.4 discusses the relevant identication strategies and test results to establish causality between ownership and investment. Section 5 discusses our results on the interaction between competition, ownership and investment. Section 6 concludes. 1 Four Facts about ownership and investment 1.1 Fact 1: Investment has Decreased Gutiérrez and Philippon [2016] provide ample evidence that investment is low relative to measures of protability and valuation, and that this weakness starts in the early 2000's. Gutiérrez and Philippon [2016] also use industry-level and rm-level data to test whether under-investment relative to Q is driven by (i) nancial frictions, (ii) measurement error (due to the rise of intangibles, globalization, etc), (iii) decreased competition (due to technology or regulation), or (iv) tightened governance and/or increased short-termism. They nd that proxies for competition and ownership explain the bulk of the investment gap, across industries and across rms. Controlling for current market conditions, industries with less entry and more concentration (traditional or due to common ownership) invest less. Within each industry-year, the investment gap is driven by rms owned by quasi-indexers and located in industries with more concentration/more common ownership. These 3

4 rms spend a disproportionate amount of free cash ows buying back their shares Fact 2: Institutional Ownership Has Increased Figure 1 shows the average share of institutional ownership across all US-incorporated rms in Compustat, by type. As shown, there has been a substantial increase in institutional ownership since 2000, primarily driven by growth in transient and quasi-indexer institutions. This is not shown in the gure, but the increase is particularly pronounced for smaller rms: since 2000, the dollar-weighted share of quasi-indexer institutional ownership increased from ~30% to ~45%, while the median share increased from ~15% to ~50%. That is, while the dollar-weighted quasi-indexer ownership increased by about 50%, it more than doubled for the median rm. Figure 1: Institutional ownership Average share of institutional ownership, by type year All institutions Dedicated Quasi Indexer Transient Notes: Annual data for all US incorporated rms in Compustat. Results are similar when including foreignincorporated rms. The vertical line in the rst graph highlights the passing of SEC rule 10b-18, which allows companies to repurchase their shares on the open market without regulatory limits. The increase in institutional ownership is linked to long term trends in stock ownership, as shown in Figure 2. The household share of ownership has declined drastically from more than 85% 2 Several papers study related issues. The decline in investment has been discussed in policy papers [Furman, 2015], especially in the context of a perceived decrease in competition in the goods market [CEA, 2016]; as well as academic papers (see, for example, Hall [2015]). Lee et al. [2016] nd that industries that receive more funds have a higher industry Q until the mid-1990s, but not since then. The change in the allocation of capital is explained by a decrease in capital expenditures and an increase in stock repurchases by rms in high Q industries since the mid-1990s. Alexander and Eberly [2016] study the implications of the rise of intangibles on investment. Last, Jones and Philippon [2016] explore the macro-economic consequences of decreased competition in a DSGE model with timevarying parameters and an occasionally binding zero lower bound. They show that the trend decrease in competition can explain the joint evolution of investment, Q, and the nominal interest rate. Absent the decrease in competition, they nd that the U.S. economy would have escaped the ZLB by the end of 2010 and that the nominal rate today would be close to 2%. Kose et al. [2017] study weak investment growth in emerging markets. 4

5 in 1960 to 35%. The decline was driven by private pension funds in the 1970s and 1980s; and the rise of mutual funds and ETFs since the 1990s. The latter part of the trend is due to the transition from dened-benet pension plans to dened contribution pension plans. Foreign ownership has also increased since Figure 2: Institutional ownership Notes: Annual data from Flow of Funds 1.3 Fact 3: Common Ownership has Increased If owners were fully disaggregated, institutional ownership would aect investment only through its impact on governance and short-termism. However, given the increased concentration in the asset management industry, common ownership of natural competitors by the same investors may introduce substantial anti-competitive eects. This is the subject of recent work linking common ownership to competition (see Section 2 for additional discussion of the literature). Figure 3 shows the mean Herndahl and Modied-Herndahl across all BEA industries in Compustat, where the Modied-Herndahl includes an adjustment to account for anti-competitive eects of common ownership. As shown, the mean Herndahl starts relatively high in the 1980s; decreases in the early 1990s as more rms go public and enter Compustat; and increases rapidly there after. The modied Herndahl increases even faster, from 25% to nearly 50%. The rise is primarily due to both the growth and concentration of institutional ownership. 5

6 Figure 3: Firm entry, exit and concentration Mean Herfindahl across industries (Compustat) Herfindahl year Mod Herfindahl Herfindahl Mod Herfindahl Note: Annual data from Compustat. 1.4 Fact 4: Payouts Have Increased Figure 4 shows the total buybacks and payouts for all US-incorporated rms in Compustat. As shown, there has been a substantial increase in total payouts, primarily driven by an increase in share buybacks. The increase starts soon after 1982, when SEC Rule 10b-18 was instituted (noted by the vertical line). Rule 10b-18 allows companies to repurchase their shares on the open market without regulatory limits. But it is most pronounced from approximately 2000 onward; where buybacks and payouts shift from 2-3% of assets to nearly 5% of assets. 6

7 Figure 4: Firm entry, exit and concentration Share Buybacks and Payouts year Payouts/Assets Buybacks/Assets Note: Annual data. 2 Ownership and Investment: Theoretical Background 2.1 Three mechanisms Ownership can aect management incentives in three main ways: (i) by aecting the investment horizon of managers (i.e., by inducing short-termism); (ii) by tightening governance, leading to less over-investment; and (iii) by inducing anti-competitive eects through common ownership. Short-termism. Regarding short-termism, some have argued that equity markets can put excessive emphasis on quarterly earnings, and that higher stock-based compensation incentivizes managers to focus on short term share prices rather than long term prots (see Martin [2015], Lazonick [2014], for example). Almeida et al. [2016] show that the probability of share repurchases is higher for rms that would have just missed the EPS forecast in the absence of a repurchase; and Jolls [1998] shows that rms which rely heavily on stock-option-based executive compensation are signicantly more likely to repurchase their stock. Given the rise of institutional ownership, an increase in market-induced short-termism may lead rms to increase buybacks and cut long term investment. 3 Governance. Regarding governance, a large literature following Jensen [1986] argues that conicts of interest between managers and shareholders can lead rms to invest in ways that do not maximize shareholder value. This does not necessarily imply that managers invest too much; they might invest in the wrong projects. The general view, however, is that managers are reluctant 3 In an unreported test, we used ExecuComp data to test whether rms with more stock-based executive compensation reduced investment more. We nd some, albeit limited support this hypothesis beyond our measures of competition and ownership. 7

8 to return cash to shareholders, and that they might over-invest. This view is supported byharford et al. [2008] and Richardson [2006], who nd evidence that poor governance associates with greater industry-adjusted investment. Thus, improvements in governance driven by changes in institutional ownership may lead to lower investment levels. Common ownership. As discussed above, the share and concentration of ownership has increased drastically since the 1960s. Institutions owned less than 10% of stocks in 1960, compared to nearly 65% today. And with the shift from dened benets to dened contribution plans, the asset management has become more concentrated. Azar [2012], Fichtner et al. [2016], Anton et al. [2016] discuss these trends in detail. Fichtner et al. [2016] show that the Big Three asset managers (BlackRock, Vanguard and State Street) together constitute the largest shareholder in 88 percent of the S&P500 rms, which account for 82% of market capitalization. This is the subject of a long theoretical literature in industrial organization, which argues that common ownership of natural competitors may reduce incentives to compete (see, for example, Salop and O'Brien [2000]). Azar [2012] shows that industries with higher levels of common ownership have higher markups on average. Azar et al. [2016b] and Azar et al. [2016a] use alternate identication strategies to show that this eect is empirically important for the U.S. Airline and the U.S. Banking industries. Azar et al. [2016b] shows that airline ticket prices increased as much as 10 percent because of common ownership of airlines; and Azar et al. [2016a] show that the increase in the concentration of bank ownership has led to higher fees and lower returns on savings. It is worth noting that the exact mechanisms through which common ownership reduces competition remain to be identied; but they need not be explicit directions from shareholders. They may result from lower incentives for owners to push rms to compete aggressively if they hold diversied positions in natural competitors; or from the ability of board members elected by and representing the largest shareholders to minimize breakdowns of cooperative arrangements and undesirable price wars between their commonly owned rms. See Salop and O'Brien [2000] and Azar et al. [2016b] for additional details. 2.2 Interaction with Activism The rise of institutional ownership, and associated implications for investment are intricately linked to the rise of activism. In fact, some have argued that activists ll a governance void created by the growth of `lazy' investors (i.e., index funds, exchange-traded funds and more broadly quasi indexers). 4 Brav et al. [2008] and Brav et al. [2010] 5 study hedge fund activism and nd that activist targets have signicantly higher institutional ownership. This is because activists typically hold minority stakes on their targets, hence they depend on the understanding and support of other shareholders to implement their desired changes. Figure 5 shows the number of activist events in the US from 1994 to Events were fairly 4 Capitalism's unlikely heroes, The Economist, Feb 7th, See also the updated results using a more recent sample [ ], but the same data collection procedure and estimation methods ( 8

9 low until the mid-2000s but rose extremely quickly thereafter. The pattern is strikingly similar to the rise of institutional ownership shown in Figure 1. Figure 5: Number of Activist Events in the US Source: JP Morgan (February 12, 2014) The implications of shareholder activism and institutional ownership on governance, shorttermism and payouts are studied in several papers. Regarding activism, Brav et al. [2008] and Brav et al. [2010] nd that target rms have lower capital expenditures pre-activism, and reduce them even further following the intervention. They also nd evidence for increased payouts in the year following the intervention, but this reverts back to normal levels two years after. Appel et al. [2016b] nd that larger ownership stakes of passive institutional investors make rms more susceptible to activists (increasing the ambitiousness of activist objectives as well as the rate of success). Regarding governance, Appel et al. [2016a] nd that passive owners inuence rms' governance choices (they lead to more independent directors, lower takeover defenses, and more equal voting rights; as well as more votes against management). And McCahery et al. [2016] survey institutional investors to better understand their role in corporate governance; and conclude that investors actively inuence governance choices. Related to quasi-indexers, they nd that long-term investors intervene more aggressively. 6 Crane et al. [2016] show that higher (total and quasi-indexer) institutional ownership causes rms to increase their payouts. In the end, it is unclear whether the higher payouts and the increased susceptibility to activist investors are evidence of tighter governance or increased short-termism. Some papers provide qualitative support for governance (e.g., Crane et al. [2016] refer to Chang et al. [2014] which argues that increasing passive institutional ownership leads to share price increases), but it is inconclusive. And other studies such as Asker et al. [2014] show that public rms invest substantially less and are less responsive to changes in investment opportunities than private rms. In the end, we are unable to dierentiate between these two hypotheses empirically. We simply test whether increases 6 It is worth highlighting that the evidence is not clear-cut: Schmidt and Fahlenbrach [2016] nd opposite eects for some governance measures (including the likelihood of CEO becoming chairman and appointment of new independent directors), and an increase in value-destructing M&A linked to institutional ownership. 9

10 in (passive) institutional ownership lead to higher payouts and lower investment. 2.3 Interaction between competition and ownership Since at least Adam Smith, economists have argued that managerial slack is primarily an issue for rms in non-competitive industries. Managers in such rms tend to enjoy the quiet life and therefore avoid generating excessive competition. By contrast, managers of rms in highly competitive industries are under constant pressure to improve eciency and are therefore less aected by managerial slack. They must constantly innovate to remain protable. Attempts to formalize the notion that competition mitigates managerial slack have proven dicult, but several recent papers have demonstrated it empirically (see, for example, Giroud and Mueller [2010, 2011]). The literature suggests that ownership, competition and investment can interact in two ways. On one hand, common ownership may aect industries dierently depending on their level of competition based on `traditional' measures. For instance, common ownership may materially reduce incentives to compete in industries that `appear' competitive according to traditional measures (e.g., have low Herndahls); yet have a limited eect on on industries that are already noncompetitive according to traditional measures. On the other hand, the impact of ownership on governance, short-termism and investment may be most material for rms in noncompetitive industries (as highlighted by Giroud and Mueller [2010, 2011], among others). We test these hypotheses in section 5. 3 A model of competition, governance, short-termism and ownership [TO BE ADDED] 4 Data We use the same dataset as in Gutiérrez and Philippon [2016]. The dataset includes a wide range of aggregate-, industry- and rm-level data. The data elds and data sources are summarized in Table 1. Sections 4.1 and 4.2 discuss the aggregate and industry datasets, respectively. Section 4.3 discusses the rm-level dataset, including key denitions. Firm- and industry-data are not readily comparable; they dier in their denitions of investment and capital, and in their coverage. As a result, we spent a fair amount of time simply reconciling the various data sources. We refer the reader to Gutiérrez and Philippon [2016] for details on the reconciliation and validation exercises. 10

11 Table 1: Data sources Primary datasets Additional datasets Data elds Source Granularity Aggregate investment and Q Flow of Funds US Industry-level investment and BEA ~NAICS L3 operating surplus Firm-level nancials Compustat Firm Institutional ownership Thomson Reuters 13F Firm Bushee's institutional investor Brian Bushee's website Institutional classication Investor 4.1 Aggregate data Aggregate data on funding costs, protability, investment and market value for the US Economy and the non nancial sector is gathered from the US Flow of Funds accounts through FRED. These data are used in the aggregate analyses discussed in Section 1; and to reconcile and ensure the accuracy of more granular data. 4.2 Industry data Industry-level investment and protability data including measures of private xed assets (currentcost and chained values for the net stock of capital, depreciation and investment) and value added (gross operating surplus, compensation and taxes) are gathered from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). Note that BEA I and K now include intangible assets (including software, R&D, and some intellectual property), not just tangible capital. Investment and protability data are available at the sector (19 groups) and detailed industry (63 groups) level, in a similar categorization as the 2007 NAICS Level 3. We start with the 63 detailed industries and group them into 47 industry groupings to ensure investment, entry and concentration measures are stable over time. In particular, we group detailed industries to ensure each group has at least ~10 rms, on average, from and it contributes a material share of investment (see Gutiérrez and Philippon [2016] for details on the investment dataset). We exclude Financials and Real Estate; and also exclude Utilities given the inuence of government actions in their investment and their unique experience after the crisis (e.g., they exhibit decreasing operating surplus since 2000). Last, we exclude Management because there are no companies in Compustat that map to this category. This leaves 43 industry groupings for our analyses. All other datasets are mapped into these 43 industry groupings using the NAICS Level 3 mapping provided by the BEA. We dene industry-level gross investment rates as the ratio of `Investment in Private Fixed Assets' to lagged `Current-Cost Net Stock of Private Fixed Assets'; depreciation rates as the ratio of `Current-Cost Depreciation of Private Fixed Assets' to lagged `Current-Cost Net Stock of Private Fixed Assets'; and net investment rates as the gross investment rate minus the depreciation rate. 11

12 Investment rates are computed across all asset types, as well as separating intellectual property from structures and equipment. 4.3 Firm-level data Dataset Firm-level data is primarily sourced from Compustat, which includes all public rms in the US. Data is available from 1950 through 2016, but coverage is fairly thin until the 1970s. We exclude rm-year observations with assets under $1 million; with negative book or market value; or with missing year, assets, Q, or book liabilities. 7 In order to more closely mirror the aggregate and industry gures, we exclude utilities (SIC codes 4900 through 4999), real estate (SIC codes 5300 through 5399) and nancial rms (SIC codes 6000 through 6999); and focus on US incorporated rms (see Section Gutiérrez and Philippon [2016] for more details on the sample selection). Firms are mapped to BEA industry segments using `Level 3' NAICS codes, as dened by the BEA. When NAICS codes are not available, rms are mapped to the most common NAICS category among those rms that share the same SIC code and have NAICS codes available. Firms with an `other' SIC code (SIC codes 9000 to 9999) are excluded from industry-level analyses because they cannot be mapped to an industry. Firm-level data is used for two purposes: rst, we aggregate rm-level data into industrylevel metrics and use the aggregated quantities to explain industry-level investment behavior. We consider the aggregate (i.e., weighted average), the mean and the median for all quantities, and use the specication that exhibits the highest statistical signicance. Second, we use rm-level data to analyze the determinants of rm-level investment through panel regressions. We compute a wide range of nancial measures, including investment, cash ow, operating surplus, etc. The main variables are discussed in the following section; with additional details on the sample selection, variable denitions and data quality tests available in Gutiérrez and Philippon [2016] Denitions Investment. We consider two main denitions of investment. First, the `traditional' gross investment rate is dened as in Rajan and Zingales [1998] specically, as capital expenditures (Compustat item CAPX) at time t scaled by net Property, Plant and Equipment (item PPENT) at time t 1. Net investment rate is calculated by imputing the industry-level depreciation rate from BEA gures. In particular, note that the depreciation gures available in Compustat include only the portion of depreciation that aects the income statement, and therefore exclude depreciation included in Cost of Goods Sold. For consistency, and because we are interested in aggregate quantities, we assume all rms in a given industry have the same depreciation rate, and compute the net investment rate as the gross investment rate minus the BEA-implied depreciation rate. We use 7 These exclusion rules are applied for all measures except rm age, which starts on the rst year in which the rm appears in Compustat irrespective of data coverage 12

13 the industry-level depreciation rate for structures and equipment only since it is applied to CAPX. Second, we proxy investment in intangibles with the ratio of R&D expenses to assets (Compustat XRD / AT) 8. We consider only the gross investment rate (i.e., do not subtract depreciation) since a good proxy for R&D depreciation is not available. Q. Firm-level Q is dened as the book value of total assets (AT) plus the market value of equity (ME) minus the book value of equity scaled by the book value of total assets (AT). The market value of equity (ME) is dened as the total number of common shares outstanding (item CSHO) times the closing stock price at the end of the scal year (item PRCC_F). Book value of equity is computed as AT - LT - PSTK. The resulting aggregate and mean Q from Compustat closely mirror the Flow of Funds Q. Buybacks. Last, we compute the ratio of share repurchases (item PRSTKC) to assets as a measure of buybacks. 9 Ownership. We gather data on institutional ownership from Thomson-Reuters' Institutional Holdings (13F) Database. This dataset includes investments in all US publicly traded stocks by institutional investors managing more than $100 million. We use these data to compute the MHHI (see below); as well as the share of institutional ownership; and the share of quasi indexer ownership. Quasi indexer ownership is computed following Brian Bushee's permanent classication of institutional investors, available on his website. Quasi indexers are institutional investors with diversied holdings and low portfolio turnover consistent with a passive, buy-and-hold strategy of investing portfolio funds in a broad set of rms. This category includes `pure' index investors as well as actively managed investors that hold diversied portfolios. It is therefore heavily inuenced by index position and participation (see, for example, Wurgler [2011] for more details). Quasi-indexers are the largest category, and account for ~60% of total institutional ownership. Appel et al. [2016a,b] and Crane et al. [2016] all use Bushee's classications when studying the implications of institutional ownership on governance and payouts. The classication is available from 1981 to Competition. Measures of competition typically aim to measure business dynamism (e.g., entry and exit), concentration (e.g., Herndahls) and/or market power (e.g., price-cost ratios). We consider versions of all such measures, 10 but use the `modied Herndahl' as our primary measure. The Modied Herndahl described in Salop and O'Brien [2000] and Azar et al. [2016b] is dened as 118 XRD set to zero if missing 9 We also considered total payouts to assets and found very similar results 10 In particular, we compute (i) the log-change in the number of rms in a given industry as a measure of entry and exit; (ii) the share of sales and market value held by the top 4, 8 and 20 rms in each industry; and (iii) the price-cost ratio (also known as the Lerner index). 11 According to the theory, it would better to compute MHHI = HHI + j k j sjs k i γ ij β ik i γ ij β ij, where γ ij denotes the control share of investor i in rm j. However, because data on the total number of voting shares per company is 13

14 MHHI = j s 2 j + j k j i s j s β ijβ ik k i β2 ij = HHI + HHI adj where s j and s k denote the share of sales for rms j, k in a given industry; and β ik denotes the ownership share of investor i in rm j.we refer to the rst term (HHI) as the `traditional' Herndahl; and to the second term (HHI adj ) as the `common ownership adjustment'. The second term follows a long theoretical literature in industrial organization that recognizes that common ownership of natural competitors by the same investors reduces incentives to compete (see, for example, Salop and O'Brien [2000]). Theoretical justication for the M HHI can be derived in a Cournot setting with common ownership. 12 See Salop and O'Brien [2000] and Azar et al. [2016b] for additional details. We focus on this measure because it exhibits robust correlations with investment, as discussed in Gutiérrez and Philippon [2016]. We consider the combined MHHI in most of our tests; but also separate HHI and HHI adj to assess their impact independently in some cases. We make two assumptions to compute this measure empirically: rst, because ownership data is only available for institutional investors, we compute β ik as the ownership share of investor i in rm j relative to total institutional ownership reported in the 13F database, not total ownership. This is not expected to substantially inuence the results because ownership by non-institutional investors is likely limited and restricted to a single rm, which does not induce common ownership links. Second, following Azar et al. [2016b], we restrict the data to holdings of at least 0.5% of shares outstanding. We use Compustat item SALE for measures of sales concentration and market value as dened in the computation of Q above for measures of market value concentration.we also compute age (from entrance into Compustat) and size (log of total assets) as rm-level controls. 4.4 Empirical tests and results Consider a rm with a given amount of free cash ow. It can either invest it, pay it out to shareholders (or continue to hold it as cash). 13 Thus, a rm that repurchases more shares, invests less almost by denition. We want to show that higher quasi indexer institutional ownership leads to higher buybacks and as a result lower investment. The results in Gutiérrez and Philippon [2016] establish a correlation between these eects i.e., that rms with higher quasi indexer ownership spend a disproportionate not readily available, we assume γ ij = β ik (i.e., we consider total ownership rather than voting and non-voting shares separately). 12 Azar et al. [2016b] and Azar et al. [2016a] use versions of the modied Herndahl and show that the eect of common ownership is empirically signicant for the U.S. Airline and the U.S. Banking industries as test-cases. 13 Formally, the nancing decit can be split into dividends, investment, changes in working capital and internal cash ow (see Frank and Goyal [2003]) 14

15 amount of free cash ows buying back their shares; and they also invest less. However, those results do not establish causality. The main problem with those regressions is that ownership, buybacks and investment all depend on current and expected nancial performance and investment opportunities. Investors even quasi indexers have some discretion on which rms to invest in. They may have requirements to track and/or benchmark against particular indices, but beyond that, their investment decisions are aimed at maximizing alpha (see, for example, Wurgler [2011]). Indeed, we can infer investor preferences by studying the characteristics of stocks with higher quasi indexer ownership. For instance, rms with lower leverage seem to have higher quasi indexer ownership, even after controlling for other rm- and industry- characteristics. Similarly, managers choose how much to invest and/or buyback depending on the nancial performance and investment opportunities of their rms (and, arguably, other private incentives that aect governance and short-termism, such as compensation). We therefore need to isolate the portion of buybacks that is driven by ownership, but is exogenous to nancial performance; and then study its implications for investment. We follow a two-pronged approach that relies on a mix of Natural Experiments and Instrumental Variables Natural Experiment: Russell Index threshold In particular, we start by discussing Crane et al. [2016], who exploit a discontinuity in institutional ownership around the Russell index thresholds to establish a causal relationship between ownership and payouts. In particular, note that Russell indices are re-constituted annually; and they result in dierential weights for rms around the 1000/2000 cuto (e.g., in 2005, the ten smallest rms in the Russell 1000 had a combined index weight of 0.004%, and the next ten largest rms were in the Russell 2000 with a combined index weight of 2.3%). These dierences in weights lead to sharp exogenous variation in institutional ownership; which can be used as an instrument for institutional ownership. 14 Crane et al. [2016] use a two-stage least-squares specication, where the rst stage models ownership as a function of index inclusion; and the second stage tests the eect of instrumented ownership on dividends, buybacks and payouts. They nd that more institutional ownership (and more quasi indexer ownership) indeed leads to higher payouts; and that this eect is economically important. Rather than replicate their analysis, we simply validate their conclusions for our sample. They report a coecient of 4.57 when regressing log-payouts on the percent of institutional ownership and 2.53 when regressing log-buybacks. 15 We run a simple OLS regression of log-payouts and logbuybacks on institutional ownership across all rms in our sample and obtain coecients of Indeed, this discontinuity has been exploited in a variety of papers such as Appel et al. [2016a,b] and Schmidt and Fahlenbrach [2016]. 15 Results for the ±100 rms around the threshold. They nd larger coecients (4.39 and 4.13, respectively) when considering ±750 rms around the threshold 15

16 and 3.68, respectively. These coecients are of the same magnitude; and indeed very close to those of Crane et al. [2016]. Considering only quasi-indexer ownership yields slightly larger coecients. The results in Crane et al. [2016] provide robust identication, but apply only to a small subset of rms/industries. Indeed they focus on the ±100 rms around the threshold; and provide results for ±750 rms cautioning that widening the bands can introduce bias. We therefore move to an instrumental variable approach that has weaker identication but applies to all rms Instrumental Variables: Lagged Ownership Empirical Strategy. To gain external validity, we use pre-2000 quasi-indexer ownership as an instrumental variable for post-2000 buybacks, controlling for industry, protability, Q and rm characteristics. The exclusion restriction is as follows. Exclusion restriction: Controlling for industry, protability, Q and rm characteristics, pre-2000 quasi-indexer ownership is uncorrelated with post-2000 expected growth and nancial performance This is supported by three facts: First, quasi indexer ownership is highly persistent. For instance, a regression of ownership at t on ownership ve years prior yields a coecient of 0.9, even after controlling for rm characteristics (including market value of equity). This suggests that quasi indexer investment decisions made before 2000 are likely to persist and inuence buybacks post- 2000; but are not heavily inuenced by changes in expected growth and nancial performance. This is particularly critical because of the second fact: the dot-com bubble crash substantially impacted expected growth and nancial performance. Investors made pre-2000 decisions at the height of the bubble, under optimistic growth prospects. Those growth prospects changed with the burst of the bubble, yet ownership remained generally stable. Last, one of primary mechanisms through which ownership aects buybacks is activism. Yet as Figure 5 shows, activism increased substantially only after Pre-2000 investment decisions could not have foreseen (or timed) the rise of Activism in the mid-2000s. Together, these facts suggest that pre-2000 quasi indexer ownership is indeed uncorrelated with post-2000 expected growth and nancial performance. It can therefore be used as an instrument for post-2000 buybacks, which in turn aects investment. Results. 16 Table2 shows our regression results. All regressions are based on the post-2000 period. The rst two columns instrument buybacks with pre-2000 quasi indexer ownership; and Q with the industry median stock Q to mitigate some of the measurement error. Column 3 then uses the portion of buybacks that is explained by ownership to predict investment. All regressions include industry and year xed eects; as well as a wide range of controls including measures of pre-2000 size, market capitalization, protability, cash ow, dividend payments, sales growth and leverage, 16 The limited time-period in our regression introduces a limitation to our results as they pertain to a particular period of time, over which investor preferences for buybacks may have been particularly high. 16

17 among others. As shown, higher pre-2000 quasi indexer ownership causes higher buybacks, which in turn cause lower investment. Note that we use the ratio of buybacks to assets as the dependent variable, instead of log-buybacks as used by Crane et al. [2016]. This explains the substantially lower coecient. The next regression (columns 4-6) adds the interaction between pre-2000 quasi indexer ownership and average buybacks across all rms in our sample. It shows that rms with higher quasi indexer ownership are more sensitive to aggregate trends in the level of buybacks. And given that the level of buybacks has increased drastically since 2000 (see Figure 1), this implies they increased their share buybacks even more. The last regression (columns 7-9) adds rm-level xed eects, but omits all pre-2000 controls because they would be absorbed into the xed eect. We do keep log-age as a control, and the interaction between quasi indexer ownership and aggregate buybacks. As shown, even including rm-level xed eects, rms with higher quasi indexer ownership exhibit higher sensitivity to aggregate buyback trends. Figure 6 supports these results: it shows the mean buyback rates across all rms, by quasi indexer ownership tercile (assigned within each industry and year). As shown, rms with higher ownership payout more; and exhibit far more sensitivity to aggregate trends. Figure 6: Buyback rate by quasi indexer ownership Mean Buyback/Assets year Low QIX High QIX Med QIX Notes: Annual data for all US incorporated rms in Compustat. Firm nancials from Compustat; ownership from Thomson Reuters and Brian Bushee's website. Figure 7 shows rst stage for the last regression graphically (columns 7-9). In particular, it plots the residual from regressing Buybacks/Assets on industry medianq, log-age, rm and year xed eects (as in the last regression), against the residual from regressing the interaction term QIX 96 99(i) BBA(t) on all other variables included in the columns 7-9. As shown, the slope is strongly positive and is not heavily inuenced by outliers. More quasi-indexer ownership increases the sensitivity of rms to aggregate trends in buybacks. 17

18 Table 2: Ownership IV: Regression results Table shows the results of rm-level 2SLS regressions of industry-level investment. Q instrumented by median industry Q; and buybacks instrumented by pre-2000 quasi indexer ownership. Firm-level controls include market capitalization, leverage, sales growth, dividends, protability, size...). Data sourced from Compustat. T-stats in brackets. + p<0.10, * p<0.05, ** p<.01. 1st Stage 2nd 1st Stage 2nd 1st Stage 2nd (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Stock Q Buyb/Ass Net I/K Stock Q Buyb/Ass Net I/K Stock Q Buyb/Ass Net I/K Industry Median Q (t-1) 0.650** ** ** [21.46] [-0.56] [21.22] [-0.7] [25.47] [-0.33] % QIX owners(96-99) 0.279** 0.013** 0.771** ** [3.03] [4.32] [4.97] [-8.26] QIX96 99(i) BBA(t) ** 4.140** * 3.969** [-3.7] [13.05] [-2.36] [14.85] Stock Q (t-1) 0.048** 0.046** 0.046** [2.99] [3.15] [2.86] Buyback/Assets (t-1) * ** ** [-1.98] [-3.16] [-6.08] Pre-2000 rm-level controls Yes Yes No Year FE Yes Yes Yes Industry FE Yes Yes No Firm FE No No Yes Observations Between/OverallR % / 4.6% 28.4 / 10.0% 8.1% / 4.0% Only log-age is included as control. 18

19 Figure 7: IV rst stage regression results Notes: Figure shows rst stage for the last regression graphically (columns 7-9). Annual data for all US incorporated rms in Compustat. Firm nancials from Compustat; ownership from Thomson Reuters and Brian Bushee's website. See text for additional details. The above industry- and rm-level regression results show that higher quasi indexer ownership causes higher buybacks and lower investment. And Gutiérrez and Philippon [2017] shows that higher concentration also causes lower industry- and rm-level investment. These analyses consider each hypothesis independently, and therefore do not account for the interaction between ownership, competition and investment (beyond the inclusion of anti-competitive eects of common ownership in the modied Herndahl). This is the subject of the next section. 5 Interaction between competition and ownership As discussed above, the literature suggests that ownership, competition and investment can interact in two ways. First, common ownership may aect industries dierently depending on their level of competition based on `traditional' measures. Second, the impact of ownership on governance, shorttermism and investment may be most material for rms in noncompetitive industries (as highlighted by Giroud and Mueller [2010, 2011], among others). 5.1 Test results We start by testing the rst hypothesis at the industry-level. In particular, we regress industrylevel investment on the two components of the modied Herndahl the traditional Herndahl and the common ownership-adjustment as well as their interaction. The traditional Herndahl measures the `traditional' level of competition in an industry, while the common ownership-adjustment measures the anti-competitive eects of common ownership. Results are shown in Table 3. Column 1 is based on OLS, while columns 2-7 instrument for the 19

20 Herndahl using excess entry as dened in Gutiérrez and Philippon [2017]. The interaction term is not instrumented instead, we report reduced form results considering the Herndahl, excess entry and China import exposure as measures of competition for the interactions (columns 2, 3 and 4, respectively). As shown, the interaction coecient is nearly signicant in the rst test and signicant in the next two. Columns 5 to 7 instrument for common ownership using the common ownership adjustment as of Again, coecients are signicant and exhibit the right sign. To gain intuition about this result, consider the eect of substantial common ownership (75th percentile) on a competitive (25th percentile) and non-competitive (75th percentile) industry, as measured by the traditional Herndahl. The 25th and 75th percentile of the traditional Herndahl are 0.07 and 0.2, respectively; while the 75th percentile of the common ownership adjustment is The interaction term for the competitive industry is therefore 0.02, while for the non-competitive industry it is Applying the coecients in the rst IV regression (column 2), traditional competition implies a reduction in net investment of 1.4% for the competitive industry and 3.8% for the non-competitive industry; and the common ownership adjustment implies an additional 4.08% reduction for both industries. The interaction term reduces the impact of common ownership by only 1.2% in the competitive industry but by 3.2% in the non-competitive one. That is, the reductions amount to roughly 30% and 80% of the impact of common ownership, respectively. Thus, common ownership has a dampened eect on industries that are non-competitive to begin with; but a substantial eect on industries that appear competitive according to traditional measures but have large amounts of common ownership. Let's move on to the second hypothesis: that ownership (and therefore governance and shorttermism) aect investment primarily in noncompetitive industries. We test this at the rm-level, by adding interactions between the Herndahl and pre-2000 ownership to the rm-level regressions reported in Table 2 above. We use the point-in-time Herndahl rather than an IV because we are mainly interested in the eect of ownership on buybacks for a given level of competition irrespective of how that level of competition aroused. Table 4 shows the results. As shown, the interaction term is positive and signicant in column 2 suggesting that quasi indexer ownership disproportionately aects rms in non-competitive industries. The next regression (columns 4-6) adds the interaction between pre-2000 quasi indexer ownership and average buybacks across all rms in our sample. It adds rm-level xed eects, but omits all pre-2000 variables because they would be absorbed into the xed eect. It shows that rms with higher quasi indexer ownership are more sensitive to aggregate trends in the level of buybacks. And given that the level of buybacks has increased drastically since 2000 (see Figure 1), this implies they increased their share buybacks by more. This is true even controlling for time invariant rm-level characteristics through xed eects. We conclude that ownership has an outsized eect on investment for rms in non-competitive industries. OLS results (not reported) are consistent with those using IVs. 20

Ownership, Concentration and Investment

Ownership, Concentration and Investment Ownership, Concentration and Investment Germán Gutiérrez and Thomas Philippon January 2018 Abstract The US business sector has under-invested relative to profits, funding costs, and Tobin s Q since the

More information

Investmentless Growth: An Empirical Investigation

Investmentless Growth: An Empirical Investigation BPEA Conference Drafts, September 7 8, 2017 Investmentless Growth: An Empirical Investigation Germán Gutiérrez, New York University Thomas Philippon, New York University Conflict of Interest Disclosure:

More information

Investment-less Growth: An Empirical Investigation

Investment-less Growth: An Empirical Investigation Investment-less Growth: An Empirical Investigation Germán Gutiérrez and Thomas Philippon November 2016 Abstract We analyze private fixed investment in the U.S. over the past 30years. Weshowthatinvestment

More information

Why Have Debt Ratios Increased for Firms in Emerging Markets?

Why Have Debt Ratios Increased for Firms in Emerging Markets? Why Have Debt Ratios Increased for Firms in Emerging Markets? Todd Mitton Brigham Young University March 1, 2006 Abstract I study trends in capital structure between 1980 and 2004 in a sample of over 11,000

More information

Investment-less Growth: An Empirical Investigation

Investment-less Growth: An Empirical Investigation Investment-less Growth: An Empirical Investigation Germán Gutiérrez and Thomas Philippon October 2017 Abstract We analyze private fixed investment in the U.S. over the past 30years. Weshowthatinvestment

More information

Aggregate Demand in Keynesian Analysis

Aggregate Demand in Keynesian Analysis OpenStax-CNX module: m48750 1 Aggregate Demand in Keynesian Analysis OpenStax College This work is produced by OpenStax-CNX and licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution License 4.0 By the end of

More information

University of Mannheim

University of Mannheim Threshold Events and Identication: A Study of Cash Shortfalls Bakke and Whited, published in the Journal of Finance in June 2012 Introduction The paper combines three objectives 1 Provide general guidelines

More information

Appendix for Investment-less Growth: An Empirical Investigation

Appendix for Investment-less Growth: An Empirical Investigation Appendix for Investment-less Growth: An Empirical Investigation Germán Gutiérrez and Thomas Philippon March 2018 A Data Appendix This Appendix presents additional details, definitions and discussion related

More information

Research Philosophy. David R. Agrawal University of Michigan. 1 Themes

Research Philosophy. David R. Agrawal University of Michigan. 1 Themes David R. Agrawal University of Michigan Research Philosophy My research agenda focuses on the nature and consequences of tax competition and on the analysis of spatial relationships in public nance. My

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

Investor Valuation of the Abandonment Option. Itzhak Swary. Tel Aviv University. Faculty of Management. Ramat Aviv, Israel (972)

Investor Valuation of the Abandonment Option. Itzhak Swary. Tel Aviv University. Faculty of Management. Ramat Aviv, Israel (972) Investor Valuation of the Abandonment Option Philip G. Berger 1 Wharton School University of Pennsylvania 2433 SH-DH Philadelphia, PA 19104-6365 (215) 898-7125 Eli Ofek Stern School of Business New York

More information

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Miguel Antón, Florian Ederer, Mireia Giné, and Martin Schmalz August 13, 2016 Abstract This internet appendix provides

More information

Non-interest Income and Systemic risk: The Role of Concentration

Non-interest Income and Systemic risk: The Role of Concentration Non-interest Income and Systemic risk: The Role of Concentration Fariborz Moshirian, Sidharth Sahgal, Bohui Zhang University of New South Wales Nov 17,2011 Motivation After the nancial crisis, the diversication

More information

The Distributions of Income and Consumption. Risk: Evidence from Norwegian Registry Data

The Distributions of Income and Consumption. Risk: Evidence from Norwegian Registry Data The Distributions of Income and Consumption Risk: Evidence from Norwegian Registry Data Elin Halvorsen Hans A. Holter Serdar Ozkan Kjetil Storesletten February 15, 217 Preliminary Extended Abstract Version

More information

Subjective Cash Flows and Discount Rates

Subjective Cash Flows and Discount Rates Subjective Cash Flows and Discount Rates Ricardo De la O Stanford University Sean Myers Stanford University December 4, 2017 Abstract What drives stock prices? Using survey forecasts for dividend growth

More information

Global Imbalances and Bank Risk-Taking

Global Imbalances and Bank Risk-Taking Global Imbalances and Bank Risk-Taking Valeriya Dinger & Daniel Marcel te Kaat University of Osnabrück, Institute of Empirical Economic Research - Macroeconomics Conference on Macro-Financial Linkages

More information

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings Abstract This paper empirically investigates the value shareholders place on excess cash

More information

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva* The Role of Credit Ratings in the Dynamic Tradeoff Model Viktoriya Staneva* This study examines what costs and benefits of debt are most important to the determination of the optimal capital structure.

More information

INTANGIBLE CAPITAL: IMPLICATIONS FOR INVESTMENT AND MARKET STRUCTURE. Janice Eberly 1,2

INTANGIBLE CAPITAL: IMPLICATIONS FOR INVESTMENT AND MARKET STRUCTURE. Janice Eberly 1,2 INTANGIBLE CAPITAL: IMPLICATIONS FOR INVESTMENT AND MARKET STRUCTURE Janice Eberly 1,2 1 Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University and NBER 2 Based on research with Nicolas Crouzet, Kellogg

More information

Understanding Weak Capital Investment: the Role of Market Concentration and Intangibles Nicolas Crouzet and Janice Eberly

Understanding Weak Capital Investment: the Role of Market Concentration and Intangibles Nicolas Crouzet and Janice Eberly Understanding Weak Capital Investment: the Role of Market Concentration and Intangibles Nicolas Crouzet and Janice Eberly Questions Findings 1. Why is capital investment low? - 5percentagepointsbelowpre-2

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

Does Risk Management Aect Firm Value? Evidence from a Natural Experiment

Does Risk Management Aect Firm Value? Evidence from a Natural Experiment Does Risk Management Aect Firm Value? Evidence from a Natural Experiment Erik P. Gilje Jérôme P. Taillard February 12, 2014 Abstract We study how hedging aects rm value and real investment activity. We

More information

The determinants and implications of corporate cash holdings

The determinants and implications of corporate cash holdings Journal of Financial Economics 52 (1999) 3}46 The determinants and implications of corporate cash holdings Tim Opler, Lee Pinkowitz, ReneH Stulz *, Rohan Williamson Fisher College of Business, The Ohio

More information

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 17 Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 Luísa Farinha Pedro Prego 2 Abstract The analysis of liquidity management decisions by firms has recently been used as a tool to investigate the

More information

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix Conrad Miller Contents A Extensions and Robustness Checks 2 A. Heterogeneity by Employer Size.............................. 2 A.2

More information

Online Appendix. A.1 Map and gures. Figure 4: War deaths in colonial Punjab

Online Appendix. A.1 Map and gures. Figure 4: War deaths in colonial Punjab Online Appendix A.1 Map and gures Figure 4: War deaths in colonial Punjab 1 Figure 5: Casualty rates per battlefront Figure 6: Casualty rates per casualty prole Figure 7: Higher ranks versus soldier ranks

More information

Inside Debt and Bank Performance During the. Financial Crisis. This Version: March 3, 2012

Inside Debt and Bank Performance During the. Financial Crisis. This Version: March 3, 2012 Inside Debt and Bank Performance During the Financial Crisis This Version: March 3, 2012 Abstract This paper examines how inside debt holdings inuence bank performance during the recent nancial crisis.

More information

Top Marginal Tax Rates and Within-Firm Income Inequality

Top Marginal Tax Rates and Within-Firm Income Inequality . Top Marginal Tax Rates and Within-Firm Income Inequality Extended abstract. Not for quotation. Comments welcome. Max Risch University of Michigan May 12, 2017 Extended Abstract Behavioral responses to

More information

China's Saving and Investment Puzzle

China's Saving and Investment Puzzle China's Saving Puzzle China's Saving and Investment Puzzle Kaiji Chen University of Oslo March 13, 2007 1 China's Saving Puzzle Why should we care about China's saving and investment? Help to understand

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.

Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C. Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C. The Effect of Common Ownership on Profits: Evidence From the U.S.

More information

Heterogeneous Institutional Investors and Earnings Smoothing

Heterogeneous Institutional Investors and Earnings Smoothing Heterogeneous Institutional Investors and Earnings Smoothing Yudan Zheng Long Island University This paper examines the relationship between institutional ownership and earnings smoothing by taking into

More information

Do Corporate Taxes Hinder Innovation? Internet Appendix

Do Corporate Taxes Hinder Innovation? Internet Appendix Do Corporate Taxes Hinder Innovation? Internet Appendix 1 A.1 Empirical Tests Supporting Main Results 1. Cross Country Analysis In this section we report cross country results. We collected data on international

More information

Applied Economics. Quasi-experiments: Instrumental Variables and Regresion Discontinuity. Department of Economics Universidad Carlos III de Madrid

Applied Economics. Quasi-experiments: Instrumental Variables and Regresion Discontinuity. Department of Economics Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Applied Economics Quasi-experiments: Instrumental Variables and Regresion Discontinuity Department of Economics Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Policy evaluation with quasi-experiments In a quasi-experiment

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion. Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b

Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion. Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b a Department of Finance, Spears School of Business, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, OK

More information

Taxes and Growth in a Financially underdeveloped country: Evidence from the Chilean Investment Boom, by Hsieh and Parker

Taxes and Growth in a Financially underdeveloped country: Evidence from the Chilean Investment Boom, by Hsieh and Parker Taxes and Growth in a Financially underdeveloped country: Evidence from the Chilean Investment Boom, by Hsieh and Parker Comments by Claudio Raddatz 24th August 2007 In 1982, Chile experienced its largest

More information

Discussion of: Banks Incentives and Quality of Internal Risk Models

Discussion of: Banks Incentives and Quality of Internal Risk Models Discussion of: Banks Incentives and Quality of Internal Risk Models by Matthew C. Plosser and Joao A. C. Santos Philipp Schnabl 1 1 NYU Stern, NBER and CEPR Chicago University October 2, 2015 Motivation

More information

Does Leverage Affect Company Growth in the Baltic Countries?

Does Leverage Affect Company Growth in the Baltic Countries? 2011 International Conference on Information and Finance IPEDR vol.21 (2011) (2011) IACSIT Press, Singapore Does Leverage Affect Company Growth in the Baltic Countries? Mari Avarmaa + Tallinn University

More information

A Tough Act to Follow: Contrast Effects in Financial Markets. Samuel Hartzmark University of Chicago. May 20, 2016

A Tough Act to Follow: Contrast Effects in Financial Markets. Samuel Hartzmark University of Chicago. May 20, 2016 A Tough Act to Follow: Contrast Effects in Financial Markets Samuel Hartzmark University of Chicago May 20, 2016 Contrast eects Contrast eects: Value of previously-observed signal inversely biases perception

More information

Intangibles, Investment, and Efficiency

Intangibles, Investment, and Efficiency Intangibles, Investment, and Efficiency By Nicolas Crouzet and Janice Eberly The severity of the global financial crisis tended to obscure lower frequency macroeconomic trends over the last several decades.

More information

Investment and the weighted average cost of capital: new micro evidence for France

Investment and the weighted average cost of capital: new micro evidence for France Investment and the weighted average cost of capital: new micro evidence for France J. Carluccio 1 C. Mazet-Sonilhac 1 J.S. Mésonnier 1 1 Banque de France Very Preliminary. Please do not circulate. This

More information

Internet Appendix for Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation? 1. Additional robustness checks

Internet Appendix for Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation? 1. Additional robustness checks Internet Appendix for Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation? This internet appendix provides robustness tests and supplemental analyses to the main results presented in Does Banking Competition Affect

More information

The cash-#ow permanence and information content of dividend increases versus repurchases

The cash-#ow permanence and information content of dividend increases versus repurchases Journal of Financial Economics 57 (2000) 385}415 The cash-#ow permanence and information content of dividend increases versus repurchases Wayne Guay, Jarrad Harford * The Wharton School, University of

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

Credit Smoothing. Sean Hundtofte and Michaela Pagel. February 10, Abstract

Credit Smoothing. Sean Hundtofte and Michaela Pagel. February 10, Abstract Credit Smoothing Sean Hundtofte and Michaela Pagel February 10, 2018 Abstract Economists believe that high-interest, unsecured, short-term borrowing, for instance via credit cards, helps individuals to

More information

When risk and return are not enough: the role of loss aversion in private investors' choice of mutual fund fee structures

When risk and return are not enough: the role of loss aversion in private investors' choice of mutual fund fee structures When risk and return are not enough: the role of loss aversion in private investors' choice of mutual fund fee structures Christian Ehm Martin Weber April 17, 2013 Abstract We analyze why investors chose

More information

Financing Lumpy Adjustment *

Financing Lumpy Adjustment * Financing Lumpy Adjustment * Christoph Görtz University of Birmingham Plutarchos Sakellaris Athens University of Economics and Business This draft: April 2017 John D. Tsoukalas University of Glasgow Abstract

More information

Investment Platforms Market Study Interim Report: Annex 7 Fund Discounts and Promotions

Investment Platforms Market Study Interim Report: Annex 7 Fund Discounts and Promotions MS17/1.2: Annex 7 Market Study Investment Platforms Market Study Interim Report: Annex 7 Fund Discounts and Promotions July 2018 Annex 7: Introduction 1. There are several ways in which investment platforms

More information

Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation

Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation University of Massachusetts Boston From the SelectedWorks of Atreya Chakraborty January 1, 2010 Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation

More information

Multiple blockholders and rm valuation: Evidence from the Czech Republic

Multiple blockholders and rm valuation: Evidence from the Czech Republic Multiple blockholders and rm valuation: Evidence from the Czech Republic Ondrej Nezdara December 3, 2007 Abstract Using data for the Prague Stock Exchange in 996 to 2005, I investigate how presence and

More information

2018 Municipal Finance Conference: Public Pensions, Political Economy and State Government Borrowing Costs

2018 Municipal Finance Conference: Public Pensions, Political Economy and State Government Borrowing Costs 2018 Municipal Finance Conference: Public Pensions, Political Economy and State Government Borrowing Costs Chuck Boyer University of Chicago July 17, 2018 Motivation Over $1.1 trillion in U.S. state bonded

More information

Depreciation shocks and the bank lending activities in the EU countries

Depreciation shocks and the bank lending activities in the EU countries Depreciation shocks and the bank lending activities in the EU countries Svatopluk Kapounek and Jarko Fidrmuc Mendel University in Brno, Czech Republic Zeppelin University in Friedrichshafen, Germany Slovak

More information

Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity *

Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity * Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity * Index Section 1: High bargaining power of the small firm Page 1 Section 2: Analysis of Multiple Small Firms and 1 Large

More information

Swinging for the Fences: Executive Reactions to Quasi-Random Option Grants

Swinging for the Fences: Executive Reactions to Quasi-Random Option Grants Swinging for the Fences: Executive Reactions to Quasi-Random Option Grants February 3, 2013 Abstract In the wake of the nancial crisis, there has been renewed interest in the relationship between compensation

More information

The Tax Gradient. Do Local Sales Taxes Reduce Tax Dierentials at State Borders? David R. Agrawal. University of Georgia: January 24, 2012

The Tax Gradient. Do Local Sales Taxes Reduce Tax Dierentials at State Borders? David R. Agrawal. University of Georgia: January 24, 2012 The Tax Gradient Do Local Sales Taxes Reduce Tax Dierentials at State Borders? David R. Agrawal University of Michigan University of Georgia: January 24, 2012 Introduction Most tax systems are decentralized

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

If the market is perfect, hedging would have no value. Actually, in real world,

If the market is perfect, hedging would have no value. Actually, in real world, 2. Literature Review If the market is perfect, hedging would have no value. Actually, in real world, the financial market is imperfect and hedging can directly affect the cash flow of the firm. So far,

More information

The Impact of Shareholder Taxation on Merger and Acquisition Behavior

The Impact of Shareholder Taxation on Merger and Acquisition Behavior The Impact of Shareholder Taxation on Merger and Acquisition Behavior Eric Ohrn, Grinnell College Nathan Seegert, University of Utah Grinnell College Department of Economics Seminar November 8, 2016 Introduction

More information

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Jian Liu ** University of Exeter This draft: August 2016 Abstract We examine

More information

Can the Market Multiply and Divide? Non-Proportional Thinking in Financial Markets. Legacy Events Room CBA Thursday, May 3, :00 am

Can the Market Multiply and Divide? Non-Proportional Thinking in Financial Markets. Legacy Events Room CBA Thursday, May 3, :00 am Legacy Events Room CBA 3.202 Thursday, May 3, 2018 11:00 am Can the Market Multiply and Divide? Non-Proportional Thinking in Financial Markets Kelly Shue and Richard R. Townsend April 10, 2018 Abstract

More information

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK Scott J. Wallsten * Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research 579 Serra Mall at Galvez St. Stanford, CA 94305 650-724-4371 wallsten@stanford.edu

More information

Investment and the weighted average cost of capital: new firm-level evidence for France

Investment and the weighted average cost of capital: new firm-level evidence for France Investment and the weighted average cost of capital: new firm-level evidence for France J. Carluccio 1 C. Mazet-Sonilhac 1,2 J.S. Mésonnier 1 1 Banque de France 2 Sciences Po Paris Work in progress. This

More information

Can book-to-market, size and momentum be risk factors that predict economic growth?

Can book-to-market, size and momentum be risk factors that predict economic growth? Journal of Financial Economics 57 (2000) 221}245 Can book-to-market, size and momentum be risk factors that predict economic growth? Jimmy Liew, Maria Vassalou * Morgan Stanley Dean Witter, 1585 Broadway,

More information

Monetary Policy and Economic Outcomes *

Monetary Policy and Economic Outcomes * OpenStax-CNX module: m48773 1 Monetary Policy and Economic Outcomes * OpenStax This work is produced by OpenStax-CNX and licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution License 4.0 By the end of this section,

More information

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect?

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? Yi Jiang Department of Finance, California State University, Fullerton SGMH 5160, Fullerton, CA 92831 (657)278-4363 yjiang@fullerton.edu Yiming Qian

More information

Consumption Tax Incidence: Evidence from the Natural Experiment in the Czech Republic

Consumption Tax Incidence: Evidence from the Natural Experiment in the Czech Republic Consumption Tax Incidence: Evidence from the Natural Experiment in the Czech Republic Jan Zapal z j.zapal@lse.ac.uk rst draft: October, 2007 this draft: October, 2007 PhD program, London School of Economics

More information

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits Day Manoli UCLA Andrea Weber University of Mannheim February 29, 2012 Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

The Impact of the National Bank of Hungary's Funding for Growth Program on Firm Level Investment

The Impact of the National Bank of Hungary's Funding for Growth Program on Firm Level Investment The Impact of the National Bank of Hungary's Funding for Growth Program on Firm Level Investment Marianna Endrész, MNB Péter Harasztosi, JRC Robert P. Lieli, CEU April, 2017 The views expressed in this

More information

Regression Discontinuity and. the Price Effects of Stock Market Indexing

Regression Discontinuity and. the Price Effects of Stock Market Indexing Regression Discontinuity and the Price Effects of Stock Market Indexing Internet Appendix Yen-Cheng Chang Harrison Hong Inessa Liskovich In this Appendix we show results which were left out of the paper

More information

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg William Paterson University, Deptartment of Economics, USA. KEYWORDS Capital structure, tax rates, cost of capital. ABSTRACT The main purpose

More information

On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty

On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty Christopher F Baum Department of Economics, Boston College and DIW Berlin Mustafa Caglayan Department of Economics, University of Sheffield Oleksandr

More information

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation ECONOMIC BULLETIN 3/218 ANALYTICAL ARTICLES Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation Ángel Estrada and Francesca Viani 6 September 218 Following

More information

Skewed Business Cycles

Skewed Business Cycles Skewed Business Cycles Sergio Salgado Fatih Guvenen Nicholas Bloom June 19, 2015 Preliminary and Incomplete. Comments Welcome. Abstract Using a panel of Compustat rms from 1962 to 2013, we study how the

More information

Cash Flow Sensitivity of Investment: Firm-Level Analysis

Cash Flow Sensitivity of Investment: Firm-Level Analysis Cash Flow Sensitivity of Investment: Firm-Level Analysis Armen Hovakimian Baruch College and Gayane Hovakimian * Fordham University May 12, 2005 ABSTRACT Using firm level estimates of investment-cash flow

More information

Essays on the Repatriation Policies of Multinational Firms. Anne Barrett Moore. A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the

Essays on the Repatriation Policies of Multinational Firms. Anne Barrett Moore. A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the Essays on the Repatriation Policies of Multinational Firms By Anne Barrett Moore A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Economics

More information

J. Account. Public Policy

J. Account. Public Policy J. Account. Public Policy 28 (2009) 16 32 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect J. Account. Public Policy journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jaccpubpol The value relevance of R&D across profit

More information

Understanding Weak Capital Investment: the Role of Market Concentration and Intangibles

Understanding Weak Capital Investment: the Role of Market Concentration and Intangibles Understanding Weak Capital Investment: the Role of Market Concentration and Intangibles Nicolas Crouzet and Janice Eberly Prepared for the Jackson Hole Economic Policy Symposium Federal Reserve Bank of

More information

Acquiring Intangible Assets

Acquiring Intangible Assets Acquiring Intangible Assets Intangible assets are important for corporations and their owners. The book value of intangible assets as a percentage of total assets for all COMPUSTAT firms grew from 6% in

More information

Does Macro-Pru Leak? Empirical Evidence from a UK Natural Experiment

Does Macro-Pru Leak? Empirical Evidence from a UK Natural Experiment 12TH JACQUES POLAK ANNUAL RESEARCH CONFERENCE NOVEMBER 10 11, 2011 Does Macro-Pru Leak? Empirical Evidence from a UK Natural Experiment Shekhar Aiyar International Monetary Fund Charles W. Calomiris Columbia

More information

Time Variation in Asset Return Correlations: Econometric Game solutions submitted by Oxford University

Time Variation in Asset Return Correlations: Econometric Game solutions submitted by Oxford University Time Variation in Asset Return Correlations: Econometric Game solutions submitted by Oxford University June 21, 2006 Abstract Oxford University was invited to participate in the Econometric Game organised

More information

Generalized Herfindahl-Hirschman Index to Estimate Diversity Score of a Portfolio across Multiple Correlated Sectors

Generalized Herfindahl-Hirschman Index to Estimate Diversity Score of a Portfolio across Multiple Correlated Sectors IFMR FINANCE FOUNDATION Generalized Herfindahl-Hirschman Index to Estimate Diversity Score of a Portfolio across Multiple Correlated Sectors Vaibhav Anand 12 Ramasubramanian S V Abstract Portfolio diversification

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1 Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1 Philippe Bacchetta Study Center Gerzensee University of Lausanne Swiss Finance Institute & CEPR Eric van Wincoop University of Virginia NBER January

More information

Institutional Investor Cliques and Governance: Internet Appendix

Institutional Investor Cliques and Governance: Internet Appendix Institutional Investor Cliques and Governance: Internet Appendix Alan D. Crane Jones Graduate School of Business Rice University Andrew Koch Katz Graduate School of Business University of Pittsburgh Sébastien

More information

Adverse Selection on Maturity: Evidence from On-Line Consumer Credit

Adverse Selection on Maturity: Evidence from On-Line Consumer Credit Adverse Selection on Maturity: Evidence from On-Line Consumer Credit Andrew Hertzberg (Columbia) with Andrés Liberman (NYU) and Daniel Paravisini (LSE) Credit and Payments Markets Oct 2 2015 The role of

More information

Model and Numerical Solutions. This appendix provides further detail about our model and numerical solutions as well as additional empirical results.

Model and Numerical Solutions. This appendix provides further detail about our model and numerical solutions as well as additional empirical results. Online Appendix for Trade Liberalization and Embedded Institutional Reform: Evidence from Chinese Exporters (Amit K. Khandelwal, Peter K. Schott and Shang-Jin Wei) This appendix provides further detail

More information

Institutional Investor Monitoring Motivation and the Marginal Value of Cash

Institutional Investor Monitoring Motivation and the Marginal Value of Cash Institutional Investor Monitoring Motivation and the Marginal Value of Cash Chao Yin 1 1 ICMA Centre, Henley Business School, University of Reading Abstract This paper examines whether the motivation of

More information

Additional Evidence and Replication Code for Analyzing the Effects of Minimum Wage Increases Enacted During the Great Recession

Additional Evidence and Replication Code for Analyzing the Effects of Minimum Wage Increases Enacted During the Great Recession ESSPRI Working Paper Series Paper #20173 Additional Evidence and Replication Code for Analyzing the Effects of Minimum Wage Increases Enacted During the Great Recession Economic Self-Sufficiency Policy

More information

Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know?

Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know? Preliminary Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know? by Robert Harris*, Tim Jenkinson** and Steven N. Kaplan*** This Draft: September 9, 2011 Abstract We present time series evidence on the performance

More information

The Impact of Unconventional Monetary Policy On Firm Financing Constraints: Evidence from the Maturity Extension Program

The Impact of Unconventional Monetary Policy On Firm Financing Constraints: Evidence from the Maturity Extension Program The Impact of Unconventional Monetary Policy On Firm Financing Constraints: Evidence from the Maturity Extension Program Nathan Foley-Fisher Federal Reserve Board of Governors Rodney Ramcharan Federal

More information

ECON 652: Graduate Public Economics I

ECON 652: Graduate Public Economics I ECON 652: Graduate Public Economics I Lesley Turner Fall 2013 Week 1: Introduction and Course Overview Plan for Today 1. What is public economics (and why should you care)? 2. Semester road map What is

More information

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital

Appendices. A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Appendices A A Simple Model of Contagion in Venture Capital Given the structure of venture capital financing just described, the potential mechanisms by which shocks might propagate across companies in

More information

Ten Years after the Financial Crisis: What Have We Learned from. the Renaissance in Fiscal Research?

Ten Years after the Financial Crisis: What Have We Learned from. the Renaissance in Fiscal Research? Ten Years after the Financial Crisis: What Have We Learned from the Renaissance in Fiscal Research? by Valerie A. Ramey University of California, San Diego and NBER NBER Global Financial Crisis @10 July

More information

Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior

Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior By Jackson Mills Abstract The retention of deep in-the-money exercisable stock options by CEOs has generally been attributed to managers

More information

Employment Effects of Reducing Capital Gains Tax Rates in Ohio. William Melick Kenyon College. Eric Andersen American Action Forum

Employment Effects of Reducing Capital Gains Tax Rates in Ohio. William Melick Kenyon College. Eric Andersen American Action Forum Employment Effects of Reducing Capital Gains Tax Rates in Ohio William Melick Kenyon College Eric Andersen American Action Forum June 2011 Executive Summary Entrepreneurial activity is a key driver of

More information

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations Online Appendix of Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality By ANDREAS FAGERENG, LUIGI GUISO, DAVIDE MALACRINO AND LUIGI PISTAFERRI This appendix complements the evidence

More information

Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time,

Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time, 1. Introduction Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time, many diversified firms have become more focused by divesting assets. 2 Some firms become more

More information

Credit vs. demand constraints: the determinants of US rm-level investment over the business cycles from 1977 to 2011

Credit vs. demand constraints: the determinants of US rm-level investment over the business cycles from 1977 to 2011 Credit vs. demand constraints: the determinants of US rm-level investment over the business cycles from 1977 to 2011 Christian Schoder The New School for Social Research March 21, 2012 Abstract The paper

More information