Consumption Volatility, Marketization, and Expenditure in Emerging Market Economies

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Consumption Volatility, Marketization, and Expenditure in Emerging Market Economies"

Transcription

1 Consumption Volatility, Marketization, and Expenditure in Emerging Market Economies Daniel L. Hicks Department of Economics University of Oklahoma 5/25/2012 Abstract: Consumption and income in emerging market economies are significantly more volatile than in developed economies. A volatility decomposition using Mexico s ENIGH, a nationally representative household-level income and expenditure survey from 1984 to 2006, suggests that a significant portion of fluctuations result from the large expenditure share devoted to goods and services with a low cost of substitution between market and home inputs such as food provision. During shocks, expenditure is found to be more volatile than direct measures of household consumption. I show that this result holds both at the aggregate level over the business cycle and, using pseudo-panel analysis, at the household level over unemployment spells. Using expenditure as our measure of consumption over the business cycle creates marketization bias, generating excessive levels of aggregate volatility and overstating differences in volatility across countries. Keywords: marketization; household production; consumption; expenditure; bias; volatility; JEL CODES: E01, E2, E3, O11, O47, O54 Acknowledgments: I am especially grateful to Chang-Tai Hsieh, Charles Jones, and Edward Miguel for their encouragement and suggestions. I am indebted to two anonymous referees for valuable comments. I would also like to thank Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, Kevin Grier, Joan Hamory Hicks, Gordon Hanson, Ethan Ligon, Richard Lyons, Alex Rothenberg, John Tang, and numerous seminar participants for helpful comments and discussions. Tilsa Ore provided valuable research assistance. I am grateful to the Instituto Nacional De Estadistica Geographica e Informatica for compiling the ENIGH survey data and for fielding questions on its use.

2 1. Introduction and Motivation Recent research in the US has documented that expenditure is a poor proxy for consumption when the opportunity cost of engaging with the market changes over the lifecycle (Aguiar and Hurst, 2005; 2007; 2009) and over the business cycle (Aguiar et al., 2011). This study confirms that the distinction between actual consumption and measured expenditure extends to Mexican households and demonstrates that substitution between home and market inputs leads to overstated aggregate volatility when consumption is measured by expenditure. 1 Furthermore, I provide evidence that this bias applies to a sizeable portion of the Mexican economy and is systematically larger among developing economies, confounding cross-country business cycle analysis. The idea that marketization can lead to overestimation of the rate of economic growth is not new. Deaton (2005) describes how, during periods of expansion, households shift resources from informal to formal market activities, leading to a greater share of economic behavior in the formal sector and generating positive growth bias in GDP statistics. I extend this line of reasoning to explain overestimation of aggregate volatility. I show that while Mexico has grown and become increasingly marketized over the past two decades, during economic contractions such as the Peso Crisis, households realized substantial declines in expenditure in patterns consistent with substitution away from the market sector and towards household time input in the consumption process. These reallocations imply that measured expenditure understates actual consumption of commodities during crises. Together, marketization and de-marketization shifts combine to exaggerate overall consumption volatility when measured by expenditure. Furthermore, marketization bias should be a larger problem for measuring consumption in emerging market economies because the typical expenditure bundle is more heavily skewed towards commodities for which household time is a viable alternative to market inputs in the consumption process, such as for food preparation. 2 For example, if households in both economies behaved in a similar fashion, the corresponding level of marketization bias in the US would be around one-third of the size of that in Mexico simply because of differences in the expenditure share devoted to food. Broadly, food expenditure for a typical emerging market household comprises two to three times the 1 Mexico is an ideal setting to examine fluctuations, enduring measured consumption volatility two and half times greater than the developed country average over the last two decades (as measured by the standard deviation of quarterly consumption expenditure). Similarly, Mexico s quarterly GDP over the past 20 years has a standard deviation roughly two times larger than the OECD average. 2 It is also plausible that the elasticity of substitution between home and market production would be highest in these economies where a range of consumption activities are not yet fully marketized. Similarly, among poor economies characterized by subsistence farming, a lack of opportunities to engage with the market may limit the scope of marketization changes. A growing set of estimates of this elasticity exist (see below).

3 services. 4 The home production literature provides existing theory concerning consumer behavior. In average budget share of their developed country counterparts, as would be expected by Engel's Law. Thus, marketization bias should systematically exaggerate the relative volatility of less developed economies. Because food expenditure can be a significant source of overall volatility (it alone accounts for close to 30% of total consumption variance in Mexico), this pattern may help explain the high level of consumption volatility in emerging markets relative to developed economies. 3 To estimate the impact of marketization bias on the measurement of fluctuations in Mexico, I decompose macroeconomic volatility using household survey data over the period 1984 to The bulk of consumption volatility can be attributed to changes in expenditure on non-durables and services. Non-durable volatility is primarily driven by fluctuations in food expenditure, nearly half of which is due to changes in expenditure on food consumed away from home. Volatility in expenditure on services, which accounts for over half of measured volatility, meanwhile appears to be driven in part by large changes in demand for a broad range of services with scope for household time input in the consumption process such as domestic service, childcare, and personal care models based on Becker (1965), commodities are composed of both market expenditures and time inputs. Individuals can substitute between these two components in the process of consumption. 5 Aguiar et al. (2012) shows that holding constant the marginal utility of wealth, when wages are growing, agents will shift toward market expenditures, and conversely when wage shocks lower the opportunity cost of time, agents will reallocate time to non-market production in the consumption process. 6 Adjusting between expenditure and time in consumption can be accomplished in a number of ways. For instance, within a specific service, such as childcare, households can substitute greater amounts of time in place of expenditure. They can do the same for a specific good such as a tortilla by purchasing the necessary inputs at different stages of processing, choosing between corn grain, corn meal, and fully prepared tortillas. Alternatively, households may simply substitute across 3 There are a number of intriguing differences between fluctuations in emerging markets and those in developed economies, including higher volatility of macroeconomic aggregates such as investment, consumption, and output in emerging economies (Backus and Kehoe, 1992; Lane, 2003; Agénor et al., 2000). Indeed, recent work has shown consumption is actually more volatile than income in emerging markets (Kose et al., 2003; Neumeyer and Perri, 2004; Aguiar and Gopinath, 2007; Raffo, 2008). 4 A significant portion is also attributable to swings in the estimated rental value of owner occupied housing. 5 This reallocation can be undertaken at either at the intensive margin through reduced market hours or at the extensive margin through lower participation in the labor force. 6 Aguiar et al. (2012) makes clear that the issue is complicated by household's ability to substitute across time as well. Formally, what is required for households to devote more time to producing commodities during recessions and less time during booms is for the elasticity of substitution between market inputs and time to be greater than the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. For this reason, the analysis here focuses on commodities for which the possibility of substitution of time for expenditure is large, such as food expenditure.

4 different but related commodities which vary in the level of market expenditure relative to time input required (i.e. choosing between dining out or preparing a meal at home). The evidence presented in this paper addresses several aspects of this theory. First, I document that over the past few decades, as wages and market employment opportunities have increased in Mexico, household consumption has become increasingly marketized. This shift is evident in long-term expenditure patterns, with households reallocating purchases away from goods and services requiring high levels of time input in favor of highly marketized substitutes, behavior consistent with an increase in the opportunity cost of their time. 7 Second, I show that households undertake this substitution even within the same product, as higher income households purchase more highly marketized versions of specific commodities. Furthermore, the shock of the Peso Crisis, which can be thought of as reducing the availability of well paying market jobs, temporarily reversed the marketization process (likely by lowering the opportunity cost to households of providing a greater extent of own time in the consumption process). In this instance, households reverted to purchasing less processed products such as corn meal in lieu of tortillas, as well as substituted across similar commodities with very different levels of market and own time inputs such as between restaurant meals and grocery store purchases. Finally, to explore differences between expenditure and direct measures of consumption, I show that nutritional intake is significantly less volatile than food expenditure, and provide descriptive evidence that the allocation of time spent on a range of household activities is consistent with time substitution in the consumption process. A set of macroeconomic models which incorporate home production have modeled substitution in the allocation of household resources during economic fluctuations (Benhabib et al., 1991; Greenwood and Herkowitz, 1991; Greenwood et al., 1993; and Baxter and Jermann 1999). These models assume a reasonable degree of elasticity in substitution between home and market production. Estimates of this value exist, with the most relevant being Aguiar et al. (2011) which finds a value of 2.5 in the context of business cycle fluctuations in the US. 8 Given the sheer size 7 The marketization process is akin to the process of Smithian growth where during expansions individuals become more highly specialized and more heavily engaged with the market. 8 A number of estimates for this elasticity of substitution exist including Rupert et al., (1995), McGrattan, Rogerson and Wright (1997) and Aguiar and Hurst (2007). See Aguiar et al., (2012a) for a summary of the literature.

5 difference of the informal sector and the comparatively weaker market institutions in developing countries, it would seem plausible this value is higher in less developed countries. 9 Existing studies have documented declines in the consumption of basic necessities during large crises, arguing that individuals lack sufficient resources and mechanisms for coping with these shocks. For instance, in their study of the Indonesian Financial Crisis, Frankenberg et al. (1999) document a dramatic decline in both education and health spending. McKenzie (2006) finds a similar decline in both food and health spending in Mexico during the Peso crisis. 10 Reductions in human capital investments imply possible long-term costs to short-run volatility and accurately quantifying the impact of crises is essential for policy-making. 11 This paper suggests that expenditure based measures of consumption during shocks overstate the extent to which final consumption of many commodities declines, and reliance on these expenditure metrics mask other important costs faced by the household such as large time reallocations within the household. 12 The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the sources of nutrition, income, and expenditure data and presents some basic summary statistics. Section 3 documents changes in the level of marketization during periods of growth and over. Section 4 examines the importance of marketization bias in driving overall consumption volatility in Mexico. Section 5 compares nutritional measures of food consumption with those for food expenditure, revealing that in the presence of home production, measures based on expenditure overstate volatility relative to direct measures. Section 6 examines time use data to show that time allocation of Mexican households is consistent with household substitution between home and market goods across numerous sectors of the economy. Section 7 concludes. 2. Data Description 2.1 The ENIGH Household Income and Expenditure Survey 9 Cardoso-Lecourtois (2002) estimates that the elasticity of substitution between home and market goods in Mexico is significantly higher than in the United States. The inclusion of these values for substitution between home and market goods into an RBC model suggests that home production can explain over two-thirds of observed consumption volatility in Mexico. 10 McKenzie shows that households coped with the shock primarily by changing the composition of consumption, increasing the share of spending on food to an even greater degree than would be predicted by Engel s Law. Divergence between the path of actual consumption and consumption expenditure may help explain observed changes in food expenditure which are larger than those predicted by theory. 11 Morduch (1995) argues that consumption and income smoothing are substitutes, and that efforts to estimates of the cost of consumption smoothing will be understated if risk aversion drives individuals to smooth income as well. Consumption smoothing via income smoothing might entail lower risk taking in production, employment, and investment decisions, all of which can reduce longer term income and profitability. 12 In this regard, this research relates to the existing literature which examines differences between household surveys and national accounts in the measurement of economic activity (Ravallion, 2003; Deaton, 2005).

6 Mexico s Encuesta Nacional de Ingresos y Gastos de los Hogares (ENIGH) is a nationally representative survey of income and expenditure carried out by the Instituto Nacional de Estadística Geografía e Informática (INEGI). The ENIGH surveys are highly detailed household-level questionnaires that record both monetary and non-monetary transactions for over 500 distinct goods and services. Households also report transfers and detailed income information by source. Additionally, information is collected on a range of individual characteristics such as age, occupation, employment status, hours worked, and educational attainment, as well as detailed records on characteristics of the residence and on household asset ownership. Comparable ENIGH surveys have been carried out at irregular intervals for the past two decades. In total the surveys provide eleven rich cross-sectional observations: 1984, 1989, 1992, 1994, 1996, 1998, 2000, 2002, 2004, 2005 and With the exception of the 1984 survey which includes just over 4,700 households, the surveys range in coverage from 10,500 to 23,805 households. There is no panel component, and enumeration occurs during the third quarter of each survey year, making the surveys comparable but restricting ability to explore seasonal variations or track individual households over time. The surveys also lack precise geographic information, limiting the scope for regional comparisons within Mexico. The 1994 and 1996 ENIGH surveys bracket a severe economic shock in Mexico, the Peso Crisis. The latest in a series of exchange rate shocks for Mexico, the aftermath included a large decline in stock market valuation, a more than 5% percentage point rise in the unemployment rate, and a rapid run up in prices. In addition, households experienced a 23% decline in consumption expenditure over the crisis resulting from both falling income and rising prices. Inflation over the period was enormous, averaging 2.5% a month yielding an 86.5% increase in prices in just two years. Prices for food more than doubled. Since the crisis period, Mexico s central bank performance has improved, with inflation moderating in recent years. In calculating consumption and income, I correct for the introduction of the new peso in 1993 and deflate the surveys using the National CPI from September of each survey year. 13 Looking more broadly over the ENIGH survey period, one would characterize households in Mexico as having experienced rather rapid economic growth and a number of large shocks. The high level of both consumption and income volatility can clearly been seen in Figure 1, with 13 This practice follows McKenzie (2006), although he employs the basic needs CPI which he argues more accurately captures welfare changes over the crisis period because prices increases disproportionately affected the consumption basket of low-income households. I compare aggregate changes in the data to those in the national accounts over a longer period and employ the National CPI which seems likely to provide greater comparability in this context. Much of the analysis employs expenditure shares for which the results are largely insensitive to the choice of deflator.

7 slowdowns evident from , and , although the 1995 Crisis is clearly the most dramatic. Movements in consumption exhibit a high degree of co-movement with those in income. In contrast to evidence from national accounts figures, consumption swings in the household data are smaller than those in income. Several demographic and socioeconomic changes occur over the 22 year survey period. The majority of households are headed by males, although this fraction declines steadily over time. Mean age of household head rises from 44.5 to 47. Household heads tend to be literate and to have increasing educational attainment. Questions on literacy were dropped from surveys in later years, but for the years during which the information was collected, it was consistently above 85% and rising. The majority of households are nuclear, with a clear downward trend in household size over time, falling from roughly 5 to 4 over the period. These trends are consistent with the maturation of a still relatively young population. The extent to which declines in household size affect household economies of scale and thus influence the cost of providing home production relative to purchasing market consumption is likely a valuable avenue of future research. 2.2 USDA Food and Nutrient Database for Dietary Studies ENIGH households were asked to keep consumption logs for one week detailing daily food transactions, including both prices paid and quantities purchased. These logs cover expenditure on over 200 distinct categories of food and drink purchased by Mexican households. I create a database of household-level nutrient availability by linking the quantity of each food and drink purchased to nutritional information from the USDA s Food and Nutrient Database for Dietary Studies 3.0 (USDA, 2008). There are a number of limitations of this constructed database that should be noted. First, for the subset of meals consumed outside the home, only total expenditures (and neither quantities nor specific foods consumed) are recorded in the ENIGH consumption logs. In order to estimate caloric and nutrient values for these purchases, I follow the practice of Subramanian and Deaton (1996) of computing the average price per calorie (in this case the average price per nutrient) from the current household food consumption bundle of food purchased for the home and apply a 50% premium since restaurant meals are likely to be more expensive than those at home. Expenditure is then deflated by these nutrient prices to compute estimated calories and nutrients consumed outside the home. While useful, this estimation technique is likely to overstate the volatility of calories relative to consumption expenditure, as households are likely to consume cheaper meals out during

8 shocks and splurge on more expensive restaurants during times of plenty. Fortunately the direction of this bias would serve to make expenditure smoother than nutrition and thus suggest any finding to the contrary would be understated. 14 Similarly, this analysis will be unable to address issues of intra-household food distribution. 15 Consumption logs only provide information on food and drink spending for the household as a whole, revealing nothing about which household members actually consume those specific expenditures. Nevertheless, we can recognize the role of life-cycle dietary needs and employ adultequivalent household figures (in which household members under age 16 are treated as 0.5 adults). Another limitation of the database constructed here is that food quality can only be observed across categories, and while food categories are highly disaggregated, this likely misses out on changes in food quality. For instance, food logs distinguish between many different cuts of steak, but not between purchases of lean or regular ground beef. To some extent some of this substitution will occur on the price margin, and be captured by the fact that households get a larger quantity for or purchase a cheaper food substitute when times are tough. Section 5 provides evidence that households substitute across goods with various levels of market processing, but it is likely that actual household substitution is more complex than revealed by the ENIGH data. A final concern is the issue of wastage. Measures derived from merging the ENIGH food expenditure logs and the USDA database capture caloric and nutrient availability to the household, not actual intake. One factor driving a wedge between the two is the amount of food wastage which occurs. While wastage is generally regarded as a more important issue in developed economies, it is likely to increase with income. Further, wastage is liable to increase during good times and decrease during hard times, meaning that the true path of caloric intake should be smoother than the observed path of caloric availability. Therefore, this issue could result in overstated volatility in calories in the subsequent analysis. Once again, the direction of this bias works in my favor, and will only attenuate any finding that nutrition is smoother than expenditure in Mexican households. 3. Growth, Volatility, and Marketization Bias in Mexico and Beyond This section examines whether aggregated measures of consumption expenditure are consistent with the marketization hypothesis and compares the case of Mexico to other economies. 14 On the other hand, the presence of countercyclical mark-ups in restaurants may lead this approach to understate volatility because during recessions the mark-up would actually increase and the amount of nutrients per expenditure would then fall (although, a similar offsetting countercyclical mark-up may exist in grocery stores as well). Additionally, it is likely that the average dinner party size and the availability of restaurants also vary over the cycle making too much reliance on this information problematic. 15 It is however possible to address intra-household time allocation, which will be examined in Section 6.

9 Specifically, do we observe increased marketization during periods of growth and demarketization during shocks? Changes in the pattern of income and consumption among ENIGH households over the period are shown in Table 1 and are suggestive of a growing economy becoming increasingly marketized over time. Column 1 reports that consumption expenditure nearly doubles over this period, with households experiencing an average annual growth rate of 2.2% for real consumption expenditure and of 2.3% for real income. Changes in the source of income are also consistent with increased marketization as net compensation of employees, a measure of market wages and salaries, rose as a share of total income from 64% to 71% (not shown). As Mexican households become more affluent, the composition of the typical consumption bundle shifts from nondurable goods to services (columns 3-5). This shift is in large part due to declines in the expenditure share on food, which falls from 42% to 27% of the average household budget over the sample period. Market expenditure on many services traditionally considered to have a high elasticity of substitution between home and market production such as domestic service, personal care, infant care, and meals consumed outside the home increased over the period, both in terms of total consumption and in terms of expenditure share (as evidenced by the faster average annual growth rate for these consumption categories than for overall consumption). This trend is consistent with increasing marketization as the Mexican grew, where as market wages rise, the tradeoff between home and market inputs in the consumption process shifts more in favor of market goods. As a robustness check on the data quality of the 1984 and 2006 survey waves, these trends are evident when comparing the average expenditure share from the first 2 to 3 survey rounds and final 2 to3 survey rounds as well. Evidence concerning regression from the market can be seen by examining changes in expenditure over the Peso crisis (Table 1, column 6). From 1994 to 1996 expenditure on these same activities falls much more rapidly than overall spending. For example, expenditure on food out falls by 31% and expenditure on infant care by 69%, while overall expenditure declines only 23%. Some of these were offset by increases in expenditure share of substitutes with different levels of marketization. For example, while from spending on domestic services declines nearly 40%, the budget share devoted to purchasing household cleaning and care products increased, suggesting that households may be substituting their own labor for what was previously a service purchased in the market. These trends are consistent with a story of marketization during expansion and de-marketization during contraction.

10 To what extent does marketization bias extend across countries? Column 7 of Table 1 presents expenditure shares for a number of goods and services categories in the United States for 2006, and comparison with Mexico in 2006 (column 4) reveals stark differences. The expenditure share on food among Mexican households exceeds that of the US by more than a factor of two. This finding has broad implications for studies of cross-country differences in measured consumption expenditure. To the extent that household consumption is much smoother than expenditure, measuring food expenditure rather than consumption overstates actual consumption volatility for over 30% of the Mexican economy, a much larger share than for the US. This result is not limited to just Mexico and the US. Figure 2 presents food's share of consumption expenditure by income across a range of developed and less-developed countries. Food expenditure shares are declining in income in a systematic manner and the clear downward slope illustrates Engel s Law. Research by Regmi et al. (2001) has shown that lower income economies spend significantly more of their budgets on food (~47%) than both middle income (29%) and high income economies (13%). 16 If households in less developed countries are more likely to substitute own time for market time in the production of food in response to changing wages, then we might expect to observe larger expenditure responses to shocks and thus higher income elasticity of food expenditure in this settings. This is indeed the case, as low income economies additionally have much higher income elasticity for food expenditure (0.73) compared to middle (0.58) and high income economies (0.29). Most emerging market economies fall into the middle income category and have income elasticities roughly five to six times that of the U.S. (Seale et al., 2003). 4. Sources of Consumption Expenditure Volatility among Mexican Households The previous section presented evidence that the process of marketization is procyclical, rising during periods of growth and declining during downturns. It also suggested that on average, a sizeable share of the Mexican economy is exposed to marketization bias. To more rigorously assess how much of overall volatility is attributable to specific commodities such as food expenditure, total swings have to be decomposed into component fluctuations. This is because aggregate volatility depends not only on the expenditure share of components of consumption, but also on the extent to which these components move with the economic cycle. One simple way to decompose volatility is to think of aggregate fluctuations as a weighted sum of the fluctuations in the individual 16 Here, low income economies are defined to have <15%, middle income 15-50%, and high income > 50% of U.S. GDP.

11 components of consumption spending. Taking as weights their contribution to overall consumption growth between periods, the contribution of component i to an overall change in consumption over τ years can then be written as: CAAPC i C C i, t Agg, t C C i, t Agg, t C C Agg, t Agg, t 1 Figure 3 graphically displays changes in consumption between ENIGH survey rounds, broken out by broad expenditure category using this method. The first point of interest is the behavior of durable goods. Not only are durable goods purchases the first to be abandoned in a slowdown as is the case from , and , but it also apparent that consumers are merely delaying these purchases, as indicated by the explosive growth from and Cecchetti et al. (2006) argues that durable goods are frequently cited as an important factor driving consumption volatility in developed nations and McKenzie's (2006) analysis found that Mexican consumers responded to the crisis by postponing purchases of durables. 18 Given the high purchase price of many durables, liquidity constraints (which are more severe in less developed economies) may be a factor driving volatility in durables. 19 If Mexican consumers are merely postponing durable expenditures and not eliminating these purchases over the course of income shocks, this could drive high consumption volatility by depressing consumption during recessions and inflating consumption during expansions. Nevertheless, throughout the survey period, durables only comprise 6-7% of total consumption expenditure. Thus, even though they are individually much more volatile than non-durables and services, they still have only a small impact on overall changes. Instead, Figure 3 suggests the bulk of changes in consumption expenditure can be attributed to swings in food and service expenditures. This is even apparent during the Peso Crisis, where despite a rise in food s share of consumption, food expenditure, services and other non-durables comprise the vast majority of the expenditure decline Where CAAPC approximates the discrete contribution of component i to the average annual percentage change of aggregate consumption between survey waves. For instance, if the average annual growth rate of aggregate consumption between 1998 and 2000 was 4% and one-half of this increase could be attributed to growth in services expenditure, then the CAAPC of services would be 2 percentage points. 18 McKenzie (2006) provides a rigorous evaluation of the consumer response to the Peso Crisis and shows that Mexican consumers alter the timing and composition of their consumption behavior. I find that by the time of the 1994 ENIGH surveys, the economy had already begun to slow. This can be seen in Figure 3, where in 1994, prior to the full onset of the crisis, households begin postponing purchases of durables, especially big ticket items such as automobiles. Given the timing of the 1994 survey, some of the decrease in consumption could be attributable to consumer uncertainty surrounding the future of the economy or to the tightening of credit markets. 19 Similarly, sudden stops in foreign investment may externally impose credit crunches.

12 While the above disaggregation intuitively captures period by period fluctuations, it misses out on which components of the economy can create shocks through covariance. A second method of variance decomposition would be to analyze the individual contribution of a specific sector to aggregate volatility over a longer period using fundamentals from portfolio theory, where individual assets each contribute to an overall portfolio's volatility. Koenig and Ball (2007) show that a random variable I C which is the weighted sum of individual components C i, where the weights α i i i C i are constant, has covariance Cov(C,C i ) = C, C i C Ci, and overall volatility given by I C i C, Ci C. Assuming expenditure shares are relatively stable, we can calculate how much i i of aggregate volatility is attributable to each individual component of consumption by looking at the product of three factors: individual expenditure shares, correlation with aggregate consumption, and individual volatility. 20 Table 2 presents decompositions of consumption volatility from using each of the two methods detailed above. Both exercises paint a similar picture of the driving forces behind volatility in consumption expenditure. The results suggest that expenditure on food and alcohol alone accounts for more than a quarter of total consumption volatility, suggesting that for Mexico a sizeable portion of consumption volatility is directly attributable to expenditure for which the household can easily substitute between own and market inputs during the consumption process. 21 Assuming that this phenomenon extends beyond food preparation and into other activities with high potential for non-market substitution in the consumption process, then this fraction rises to roughly 1/3 rd once we include a small subset of additional services for which there is likely a large scope for substitution of home labor for market labor such as child care, personal care, and domestic service. 5. Food Expenditure and Consumption The volatility decomposition of the previous section suggests that any examination of consumption volatility should focus on the role of non-durables and services in driving fluctuations. This section undertakes several exercises which analyze the volatility of food consumption, the 20 Expenditure shares are in fact slowly changing over time, so as an approximation I employ the average expenditure share over the entire period. 21 Similarly, separate results (not reported) calculating variance and incrementally removing food expenditure from total consumption results in a decrease in variance of 25%.

13 largest component of non-durable purchases. First, households are shown to substitute between own time inputs and market production in the consumption of a specific commodity with identifiable levels of marketization, tortillas. Additionally, households appear to revert to versions requiring more time input during the Peso Crisis. Next, expenditure volatility across households is explored rigorously using pseudo-panel regression analysis to examine changes in consumption expenditure over a particular household income shock - unemployment spells. Finally, although nutritional intake is shown to vary with household resources, nutritional measures of food consumption are found to be significantly smoother than food expenditure both at the aggregate level over the business cycle and at the level of the household during unemployment. First, I examine substitution between home and market inputs in food provision as income rises. Perhaps the clearest way to examine household substitution of own time for market inputs within a specific commodity is to identify categories of food expenditure for which there is clear differentiation in the level of time input required and ideally a sizeable degree of quality homogeneity. Fortunately, the richness of the ENIGH surveys allows for such an exercise. Tortillas, particularly those made of corn, are a staple of the Mexican diet and can be purchased in various stages of finishing. To produce tortillas from scratch involves a rather intensive time input from the household. They must purchase corn grains, soak them in a lime-alkaline solution, rinse them, sometimes hull the kernels, grind the grains produce corn meal or dough, and then shape and cook them to finally produce the tortillas. 22 Alternatively households can purchase cornmeal flour or dough to cook directly, or purchase tortillas outright. Each increase in market based preparation reflects fewer household time inputs but also increasing cost. Over the entire sample, 81% of households reported purchasing some corn tortillas in the last week, and 12% reported positive expenditure on corn grains and 12% reported positive expenditure on corn meal or dough. Table 3 presents the results of semi-log regressions for the various production stages of corn and wheat tortillas, and meals outside the home. Specifically, I estimate a semi-log regression of the following form: E it ln( YPerm, it ) X where the dependent variable is an indicator taking on the value 1 when household i undertakes positive expenditure in category E during year t. Household income, Y has both a permanent and a transitory component. Following Aguiar and Hurst (2005), I instrument for current income with it it (1) 22 Processing of corn kernels through the use of the lime-alkaline solution to produce corn meal is known as Nixtamalization.

14 indicators for household head education and occupation, and a full set of interactions between the two, in order to elicit the permanent component of income variation. X is a vector of controls including gender of household head, number of young and old age dependents, number of men and women, adult equivalent household size, as well as an indicator for urban households and for each survey year. Regressions are run for the period because food, occupation, and education categories are consistent over this period (and not so for the 1984, 1989, 2005 and 2006 survey rounds). The sample is restricted to households with heads aged 35 to 50 who work full time (at least 40 hours per week), out of concern that the inclusion of young, elderly, or underemployed heads may yield non-standard elasticities owing to differences in preferences and demands over the lifecycle. Semi-elasticities estimated using equation (1) are reported in column of Table 3. The results are significant and consistent with the expected sign. Poorer households are more likely to consume raw corn grain, and wheat flour as well as slightly more likely to buy corn meal and dough. Higher income is associated with fewer purchases of these products and more expenses on finished corn and wheat tortillas. Specifically, a doubling in household permanent income is associated with a 12 percentage point decline in the likelihood of purchasing corn grain, a 4.1 percentage point decline in the likelihood of corn meal purchases, and a 7.6 percentage point increase in the likelihood of buying corn tortillas. As the bottom panel of Table 3 shows, these patterns extend beyond tortilla production to the marketization of food expenditure more broadly. A doubling in household income increases the probability that a household purchases meals away from the home by 16.5 percentage points and the probability that they spend a positive amount on prepared foods (such as frozen pizza or readymade meals) by 8.2 percentage points. Together, all of this indicates that households with higher income appear to substitute towards market labor in the place of their own labor, for example shifting from home consumption to consumption of meals outside the home. If households are substituting own time for market time in the production of tortillas, then in response to a shock to labor market opportunities such as presented by the Peso Crisis, we should observe a reallocation in market expenditures towards less processed products (those requiring a greater degree of household time input in the consumption process). Column 5 of Table 3 presents changes in expenditure over the crisis period from Household consumption expenditure is consistent with this behavior. Expenditure on corn grain, corn meal and dough, and wheat flour, actually rises significantly over the crisis period. At the same time, expenditure on prepared corn

15 and flour tortillas which have larger market inputs and on Nixtamal services (an activity which can be replaced with household time input) declines. As would be expected, reductions in expenditure on other highly marketized foods such as meals out and prepared foods are even larger. Reallocations in expenditure between goods and services with a low level of marketization and highly marketized commodities are also evident over the whole period. Recall, Table 1 shows that as household income in Mexico grew over , the share of food expenditure devoted to meals out increased and the share of food for home consumption decreased (column 5). Figure 4 shows the dynamics of this relationship by focusing on the decomposition of changes in food expenditure between survey waves. The procyclical nature of fluctuations in expenditure on meals out is evident. One can explore expenditure volatility across households more rigorously using regression analysis to examine changes in food consumption expenditure over a particular type of household income shock - unemployment spells. To do this, I perform an exercise analogous to that of Aguiar and Hurst (2005), who focus on changes in food consumption after retirement and unemployment in the US. Also, because the ENIGH data lacks a panel component and individuals may select into unemployment, I analyze such changes using a pseudo-panel, cohort based analysis. The biannual nature of the cross-sectional ENIGH surveys during the 1990s and early 2000s presents a natural setting to employ cohort analysis. I construct cohorts based on year of birth and educational attainment of household head, and utilize survey data collected during the period , when questions classifying educational attainment remained relatively consistent over time. The large sample size of the ENIGH allows for 5-year year of birth cohorts across 5 educational groups generating 40 cohorts per survey year with an average size of 277 households per cohort. 23 I assess the impact of household level unemployment shocks on expenditure by estimating the following regression equation: ln( C ) unemp it it X it J where, as before, i indexes households and t indexes survey years. The definition of household consumption expenditure (C) varies across different specifications to include total expenditure, food expenditure, and expenditure on food at home or food outside of the house separately. The independent variable of interest is the unemployment term (defined in terms of the status of the household head). X is a vector of socioeconomic and demographic controls including the gender, i it (2) 23 Results presented are insensitive to variations in the cohort definition such as variation in inclusion of particular sets of years of birth, or redefining cohorts as year of birth only, or year of birth / education / gender cohorts.

16 age, and education level of the household head, as well as adult equivalent household size, numbers of men, women, young age dependents, and old age dependents in the household, an indicator for whether the household is rural, and survey year dummies. J represents the year of birth, education cohort fixed effects. Table 4, Panel A presents the results of these regressions. The ENIGH surveys contain rich information about individual employment status, and each column examines a different definition of household head unemployment. In column 1, an individual is counted as unemployed if they are part of the labor force, but lacked work for any number of reasons including temporary work loss due to strikes, supply shortages, necessary equipment repair, and sickness. One concern is that household may view a bout of unemployment, particularly one due to a strike or seasonal factors, as highly transitory. In column 2, the definition is restricted to household heads that report both lacking work and active job search, a situation where the household faces greater uncertainty. Finally, since many employment changes occur at the margin, column 3 examines changes in expenditure occurring when the household head works less than full time. The results in columns 1 and 2 of Panel A are strikingly similar. Unemployment of the household head is associated with significant reductions in expenditure. Total expenditure declines 17 to 23% when the household head becomes unemployed, and expenditure on food declines more than 13 to 14%. The reduction in food consumed at home is smaller than the reduction in food consumed out, although this difference is statistically significant only for column 3. As one would expect, results in column 3 where the dependent variable is an indicator for full-time employment are smaller in magnitude, but otherwise substantively similar to the results in columns 1 and 2. The results in Tables 3 and 4 (panel A) together suggest that households substitute own production for market production during difficult times. Unlike the tortillas exercise, I cannot distinguish the between substitution within goods and substitution across goods in this case, although both are likely occurring. For example, households can buffer against shocks through changes in dietary composition, such as switching consumption from meat to beans in order to maintain protein more cheaply. Still, if households do smooth consumption in this way, then expenditure would likely not accurately capture true household consumption, and although welfare would likely be impacted, the expenditure based measure could still be misleading. As previously mentioned, the Peso Crisis provides an excellent instance to examine extreme volatility in an emerging market setting. While households reduced overall expenditure on food by nearly 25% between 1994 and 1996, food s share in total expenditure actually increased (see Figure

17 5, left panel). However, households dramatically reduced expenditure on meals away from the home (see Figure 5, right panel) and shifted expenditure away from relatively expensive foods such as meals out, meat, and fruit towards foods generally considered staples such as cereals and dairy. A larger share of calories after the crisis was derived from cheap sources such as cereals, tubers, and vegetables (results not shown). 24 Were Mexican households able to smooth nutritional availability over the Peso Crisis? Figure 6 presents average annual changes in adult equivalent food expenditure, calories, protein and a broad nutrient index from 1992 to It is immediately apparent that over the crisis households on average were better able to smooth calories, protein, and nutrient availability over the aggregate shock of the crisis than they were able to smooth expenditure. Whereas expenditure on food declined nearly 9% per year over the crisis, calories declined by 0.6% and the nutrient index declined by 0.29%. In order to compare expenditure and nutrition volatility more rigorously in a regression context, it is useful to first estimate the income elasticity of the typical Mexican household's nutritional profile. This will inform us as to which nutrients we should expect to see change in availability to the household during expenditure shocks. To calculate this elasticity, I estimate an instrumental variables regression similar to equation (1), where this time the dependent variable is the log of household level availability of a given nutrient. 26 As in the semi-elasticity regressions estimated previously, current income is instrumented in order to identify the permanent component of household income, X includes the same set of controls, and the sample is again limited to household heads aged who work full time. 27 Results of these income elasticity regressions are presented in Table 5. Both calories and protein exhibit low income elasticities, with coefficients of 0.08 and 0.10 respectively, indicating that their consumption does not dramatically rise with income. Vitamins and minerals appear more responsive to income changes, especially Calcium, Vitamins A, B12, and E. Surprisingly, Vitamin E exhibits negative income elasticity, which likely results from poorer households purchasing greater quantities of certain goods that are relatively rich in the nutrient such as cooking oil and beans. Surprisingly, "bads" such as sugars, cholesterol and fat exhibit relatively low income elasticities. 24 Regmi et al. (2001) suggests high income elasticity can be seen among for many food categories in lower income countries, suggesting that households are very willing to substitute across food categories. 25 The nutrient index includes household availability of Calcium, Iron, and Vitamins A, B12, C and E. The index is constructed by demeaning each nutrient and then weighting each equally. 26 I estimate these regressions using nutrient availability of food consumed at home only. 27 Additionally, the log of total household caloric intake is included as a control in all regressions other than the one in which calories are the dependent variable.

Online Appendix. Consumption Volatility, Marketization, and Expenditure in an Emerging Market Economy. Daniel L. Hicks

Online Appendix. Consumption Volatility, Marketization, and Expenditure in an Emerging Market Economy. Daniel L. Hicks Online Appendix Consumption Volatility, Marketization, and Expenditure in an Emerging Market Economy Daniel L. Hicks Abstract This appendix presents additional results that are referred to in the main

More information

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM August 2015 151 Slater Street, Suite 710 Ottawa, Ontario K1P 5H3 Tel: 613-233-8891 Fax: 613-233-8250 csls@csls.ca CENTRE FOR THE STUDY OF LIVING STANDARDS SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING

More information

A simple model of risk-sharing

A simple model of risk-sharing A A simple model of risk-sharing In this section we sketch a simple risk-sharing model to show why the credit and insurance market is an important channel for the transmission of positive income shocks

More information

Measuring Poverty in Armenia: Methodological Features

Measuring Poverty in Armenia: Methodological Features Working paper 4 21 November 2013 UNITED NATIONS ECONOMIC COMMISSION FOR EUROPE CONFERENCE OF EUROPEAN STATISTICIANS Seminar "The way forward in poverty measurement" 2-4 December 2013, Geneva, Switzerland

More information

PART 4 - ARMENIA: SUBJECTIVE POVERTY IN 2006

PART 4 - ARMENIA: SUBJECTIVE POVERTY IN 2006 PART 4 - ARMENIA: SUBJECTIVE POVERTY IN 2006 CHAPTER 11: SUBJECTIVE POVERTY AND LIVING CONDITIONS ASSESSMENT Poverty can be considered as both an objective and subjective assessment. Poverty estimates

More information

Robustness Appendix for Deconstructing Lifecycle Expenditure Mark Aguiar and Erik Hurst

Robustness Appendix for Deconstructing Lifecycle Expenditure Mark Aguiar and Erik Hurst Robustness Appendix for Deconstructing Lifecycle Expenditure Mark Aguiar and Erik Hurst This appendix shows a variety of additional results that accompany our paper "Deconstructing Lifecycle Expenditure,"

More information

Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender

Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender IFS Working Paper W15/03 Guy Laroque Sophie Osotimehin Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across ages and gender Guy Laroque

More information

CRS Report for Congress

CRS Report for Congress Order Code RL33519 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Why Is Household Income Falling While GDP Is Rising? July 7, 2006 Marc Labonte Specialist in Macroeconomics Government and Finance

More information

MONITORING JOBS AND INFLATION

MONITORING JOBS AND INFLATION 21 MONITORING JOBS AND INFLATION After studying this chapter, you will be able to: Explain why unemployment is a problem and define the unemployment rate and other labour market indicators Explain why

More information

Business Cycles II: Theories

Business Cycles II: Theories Macroeconomic Policy Class Notes Business Cycles II: Theories Revised: December 5, 2011 Latest version available at www.fperri.net/teaching/macropolicy.f11htm In class we have explored at length the main

More information

Labor force participation of the elderly in Japan

Labor force participation of the elderly in Japan Labor force participation of the elderly in Japan Takashi Oshio, Institute for Economics Research, Hitotsubashi University Emiko Usui, Institute for Economics Research, Hitotsubashi University Satoshi

More information

THE NAIRU AND ITS EVOLUTION

THE NAIRU AND ITS EVOLUTION suggests that all signs point to continued stable growth. The final section describes the economic outlook and presents the Administration's economic forecast. THE NAIRU AND ITS EVOLUTION The nonaccelerating-inflation

More information

1. Help you get started writing your second year paper and job market paper.

1. Help you get started writing your second year paper and job market paper. Course Goals 1. Help you get started writing your second year paper and job market paper. 2. Introduce you to macro literatures with a strong empirical component and the datasets used in these literatures.

More information

CHAPTER 2. Hidden unemployment in Australia. William F. Mitchell

CHAPTER 2. Hidden unemployment in Australia. William F. Mitchell CHAPTER 2 Hidden unemployment in Australia William F. Mitchell 2.1 Introduction From the viewpoint of Okun s upgrading hypothesis, a cyclical rise in labour force participation (indicating that the discouraged

More information

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits Day Manoli UCLA Andrea Weber University of Mannheim February 29, 2012 Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence

More information

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Linda Goldberg and Joseph Tracy Federal Reserve Bank of New York and NBER April 2001 Abstract Although the dollar has been shown to influence

More information

CHAPTER 2. A TOUR OF THE BOOK

CHAPTER 2. A TOUR OF THE BOOK CHAPTER 2. A TOUR OF THE BOOK I. MOTIVATING QUESTIONS 1. How do economists define output, the unemployment rate, and the inflation rate, and why do economists care about these variables? Output and the

More information

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* Sónia Costa** Luísa Farinha** 133 Abstract The analysis of the Portuguese households

More information

THE U.S. ECONOMY IN 1986

THE U.S. ECONOMY IN 1986 of women in the labor force. Over the past decade, women have accounted for 62 percent of total labor force growth. Increasing labor force participation of women has not led to large increases in unemployment

More information

CONSUMPTION SMOOTHING AND POVERTY VULNERABILITY IN RURAL MEXICO

CONSUMPTION SMOOTHING AND POVERTY VULNERABILITY IN RURAL MEXICO CONSUMPTION SMOOTHING AND POVERTY VULNERABILITY IN RURAL MEXICO A Thesis submitted to the Graduate School of Arts & Sciences at Georgetown University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the

More information

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016)

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016) Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016) 68-131 An Investigation of the Structural Characteristics of the Indian IT Sector and the Capital Goods Sector An Application of the

More information

Time Use During Recessions

Time Use During Recessions Time Use During Recessions Mark Aguiar Princeton University Loukas Karabarbounis University of Chicago July 2011 Erik Hurst University of Chicago Abstract We use data from the American Time Use Survey

More information

2009 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study

2009 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study 2009 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study (Using November 2008 Forecast) An analysis of Minnesota s household and business taxes. March 2009 For document links go to: Table of Contents 2009 Minnesota Tax Incidence

More information

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Learning Objectives. Chapter 7. Explain how the U.S. government calculates the official unemployment rate

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Learning Objectives. Chapter 7. Explain how the U.S. government calculates the official unemployment rate Chapter 7 The Macroeconomy:, Inflation, and Deflation Introduction Why is it that the responsibility for announcing the start of economic contractions and expansions does not rest with elected officials?

More information

Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORA SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT CENTRE

Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORA SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT CENTRE Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORA SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT CENTRE Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORAMA Haroon

More information

Credit Expansion and Credit Contraction: their Effects on Households Savings Behavior in a Fragmented Economy

Credit Expansion and Credit Contraction: their Effects on Households Savings Behavior in a Fragmented Economy Very Preliminary and Incomplete Credit Expansion and Credit Contraction: their Effects on Households Savings Behavior in a Fragmented Economy Fernando Aportela * Research Department Banco de México Abstract

More information

As shown in chapter 2, output volatility continues to

As shown in chapter 2, output volatility continues to 5 Dealing with Commodity Price, Terms of Trade, and Output Risks As shown in chapter 2, output volatility continues to be significantly higher for most developing countries than for developed countries,

More information

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings Upjohn Institute Policy Papers Upjohn Research home page 2011 The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings Leslie A. Muller Hope College

More information

The labor market in Australia,

The labor market in Australia, GARRY BARRETT University of Sydney, Australia, and IZA, Germany The labor market in Australia, 2000 2016 Sustained economic growth led to reduced unemployment and real earnings growth, but prosperity has

More information

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market An overview of the South African labour market from 3 of 2010 to of 2011 September 2011 Contents Recent labour market trends... 2 A brief labour

More information

Challenges For the Future of Chinese Economic Growth. Jane Haltmaier* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. August 2011.

Challenges For the Future of Chinese Economic Growth. Jane Haltmaier* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. August 2011. Challenges For the Future of Chinese Economic Growth Jane Haltmaier* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System August 2011 Preliminary *Senior Advisor in the Division of International Finance. Mailing

More information

Did the Social Assistance Take-up Rate Change After EI Reform for Job Separators?

Did the Social Assistance Take-up Rate Change After EI Reform for Job Separators? Did the Social Assistance Take-up Rate Change After EI for Job Separators? HRDC November 2001 Executive Summary Changes under EI reform, including changes to eligibility and length of entitlement, raise

More information

Additional Slack in the Economy: The Poor Recovery in Labor Force Participation During This Business Cycle

Additional Slack in the Economy: The Poor Recovery in Labor Force Participation During This Business Cycle No. 5 Additional Slack in the Economy: The Poor Recovery in Labor Force Participation During This Business Cycle Katharine Bradbury This public policy brief examines labor force participation rates in

More information

The Aggregate Implications of Regional Business Cycles

The Aggregate Implications of Regional Business Cycles The Aggregate Implications of Regional Business Cycles Martin Beraja Erik Hurst Juan Ospina University of Chicago University of Chicago University of Chicago Fall 2017 This Paper Can we use cross-sectional

More information

2007 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study

2007 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study 2007 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study (Using November 2006 Forecast) An analysis of Minnesota s household and business taxes. March 2007 2007 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study Analysis of Minnesota s household

More information

The Productivity to Paycheck Gap: What the Data Show

The Productivity to Paycheck Gap: What the Data Show The Productivity to Paycheck Gap: What the Data Show The Real Cause of Lagging Wages Dean Baker April 2007 Center for Economic and Policy Research 1611 Connecticut Avenue, NW, Suite 400 Washington, D.C.

More information

The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital

The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital Audra Bowlus and Chris Robinson University of Western Ontario Presentation at Craig Riddell s Festschrift UBC, September 2016 Introduction and Motivation

More information

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market An overview of the South African labour market for the Year ending 2011 5 May 2012 Contents Recent labour market trends... 2 A labour market

More information

Issues in the Measurement and Construction of the Consumer Price Index in Pakistan

Issues in the Measurement and Construction of the Consumer Price Index in Pakistan WORKING PAPER No. 020 August 2014 Issues in the Measurement and Construction of the Consumer Price Index in Pakistan Sohail Jehangir Malik, Hina Nazli, Amina Mehmood and Asma Shahzad 8/20/2014 1. INTRODUCTION

More information

The Composition Effect of Consumption around Retirement: Evidence from Singapore

The Composition Effect of Consumption around Retirement: Evidence from Singapore The Composition Effect of Consumption around Retirement: Evidence from Singapore By SUMIT AGARWAL, JESSICA PAN AND WENLAN QIAN* * Agarwal: National University of Singapore, 15 Kent Ridge Drive, NUS Business

More information

Working Paper No Accounting for the unemployment decrease in Australia. William Mitchell 1. April 2005

Working Paper No Accounting for the unemployment decrease in Australia. William Mitchell 1. April 2005 Working Paper No. 05-04 Accounting for the unemployment decrease in Australia William Mitchell 1 April 2005 Centre of Full Employment and Equity The University of Newcastle, Callaghan NSW 2308, Australia

More information

Labour. Overview Latin America and the Caribbean. Executive Summary. ILO Regional Office for Latin America and the Caribbean

Labour. Overview Latin America and the Caribbean. Executive Summary. ILO Regional Office for Latin America and the Caribbean 2017 Labour Overview Latin America and the Caribbean Executive Summary ILO Regional Office for Latin America and the Caribbean Executive Summary ILO Regional Office for Latin America and the Caribbean

More information

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy

The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy The Goals of Macroeconomic Policy Dr. Ashraf Samir Website: ashraffeps.yolasite.com Contents Introduction I) The Goal of Economic Growth II) The Goal of Low Unemployment III) The Goal of Low Inflation

More information

Output and Unemployment

Output and Unemployment o k u n s l a w 4 The Regional Economist October 2013 Output and Unemployment How Do They Relate Today? By Michael T. Owyang, Tatevik Sekhposyan and E. Katarina Vermann Potential output measures the productive

More information

Chapter Four Business Cycles

Chapter Four Business Cycles Chapter Four Business Cycles BUSINESS CYCLES AND REASONS FOR BUSINESS FLUCTUATIONS... 4-1 Recession Phase Deflation EXPANSION, OR RECOVERY, PHASE... 4-2 Peak Phase Unemployment Chapter Four Business Cycles

More information

If the Economy s so Bad, Why Is the Unemployment Rate so Low?

If the Economy s so Bad, Why Is the Unemployment Rate so Low? If the Economy s so Bad, Why Is the Unemployment Rate so Low? Testimony to the Joint Economic Committee March 7, 2008 Rebecca M. Blank University of Michigan and Brookings Institution Rebecca Blank is

More information

POLICY BASICS INTRODUCTION TO THE FOOD STAMP PROGRAM

POLICY BASICS INTRODUCTION TO THE FOOD STAMP PROGRAM POLICY BASICS INTRODUCTION TO THE FOOD STAMP PROGRAM The Food Stamp Program, the nation s most important anti-hunger program, helped more than 30 million low-income Americans at the beginning of fiscal

More information

Household food purchasing behaviour

Household food purchasing behaviour Household food purchasing behaviour Incomes, Prices and Nutrition Rachel Griffith, Martin O Connell and Kate Smith IFS March 2012 Griffith, O Connell and Smith (IFS) Resource allocation within households

More information

Full file at

Full file at ADDITIONAL QUESTIONS Problems and/or Essay Questions: CHAPTER 2: MEASUREMENT OF MACROECONOMIC VARIABLES 1. What impact do you think that the movement of women from working in the household to working in

More information

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates Introduction 3 The unemployment rate in the Baltic States is volatile. During the last recession the trough-to-peak increase in the unemployment

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CONSUMPTION VS. EXPENDITURE. Mark Aguiar Erik Hurst. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CONSUMPTION VS. EXPENDITURE. Mark Aguiar Erik Hurst. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CONSUMPTION VS. EXPENDITURE Mark Aguiar Erik Hurst Working Paper 10307 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10307 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

China's Saving and Investment Puzzle

China's Saving and Investment Puzzle China's Saving Puzzle China's Saving and Investment Puzzle Kaiji Chen University of Oslo March 13, 2007 1 China's Saving Puzzle Why should we care about China's saving and investment? Help to understand

More information

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve Capacity Utilization As a Real-Time Predictor of Manufacturing Output Evan F. Koenig Research Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve indices

More information

Executive Summary. The CACFP and Tiering

Executive Summary. The CACFP and Tiering Executive Summary The introduction of tiered reimbursement rates in the Child and Adult Care Food Program (CACFP) concentrated program benefits more intensely on low-income children, as intended. Tiering

More information

Week 1. H1 Notes ECON10003

Week 1. H1 Notes ECON10003 Week 1 Some output produced by the government is free. Education is a classic example. This is still viewed as a service and valued at the cost of production which is primarily the salary of the workers

More information

How Much Spare Capacity is there in the UK Economy? Stephen Nickell. Bank of England Monetary Policy Committee and London School of Economics

How Much Spare Capacity is there in the UK Economy? Stephen Nickell. Bank of England Monetary Policy Committee and London School of Economics How Much Spare Capacity is there in the UK Economy? Stephen Nickell Bank of England Monetary Policy Committee and London School of Economics May 25 I am very grateful to Jumana Saleheen and Ryan Banerjee

More information

An Assessment of the Operational and Financial Health of Rate-of-Return Telecommunications Companies in more than 700 Study Areas:

An Assessment of the Operational and Financial Health of Rate-of-Return Telecommunications Companies in more than 700 Study Areas: An Assessment of the Operational and Financial Health of Rate-of-Return Telecommunications Companies in more than 700 Study Areas: 2007-2012 Harold Furchtgott-Roth Kathleen Wallman December 2014 Executive

More information

Week 1 - Chapter 3 Measures of Macroeconomic Performance: Output and Prices

Week 1 - Chapter 3 Measures of Macroeconomic Performance: Output and Prices INTRODUCTORY MACROECONOMICS Week 1 - Chapter 3 Measures of Macroeconomic Performance: Output and Prices 3.1 When is the Economy Performing Well? Broadly, we say that a macroeconomy is performing well if

More information

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Petra Gerlach-Kristen Hong Kong Institute of Economics and Business Strategy May, Abstract This paper uses unobserved components analysis to estimate

More information

Macroeconomic TOPIC Measurements, Part I: Prices and Unemployment

Macroeconomic TOPIC Measurements, Part I: Prices and Unemployment 1 Macroeconomic TOPIC Measurements, Part I: Prices and Unemployment Employment and Unemployment Population Survey In the U.S., the population is divided into two groups: The working-age population or civilian

More information

Unemployment Rate = 1. A large number of economic statistics are released regularly. These include the following:

Unemployment Rate = 1. A large number of economic statistics are released regularly. These include the following: CHAPTER The Data of Macroeconomics Questions for Review 1. GDP measures the total income earned from the production of the new final goods and services in the economy, and it measures the total expenditures

More information

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market An overview of the South African labour market for the Year Ending 2012 6 June 2012 Contents Recent labour market trends... 2 A labour market

More information

Corporate Payout Smoothing: A Variance Decomposition Approach

Corporate Payout Smoothing: A Variance Decomposition Approach Corporate Payout Smoothing: A Variance Decomposition Approach Edward C. Hoang University of Colorado Colorado Springs Indrit Hoxha Pennsylvania State University Harrisburg Abstract In this paper, we apply

More information

Figure Sarver

Figure Sarver I. Learning Objectives In this chapter students will learn: A. About the business cycle and its primary phases. B. How unemployment and inflation are measured. C. About the types of unemployment and inflation

More information

Consumption vs. Expenditure

Consumption vs. Expenditure Consumption vs. Expenditure Mark Aguiar University of Chicago mark.aguiar@gsb.uchicago.edu Erik Hurst University of Chicago NBER erik.hurst@gsb.uchicago.edu June 2004 Abstract Standard tests of the permanent

More information

Demographic Situation: Jamaica

Demographic Situation: Jamaica Policy Brief: Examining the Lifecycle Deficit in Jamaica and Argentina Maurice Harris, Planning Institute of Jamaica Pablo Comelatto, CENEP-Centro de Estudios de Población, Buenos Aires, Argentina Studying

More information

Economic Perspectives

Economic Perspectives Economic Perspectives What might slower economic growth in Scotland mean for Scotland s income tax revenues? David Eiser Fraser of Allander Institute Abstract Income tax revenues now account for over 40%

More information

How would an expansion of IDA reduce poverty and further other development goals?

How would an expansion of IDA reduce poverty and further other development goals? Measuring IDA s Effectiveness Key Results How would an expansion of IDA reduce poverty and further other development goals? We first tackle the big picture impact on growth and poverty reduction and then

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

1. The Armenian Integrated Living Conditions Survey

1. The Armenian Integrated Living Conditions Survey MEASURING POVERTY IN ARMENIA: METHODOLOGICAL EXPLANATIONS Since 1996, when the current methodology for surveying well being of households was introduced in Armenia, the National Statistical Service of

More information

Automated labor market diagnostics for low and middle income countries

Automated labor market diagnostics for low and middle income countries Poverty Reduction Group Poverty Reduction and Economic Management (PREM) World Bank ADePT: Labor Version 1.0 Automated labor market diagnostics for low and middle income countries User s Guide: Definitions

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

Household Income Trends April Issued May Gordon Green and John Coder Sentier Research, LLC

Household Income Trends April Issued May Gordon Green and John Coder Sentier Research, LLC Household Income Trends April 2018 Issued May 2018 Gordon Green and John Coder Sentier Research, LLC Household Income Trends April 2018 Source This report on median household income for April 2018 is based

More information

Unemployment Rate = 1. A large number of economic statistics are released regularly. These include the following:

Unemployment Rate = 1. A large number of economic statistics are released regularly. These include the following: CHAPTER The Data of Macroeconomics Questions for Review 1. GDP measures the total income earned from the production of the new final goods and services in the economy, and it measures the total expenditures

More information

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact Georgia State University From the SelectedWorks of Fatoumata Diarrassouba Spring March 29, 2013 Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact Fatoumata

More information

Indian Households Finance: An analysis of Stocks vs. Flows- Extended Abstract

Indian Households Finance: An analysis of Stocks vs. Flows- Extended Abstract Indian Households Finance: An analysis of Stocks vs. Flows- Extended Abstract Pawan Gopalakrishnan S. K. Ritadhi Shekhar Tomar September 15, 2018 Abstract How do households allocate their income across

More information

The Gender Earnings Gap: Evidence from the UK

The Gender Earnings Gap: Evidence from the UK Fiscal Studies (1996) vol. 17, no. 2, pp. 1-36 The Gender Earnings Gap: Evidence from the UK SUSAN HARKNESS 1 I. INTRODUCTION Rising female labour-force participation has been one of the most striking

More information

Household Income Trends March Issued April Gordon Green and John Coder Sentier Research, LLC

Household Income Trends March Issued April Gordon Green and John Coder Sentier Research, LLC Household Income Trends March 2017 Issued April 2017 Gordon Green and John Coder Sentier Research, LLC 1 Household Income Trends March 2017 Source This report on median household income for March 2017

More information

Abstract. Family policy trends in international perspective, drivers of reform and recent developments

Abstract. Family policy trends in international perspective, drivers of reform and recent developments Abstract Family policy trends in international perspective, drivers of reform and recent developments Willem Adema, Nabil Ali, Dominic Richardson and Olivier Thévenon This paper will first describe trends

More information

2011 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study

2011 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study 2011 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study (Using February 2011 Forecast) An analysis of Minnesota s household and business taxes. March 2011 For document links go to: Table of Contents 2011 Minnesota Tax Incidence

More information

When Interest Rates Go Up, What Will This Mean For the Mortgage Market and the Wider Economy?

When Interest Rates Go Up, What Will This Mean For the Mortgage Market and the Wider Economy? SIEPR policy brief Stanford University October 2015 Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research on the web: http://siepr.stanford.edu When Interest Rates Go Up, What Will This Mean For the Mortgage

More information

The State of Young Adult s Balance Sheets: Evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances

The State of Young Adult s Balance Sheets: Evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances The State of Young Adult s Balance Sheets: Evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances Lisa J. Dettling Federal Reserve Board Joanne W. Hsu Federal Reserve Board May 2014 Abstract In this paper, we investigate

More information

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates) Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates) Emmanuel Saez March 2, 2012 What s new for recent years? Great Recession 2007-2009 During the

More information

Development Economics Part II Lecture 7

Development Economics Part II Lecture 7 Development Economics Part II Lecture 7 Risk and Insurance Theory: How do households cope with large income shocks? What are testable implications of different models? Empirics: Can households insure themselves

More information

Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks

Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks Robert M. Feinberg Professor of Economics American University With the assistance of: Ataur Rahman Ph.D. Student in Economics American University

More information

Revisiting the Poverty Trend in Rwanda

Revisiting the Poverty Trend in Rwanda Policy Research Working Paper 8585 WPS8585 Revisiting the Poverty Trend in Rwanda 2010/11 to 2013/14 Freeha Fatima Nobuo Yoshida Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure

More information

Theory of the rate of return

Theory of the rate of return Macroeconomics 2 Short Note 2 06.10.2011. Christian Groth Theory of the rate of return Thisshortnotegivesasummaryofdifferent circumstances that give rise to differences intherateofreturnondifferent assets.

More information

The Regional Economist January Inflation: Ijrooo.Ijror ijnouani. By William T. Gavin and Rachel J. Mandal

The Regional Economist January Inflation: Ijrooo.Ijror ijnouani. By William T. Gavin and Rachel J. Mandal The Regional Economist January 2002 Inflation: Ijrooo.Ijror ijnouani By William T. Gavin and Rachel J. Mandal "When I was your age, I walked 20 miles uphill in the snow to get to school and a gallon of

More information

Additional Evidence and Replication Code for Analyzing the Effects of Minimum Wage Increases Enacted During the Great Recession

Additional Evidence and Replication Code for Analyzing the Effects of Minimum Wage Increases Enacted During the Great Recession ESSPRI Working Paper Series Paper #20173 Additional Evidence and Replication Code for Analyzing the Effects of Minimum Wage Increases Enacted During the Great Recession Economic Self-Sufficiency Policy

More information

The End of the Business Cycle?

The End of the Business Cycle? to look at not only how much we save, but also at how that saving is invested and how productive that investment is. Much saving goes ultimately into business investment, where it raises future productivity

More information

EXPENDITURE APPROACH: The expenditures on all final goods and services made by all sectors of the economy are added to calculate GDP. Expenditures are

EXPENDITURE APPROACH: The expenditures on all final goods and services made by all sectors of the economy are added to calculate GDP. Expenditures are Chapter 1 MEASURING GDP AND PRICE LEVEL MEASURING EONOMIC ACTIVITY Macroeconomics studies the aggregate (or total) concept of economic activity. Its focus is on the aggregate output, the aggregate income,

More information

Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages. Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder

Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages. Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder Introduction For most of the past quarter century, the labor force participation rates of the older

More information

How The Chained Consumer Price Index Would Affect Social Security Benefits

How The Chained Consumer Price Index Would Affect Social Security Benefits How The Chained Consumer Price Index Would Affect Social Security Benefits By Mary Johnson February 2018 How The Chained Consumer Price Index Would Affect Social Security Benefits By Mary Johnson, Social

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. Questions of this SAMPLE exam were randomly chosen and may NOT be representative of the difficulty or focus of the actual examination. The professor did NOT review these questions. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose

More information

Consumption Inequality in Canada, Sam Norris and Krishna Pendakur

Consumption Inequality in Canada, Sam Norris and Krishna Pendakur Consumption Inequality in Canada, 1997-2009 Sam Norris and Krishna Pendakur Inequality has rightly been hailed as one of the major public policy challenges of the twenty-first century. In all member countries

More information

Jamie Wagner Ph.D. Student University of Nebraska Lincoln

Jamie Wagner Ph.D. Student University of Nebraska Lincoln An Empirical Analysis Linking a Person s Financial Risk Tolerance and Financial Literacy to Financial Behaviors Jamie Wagner Ph.D. Student University of Nebraska Lincoln Abstract Financial risk aversion

More information

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018 Summary of Keister & Moller 2000 This review summarized wealth inequality in the form of net worth. Authors examined empirical evidence of wealth accumulation and distribution, presented estimates of trends

More information

PUBLIC HEALTH CARE CONSUMPTION: TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS OR

PUBLIC HEALTH CARE CONSUMPTION: TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS OR PUBLIC HEALTH CARE CONSUMPTION: TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS OR A COMMON GOOD? Department of Demography University of California, Berkeley March 1, 2007 TABLE OF CONTENTS I. Introduction... 1 II. Background...

More information

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS*

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS* Chapter 4 A FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS* Key Concepts Origins and Issues of Macroeconomics Modern macroeconomics began during the Great Depression, 1929 1939. The Great Depression was a decade of high

More information

Household debt and spending in the United Kingdom

Household debt and spending in the United Kingdom Household debt and spending in the United Kingdom Philip Bunn and May Rostom Bank of England Fourth ECB conference on household finance and consumption 17 December 2015 1 Outline Motivation Literature/theory

More information