A Quantitative Evaluation of. the Housing Provident Fund Program in China

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A Quantitative Evaluation of. the Housing Provident Fund Program in China"

Transcription

1 A Quantitative Evaluation of the Housing Provident Fund Program in China Xiaoqing Zhou Bank of Canada December 6, 217 Abstract The Housing Provident Fund (HPF) is the largest public housing program in China. It was created in 1999 to enhance homeownership. This program involves a mandatory savings scheme based on labor income. Past deposits are refunded when the worker purchases a house or retires. The program provides mortgages at subsidized rates to facilitate these home purchases. I calibrate a life-cycle model to quantify the effectiveness of these polices. My analysis shows that a housing program with these features is expected to increase the rate of homeownership by 6.7 percentage points and to raise the average home size by 21. These results are largely unaffected by the inclusion of employer contributions and rental markets in the model. I discuss the economic mechanisms by which these outcomes are achieved and which features of the HPF program are most effective. Keywords: Public housing program, Housing Provident Fund, Program evaluation, China, Life-cycle model, Homeownership, Average home size. JEL Codes: E2, E6, H3, R2, R3. Correspondence to: Xiaoqing Zhou, Bank of Canada, 234 Wellington St., Ottawa, ON K1A G9, Canada. xzhou@bankofcanada.ca. Phone: (+1) I thank Jason Allen, Joshua Hausman, Lutz Kilian and Dmitriy Stolyarov for helpful comments and discussions. The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the author and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Bank of Canada. 1

2 1 Introduction Governments around the world take measures to promote homeownership. These actions are driven by the belief that housing, for most households, is both an important investment asset and a consumption good, and that homeownership promotes social and economic stability (see DiPasquale and Glaeser (1999)). The U.S. government, for example, has fostered homeownership by encouraging subprime lending and expanding secondary mortgage markets (see, e.g., Mian and Sufi (29) and Gabriel and Rosenthal (21)). Many Asian governments, in contrast, have adopted more centralized, mandatory savings plans intended to fund households housing needs. The Housing Provident Fund (HPF) in China is one such an example. Table 1 provides examples of similar programs in other countries. The HPF was first enacted in 1999 and has been applied to an increasing number of regions within China since then. 1 The policies stipulated by the HPF apply to all urban workers, regardless of the type of the firm they work for (state-owned, collective, or private). There are two key features of this program. First, it is a mandatory savings scheme intended to fund housing purchases. Specifically, the government requires each worker to deposit a mandatory fraction of his salary to the program until the worker purchases his first house, at which point the government refunds the worker s past deposits. If the worker never purchases a house during his working life, the HPF returns all past deposits to the worker at the time of retirement. Second, the program provides mortgages at below-market rates to participants. The HPF is the largest public housing program in China, both in terms of the number of workers enrolled and of the funds deposited and distributed. According to the annual report published by the Ministry of Housing and Urban-Rural Development in China, in 215, 124 million workers enrolled in the HPF (4 of urban employment), 1.5 trillion Yuan (2 of GDP) were deposited in the program, and 1.1 trillion Yuan were lent out for home purchases and building. Although compliance with the HPF program has been limited so far, it is expected that this program will eventually be extended to all urban workers. There has been much interest in the question of how effective the HPF program has been at stimulating homeownership (see, e.g., Logan et al. (1999), Li (2), Fu et al. (2), Huang and Clark (22), Buttimer et al. (24), Meng et al. (25), Yeung and Howes (26), Xu (216), 1 For further details on the HPF and a review of the history of related Chinese housing policies, see Xu (216). 2

3 and Tang and Coulson (217)). Empirically evaluating the success of this program is not easy. There are several challenges. For example, at the micro level, workers may select when to join the program. If this decision depends on unobserved characteristics, regression estimates suffer from selection bias. Alternatively, one may exploit regional variation in the timing of the implementation of this program. To the extent that the adoption of this program is anticipated by households, however, the causal effect will not be identified. Finally, at the national level, the length of time for which these policies have been in effect is too short to estimate the impact of the program, even if a credible counterfactual could be constructed. Given these empirical challenges, a natural alternative approach is to quantify the effectiveness of the HPF program based on a calibrated model. For this purpose, I develop a life-cycle model to evaluate the expected impact of the HPF program. The use of quantitative theory also helps understand the mechanisms by which these polices affect the housing market. I focus on the effect of the program on two outcome variables: the rate of homeownership and the average home size. The baseline model captures the consumption and savings behavior of Chinese households over their life cycle. Households can choose both the timing and the size of their home purchase. Within the same generation, households are heterogeneous in that each house purchase is associated with a random transaction cost. As a result, homeownership and average home size vary over the life cycle and across households. I calibrate the model based on household survey data from the Chinese Household Income Project Series (CHIPS). The model produces a rate of homeownership that is increasing with age, and a roughly flat path of the average home size over the life cycle. I then incorporate the two key features of the HPF program into this baseline model. First, the mandatory-savings feature is captured by a parameter that represents the fraction of income to be deposited into the program. Second, the mortgage subsidies are captured by the below-market mortgage rate. I set these parameters according to the values implemented by the HPF program. Finally, I compare the life-cycle path of homeownership and of the average home size with the corresponding paths in the baseline model. The objective is to capture the steady state effects of the HPF policies on housing demand when all urban workers are covered by this program. My analysis shows that a housing program with these features is expected to increase the rate of homeownership by 6.7 percentage points, which is equivalent to a 11 increase in the 3

4 homeownership rate relative to the baseline model. This increase is mainly due to the fact that many young households, who would otherwise buy a house later in life or who would simply choose never to buy a house, under this program choose to become homeowners. In addition, the average home size increases by 21 relative to the baseline model. This effect is driven by an increase in the size of new homes purchased in all age groups. My analysis also helps us understand which features of the HPF program are most effective. Two additional policy experiments shed light on this question. First, I consider a housing program that requires mandatory savings, but that does not offer mortgages at below-market rates. Second, I consider a program that offers subsidized mortgages, but that does not require mandatory savings. The first experiment shows that the mandatory-savings feature, as currently implemented in the HPF, has no impact on home purchase and consumption behavior. This is because when the mandatory savings are below the optimal savings in the absence of the policy, households keep the sum of their private and mandatory savings equal to the optimal savings in the absence of the policy. Since other conditions such as income, transaction costs and prices are unchanged, households make exactly the same decisions on home purchase and consumption. In contrast, the second experiment shows that the subsidized mortgages create a wealth effect by allowing households to borrow at a lower cost. This effect drives more households to purchase a house earlier in their life and to purchase a larger house. There are several ways of making the life-cycle model more realistic. For example, employers are often required by the government to contribute to workers HPF savings. Depending on how much an employers contributes, workers may change their home purchase decisions accordingly. Moreover, the baseline model abstracts from the existence of rental markets and renters choices. In Section 5, I investigate how these extensions affect the expected impact of the HPF program. I show that the baseline results are robust to these modifications. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the baseline model and discusses how to incorporate the key features of the HPF program into the baseline model. Section 3 outlines the model calibration. Section 4 presents the results from a series of policy experiments. Section 5 extends the model to incorporate employer contributions and rental markets. Section 6 concludes. 4

5 2 Model The baseline life-cycle model is intended to capture households decisions about non-housing consumption, the timing of purchasing one s first home, and the size of this home purchase. This partial equilibrium consumption-choice framework has the advantage of allowing us to model more complicated household decisions such as discrete purchases and heterogeneous household behavior (see, e.g., Ortalo-Magne and Rady (26), Yang (29), and Berger et al. (217)). I abstract from the general equilibrium effects of the HPF program because my focus is on assessing how effective the program is at reaching its stated objectives rather than assessing its welfare implications. This approach avoids the difficult task of developing a fully specified model of the Chinese economy. Due to the presence of transaction costs and the requirement of a down payment in the life-cycle model, households first accumulate their wealth and then make one home purchase. In this purchase, they choose the size of the home. The model has two important features. First, I assume that households purchase a house, if at all, only once in their lives. This assumption appears realistic for the Chinese housing market. According to Huang and Yi (211), in 22, only 6.6 of urban households in China owned two or more homes. Second, a house purchase is associated with a randomly drawn transaction cost. This assumption creates heterogeneity in the timing of the purchase, in the size of the home purchased, and in non-housing consumption across households within the same generation. The advantage of a random transaction cost compared with idiosyncratic income shocks is that, in junction with heterogeneity in wealth within the same age group, it captures a range of additional unobserved determinants of home purchases in China such as local regulations and fees. It can be shown that the model with random transaction costs replicates key features of the Chinese housing market even in the absence of idiosyncratic income shocks. 2.1 Baseline Model The model is built on a discrete-time version of Leahy and Zeira (25) by introducing the housing collateral constraint and random transaction costs. The random transaction cost provides a source of heterogeneity across households of the same age. It captures unobserved characteristics 5

6 that affect households home purchase decisions. The advantage of this approach compared with modeling idiosyncratic income shocks within the same age group is that in China home purchase decisions depend not only on income but also on local regulations and fees. The economy is populated with overlapping generations of households whose income and wealth differ across the life cycle. In each period, a mass of households is born and lives for J periods. In the first J y periods of life, households work and earn labor income. In the remaining J J y periods, households retire and receive retirement income. Households derive utility from consuming the non-housing good and housing services. Utility is additive in the two goods. Let u(c) denote the flow utility from consuming the non-housing good, where c is non-housing consumption (henceforth referred to as consumption). Let v(h) denote the flow utility from consuming the housing services generated by a home of size h. There is a minimum size of the house, h, that generates utility. Let v(h) = for h h, where h >. v(h) is increasing and concave for h > h, and is continuous at h. Households start their life without a house. In each period, households make decisions about consumption, about whether to become a homeowner if they are not already, about the size of the home they decide to buy, and about their savings for the next period. At the end of their life, households leave their wealth as a bequest, consisting of savings and the value of their house. In the baseline model, I assume that a house never depreciates. This assumption is relaxed in Section 5, where I discuss how the depreciation rate is relevant for household decisions and for the effects of the HPF program. A household maximizes expected lifetime utility, J 1 E β j [u(c j ) + v(h j )] + β J Φ(w J, h J ). j= The second term inside the expectation operator represents the discounted utility from leaving a bequest, specified by the bequest function Φ, the functional form of which is discussed in Section 3. w J denotes the wealth at the end of the household s life. The household problem has a recursive form. The value at the end of the household s life, V J, is given by the bequest function V J (a, h) = Φ ((1 + r)a + ph, h), 6

7 where a denotes savings, p denotes the house price, and r denotes the interest rate. For lifetime period j =,..., J 1, the value V j depends on whether the household owns a house at the beginning of the period. If the household owns a house of size h at the beginning of the period, the value is given by V j (a, h) = max c,a u(c) + v(h) + βv j+1 (a, h) s.t. c + a = y + (1 + r)a a γph. The first constraint is the budget constraint, where y denotes income. The second constraint is the housing collateral constraint. If the household borrows, the borrowing amount cannot exceed a fraction γ of the home value. Therefore, 1 γ denotes the down payment rate. If the household does not own a house at the beginning of the period, V j is the maximum of the value of purchasing a home, V P j The value of purchasing a home is, and of not purchasing a home, V N, i.e., { V j (a, f) = max V P j } (a, f), Vj N (a). Vj P (a, f) = max u(c) + βv j+1 (a, h ) c,a,h j s.t. c + a + ph = y + (1 + r)a f a γph, where f is an i.i.d. transaction cost drawn from a continuous distribution F. The value of not purchasing a home is Vj N (a) = max c,a [ ] u(c) + βe V j+1 (a, f ) s.t. c + a = y + (1 + r)a a, [ ] where E V j+1 (a, f ) = V j+1(a, f )df (f ). The second constraint is the liquidity constraint, which requires liquid savings to be non-negative. The presence of the collateral constraint and the liquidity constraint jointly imply that any positive borrowing amount must be collateralized by a house. The policy function is characterized by a cut-off rule. For each age j and a wealth level a, 7

8 there exists a cut-off transaction cost value, fj (a), such that the household purchases a house if f f j (a), and does not purchase a house if f > f j (a). 2.2 Modeling Mandatory Savings One important feature of the HPF program is a mandatory savings requirement for workers who are not homeowners. Specifically, the government requires each worker to deposit a mandatory fraction of his salary to the HPF until the worker purchases his first house, at which point the government refunds the worker for all past deposits. 2 The mandatory-savings policy affects the budget constraint of workers who choose not to purchase a house. After subtracting a fraction of their income, for j =,..., Jy 1, Vj N (a) = max c,a [ ] u(c) + βe V j+1 (a, f ) s.t. c + a = (1 θ)y + (1 + r)a a, where θ is the fraction of a worker s income taken away by the program. The HPF refunds the worker for all past deposits with interest if the worker purchases a house. The value of purchasing a house at age j = 1,..., Jy becomes Vj P (a, f) = max u(c) + βv j+1 (a, h ) c,a,h s.t. j 1 c + a + ph = y + (1 + r)a f + θ y k (1 + r) j k a γph. Finally, if the worker never purchases a house during his or her working life, the HPF returns all past deposits to the worker at the time of retirement. This implies that the budget constraint for a household who has not been a homeowner at the retirement age includes an extra income term, θ J y 1 k= y k(1 + r) Jy k. Since the mandatory-savings requirement does not apply to retired workers, the household problem during the retirement is the same as in the baseline model. k= 2 After the worker purchases the first house, the HPF still collects a fraction of the worker s salary every month, but refunds this amount to the worker usually within the same month. Therefore, income is not affected. Hence in the model, existing homeowners are not affected by the HPF program any more. 8

9 2.3 Modeling Below-Market Mortgage Rate In an effort to make housing more affordable, the HPF also provides mortgages at below-market rates. These rates are set by the People s Bank of China, the central bank of China. According to the People s Bank of China, the historical spread between the long-term market mortgage rate and the HPF s lending rate is about 2 percentage points. In modeling the mortgages provided by the HPF, I assume that households have two financial assets: liquid savings that earns a market interest rate, and a mortgage debt that is repaid at the rate specified by the HPF. I consider an interest-only repayment schedule that requires interest to be paid every period, but the principal can be paid when the mortgage contract terminates at the end of a borrower s life. Allowing two financial assets adds an additional state variable to the model, which greatly increases the computational cost of solving the model. The value V J at the end of the household s life becomes ( ) V J (a, h, b) = Φ (1 + r)a + ph (1 + r b )b, h, where a denotes liquid savings, r denotes the market interest rate, b denotes the amount of mortgage debt, and r b denotes the mortgage rate set by the HPF. For lifetime period j =,..., J 1, the value V j depends on whether the household owns a house and a mortgage at the beginning of the period, V j (a, h, b), if h > V j = V j (a, f), if h =, where V j (a, h, b) = max c,a u(c) + v(h) + βv j+1 (a, h, b ) s.t. c + a = y + (1 + r)a M a b = (1 + r b )b M, where M is the periodic interest repayment. b is the mortgage debt at the beginning of the next period. The liquidity constraint applies to liquid savings. 9

10 If the household does not own a house at the beginning of the period, V j is the maximum between the value of purchasing a house V P j and not purchasing Vj N. Vj N is the same as in the baseline model, because a lower mortgage rate would not affect households who choose not to buy a home. V P j becomes V P j (a, f) = max c,a,h,b u(c) + βv j+1 (a, h, b ) s.t. c + a + ph = y + (1 + r)a f + b a b γph. Given this analysis, it is straightforward to combine Sections 2.2 and 2.3 to model the two program features simultaneously. The model is solved numerically by backward induction using a two-step procedure. In the first step, I discretize the state space and then solve the value functions over fixed grids of the states. In the second step, I obtain the policy functions by solving the optimization problem over finer grids, given the value functions obtained in the first step. The numerical procedure is described in detail in the Appendix. 3 Calibration To quantify the impact of the HPF program, the model parameters are calibrated. A summary of the parameter values can be found in Table 2. Age is indexed by j =,..., J 1. The model frequency is five-year intervals. Households start their life at age 21, work for 4 years until age 6, and then live for 2 years in retirement, so J = 12 and Jy = 8. Households do not have initial liquid savings, i.e., a =. The discount factor is set to β =.93. The flow utility from consumption is u(c) = ln c. The flow utility from housing services is, s ln h, if h > h, v(h) = if h h, where s denotes the utility weight on housing services, and h is the minimum home size. I set 1

11 s =.25, so that the expenditures on housing account for 2 of total consumer expenditures. This is consistent with the expenditure share of housing and household goods in total consumer expenditures for urban households in China between 1998 and 22, according to the Statistical Yearbooks published by the National Bureau of Statistics of China. I set h to 1, so that the utility function is continuous and increasing. The bequest function is Φ(w) = η [u(w) + v(h)], where w denotes the wealth at the end of a household s life. u( ) and v( ) are specified earlier. η is the bequest parameter. Since a direct measurement of the bequest motive is hard to obtain from the data, I conduct a sensitivity analysis in Section 4.5. It shows that the effects of the HPF program are not sensitive to alternative values. Therefore, I set η = 1. I use survey data from the CHIPS for 22 to calibrate household income by age group. 3 The survey collects data on household income between 1998 and 22. I obtain a smooth income measure by averaging the income of a household across these years. I then regress the log of this income measure on the first and second polynomial of the household head s age. The coefficients from the regression can be used to construct a smooth income path over the life cycle. I then take the average of the estimated income within each age group, and normalize the income of age group to 1. Figure 1 shows the age distribution of income used to calibrate the model. The down payment rate, 1 γ, is set to 22. This is consistent with the Chinese government regulations on residential housing markets during the 2s, which require a minimum down payment rate for the first home to be between The i.i.d. transaction cost is assumed to be uniformly distributed with a lower bound of zero (f =). The upper bound is set to.6 to match the overall rate of homeownership in the data (f 1 =.6). The house price is normalized to p = 1. The mandatory fraction of income to be deposited into the program is set as θ =.12, consistent with the average of the workers contribution rate across cities in China from 1999 to The 3 The CHIPS are intended to measure the distribution of personal income in both rural and urban areas of China. These survey data were collected in 1988, 1995 and 22. Individual respondents reported their demographic characteristics, income, employment, and expenditures. I obtain the 22 CHIPS data from the ICPSR at the University of Michigan. 4 The required fraction of a worker s income deposited into the program varies across cities and years. Between 11

12 market savings rate is set at r =.5, consistent with the deposit interest rate in China. In all simulations, the HPF program creates an interest rate spread of 2 percent, i.e., r b =.3. 4 Policy Experiments In this section, I evaluate the impact of the HPF program on the rate of homeownership, defined as the fraction of homeowners in the population, on the average home size, defined as the average size of all owner-occupied homes, and on expected life-time utility, in steady state. This helps control for transition dynamics as the program is introduced. First, I use the baseline model to describe household decisions on new home purchase, consumption and savings. I simulate the life-cycle choices of 1, households, and use them to construct the average life-cycle path of homeownership, home size, consumption and wealth. 5 I then show that the program meets the government s objective of enhancing homeownership: the expected increase is 6.7 percentage points. The HPF also raises the average home size by 21. In addition, expected utility increases. Since the program has two distinct features, each of which may affect household decisions differently, I also investigate the impact of these two features separately. The results are summarized in Table 3. I conclude that the mandatory-savings feature, as currently implemented, has no impact on households home purchase decisions. Therefore, the effects of the HPF program are mainly driven by the feature of subsidized mortgages. 4.1 Pre-Policy Patterns The baseline model in Section 2.1 captures some of the key features of the Chinese housing market. For example, in the CHIPS data for 22, the homeownership rate is The calibrated model generates a homeownership rate of 61. Moreover, the age profiles for homeownership and the fraction of new home buyers in the model are broadly consistent with the Chinese household survey data. Figure 2 shows the life-cycle profile of six key variables in the baseline model by averaging across 1, households within each age group. These variables include the rate of homeownership, 1999 and 215, this fraction fell in the range of 5-2 over the country, with 12 being the most commonly used value. 5 All results are robust to the number of simulations. 12

13 the average size of all homes, the fraction of new home buyers, the average size of new homes, consumption and wealth. The upper left panel captures a monotonically increasing pattern of homeownership over the life cycle. The difference in the homeownership rate between one age group and the previous age group represents the fraction of new home buyers, as reflected in the middle left panel. The youngest households, aged 21 to 25, choose not to buy a home because they have not saved enough for the down payment and the transaction cost. At age 26 to 3, about 9 of households buy a house and become homeowners. From age 31 to 4, the fraction of new home buyers keeps increasing, which explains the fast growing homeownership rate. By age 4, 43 of households are homeowners. After age 4, there are still households who become new homeowners, but at a decreasing fraction. At the end of the life cycle, only 2.7 of households never become a homeowner. The upper right panel shows the average size of all homes within each age group. Since no households in age group buy a home, I set the average home size for this age group to. The average home value to income ratio ph/y, excluding the youngest age group is 3.6, which implies that on average the home value is 18 times the annual income. Over the life cycle, the average size of all homes is gradually increasing but not varying much. However, examining the average size of new homes in the middle right panel reveals that the size of new homes is increasing with age to a larger extent. Since households who have not been a homeowner constantly accumulate their savings as they grow old, they can afford a larger house when they choose to be a homeowner. The lower left panel shows a hump shaped life-cycle path of consumption. Before age 5, consumption is increasing due to the fact households are constrained by their borrowing capacity. After age 5, consumption is decreasing because households are impatient. Wealth is increasing before age 6 as households either become a homeowner, or build up their savings to prepare for future home purchase. Wealth is flat after 6, because homeowners do not downsize their house, and because the bequest motive prevents households to dissave. 4.2 Impact of the HPF Program Figure 3 shows the life-cycle profile of four variables, homeownership, the average size of all homes, the fraction of new home buyers and the average size of new homes, in the baseline model 13

14 (solid lines) and in the model including the HPF policies (dotted lines). Under the HPF program, homeownership increases in all age groups beyond age 3. The overall rate of homeownership increases by 6.7 percentage points, equivalent to a 11 increase in homeownership. At the end of the life cycle, only.4 of households are not homeowners. These facts imply that the HPF program pushes forward some households decisions on home purchase, and stimulates some households to become homeowners who otherwise would not. These effects can be seen from the change in the fraction of new home buyers. Under the program, the fraction of new home buyers substantially increases from age 31 to 45. By age 45, almost 7 of households already become homeowners. Later in life, the fraction of new home buyers is lower relative to the baseline scenario due to the pushing-forward effect of the program. The HPF program also increases the average home size by 21. A decomposition by age group in the upper right panel shows that the program raises the average size of all homes in all age groups. This comes from the fact that the program stimulates home buyers in all age groups to choose a large home, as shown in the lower right panel. Since the program features two distinct policies, mandatory savings and below-market rate mortgages, each may affect homeownership and home size differently. To understand the economic mechanism underlying each program feature and to quantify the extent to which each feature helps meet the policymaker s goal, I conduct two additional policy experiments. First, I consider a housing program that requires mandatory savings, but that does not offer mortgages at a subsidized rate. Second, I consider a program that offers a subsidized mortgage rate, but that does not require mandatory savings. 4.3 Effects of the Mandatory-Savings Policy in Isolation First, consider the effects of a mandatory-savings program that requires participants to deposit 12 (as currently implemented by the HPF) of their income every period until they purchase a home or retire, whichever is earlier. The program then returns the participants their previous mandatory savings with interest. It turns out that this program has no effect on households home purchase and consumption decisions. Homeownership and the average home size are the same as in the baseline scenario. The intuition is that if the mandatory savings are below the optimal savings 14

15 in the absence of the policy, households dissave the same amount and keep the sum of their private and mandatory savings equal to the optimal savings in the absence of the policy. Since other conditions such as income, transaction costs and prices are unchanged, households make exactly the same decisions on home purchase and consumption. Thus, the mandatory savings feature of the current HPF program is ineffective. Figure 4 illustrates this intuition by plotting the wealth of households who are not yet homeowners when entering each age group (left), and the wealth of existing homeowners in each age group (right). For households who are not homeowners, their previous savings determines their home purchase and consumption. Under the current policy value, θ =.12, these households keep their wealth (defined as the sum of their private and mandatory savings) unchanged at the pre-policy level. For existing homeowners, their wealth determines their consumption. The wealth of homeowners consists of private savings and the value of their house, which is unaffected by the mandatory savings scheme. The reason why the mandatory savings feature of the HPF program has no impact on household decisions is that the mandatory savings are below the optimal savings in the absence of the policy. I explore two extensions where a mandatory-savings scheme can have actual impact. First, in Section 4.5, I consider alternative policy values for θ, the fraction of worker s income deposited to the program. I show that a high value of θ can distort household decisions. Second, in Section 5.1, I consider the case that employers can match workers mandatory deposits, and home buyers are refunded with both their own mandatory savings and their employer s contributions. This additional feature affects household decisions by generating a windfall wealth effect. In the latter case, the mandatory savings feature of the HPF program is somewhat effective but remains quantitatively unimportant. 4.4 Effects of Below-Market Mortgage Rates in Isolation I now consider the effects of a program that offers home buyers a mortgage rate below the market rate. This program replicates all the effects under the HPF program, as shown in Figure 3. Both homeownership and the average home size increase in all age groups beyond age 3. This policy affects household decisions mainly through a wealth effect brought about by the lower 15

16 borrowing cost. The wealth effect increases homeownership by pushing forward home purchasing decisions and by inducing some households to own a home who otherwise would not. Note that for households under age 3, this policy does not affect the timing of their home purchase (and hence their rate of homeownership), because at those ages most households have not accumulated enough wealth to pay for the down payment and the transaction cost. These payments are necessary to become a homeowner and to enjoy the program benefit. The wealth effect of mortgage subsidies can be illustrated by plotting the wealth and consumption of homeowners, who directly benefit from a lower borrowing cost. Figure 5 shows that the wealth and consumption of homeowners increase in all age groups when the policy is implemented. 4.5 Sensitivity Analysis I now examine how the rate of homeownership, the average home size and expected utility change for different values of the two policy parameters, the fraction of income deposited, θ, and the mortgage rate provided by the program, r b. I also investigate how sensitive the effects of the HPF program are to changes in the bequest parameter. Figure 6 plots the change in the rate of homeownership, the change in the home size and the change in expected utility relative to the baseline model as a function of θ, assuming the program also offers a mortgage rate of 2 percent below the market rate. For θ smaller than.15, the program has the same effects as in the HPF program where θ is set to.12. This result is consistent with the intuition from Section 4.3 that if the mandatory savings are below the optimal savings in the absence of the mandatory-savings policy, households keep their total savings, hence home purchase decisions, unchanged. For θ greater than.15, both homeownership and the average home size increase in θ. However, expected utility decreases. This is because when the required savings are above the optimal savings, households sacrifice their own consumption to fulfill the required savings, which leads to over-save. Later in life, households have more wealth due to the transfer of income from early life. This transfer of income increases the probability of buying a home and raises demand for a larger house. As θ increases further, households are forced to shift more of their income to later life, leading to a larger wealth effect that further increases homeownership and the 16

17 size of the home purchased. The increased homeownership and increased home size, however, come at the cost of lower expected utility, as households find it more difficult to smooth consumption. This point is illustrated in Figure 7, which plots the optimal savings of non-homeowners in the absence of mandatory savings, and their total savings under alternative θ. For θ greater than.15, total savings is above optimal savings, and hence creates distortion in consumption and home purchase decisions. Figure 8 shows the results of a similar exercise with θ fixed at.12 and the mortgage rate taking different values. The horizontal axes illustrate the intensity of these changes by a spread between the market interest rate and the subsidized mortgage rate. When the spread is zero, the policy boils down to a mandatory savings program, so the impact is zero. As the spread increases, homeownership, average home size and expected utility increase. These results are due to the wealth effect created by the lower borrowing cost. Households push forward their home purchase in response to this wealth effect, and they can afford a larger home as the interest rate spread increases. The wealth effect also raises consumption. Therefore, expected utility goes up as the spread increases. Since a direct measurement of the bequest motive is hard to obtain from the data, I now examine how sensitive the effects of the HPF program are to the change in the bequest parameter, η. I first recompute the baseline model for a given value of η as the pre-policy scenario. I then compute the model with this value of η under the HPF polices (θ =.12, r r b =.2). Figure 9 shows that homeownership, average home size and expected utility do not change much with different values of the bequest parameter. Based on the previous analysis, the HPF program affects overall homeownership mainly by pushing forward young households home purchase decisions. Young households, however, are less sensitive to the change at the end of the life cycle, such as a change in the utility weight of leaving a bequest. Therefore, changing the bequest parameter does not have much effect on homeownership. The HPF program also increases the average home size, mainly through the wealth effect, whether households value their bequest or not. Such increase is not sensitive to the change in the bequest parameter. 17

18 5 Extensions In this section, I consider two extensions to the model in Section 2 intended to make the model more realistic. First, I allow employers to contribute to worker s HPF savings by matching a fraction of workers HPF deposits. Second, I model rental markets and renters choices explicitly. I show that the results in Section 4 are robust to these extensions. 5.1 Employer Contributions Often, the employer of a program participant is required by the government to contribute to the participant s HPF savings. Both the worker s deposits and the employer s contributions are refunded to the worker with interest when the worker purchases a house or retires, whichever is earlier. How much an employer contributes, however, is chosen by the employer, and varies according to local regulations and the employer s profit condition. The HPF program requires that the amount the employer contributes to the worker s HPF savings should not exceed the worker s own deposits into the program. This additional contribution from employers is not accounted for in Section 2. In this section, I model the employer contribution by assuming that an employer has to match x of the worker s deposit, where x 1. Therefore, the total deposit of the worker to the program in period t is (1 + x) θy t. The case x = corresponds to no employer contributions, as modeled earlier. The case x = 1 means that the employer matches the worker s contribution dollar by dollar. First consider the program with a mandatory savings feature only, in which workers deposit 12 of their income to the program, consistent with the baseline calibration. In addition, let employers contribute to workers savings by matching x of their deposits. Both a worker s deposits and the contribution from his or her employer are refunded with interest when the worker purchases a house or retires, whichever is earlier. However, this program does not offer a subsidized mortgage rate. Figure 1 shows the results for this exercise. The left panel shows the change in homeownership in each age group as employers match 2, 4 and 6 of workers deposit, relative to no employer 18

19 contributions. When employers match 2 of workers deposits, the rate of homeownership is lower for young age groups. It gradually converges to the no-contribution case toward the end of the life cycle. This implies that employer contributions delay households decisions to purchase a home. This result is expected because workers treat their employer s contributions as windfall income, when they withdraw their program savings. This windfall income is larger if a worker deposits his or her own income for a longer time. Since no deposit can be made to the program once a worker buys a house, the worker may delay the purchase, and buy a larger house later when he or she can receive more windfall income. This delay effect is stronger as the contribution from employers increases. On the other hand, as shown in the right panel, buyers choose a larger home as the employer contribution increases, because they have more cash available. The lower panel of Table 4 summarizes the change in overall homeownership and the average home size for this exercise. Next, I reintroduce the below-market mortgage rate feature and quantify how much employer contributions can alter the effects of the HPF program. Figure 11 shows the change in homeownership and the average home size when the HPF program is characterized by a 2, 4 and 6 matching deposit from employers. The intuition from the earlier exercise survives here: households delay their home purchases in expecting a larger future windfall income from employer contributions. When they buy a house, they choose a larger size. The quantitative results are summarized in the upper panel of Table 4. To sum up, the results on the average home size are similar to Section 4, and the results on homeownership is similar if the matching deposit made by employers are small. To the extent that x is large on average, the average home size remains similar to Section 4, but the rate of homeownership decreases, making the program less effective. 5.2 Rental Markets In this section, I model the rental option explicitly by allowing households who are not homeowners to choose their housing services in the rental markets. 6 Unlike purchasing a home, renters can adjust their housing services without paying a transaction cost. However, the rental cost can be expensive relative to owner-occupied housing. This motivates renters to become homeowners. 6 Models in the previous sections can be considered as incorporating a simple rental market which provides houses of a size less than h, and the rental cost on such housing is negligible. 19

20 With rental markets, households who do not own a house can choose a rental house of size d at a unit rental cost of R per period. The flow utility of renters is u(c) + v(d). There is a minimum size of the rental house, d >, that generates utility. Therefore, v(d) = for d d. Households make other decisions such as home purchases and consumption as in Section 2. The model now has a new parameter to calibrate, the rental cost R. In the CHIPS data, homeowners report their own home value. They also give an estimate of how much they expect to charge if they rent their home out. The ratio of these two variables gives an empirical rent to price ratio, R/P, which pins down the value of R. In the data, R/P =.1 7. Figure 12 illustrates the key variables in the baseline model with rental markets. Incorporating this additional sector does not change household behavior much: homeownership and the average home size are monotonically increasing over the life cycle. Consumption exhibits a hump shape. Wealth is increasing at a faster rate early in life than later, and flattens out after retirement. Homeowners choose a larger home size than renters, because the rental cost is more expensive, and because renters have to accumulate their savings for being a homeowner in the future. Table 5 summarizes the steady-state impact of the HPF program in the model with rental markets. The program increases the rate of homeownership by about 8 percentage points and raises the average home size by 2, In addition, expected utility increases. I then examine the effects of each program feature in isolation. The mandatory-savings feature does affect household choices slightly, and increases both homeownership and home size. Unlike in the model of Section 2.2, households who are not homeowners have to pay for their rental services and hence reduce their optimal savings in the absence of the mandatory savings requirement. Therefore, the same policy rate of θ now can cause households to oversave, and distort home purchase decisions as discussed in the first sensitivity analysis. However, the effects from the mandatory-savings feature are negligible, as the program effects are mainly driven by the feature of below-market rate mortgages. This analysis shows that the results in Section 4 are robust to adding the rental markets that represent the current rental market conditions in China. Do the effects of the HPF program differ if alternative rental market conditions are considered? 7 r+δ Note that this empirical rent to price ratio is higher than the user cost of owner-occupied housing,, where β(1+r) δ is the housing depreciation rate, assumed to be zero in the model. This user cost is about.5 using the calibrated value of r and β 2

21 It can be shown that the more attractive the rental option is in the baseline scenario, the more effective the HPF policies are in raising homeownership and home size. First, I consider the effects of the HPF program when the rental cost increases. Second, I consider the effects of the HPF program when the user cost of owner-occupied housing increases. The intuition is that when the rental option is more attractive in the baseline scenario, more households stay renters and the rate of homeownership is lower. Therefore, the extent to which the program can stimulate home purchases is larger. Figure 13 shows how effective the HPF program is in increasing homeownership and the average home size for different rental costs. When the rental cost is small, more households choose to be renters in the baseline model, the rate of homeownership is low, and the average home size is small. In this case, the HPF program is more effective in raising homeownership. Since home buyers tend to choose larger homes than renters, the average home size is also larger. Figure 14 shows how effective the HPF program is when the housing depreciation rate changes. 8 This change leads to a change in the user cost of owner-occupied housing. As δ increases, owner-occupied housing is less attractive than rental housing, more households choose to be renters, and the rate of homeownership and the average home size is low. Therefore, the HPF program is more effective. 6 Conclusion There has been much interest in the question of how the HPF has affected homeownership in China. This question is of interest not only to Chinese authorities but to policymakers more broadly, because similar policies have been implemented in a range of countries. Addressing this question empirically is not straightforward because of selection bias, because of anticipation effects, and because of the short duration of this program to date. An alternative approach to quantifying the expected effects of this program is the use of quantitative theory. Existing theoretical studies of this question have relied on representative-agent models (see., e.g., Buttimer et al. (24) and Tang and Coulson (217)). Such models are not well-suited for studying the effect of these policies, because in representative-agent models either everyone or no one buys a house. The current paper introduces a life-cycle model with heterogeneous 8 To maintain the size of their home as in the previous period, homeowners have to spend on the cost of depreciation, i.e., δph. In earlier sections, δ is assumed to be zero. 21

22 agents that allows agents purchases of homes to depend on their age and unobserved characteristics. This model allows me to quantify the increase in homeownership one would expect in response to this program. I show that the HPF program is expected to increase the rate of homeownership by 6.7 percentage points in steady state. It also increases the average size of homes. These results are robust to allowing employers to match the workers contributions and to introducing the rental markets. One advantage of addressing this question based on a quantitative model is a better understanding of the mechanisms by which these policies affect economic outcomes. I find that the mandatory savings feature, as currently implemented, has no impact on household home purchase decisions because the mandatory savings are below the optimal savings in the absence of the policy. In this situation, households keep the sum of their private and mandatory savings equal to the optimal savings in the pre-policy scenario. Since other conditions such as income, transaction costs and prices are unchanged, households make exactly the same decisions on home purchases and consumption. Regardless of how long households are forced to save, the program also provides access to subsidized mortgages, which stimulate more households to become homeowners, and to purchase a larger home. This feature alone accounts for all of the estimated effects of the HPF program. However, households ability to take advantage of these mortgage subsidies depends on unobserved characteristics. In the calibrated model, the fraction of participating households who are unable to buy a house by the end of their life time is about.4. Although the model presented in this paper is more realistic than previous theoretical models of Chinese housing policies, the analysis in this paper is only a first step. I showed that the modeling device of a random transaction cost for potential home buyers in conjunction with heterogeneity in wealth within the same age group suffices to match some of the key features of the Chinese housing market. The model abstracts from heterogeneity in family size. This simplifying assumption is unproblematic to the extent that the one-child policy has largely eliminated this problem and that current efforts to increase population growth thus far have had little effect. An implicit assumption underlying my analysis is that the supply of housing is elastic. This assumption is supported by evidence in Wang et al. (212) whose estimates of the price elasticity 22

Home Equity Extraction and the Boom-Bust Cycle in Consumption and Residential Investment

Home Equity Extraction and the Boom-Bust Cycle in Consumption and Residential Investment Home Equity Extraction and the Boom-Bust Cycle in Consumption and Residential Investment Xiaoqing Zhou Bank of Canada January 22, 2018 Abstract The consumption boom-bust cycle in the 2000s coincided with

More information

Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership

Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership Kamila Sommer Paul Sullivan August 2017 Federal Reserve Board of Governors, email: kv28@georgetown.edu American

More information

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Minchung Hsu Pei-Ju Liao GRIPS Academia Sinica October 15, 2010 Abstract This paper aims to discover the impacts

More information

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel Martin Eichenbaum, Sergio Rebelo, and Arlene Wong May 2018 Motivation In the US, bulk of household borrowing is in fixed rate mortgages with

More information

Notes for Econ202A: Consumption

Notes for Econ202A: Consumption Notes for Econ22A: Consumption Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas UC Berkeley Fall 215 c Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, 215, ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. Disclaimer: These notes are riddled with inconsistencies, typos and

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Consumer Spending and Aggregate Shocks

Consumer Spending and Aggregate Shocks Consumer Spending and Aggregate Shocks by Xiaoqing Zhou A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy (Economics) in the University of Michigan

More information

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Matthias Doepke UCLA Martin Schneider NYU and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Abstract This paper shows that a zero-sum redistribution

More information

Consumption and House Prices in the Great Recession: Model Meets Evidence

Consumption and House Prices in the Great Recession: Model Meets Evidence Consumption and House Prices in the Great Recession: Model Meets Evidence Greg Kaplan Kurt Mitman Gianluca Violante MFM 9-10 March, 2017 Outline 1. Overview 2. Model 3. Questions Q1: What shock(s) drove

More information

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Yan Bai University of Rochester NBER Dan Lu University of Rochester Xu Tian University of Rochester February

More information

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19 Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap (R&R Quarterly Journal of nomics) October 31, 2016 Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal

More information

Online Appendix for Liquidity Constraints and Consumer Bankruptcy: Evidence from Tax Rebates

Online Appendix for Liquidity Constraints and Consumer Bankruptcy: Evidence from Tax Rebates Online Appendix for Liquidity Constraints and Consumer Bankruptcy: Evidence from Tax Rebates Tal Gross Matthew J. Notowidigdo Jialan Wang January 2013 1 Alternative Standard Errors In this section we discuss

More information

On the Optimality of Financial Repression

On the Optimality of Financial Repression On the Optimality of Financial Repression V.V. Chari, Alessandro Dovis and Patrick Kehoe Conference in honor of Robert E. Lucas Jr, October 2016 Financial Repression Regulation forcing financial institutions

More information

How Much Competition is a Secondary Market? Online Appendixes (Not for Publication)

How Much Competition is a Secondary Market? Online Appendixes (Not for Publication) How Much Competition is a Secondary Market? Online Appendixes (Not for Publication) Jiawei Chen, Susanna Esteban, and Matthew Shum March 12, 2011 1 The MPEC approach to calibration In calibrating the model,

More information

Home Ownership, Savings and Mobility Over The Life Cycle

Home Ownership, Savings and Mobility Over The Life Cycle Introduction Model Results Home Ownership, Savings and Mobility Over The Life Cycle Jonathan Halket Gopal Vasudev NYU January 28, 2009 Jonathan Halket, Gopal Vasudev To Rent or To Own Introduction 30 percent

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan Optimal Credit Market Policy Matteo Iacoviello 1 Ricardo Nunes 2 Andrea Prestipino 1 1 Federal Reserve Board 2 University of Surrey CEF 218, Milan June 2, 218 Disclaimer: The views expressed are solely

More information

The Zero Lower Bound

The Zero Lower Bound The Zero Lower Bound Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 4 Introduction In the standard New Keynesian model, monetary policy is often described by an interest rate rule (e.g. a Taylor rule) that

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

Public Pension Reform in Japan

Public Pension Reform in Japan ECONOMIC ANALYSIS & POLICY, VOL. 40 NO. 2, SEPTEMBER 2010 Public Pension Reform in Japan Akira Okamoto Professor, Faculty of Economics, Okayama University, Tsushima, Okayama, 700-8530, Japan. (Email: okamoto@e.okayama-u.ac.jp)

More information

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality . 1 Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality Lutz Hendricks Iowa State University, CESifo, CFS March 28, 2004. 1 Introduction 2 Wealth is highly concentrated in U.S. data: The richest 1% of households

More information

Nordic Journal of Political Economy

Nordic Journal of Political Economy Nordic Journal of Political Economy Volume 39 204 Article 3 The welfare effects of the Finnish survivors pension scheme Niku Määttänen * * Niku Määttänen, The Research Institute of the Finnish Economy

More information

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho Beggar-thy-parents? A Lifecycle Model of Intergenerational Altruism Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho University of New South Wales March 2009 Motivation & Question Since Becker (1974), several studies analyzing

More information

When do Secondary Markets Harm Firms? Online Appendixes (Not for Publication)

When do Secondary Markets Harm Firms? Online Appendixes (Not for Publication) When do Secondary Markets Harm Firms? Online Appendixes (Not for Publication) Jiawei Chen and Susanna Esteban and Matthew Shum January 1, 213 I The MPEC approach to calibration In calibrating the model,

More information

Evaluating the Macroeconomic Effects of a Temporary Investment Tax Credit by Paul Gomme

Evaluating the Macroeconomic Effects of a Temporary Investment Tax Credit by Paul Gomme p d papers POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS Evaluating the Macroeconomic Effects of a Temporary Investment Tax Credit by Paul Gomme POLICY DISCUSSION PAPER NUMBER 30 JANUARY 2002 Evaluating the Macroeconomic Effects

More information

Why are real interest rates so low? Secular stagnation and the relative price of capital goods

Why are real interest rates so low? Secular stagnation and the relative price of capital goods The facts Why are real interest rates so low? Secular stagnation and the relative price of capital goods Bank of England and LSE June 2015 The facts This does not reflect the views of the Bank of England

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy Johannes Wieland University of California, San Diego and NBER 1. Introduction Markets are incomplete. In recent

More information

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours Ekonomia nr 47/2016 123 Ekonomia. Rynek, gospodarka, społeczeństwo 47(2016), s. 123 133 DOI: 10.17451/eko/47/2016/233 ISSN: 0137-3056 www.ekonomia.wne.uw.edu.pl Aggregation with a double non-convex labor

More information

Wealth Accumulation in the US: Do Inheritances and Bequests Play a Significant Role

Wealth Accumulation in the US: Do Inheritances and Bequests Play a Significant Role Wealth Accumulation in the US: Do Inheritances and Bequests Play a Significant Role John Laitner January 26, 2015 The author gratefully acknowledges support from the U.S. Social Security Administration

More information

The Lost Generation of the Great Recession

The Lost Generation of the Great Recession The Lost Generation of the Great Recession Sewon Hur University of Pittsburgh January 21, 2016 Introduction What are the distributional consequences of the Great Recession? Introduction What are the distributional

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 207 Introduction This note works through some simple two-period consumption-saving problems. In

More information

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable outlines

More information

Movements on the Price of Houses

Movements on the Price of Houses Movements on the Price of Houses José-Víctor Ríos-Rull Penn, CAERP Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Universidad de Cantabria, Penn Tue Dec 14 13:00:57 2004 So Preliminary, There is Really Nothing Conference on

More information

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) ....... Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) Rapid Aging and Chinese Pension Reform, June 3, 2014 SHUFE, Shanghai ..... The results in this

More information

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge By Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Elena Pastorino This paper is motivated by the strong correlation between changes in household debt and employment across regions

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation Internet Appendix A. Participation constraint In evaluating when the participation constraint binds, we consider three

More information

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals Selahattin İmrohoroğlu 1 Shinichi Nishiyama 2 1 University of Southern California (selo@marshall.usc.edu) 2

More information

Natural Expectations and Home Equity Extraction

Natural Expectations and Home Equity Extraction Natural Expectations and Home Equity Extraction Roberto Pancrazi 1 Mario Pietrunti 2 1 University of Warwick 2 Toulouse School of Economics, Banca d Italia 4 December 2013 AMSE Pancrazi, Pietrunti ( University

More information

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk Vasia Panousi Catarina Reis April 27 WP 27/64 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This

More information

Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity

Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity Greg Kaplan José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Pennsylvania University of Minnesota, Mpls Fed, and CAERP EFACR Consumption

More information

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions By DAVID BERGER AND JOSEPH VAVRA How big are government spending multipliers? A recent litererature has argued that while

More information

Household Saving, Financial Constraints, and the Current Account Balance in China

Household Saving, Financial Constraints, and the Current Account Balance in China Household Saving, Financial Constraints, and the Current Account Balance in China Ayşe İmrohoroğlu USC Marshall Kai Zhao Univ. of Connecticut Facing Demographic Change in a Challenging Economic Environment-

More information

Reforms in a Debt Overhang

Reforms in a Debt Overhang Structural Javier Andrés, Óscar Arce and Carlos Thomas 3 National Bank of Belgium, June 8 4 Universidad de Valencia, Banco de España Banco de España 3 Banco de España National Bank of Belgium, June 8 4

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 April Last week two benchmarks: autarky and complete markets non-state contingent bonds:

More information

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions Mario Meier 1 & Andrea Weber 2 1 University of Mannheim 2 Vienna University of Economics and Business, CEPR, IZA Meier & Weber (2016) Peers in Retirement 1 / 35 Motivation

More information

Mandatory Social Security Regime, C Retirement Behavior of Quasi-Hyperb

Mandatory Social Security Regime, C Retirement Behavior of Quasi-Hyperb Title Mandatory Social Security Regime, C Retirement Behavior of Quasi-Hyperb Author(s) Zhang, Lin Citation 大阪大学経済学. 63(2) P.119-P.131 Issue 2013-09 Date Text Version publisher URL http://doi.org/10.18910/57127

More information

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market Liran Einav 1 Amy Finkelstein 2 Paul Schrimpf 3 1 Stanford and NBER 2 MIT and NBER 3 MIT Cowles 75th Anniversary Conference

More information

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer? AEA Papers and Proceedings 2018, 108: 401 406 https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20181116 In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer? By Barbara A. Butrica and Nadia S. Karamcheva*

More information

Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy: The Interest Coverage Channel

Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy: The Interest Coverage Channel Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy: The Interest Coverage Channel Daniel L. Greenwald MIT Sloan EFA Lunch, April 19 Daniel L. Greenwald Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy EFA Lunch, April 19 1 / 6 Introduction

More information

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation Capital Income Taxes, Labor Income Taxes and Consumption Taxes When thinking about the optimal taxation of saving

More information

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives William B. Peterman Federal Reserve Board william.b.peterman@frb.gov Erick Sager Bureau of Labor Statistics sager.erick@bls.gov February 5, 206 Abstract In their

More information

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits Day Manoli UCLA Andrea Weber University of Mannheim February 29, 2012 Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence

More information

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix Conrad Miller Contents A Extensions and Robustness Checks 2 A. Heterogeneity by Employer Size.............................. 2 A.2

More information

Interest rate policies, banking and the macro-economy

Interest rate policies, banking and the macro-economy Interest rate policies, banking and the macro-economy Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California and CEPR November 10, 2017 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract Low interest rates may stimulate

More information

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model ECON 4335 Economics of Banking, Fall 2016 Jacopo Bizzotto 1 Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model The model in Diamond and Dybvig (1983) incorporates important features of the real world:

More information

A simple wealth model

A simple wealth model Quantitative Macroeconomics Raül Santaeulàlia-Llopis, MOVE-UAB and Barcelona GSE Homework 5, due Thu Nov 1 I A simple wealth model Consider the sequential problem of a household that maximizes over streams

More information

Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation

Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation Endogenous Growth with Public Capital and Progressive Taxation Constantine Angyridis Ryerson University Dept. of Economics Toronto, Canada December 7, 2012 Abstract This paper considers an endogenous growth

More information

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility and Coordination Failures What makes financial systems fragile? What causes crises

More information

Tax Benefit Linkages in Pension Systems (a note) Monika Bütler DEEP Université de Lausanne, CentER Tilburg University & CEPR Λ July 27, 2000 Abstract

Tax Benefit Linkages in Pension Systems (a note) Monika Bütler DEEP Université de Lausanne, CentER Tilburg University & CEPR Λ July 27, 2000 Abstract Tax Benefit Linkages in Pension Systems (a note) Monika Bütler DEEP Université de Lausanne, CentER Tilburg University & CEPR Λ July 27, 2000 Abstract This note shows that a public pension system with a

More information

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Robert J. Barro 1990 Represented by m.sefidgaran & m.m.banasaz Graduate School of Management and Economics Sharif university of Technology 11/17/2013

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve Jordi Galí, Mark Gertler and J. David López-Salido Preliminary draft, June 2001 Abstract Galí and Gertler (1999) developed a hybrid

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Real Estate Investors and the Housing Boom and Bust

Real Estate Investors and the Housing Boom and Bust Real Estate Investors and the Housing Boom and Bust Ryan Chahrour Jaromir Nosal Rosen Valchev Boston College June 2017 1 / 17 Motivation Important role of mortgage investors in the housing boom and bust

More information

Margin Regulation and Volatility

Margin Regulation and Volatility Margin Regulation and Volatility Johannes Brumm 1 Michael Grill 2 Felix Kubler 3 Karl Schmedders 3 1 University of Zurich 2 European Central Bank 3 University of Zurich and Swiss Finance Institute Macroeconomic

More information

Capital Adequacy and Liquidity in Banking Dynamics

Capital Adequacy and Liquidity in Banking Dynamics Capital Adequacy and Liquidity in Banking Dynamics Jin Cao Lorán Chollete October 9, 2014 Abstract We present a framework for modelling optimum capital adequacy in a dynamic banking context. We combine

More information

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description Carlos de Resende, Ali Dib, and Nikita Perevalov International Economic Analysis Department

More information

D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME H ARM S AVERS? James Bullard President and CEO

D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME H ARM S AVERS? James Bullard President and CEO D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME H ARM S AVERS? James Bullard President and CEO Nonlinear Models in Macroeconomics and Finance for an Unstable World Norges Bank Jan. 26, 2018 Oslo, Norway Any opinions

More information

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form Saddle Path Halvor Mehlum Abstract Following up a 50 year old suggestion due to Solow, I show that by including a Ramsey consumer in the Harrod-Domar

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 Instructions: Read the questions carefully and make sure to show your work. You

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics PhD Topics in Macroeconomics Lecture 12: misallocation, part four Chris Edmond 2nd Semester 2014 1 This lecture Buera/Shin (2013) model of financial frictions, misallocation and the transitional dynamics

More information

Taxes and Labor Supply: Portugal, Europe, and the United States

Taxes and Labor Supply: Portugal, Europe, and the United States Taxes and Labor Supply: Portugal, Europe, and the United States André C. Silva Nova School of Business and Economics April 2008 Abstract I relate hours worked with taxes on consumption and labor for Portugal,

More information

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment Margarita Rubio 1 Fang Yao 2 1 University of Nottingham 2 Reserve Bank of New Zealand. The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect

More information

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel Appendix to: Why Do Demand Curves for Stocks Slope Down? AMoreElaborateModel Antti Petajisto Yale School of Management February 2004 1 A More Elaborate Model 1.1 Motivation Our earlier model provides a

More information

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Introduction Intermediate Macroeconomics Consumption/Saving, Ricardian

More information

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University.

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University. The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil Brown University December 2007 Goal: analyze quantitatively the economic effects of interventions

More information

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES 1. REVIEW: SMALL TAXES SMALL DEADWEIGHT LOSS Static analysis suggests that deadweight loss from taxation at rate τ is 0(τ 2 ) that is, that for small tax rates the

More information

Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach. QSPS Summer Workshop 2016 May 19-21

Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach. QSPS Summer Workshop 2016 May 19-21 Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach Roozbeh Hosseini University of Georgia Ali Shourideh Wharton School QSPS Summer Workshop 2016 May 19-21 Roozbeh Hosseini(UGA) 0 of 34 Background and Motivation

More information

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A.

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A. THE INVISIBLE HAND OF PIRACY: AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE INFORMATION-GOODS SUPPLY CHAIN Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A. {antino@iu.edu}

More information

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame Consumption ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2016 1 / 36 Microeconomics of Macro We now move from the long run (decades and longer) to the medium run

More information

1 The Solow Growth Model

1 The Solow Growth Model 1 The Solow Growth Model The Solow growth model is constructed around 3 building blocks: 1. The aggregate production function: = ( ()) which it is assumed to satisfy a series of technical conditions: (a)

More information

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Problem Set 2: Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Exercise 2.1: An infinite horizon problem with perfect foresight In this exercise we will study at a discrete-time version of Ramsey

More information

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom WP//8 Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom Dennis Botman and Keiko Honjo International Monetary Fund WP//8 IMF Working Paper European Department and Fiscal Affairs Department Options

More information

Reverse Mortgage Design

Reverse Mortgage Design Netspar International Pension Workshop Amsterdam, 28-30 January 2015 Reverse Mortgage Design Joao F. Cocco London Business School Paula Lopes London School of Economics Increasing concerns about the sustainability

More information

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Kenichi Ueda* *The University of Tokyo PRI-ADBI Joint Workshop January 13, 2017 The views are those of the author and should not be attributed

More information

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE Macroeconomic Dynamics, (9), 55 55. Printed in the United States of America. doi:.7/s6559895 ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE KEVIN X.D. HUANG Vanderbilt

More information

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions. Suppose that a representative consumer receives an endowment of a non-storable consumption good. The endowment evolves exogenously according to ln

More information

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Postponed exam: ECON4310 Macroeconomic Theory Date of exam: Monday, December 14, 2015 Time for exam: 09:00 a.m. 12:00 noon The problem set covers 13 pages (incl.

More information

EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced)

EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced) EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced) Consumption Nicole Kuschy January 17, 2011 Course Organization Contact time: Lectures: Monday, 15:00-16:00 Friday, 10:00-11:00 Class: Thursday, 13:00-14:00 (week 17-25)

More information

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame Consumption ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2018 1 / 27 Readings GLS Ch. 8 2 / 27 Microeconomics of Macro We now move from the long run (decades

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Inflation, Nominal Debt, Housing, and Welfare

Inflation, Nominal Debt, Housing, and Welfare Inflation, Nominal Debt, Housing, and Welfare Shutao Cao Bank of Canada Césaire A. Meh Bank of Canada José Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Yaz Terajima

More information

Health Insurance Reform: The impact of a Medicare Buy-In

Health Insurance Reform: The impact of a Medicare Buy-In 1/ 46 Motivation Life-Cycle Model Calibration Quantitative Analysis Health Insurance Reform: The impact of a Medicare Buy-In Gary Hansen (UCLA) Minchung Hsu (GRIPS) Junsang Lee (KDI) October 7, 2011 Macro-Labor

More information