Aggregate labor market outcomes: The roles of choice and chance

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Aggregate labor market outcomes: The roles of choice and chance"

Transcription

1 Quantitative Economics 1(2010), / Aggregate labor market outcomes: The roles of choice and chance PER KRUSELL IIES, CAERP, CEPR, and NBER TOSHIHIKO MUKOYAMA University of Virginia and CIREQ RICHARD ROGERSON Arizona State University and NBER AYŞEGÜL ŞAHIN Federal Reserve Bank of New York Commonly used frictional models of the labor market imply that changes in frictions have large effects on steady state employment and unemployment. We use a model that features both frictions and an operative labor supply margin to examine the robustness of this feature to the inclusion of an empirically reasonable labor supply channel. The response of unemployment to changes in frictions is similar in both models, but the labor supply response present in our model greatly attenuates the effects of frictions on steady state employment relative to the simplest matching model and two common extensions. We also find that the presence of empirically plausible frictions has virtually no impact on the response of aggregate employment to taxes. KEYWORDS.Laborsupply,labormarketfrictions,taxes. JEL CLASSIFICATION.E24,J22,J64. Per Krusell: Per.Krusell@iies.su.se Toshihiko Mukoyama: tm5hs@virginia.edu Richard Rogerson: Richard.Rogerson@asu.edu Ayşegül Şahin: Aysegul.Sahin@ny.frb.org Some of the material in this paper was previously contained in our paper titled Labor supply in a frictional labor market. We thank the editor, Nicola Pavoni, Naoki Shintoyo, and two anonymous referees for useful comments, as well as seminar participants at CEMFI, Columbia, Universitat Autonoma de Barcelona, USC, UCLA, the Atlanta Fed, Yale, UC Riverside, Queen s, Georgetown, Wharton, Toronto, Ryerson, Western Ontario, Stockholm School of Economics, IIES, University of Oslo, Concordia, Northern Illinois, Yonsei University, Korea University, Ohio State, Notre Dame, Penn State, Indiana, Maryland, and George Washington, as well as conference participants at the Labor Markets Conference at the IFS (2008), the Winter Institute of Macroeconomics 2009 (Tokyo), the Bewley Conference at UT Austin, and the 2009 SED Conference. We thank Joe Song for excellent research assistance. Krusell thanks the NSF for financial support, Mukoyama thanks the Bankard Fund for Political Economy for financial support, and Rogerson thanks the NSF and the Korean Science Foundation (WCU-R ) for financial support. The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Copyright 2010 Per Krusell, Toshihiko Mukoyama, Richard Rogerson, and Ayşegül Şahin. Licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial License 3.0. Available at DOI: /QE7

2 98 Krusell, Mukoyama, Rogerson, and Şahin Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) 1. INTRODUCTION Two frameworks dominate analyses of aggregate employment frictionless models that follow in the tradition of Kydland and Prescott (1982), and frictional models in the tradition of Mortensen and Pissarides (1994). While frictionless modelsnecessarily imply that changes in employment entirely reflect changes in desired labor supply (i.e., choice), the simplest specifications of frictional models imply that changes in employment entirely reflect changes in the probability of receiving an offer (i.e., chance). It seems clear that both choice and chance influence individual employment outcomes in reality; that is, at any point in time some individuals are not employed by choice, while others are not employed by chance. There is good reason to believe that these two features have interesting interactions, in that the presence of frictions may attenuate the labor supply responses in frictionless models, while the presence of an operative labor supply margin might similarly attenuate the effects of frictions. In this paper, we assess the relative importance of these two forces in shaping aggregate steady state employment. We carry out this analysis in the model of Krusell, Mukoyama, Rogerson, and Şahin (2009). That paper built an empirically reasonable model that includes frictions and an operative labor supply margin that exhibits plausible income and substitution effects. In considering the implications of the model for labor market flows, we adopt a more general view of unemployment than adopted by official statistical agencies. Specifically, we assign an individual to this state, which we refer to as generalized unemployment, if they are not working but answer yes to the question of whether they would like to work at the market wage rate. This concept of unemployment arises naturally in our model and can be connected to the data gathered by the Current Population Survey. Our emphasis on the desire to work as opposed to active search for work is motivated both by the work of Jones and Riddell (1999, 2006) regardingmarginallyattachedworkers the fact that active search seems to imply relatively little time use and the fact that many workers find jobs through friends and relatives. We use this model to ask two simple questions about the forces that influence steady state employment and unemployment. The first question is how changes in frictions affect aggregate steady state outcomes. In the simplest matching model, the level of frictions (captured by both the offer arrival rate and the separation rate) critically affects the level of both aggregate employment and unemployment. We assess the extent to which this is altered when one embeds the frictional model in a context where individuals also solve an empirically reasonable lifetime labor supply problem. Intuitively, if employment opportunities are harder to come by (or jobs do not last very long), individuals can adjust lifetime labor supply by extending the length of employment spells when employed or by accepting more employment opportunities when not employed. In our calibrated model, we find that the increase in unemployment is very similar to that implied by a simple matching model. In contrast, we find that labor supply responses greatly attenuate the direct effect of frictions on employment. Specifically,we find that a decrease in the arrival rate of employment opportunities leads to a large increase in the unemployment rate, but only a small decrease in the employment rate. We conclude that while the role of frictions for steady state aggregate unemployment

3 Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) Aggregate labor market outcomes 99 seems robust to adding a nondegenerate labor supply decision, the impact of frictions on steady state employment is significantly overstated in simple matching models. We show that this same result holds in versions of the matching model in which match formation and match termination decisions are introduced. While these extensions add an element of choice to the simplest matching model, we show that incorporating empirically reasonable income and substitution effects is of first order importance in assessing the quantitative effects of frictions on employment. Second, we use our model to assess the effects of increases in labor taxes used to fund lump-sum transfers. This issue, recently examined in a frictionless model by Prescott (2004), seems to be a simple and sharp example of how an operative labor supply margin influences steady state employment. We ask how these effects are altered by the presence of reasonable frictions. We find that the employment effects are effectively unchanged by the presence of frictions. This result holds not only for tax increases, but also tax decreases, which is perhaps more interesting since it is more likely that frictions will interfere with the desire to increase the fraction of time spent in employment. 1 We conclude that frictions do not seem to be of first order importance in the determination of steady state employment. Interestingly, in our model with frictions, higher taxes lead to both higher unemployment and higher nonparticipation, even holding the level of frictions constant. So, although the aggregate effects on employment in our model are effectively those found in the frictionless version of the model, the analysis shows that there are also effects on both the level and nature of unemployment. Our paper is related to many papers in the literature. Merz (1995) andandolfatto (1998) werethefirsttointroducefrictionsintoanotherwisestandardversionofthe growth model. A key feature of these models is that employment is completely determined by frictions, just as in simple frictional models. The model in Alvarez and Veracierto (1999)isclosertoours,sinceitfeaturesbothastandardlabor leisurechoiceand frictions, but it cannot be calibrated to match worker flows since worker flows are indeterminate in their equilibrium. Moreover, they do not ask the question of how changes in frictions affect steady state outcomes. Garibaldi and Wasmer (2005) developedathreestate model of the labor market that matches flows between the three states, but their model assumes linear utility. Ljungqvist and Sargent (2006, 2008) considered models that feature indivisible labor and frictions, but do not consider the impact of frictions on aggregate employment. Low, Meghir, and Pistaferri (forthcoming) considered a model with frictions and a nondegenerate labor supply decision. They considered a richer model of frictions and income support programs, but their analysis is partial equilibrium and they address very different issues than we do. An outline of the paper follows. Section 2 describes the model. Section 3 describes the calibration of the model and presents the implications of the calibrated model for labor market flows. Section 4 analyzes the effects of changes in frictions on steady state outcomes in a simple matching model, while Section 5 considers the same issue in some extensions of this model. Section 6 presents the results for analyzing tax and transfer programs. Section 7 discusses robustness and Section 8 discusses some issues regarding the nature of idiosyncratic shocks. Section 9 concludes. 1 AsimilarresultwasfoundinKrusell,Mukoyama,Rogerson,andŞahin (2008), but the calibrated model in that paper was not consistent with worker flows.

4 100 Krusell, Mukoyama, Rogerson, and Şahin Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) 2. MODEL The economy is basically that in Krusell et al. (2009). 2 The model has two key features. First, abstracting from frictions, it features a canonical dynamic model of labor supply in a context that features idiosyncratic shocks and incomplete markets for both credit and risk-sharing. 3 As documented in Krusell et al. (2009), idiosyncratic shocks are an essential element in allowing the model to match the key features of labor market flows. While we could carry out our analysis in the context of a model that assumed complete markets, we believe that the incomplete markets model has become a more useful benchmark for quantitative work in models that feature idiosyncratic shocks. The frictions that we focus on are the two key frictions that characterize steady state labor market outcomes in almost any search and matching model: a job separation rate for employed individuals and an offer arrival rate for nonemployed individuals. While our model is somewhat minimalist, it seems a natural benchmark for an initial quantitative assessment of how frictions interact with labor supply. The economy is populated by a continuum of workers with total mass equal to 1. All workers have identical preferences over streams of consumption and time devoted to work given by β t [log(c t ) αe t ] t=0 where c t 0 is consumption in period t, e t {0 1} is time devoted to work in period t, 0 <β<1 is the discount factor, and α>0 is the disutility of work. Our preference specification assumes offsetting income and substitution effects, which we think represents a natural benchmark. 4 Individuals are subject to idiosyncratic shocks that affect the static payoffs of working relative to not working. While many shocks may have this property, for example, shocks to market opportunities, shocks to home production opportunities, health shocks, family shocks, preference shocks,..., we represent the net effect of all of these shocks as a single shock and model it as a shock to the return to market work. In particular, letting s t denote the quantity of labor services that people contribute if working, we assume an AR(1) stochastic process in logs, log s t+1 = ρ log s t + ε t+1 2 The model is essentially that of Krusell et al. (2009). One difference is that here we assume that a separated worker must spend at least one period out of employment. The earlier paper does not perform any analysis of how frictions or taxes affect steady state outcomes. We also explore some alternative calibrations here. 3 Several papers have recently analyzed labor supply in models with idiosyncratic shocks and incomplete markets, including Floden and Linde (2001), Low (2005), Domeij and Floden (2006), Pijoan-Mas (2006), and Chang and Kim (2006, 2007). Relative to these papers, the distinguishing feature of our model is the presence of frictions. 4 The search and matching literature commonly assumes linear utility. Relative to the linear specification, the key feature of our specification is a much more substantial income effect. To the extent that the balanced growth specification is challenged by some microstudies, the issue is that the income effect is perhaps even larger (see, for example, Hall (2009)).

5 Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) Aggregate labor market outcomes 101 where the innovation ε t is a mean zero normally distributed random variable with standard deviation σ ε. This process is the same for all workers, but realizations are independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.) across workers. We formulate equilibrium recursively and focus solely on the steady state equilibrium. In each period there are markets for output, capital services, and labor services, but there are no insurance markets, so individuals will (potentially) accumulate assets to self-insure. We normalize the price of output to equal 1 in all periods, and let r and w denote steady state rental rates for a unit of capital and a unit of labor services, respectively. If a worker with productivity s choosesto work, then he or she would contribute s units of labor services and therefore earn ws in labor income. We assume that individual capital holdings must be nonnegative or, equivalently, that individuals are not allowed to borrow. There is a government that taxes labor income at constant rate τ and uses the proceeds to finance a lump-sum transfer payment T subject to a period-by-period balanced budget constraint. In a later section, we also consider a stylized unemployment insurance system. In steady state, the period budget equation for an individual with k t units of capital and productivity s t is given by c t + k t+1 = rk t + (1 τ)ws t e t + (1 δ)k t + T The production technology is described by a Cobb Douglas aggregate production function Y t = Kt θ L1 θ t where K t is aggregate input of capital services and L t is aggregate input of labor services: K t = k it di L t = e it s it di Output can be used as either consumption or investment, and capital depreciates at rate δ. Frictions in the labor market are captured by two parameters, λ w and σ, whereλ w is the employment opportunity arrival rate and σ is the employment separation rate. Specifically, we assume there are two islands which we label as the production island and the leisure island. At the end of period t 1,anindividualiseitherontheproduction island or on the leisure island, depending on whether he or she worked during the period. At the beginning of period t, each individual will observe the realizations of several shocks. First, each worker receives a new realization for the value of his or her idiosyncratic productivity shock. Second, each individual on the production island observes the realization of an i.i.d. separation shock: with probability σ, the individual is relocated to the leisure island. At the same time, each individual who began the period on the leisure island observes the realization of an i.i.d. employment opportunity shock: with probability λ w, an individual is relocated to the production island. In terms of connecting our model with the literature, it is intuitive to think of σ as the exogenous job separation

6 102 Krusell, Mukoyama, Rogerson, and Şahin Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) rate and λ w as the exogenous job arrival rate. Note that given our timing assumption, an individual who suffers the σ shock will necessarily spend at least one period in nonemployment. Once the shocks have been realized, individuals make their labor supply and consumption decisions, although only workers with an employment opportunity can choose e = 1.Anindividualontheproductionislandwhochoosesnottoworkwillthen be relocated to the leisure island at the end of period t and will therefore not have the opportunity to return to the production island until receiving a favorable employment opportunity shock. An individual s state consists of his or her location at the time that the labor supply decision needs to be made, the level of asset holdings, and productivity. Let W(k s)be the maximum value for an individual who works and let N(k s) be the maximum value for an individual who does not work given that he or she has productivity s and capital holdings k.define V(k s)= max{w(k s) N(k s)} The Bellman equations for W and N are given by W(k s)= max c k { log(c) α + βes [(1 σ)v (k s ) + σn(k s )] } s.t. c + k = rk + (1 τ)ws + (1 δ)k + T c 0 k 0 and N(k s) = max c k { log(c) + βes [λ w V(k s ) + (1 λ w )N(k s )] } s.t. c + k = rk + (1 δ)k + T c 0 k 0 3. CALIBRATION We calibrate the model as in Krusell et al. (2009), so we refer the reader to that paper for a more detailed analysis and discussion of the calibration. A key aspect of the calibration procedure is to choose parameters so that the distribution of workers across states and the flows of workers between states are similar to those in the U.S. economy. Official statistics divide nonemployed workers into the two categories of unemployed and out of the labor force based primarily on how they answer a question regarding active search in the previous 4 weeks. Krusell et al. (2009) arguedthatadifferentcriterionis more natural, and we use their criterion to assign the nonemployed into two mutually exclusive groups. This assignment is based on how an individual responds to the question of whether they would like to work if work were available. The group who answers yes to this question is larger than the group who is unemployed based on the standard definition. We will refer to our categories as representing generalized notions of unemployment and nonparticipation: to remind the reader of this difference we will use E to denote the employment state, U G to denote the generalized unemployment state, and N G to denote the generalized not in the labor force state. To have a consistent definition in the model and the data, we use this same criterion to define generalized unemployment in the data. The generalized unemployment rate is somewhat larger than

7 Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) Aggregate labor market outcomes 103 the official unemployment rate (8 4% versus 5 1%). We also compute flows among labor market states based on our definitions of the three states. As a practical matter, it turns out that this adjustment has very little effect on the transition probabilities. An additional issue to address in calibrating the model concerns the population that the model best captures. Our model has single agent households that live forever. In reality, people have finite lives and often live in multimember households. In Krusell et al. (2009), we presented transition probabilities for different choices of the underlying population sample, and argued that the model s ability to account for the flows is not particularly affected by the choice of the underlying population, although the fit is somewhat better for males than females. We present results for calibrations based on two different population samples. For our benchmark calibration, we take a broad interpretation of the model and use it to capture labor market flows of all individuals older than 16. In Section 7, weconsideranarrowerinterpretation,inwhichwecalibratethemodelto flows for males aged 25 54, and show that our key conclusions hold for this alternative calibration. Having described how we will measure flows across states in the data and the model, we now consider how to calibrate the model s parameters. The model has nine parameters that need to be assigned: preference parameters β and α,productionparametersθ and δ, idiosyncratic shock parameters ρ and σ ε,frictionalparametersσ and λ w,and the tax rate τ. Thelengthofaperiodissetto1month.Becauseourmodelisavariation of the standard growth model, we can choose some of these parameter values using the same procedure that is typically used to calibrate versions of the growth model. The features of incomplete markets and uncertainty imply that we cannot derive analytic expressions for the steady state, and so cannot isolate the connection between certain parameters and target values. Nonetheless, it is still useful and intuitive to associate particular targets and parameter values. Specifically, given values for λ w, σ, ρ, andσ ε,we choose θ = 3 to target a capital share of 3, δ to achieve an investment to output ratio equal to 2,anddiscountfactorβ to target an annual real rate of return on capital equal to 4%. Theotherpreferenceparameterα, whichcapturesthedisutilityofworking,is set so that the steady state value of employment is equal to 633. Thisisthevalueof the employment to population ratio for the population aged 16 and older for the period The tax rate is set at τ = 30. Following the work of Mendoza, Razin, and Tesar (1994), there are several papers which produce estimates of the average effective tax rate on labor income across countries. Examples include Prescott (2004) and McDaniel (2006). There are minor variations in methods across these studies, which do produce some small differences in the estimates, and the value.30 is chosen as representative of these estimates. 6 5 We calibrate to values for the period because this is the period for which we have consistent measures of labor market flows. 6 Note that Prescott (2004) made an adjustment to the average labor tax rate to arrive at a marginal tax rate that is roughly 40%.Forthepurposeofcomputingtheeffectofchangesintaxes,thisadjustmentplays no role.

8 104 Krusell, Mukoyama, Rogerson, and Şahin Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) It remains to choose values for λ w, σ, ρ, andσ ε.wechooseλ w so that the steady state generalized unemployment rate in our model (i.e., U G /(E + U G ))isequalto 084, which is the average value for the generalized unemployment rate in the U.S. data for the period We choose σ to target the flow rate from employment to generalized unemployment. Krusell et al. (2009)showedthattheabilityofthemodeltoaccountfortheflowsbetween states remains relatively constant for a wide range of values of ρ and σ ε.what mattered most was that ρ was reasonably persistent (at least 5), but not too close to being a unit root (say less than 97), and that σ ε was not too small. In their benchmark calibration, they assumed ρ = 92 and σ ε = 21 expressed on an annual basis. These values correspond to one set of estimates of idiosyncratic wage shocks for prime-aged working males, asreported inflodenand Linde (2001). A key issue for our quantitative exercises is the extent to which different specifications of the shock process influence our results, despite having little impact on worker flows. It turns out that the results are relatively unaffected by considering different calibrated values for ρ and σ ε,giventhatineach case we recalibrate the remaining parameters to continue to hit the same targets. As a result, we will only present results for this one set of values for ρ and σ ε.table1 shows our calibrated parameter values. The labor market flows in our calibrated model and the data are displayed in Table 2. A major discrepancy has to do with the flow of workers from U G to N G.Asdiscussed in Krusell et al. (2009), this discrepancy is much less if we consider male workers aged or instead of the whole population, as we will see in our alternative calibration presented later. Additionally, assuming some survey response error that causes spurious transitions between N G and U G also removes much of the discrepancy. 7 While there is room for additional improvements relative to this simple model, we feel that the match is sufficiently close to justify using this model to revisit some basic questions about the forces that shape steady state employment and unemployment. Even accounting for survey response error as noted above, the flow rate from U G to E is somewhat high relative to the data. If one is concerned about the calibrated level of frictions being reasonable, this might be viewed as an important target. Krusell et al. (2009) alsopresentedanalternativecalibrationinwhichtheflowratefromu G to E is TABLE 1. Benchmark calibration. Targets I Y = 20, rk Y = 3, E P = 633, U G E+U G = 084, r δ = 04, E U G = 021 Parameter Values θ δ β α ρ σ ε λ w σ τ Survey response error also lowers the measured flow rate from U G to E since some of the people counted in U G are actually in N G and therefore transition to E with much lower probability.

9 Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) Aggregate labor market outcomes 105 Adjusted U.S TABLE 2. Flows in the model and data. To Model From E U G N G From E U G N G E E U G U G N G N G To targeted instead of the stock of U G. While we do not report any results for this alternative calibration, we note here that all of the results presented below are effectively identical for this alternative calibration. 8 Although our calibration targets flows for the entire population, we can still contrast outcomes across different subgroups of the population in our model. Of particular relevance is the distinction between individuals who vary in their degree of attachment to the labor force. One simple measure of this in the model is the individual s value of the idiosyncratic shock s. Inafrictionlessversionofourmodelwithcompletemarkets, individuals would work when s is above some threshold. If we look at different parts of the productivity distribution, we see very different behavior of individuals. In what follows, we will contrast how behavior changes in the upper part of the productivity distribution with that of the overall population. Specifically, we will focus on the highest 42% of the distribution. In steady state, the breakdown of this group between the three states E, U G,andN G,is 920, 056,and 024.Thekeyfeatureofthisgroupisthatvirtually everyone in this group wants to work. We will see later on that this group exhibits very different responses than the aggregate. Because wealth accumulation is a key element in shaping labor supply responses of individuals in our model, it is important to assess the extent to which the wealth distribution in our model is similar to that in the data. Table 3 shows the share of wealth held by various groups in the population, both for our model and for the United States, as well as the Gini coefficient. The values for the United States are taken from Budria Rodriguez, Diaz-Gimenez, Quadrini, and Rios-Rull (2002). TABLE 3. Share of wealth owned by various groups. Gini Top 1% Top 5% Top 10% Top 20% Top 40% Top 60% Top 80% Model Data Alternatively, if we were to use a slightly smaller value of σ, our calibration procedure would produce a much smaller value for the transition rate from U G to E,sincethestockofworkersinE is almost an order of magnitude larger than the stock in U G.

10 106 Krusell, Mukoyama, Rogerson, and Şahin Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) The basic message from Table 3 is similar to that found in previous analyses of this type. 9 In particular, the model does a reasonable job of capturing the wealth distribution except for the concentration in the upper tail. Note that the presence of our transfer program improves the model s ability to fit the lower part of the wealth distribution relative to models without this feature. The Gini coefficient in the model is about three-quarters as large as it is in the data. Although our model does not capture the existence of individuals like Bill Gates, given the very small size of this group, we believe this failure is not particularly significant from the perspective of understanding aggregate labor supply. 4. FRICTIONS AND THE STEADY STATE: I.ABENCHMARK COMPARISON One of the defining features of the Pissarides matching model and its many variants is that the level of frictions plays a key role in determining not only the level of aggregate unemployment, but also in determining the level of aggregate employment. 10 Intuitively, labor supply considerations will attenuate the impact of changes in frictions on aggregate employment. The reason for this is that if it becomes harder to find employment opportunities, then workers will be more willing to continue with a job opportunity once they find it or decide to accept employment at lower productivities. The goal of this section is to explore the quantitative importance of these effects in our model relative to standard frictional models. We begin by exploring the impact of exogenous changes in the level of λ w,thatis,we evaluate the impact on the steady state of an exogenous change in the level of frictions. We are primarily interested in the extent to which the responses in our model are different than those that would emerge in a benchmark version of the Pissarides matching model. In the simplest Pissarides model, the match separation rate is exogenous, but the job offer arrival rate is endogenously determined by the volume of vacancy posting. In this model, all job offers are accepted, so the job offer arrival rate is also the probability that an unemployed worker becomes employed. If the match separation rate is σ and the job offer arrival rate is λ w,andweassumethataseparatedindividualhastowaitone period before job offers start arriving, then the law of motion for the unemployment rate is u t+1 = (1 λ w )u t + σ(1 u t ) It follows that the steady state employment rate is given by ū = σ λ w + σ We set σ = 022 as in our benchmark calibration and then set λ w so that the steady state unemployment rate is equal to 084, whichwasthesametargetthatwematched 9 See, for example, Krusell and Smith (1998), Budria Rodriguez et al. (2002), and Castaneda, Diaz-Jimenez, and Rios-Rull (2003). 10 See Pissarides (2000) for a variety of models that have this property. In addition, see Krusell, Mukoyama, and Şahin (forthcoming) andthereferencesthereinformodelswhichfeaturecurvature inpref- erences and asset accumulation.

11 Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) Aggregate labor market outcomes 107 TABLE 4. Effect of λ w on employment and generalized unemployment rates. Our Model Pissarides Model E/P U G /(U G + E) E/P U G /(U G + E) λ w = % 5 6% λ w = % 6 1% λ w = % 8 4% λ w = % 8 4% λ w = % 16 0% λ w = % 16 4% in our calibration. The implied value of λ w is 24. We will then consider equal proportional changes in the value of λ w in the two models, that is, we increase or decrease λ w by the same percentage in the two models. Although the value of λ w is endogenously determined in the Pissarides model, we do not model the source of this change. Rather, we focus simply on the consequences of such a change for employment and generalized unemployment. Table 4 shows the effects for the aggregate employment to population ratio (E/P) and the unemployment rate in the two models, for our benchmark calibration. We emphasize that the predictions of our model are very similar for different values of ρ and σ ε,andforthealternativecalibrationprocedureinwhichλ w is targeted to match the E to U G flow. In the interest of space, we only report results for the benchmark calibration, as shown in Table 4. In reading Table 4, eachrowrepresentsthesamepercentagechangeinλ w relative to the two benchmark calibrations, which by construction each have the same unemployment rate. A striking result emerges. If one looks at the responses on generalized unemployment rates, one observes that the effects are very similar across the two different models, especially for the case of decreases in λ w.moreover,theeffectsarelarge: when λ w is decreased from the benchmark setting to the lowest value in the table, the generalized unemployment rate roughly doubles in both cases. But when one looks at the employment to population ratio responses, one sees dramatic differences. In the Pissarides model, changes in the generalized unemployment rate and changes in the employment to population ratio are necessarily mirror images of each other since, by construction, all workers are in the labor force. Hence, the Pissarides model also predicts large employment responses as a result of changes in λ w.insharpcontrast,our model predicts very small changes in employment to population ratios. The change in the employment to population ratio in our model is only about one-seventh as large as the change in the Pissarides model. For example, when moving from the benchmark specification to the lowest value of λ w in the table, the employment to population ratio decreases by 8 percentage points in the Pissarides model, but only slightly more than 1 percentage point in our model. To see why the two models give such different employment responses, it is instructive to examine the durations of employment and generalized unemployment spells, shown in Table 5. Inbothmodels,adecreaseinλ w leads to an increase in the duration of generalized unemployment. The proportional changes are very similar in the two models, but the changes in employment durations are very different. In the Pissarides

12 108 Krusell, Mukoyama, Rogerson, and Şahin Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) Our Model TABLE 5. Effect of λ w on spell durations. Pissarides Model E U G E U G λ w = λ w = λ w = λ w = λ w = λ w = model, a decrease in λ w has no effect on the duration of employment spells. In contrast, in our model, the duration of employment spells increases significantly in response to decreases in λ w. For example, in moving from the benchmark value of λ w to the lowest value in the table, the duration of employment in our model increases by more than one-quarter. Another way to present this information is to see how the transition matrix across the three states is affected. Table 6 shows the transition matrices for the original calibration (λ w = 428)andthelowervalueof 2. Most of the changes are relatively small, with the exception of the flow from U G to E and U G to U G.Consistentwiththepreviouslydescribedpatterns,thereisslightdecrease in the flow from E to N G with a corresponding increase in the transition rate from E to E. It is also useful to see how frictions affect the decision rules in the benchmark model. In steady state, each productivity level is associated with a threshold level for assets, such that the worker desires to works if assets are below this level and does not desire to work if assets are above this level. As productivity increases, so does the threshold value. Figure 1 shows the contour of reservation values and how it shifts as frictions change. As frictions become larger, that is, as λ w decreases, the asset threshold becomes smaller for any given level of productivity. Finally, it is instructive to examine how the distribution of employment across productivity states is influenced by changes in λ w. Figure 2 plots employment to population ratio at each productivity level for various values of λ w.asfrictionsincrease,someemploymentisshiftedfromtherighttailtotheleft tail. Intuitively, if there are no frictions, then all workers with sufficiently high productivity will work, but in the presence of frictions, some of these workers are not able to work because they do not have an employment opportunity. It is interesting to note that even for a very large change in frictions, the increase in mass at the bottom of the productivity TABLE 6. Transition rates for different levels of frictions. λ w = 428 To λ w = 20 From E U G N G From E U G N G E E U G U G N G N G To

13 Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) Aggregate labor market outcomes 109 FIGURE 1. Effect of frictions on the employment decision rule. distribution is quite small, and it remains true that the lowest productivity workers do not work at all. 11 It is also of interest to contrast outcomes for the sample of high productivity individuals that we described earlier with those for the aggregates shown in Table 4.Table7 shows the results for this group. The interesting result that emerges is that this group responds very much like the aggregates from the Pissarides model. In particular, for this group, the responses in E and U G are close to mirror images of each other. This suggests that while the Pissarides FIGURE 2. Frictions and employment to population ratios. 11 It is important to keep in mind that our model includes a government transfer program, so that individuals do receive some income even when not working.

14 110 Krusell, Mukoyama, Rogerson, and Şahin Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) TABLE 7. Effect of λ w. High Productivity E/P U/(U + E) λ w = % 3 9% λ w = % 5 6% λ w = % 11 3% model is an appropriate model for describing what happens to steady state outcomes for a particular subgroup of the population, it is not appropriate for understanding changes at a more aggregate level. We can also repeat the above analysis to examine how the two different models respond to exogenous changes in σ, the separation shock.proceeding as above,table 8 presents the effects on employment and generalized unemployment. 12 The results are very similar to those found for changes in λ w.changesingeneralizedunemployment rates in response to changes in σ are about one half as large in our model as in the Pissarides model and the employment response is again only about one-seventh as large in our model as in the Pissarides model. Table 9 shows that the reason for the large differences in employment rate responses has to do with a labor supply effect that produces offsetting changes in employment durations. In the Pissarides model, changes in σ lead mechanically to changes in employment duration. The implication is that the large changes in σ are associated with large and proportional changes in employment duration. In contrast, in our model, decreases in σ lead to what, in comparison, are only TABLE 8. Effect of σ on employment and generalized unemployment rates. Our Model Pissarides Model E/P U G /(U G + E) E/P U G /(U G + E) σ = % 6 2% 96 0% 4 0% σ = % 8 4% 91 6% 8 4% σ = % 9 9% 88 9% 11 1% TABLE 9. Effect of σ on spell durations. Our Model Pissarides Model E U G E U G σ = σ = σ = Because the values of σ are the same in the two benchmark economies, we now consider equal changes in the two economies.

15 Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) Aggregate labor market outcomes 111 very moderate increases in employment duration. This is due to a labor supply response. When σ is high, it is less likely that an individual has an employment opportunity in any given period, and as a result they respond by being willing to work at lower productivity levels. This in turn implies less voluntary separations. But when σ decreases, the reverse is true, and individuals become choosier about when to work, leading to more voluntary separations. To close this section we think it is important to emphasize the important role of asset accumulation in generating the above results. In particular, adding curvature to the utility function is not sufficient for capturing the effects that we are stressing. To see this, note that without asset accumulation, the individual s desire to work would depend purely on the level of the idiosyncratic shock and, in particular, not on the level of frictions. Frictions would merely influence the probability of working conditional on wanting to work. Because of this, there is no labor supply response due to a change in frictions, and the key results we stress would disappear. 5. FRICTIONS AND THE STEADY STATE: II.EXTENSIONS One of the key findings in the previous section was that labor supply responses greatly attenuate the effect of frictions on steady state employment. Readers familiar with the matching literature might reasonably argue that this result is heavily influenced by our choice of the benchmark model. In particular, a key feature of the benchmark model is that given the level of frictions, there are no other margins of adjustment that work to at least partially offset the effect of frictions. While this is a property of the benchmark model, simple and popular extensions of this model, including those in Pissarides (1985) and Mortensen and Pissarides (1994), doincludeanadditional choicemarginthatmight play the same role as the labor supply channel in our model. In Pissarides (1985), when a meeting between a worker and a firm occurs, the pair receives a random draw of a permanent match quality. The optimal decision about whether to form a match is characterized by a reservation rule, that is, proceed with forming the match if the draw for match quality is above some threshold. In this setting, steady state employment will depend on both the level of frictions and the reservation value. Intuitively, if frictions become more severe, workers will become less choosy about which matches to form, thereby giving rise to a force that can at least partially offset the direct effect of more severe frictions. Similarly, in Mortensen and Pissarides, all matches start at the same high level for match quality, but this quality subsequently evolves stochastically. In this setting a key decision is when to terminate a match, which under fairly standard conditions will again be characterized by a reservation rule. In this setting an increase in frictions can lead to alowerreservationvalue,implyingthatmatchterminationswilldecrease.onceagain, this creates an opposing effect on steady state employment relative to the direct effect. The question that we ask in this section is whether our finding about the quantitative importance of the labor supply channel for employment responses remains when we compare our model with either of these extensions. We note at the outset that although one naturally expects these extensions to lessen the difference between our model and

16 112 Krusell, Mukoyama, Rogerson, and Şahin Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) the benchmark Pissarides model, there is good reason to think that a significant difference will remain. This is due to the specification of linear utility in the matching literature. In a standard model of labor supply, including the model we are using in this paper, when a worker decreases the fraction of life spent in employment, average consumption decreases, which in turn increases the marginal utility of consumption and creates an incentive for the individual to increase the fraction of time spent in employment. In contrast, a decrease in average consumption in a model with linear utility does not increase the marginal utility of consumption and, therefore, does not contain this force leading to higher employment. In fact, we will find that our labor supply channel is a substantially more powerful offsetting force than the margins present in either of these extensions. We conclude that to assess the quantitative effects of frictions on steady state employment, it is important to not only have the presence of labor supply margins, but also that the labor supply decision exhibit reasonable income and substitution effects. We proceed to describe in more detail each of the two extensions described above. 5.1 Extension 1: Adding a match formation decision In this subsection we analyze an extension to incorporate match quality. In the spirit of our earlier calculation, we consider a continuum of workers, each of whom solves the same decision theoretic problem with the following features. Preferences are given by β t [c t bh t ] t=0 where c t is consumption in period t and h t {0 1} is time devoted to work. If the individual begins period t not employed, then he or she will receive a job offer with probability λ w.conditionalonreceivingajoboffer,thewageassociatedwiththisofferisa random draw from the distribution with cumulative distribution function (c.d.f.) F(w). The wage associated with this job will remain fixed for the duration of the match. If the worker decides to accept the offer, he or she will begin the job in the same period as the offer was made. As in our earlier models, any match that existed in period t 1 ends with probability σ at the beginning of period t. The individual who lost a job has to wait one period before he or she starts receiving job offers with probability λ w.consumptionin each period is equal to labor earnings. Letting V(w)be the value of employment at wage w and letting U be the value of being unemployed, the Bellman equations are V(w)= w b + β[(1 σ)v (w)+ σu] and U = β [(1 λ w )U + λ w ] max(v (w) U) df(w) It is easy to show that the optimal job acceptance decision for this worker is characterized by a reservation wage, which we denote by w.onecanalsoshowthatdecreasesin

17 Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) Aggregate labor market outcomes 113 λ w or increases in σ lead to decreases in the reservation wage. The equation that governs the dynamics of the employment rate, e t,is e t+1 = (1 σ)e t + λ w (1 F(w ))(1 e t ) We focus on the steady state behavior of the unit mass of workers that each solve this problem, and in particular will ask how changes in the two frictional parameters λ w and σ affect steady state employment. For our numerical calculations, we consider a period to be a month, and set the values of β, λ w,andσ to be the same as in our calibrated model. An important consideration in comparing results across models is that one might expect the shape of the distribution to affect the results, in particular in the vicinity of the reservation wage. With this in mind, we calibrate this model so that the c.d.f. F(w) is the same as the c.d.f. for the stationary distribution of the idiosyncratic shock process from our calibrated model. We then choose the value of b so that the steady state employment rate is the same as in our calibrated model, that is, equal to These last two choices imply that the distribution of wages is the same in the two settings and that at least in an average sense, the marginal decision is in the same place in the distribution Extension 2: Adding a match termination decision The second extension is in the spirit of Mortensen and Pissarides (1994). Preferencesare the same as in Extension 1. As in Extension 1, we continue to assume that if a worker receives an offer, the wage is drawn from a distribution with c.d.f. F(w).However,ifthejob is accepted, it will evolve stochastically in future periods, according to an AR(1) process, log w t+1 = ρ log w t + ε t+1 where ε is an i.i.d. normally distributed random variable with mean zero and standard deviation σ ε. The timing is as follows. For any worker who was employed in period t 1, at the beginning of t he or she is subject to a separation that occurs with probability σ. If a separation does not occur, a new draw for ε is realized, at which point the worker decides whether to continue with the job. If not, he or she separates. A worker who experienced a separation has to wait one period before he or she starts receiving new job offers. The arrival probability of job offers is λ w.lettingg(w w) denote the c.d.f. for next period s wage given that this period s wage is equal to w, which is implied by the stochastic process for wages on the job, the Bellman equations are [ V(w)= w b + β (1 σ) ] max(v (w ) U) dg(w w) + σu 13 We solve the model using value function iteration. We use a grid with 10,000 points on w on the interval [ 2σ w 2σ w ],whereσ w is the standard deviation of the distribution described by F(w),andapplyTauchen s (1986)methodforthediscreteapproximation. 14 This cannot hold exactly, since employment decisions in our model are determined by both productivity and assets.

18 114 Krusell, Mukoyama, Rogerson, and Şahin Quantitative Economics 1 (2010) and U = β [(1 λ w )U + λ w ] max(v (w) U) df(w) The optimal search strategy for this individual will be described by a single reservation wage, which is relevant both for which new offers to accept and for which jobs to separate from. We again denote the reservation wage by w. Denote the measure of employed workers over wages by M t (w).thenthelawofmotion for the employment rate in this model is described by e t+1 = (1 σ) (1 G(w w))dm t (w) + λ w (1 F(w ))(1 e t ) The evolution of M t (w) is described by M t+1 (w ) = λ w (1 e t ) max(f(w ) F(w ) 0) + (1 σ) max(g(w w) G(w w) 0)dM t (w) We calibrate this model in a similar fashion. In particular, we set β, λ w, and σ as before. We choose the parameters ρ and σ ε that describe the stochastic evolution of wages on the job to be the same as those in our original calibration and we choose the c.d.f. F(w) to correspond to that of the stationary distribution of the stochastic process on wages. We then choose b so that the steady state employment rate is equal to Results We now consider the effects of changes in frictions on steady state employment. 16 Table 10 contains results for changes in λ w.thesecondcolumnrepeatstheresultsforour model that also appeared in Table 4. The next two columns reports results for the two extensions just described. The final column shows results for the benchmark Pissarides model used in the previous section, except that we have now calibrated λ w in this model so as to give a steady state employment rate of We begin by comparing the employment effects associated with a decrease in λ w, from the benchmark value of 428 to the value of 2.Inourmodel,thedropinsteadystate employment is 1 1,whilethecorrespondingnumbersforExtension1,Extension2,and 15 Once again, we solve the model using value function iteration. We use a grid with 240 values for w on the interval [ 2σ w 2σ w ] and apply Tauchen s (1986) method for the discrete approximation of F(w) and G(w w).thecomputationofthesteadystatee is more involved: we iterate over the descretized measures M t (w) and e t using their transition equations until they converged. 16 The effects on generalized unemployment in our model are the same as those reported earlier, so we do not repeat them. For the other models, all nonemployed workers are unemployed by standard interpretations. 17 As we move from row to row, we adjust the value of λ w for this specification proportionately. Moving from the first row to the third row, the values of λ w for the Pissarides model are 053, 038,and 018.

Labor Supply in a Frictional Labor Market

Labor Supply in a Frictional Labor Market Labor Supply in a Frictional Labor Market Per Krusell Toshihiko Mukoyama Richard Rogerson Ayşegül Şahin February 2009 Abstract We develop a model featuring search frictions and a nondegenerate labor supply

More information

Labor Supply in a Frictional Labor Market

Labor Supply in a Frictional Labor Market Labor Supply in a Frictional Labor Market Per Krusell Toshihiko Mukoyama Richard Rogerson Ayşegül Şahin September 2008 Abstract We develop a model featuring search frictions and a nondegenerate labor supply

More information

Aggregate Implications of Indivisible Labor, Incomplete Markets, and Labor Market Frictions

Aggregate Implications of Indivisible Labor, Incomplete Markets, and Labor Market Frictions Aggregate Implications of Indivisible Labor, Incomplete Markets, and Labor Market Frictions Per Krusell Toshihiko Mukoyama Richard Rogerson Ayşegül Şahin October 2007 Abstract This paper analyzes a model

More information

Comparative Advantage and Labor Market Dynamics

Comparative Advantage and Labor Market Dynamics Comparative Advantage and Labor Market Dynamics Weh-Sol Moon* The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the official views of the Bank of Korea. When reporting or

More information

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis Answer each question in three or four sentences and perhaps one equation or graph. Remember that the explanation determines the grade. 1. Question

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt WORKING PAPER NO. 08-15 THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt Keith Kuester Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Final version

More information

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls Lucas (1990), Supply Side Economics: an Analytical Review, Oxford Economic Papers When I left graduate school, in 1963, I believed that the single most desirable change in the U.S. structure would be the

More information

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Kenichi Ueda* *The University of Tokyo PRI-ADBI Joint Workshop January 13, 2017 The views are those of the author and should not be attributed

More information

Taxation and Market Work: Is Scandinavia an Outlier?

Taxation and Market Work: Is Scandinavia an Outlier? Taxation and Market Work: Is Scandinavia an Outlier? Richard Rogerson Arizona State University January 2, 2006 Abstract This paper argues that in assessing the effects of tax rates on aggregate hours of

More information

Gross Worker Flows over the Business Cycle

Gross Worker Flows over the Business Cycle Gross Worker Flows over the Business Cycle Per Krusell Toshihiko Mukoyama Richard Rogerson Ayşegül Şahin September 2016 Abstract We build a hybrid model of the aggregate labor market that features both

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 April Last week two benchmarks: autarky and complete markets non-state contingent bonds:

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation Joachim Hubmer, Per Krusell, and Tony Smith Yale, IIES, and Yale March 2016 Evolution of top wealth inequality

More information

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours Ekonomia nr 47/2016 123 Ekonomia. Rynek, gospodarka, społeczeństwo 47(2016), s. 123 133 DOI: 10.17451/eko/47/2016/233 ISSN: 0137-3056 www.ekonomia.wne.uw.edu.pl Aggregation with a double non-convex labor

More information

The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation

The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation Chung Gu Chee The Ohio State University November 10, 2012 Abstract In this paper, I investigate the role of operative labor supply margin in explaining

More information

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University March 2013 Idiosyncratic risk and the business cycle How much and what types

More information

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl) University of California, Davis Date: September 1, 2011 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Macroeconomics Reading Time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Directions: Answer all

More information

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of Intermediation Costs Antnio Antunes Tiago Cavalcanti Anne Villamil November 2, 2006 Abstract This paper studies the distributional implications of intermediation

More information

The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation

The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation Chung Gu Chee The Ohio State University November 10, 2012 Abstract In this paper, I investigate the role of operative labor supply margin in explaining

More information

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk Vasia Panousi Catarina Reis April 27 WP 27/64 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This

More information

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 7b

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 7b 316-406 ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 7b Chris Edmond hcpedmond@unimelb.edu.aui Aiyagari s model Arguably the most popular example of a simple incomplete markets model is due to Rao Aiyagari (1994,

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago On the Cyclical Behavior of Employment, Unemployment and Labor Force Participation Marcelo Veracierto WP 2002-12 On the cyclical behavior of employment, unemployment and

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Postponed exam: ECON4310 Macroeconomic Theory Date of exam: Monday, December 14, 2015 Time for exam: 09:00 a.m. 12:00 noon The problem set covers 13 pages (incl.

More information

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions. Suppose that a representative consumer receives an endowment of a non-storable consumption good. The endowment evolves exogenously according to ln

More information

Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis Fed, IGIER, CEPR and NBER October 2012

Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis Fed, IGIER, CEPR and NBER October 2012 Comment on: Structural and Cyclical Forces in the Labor Market During the Great Recession: Cross-Country Evidence by Luca Sala, Ulf Söderström and Antonella Trigari Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis

More information

Unemployment (fears), Precautionary Savings, and Aggregate Demand

Unemployment (fears), Precautionary Savings, and Aggregate Demand Unemployment (fears), Precautionary Savings, and Aggregate Demand Wouter den Haan (LSE), Pontus Rendahl (Cambridge), Markus Riegler (LSE) ESSIM 2014 Introduction A FT-esque story: Uncertainty (or fear)

More information

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices : Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices (2008, AER) December 5 th, 2008 Empirical motivation US PPI-based RER is highly volatile Under PPP, this should induce a high volatility

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism Árpád Ábrahám João Brogueira de Sousa Ramon Marimon Lukas Mayr European University Institute and Barcelona GSE - UPF, CEPR & NBER ADEMU Galatina

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Intrepreting Labor Supply Regressions in a Model of Full and Part-Time Work

Intrepreting Labor Supply Regressions in a Model of Full and Part-Time Work Intrepreting Labor Supply Regressions in a Model of Full and Part-Time Work Yongsung Chang University of Rochester Yonsei University Sun-Bin Kim Yonsei University Richard Rogerson Arizona State University

More information

Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment

Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment Avihai Lifschitz Tel Aviv University This Draft: October 2015 Abstract This paper develops a dynamic model of the labor market, in which the employed workers,

More information

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of Intermediation Costs Tiago V. de V. Cavalcanti Anne P. Villamil July 14, 2005 Abstract This paper studies the distributional implications of intermediation

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases Vincent Sterk and Silvana Tenreyro UCL, LSE September 2015 Sterk and Tenreyro (UCL, LSE) OMO September 2015 1 / 28 The

More information

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Problem Set 2: Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Exercise 2.1: An infinite horizon problem with perfect foresight In this exercise we will study at a discrete-time version of Ramsey

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago On the Cyclical Behavior of Employment, Unemployment and Labor Force Participation Marcelo Veracierto REVISED February, 2008 WP 2002-12 On the cyclical behavior of employment,

More information

Movements on the Price of Houses

Movements on the Price of Houses Movements on the Price of Houses José-Víctor Ríos-Rull Penn, CAERP Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Universidad de Cantabria, Penn Tue Dec 14 13:00:57 2004 So Preliminary, There is Really Nothing Conference on

More information

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Andrew Keinsley Weber State University Version 5.02 May 1, 2017 Abstract Under the assumption that different measures of inflation draw on the same

More information

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

Without Looking Closer, it May Seem Cheap: Low Interest Rates and Government Borrowing *

Without Looking Closer, it May Seem Cheap: Low Interest Rates and Government Borrowing * Without Looking Closer, it May Seem Cheap: Low Interest Rates and Government Borrowing * Julio Garín Claremont McKenna College Robert Lester Colby College Jonathan Wolff Miami University Eric Sims University

More information

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home midterm exam. 1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility The purpose of this question is to explore a labor market puzzle that has bedeviled business

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity Ctirad Slavík, CERGE-EI, Prague (with Hakki Yazici, Sabanci University and Özlem Kina, EUI) January 4, 2019 ASSA in Atlanta 1 / 31 Motivation Optimal

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 Section 1. Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Minchung Hsu Pei-Ju Liao GRIPS Academia Sinica October 15, 2010 Abstract This paper aims to discover the impacts

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring Introduction The recent Great Recession has highlighted the potential importance of financial market

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

ABSTRACT. Alejandro Gabriel Rasteletti, Ph.D., Prof. John Haltiwanger and Prof. John Shea, Department of Economics

ABSTRACT. Alejandro Gabriel Rasteletti, Ph.D., Prof. John Haltiwanger and Prof. John Shea, Department of Economics ABSTRACT Title of Document: ESSAYS ON SELF-EMPLOYMENT AND ENTREPRENEURSHIP. Alejandro Gabriel Rasteletti, Ph.D., 2009. Directed By: Prof. John Haltiwanger and Prof. John Shea, Department of Economics This

More information

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Matthias Doepke UCLA Martin Schneider NYU and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Abstract This paper shows that a zero-sum redistribution

More information

The Rise of the Added Worker Effect

The Rise of the Added Worker Effect The Rise of the Added Worker Effect Jochen Mankart Rigas Oikonomou February 9, 2016 Abstract We document that the added worker effect (AWE) has increased over the last three decades. We develop a search

More information

Unemployment Insurance

Unemployment Insurance Unemployment Insurance Seyed Ali Madanizadeh Sharif U. of Tech. May 23, 2014 Seyed Ali Madanizadeh (Sharif U. of Tech.) Unemployment Insurance May 23, 2014 1 / 35 Introduction Unemployment Insurance The

More information

Zipf s Law, Pareto s Law, and the Evolution of Top Incomes in the U.S.

Zipf s Law, Pareto s Law, and the Evolution of Top Incomes in the U.S. Zipf s Law, Pareto s Law, and the Evolution of Top Incomes in the U.S. Shuhei Aoki Makoto Nirei 15th Macroeconomics Conference at University of Tokyo 2013/12/15 1 / 27 We are the 99% 2 / 27 Top 1% share

More information

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Sudden Stops and Output Drops Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 353 January 2005 Sudden Stops and Output Drops V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Patrick J.

More information

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism RIETI Discussion Paper Series 09-E-05 Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism INABA Masaru The Canon Institute for Global Studies KOBAYASHI Keiichiro RIETI The

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

Welfare Evaluations of Policy Reforms with Heterogeneous Agents

Welfare Evaluations of Policy Reforms with Heterogeneous Agents Welfare Evaluations of Policy Reforms with Heterogeneous Agents Toshihiko Mukoyama University of Virginia December 2011 The goal of macroeconomic policy What is the goal of macroeconomic policies? Higher

More information

Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and U.S. growth

Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and U.S. growth Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and US growth Michele Cavallo Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Anthony Landry Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas October 2008

More information

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013 Comprehensive Exam August 19, 2013 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question. Good luck! 1 1 Menu

More information

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) ....... Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) Rapid Aging and Chinese Pension Reform, June 3, 2014 SHUFE, Shanghai ..... The results in this

More information

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam MACROECONOMICS Prelim Exam Austin, June 1, 2012 Instructions This is a closed book exam. If you get stuck in one section move to the next one. Do not waste time on sections that you find hard to solve.

More information

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho Beggar-thy-parents? A Lifecycle Model of Intergenerational Altruism Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho University of New South Wales March 2009 Motivation & Question Since Becker (1974), several studies analyzing

More information

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting Masaru Inaba and Kengo Nutahara Research Institute of Economy, Trade, and

More information

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe August 2 211 This document contains supplementary material to Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (211). 1 A Two Sector

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

Labor-market Volatility in a Matching Model with Worker Heterogeneity and Endogenous Separations

Labor-market Volatility in a Matching Model with Worker Heterogeneity and Endogenous Separations Labor-market Volatility in a Matching Model with Worker Heterogeneity and Endogenous Separations Andri Chassamboulli April 15, 2010 Abstract This paper studies the business-cycle behavior of a matching

More information

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background Behzad Diba University of Bern April 2012 (Institute) Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background April 2012 1 / 19 Research Areas Research on fiscal policy typically

More information

Business Cycles in the Equilibrium Model of Labor Market Search and Self-Insurance

Business Cycles in the Equilibrium Model of Labor Market Search and Self-Insurance Business Cycles in the Equilibrium Model of Labor Market Search and Self-Insurance Makoto Nakajima University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign May 2007 First draft: December 2005 Abstract The standard Mortensen-Pissarides

More information

The Welfare Cost of Inflation. in the Presence of Inside Money

The Welfare Cost of Inflation. in the Presence of Inside Money 1 The Welfare Cost of Inflation in the Presence of Inside Money Scott Freeman, Espen R. Henriksen, and Finn E. Kydland In this paper, we ask what role an endogenous money multiplier plays in the estimated

More information

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Department of Economics HKUST August 7, 2018 Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics 1 / 48 Reference Krueger, Dirk, Kurt Mitman, and Fabrizio Perri. Macroeconomics

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Yan Bai University of Rochester NBER Dan Lu University of Rochester Xu Tian University of Rochester February

More information

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function: Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function: β t log(c t ), where C t is consumption and the parameter β satisfies

More information

Employment, Unemployment and Turnover

Employment, Unemployment and Turnover Employment, Unemployment and Turnover D. Andolfatto June 2011 Introduction In an earlier chapter, we studied the time allocation problem max { ( ) : = + + =1} We usually assume an interior solution; i.e.,

More information

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge By Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Elena Pastorino This paper is motivated by the strong correlation between changes in household debt and employment across regions

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES 1. REVIEW: SMALL TAXES SMALL DEADWEIGHT LOSS Static analysis suggests that deadweight loss from taxation at rate τ is 0(τ 2 ) that is, that for small tax rates the

More information

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable outlines

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Structural Change in Investment and Consumption: A Unified Approach

Structural Change in Investment and Consumption: A Unified Approach Structural Change in Investment and Consumption: A Unified Approach Berthold Herrendorf (Arizona State University) Richard Rogerson (Princeton University and NBER) Ákos Valentinyi (University of Manchester,

More information

the Federal Reserve to carry out exceptional policies for over seven year in order to alleviate its effects.

the Federal Reserve to carry out exceptional policies for over seven year in order to alleviate its effects. The Great Recession and Financial Shocks 1 Zhen Huo New York University José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Pennsylvania University College London Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis CAERP, CEPR, NBER

More information

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Postponed exam: ECON4310 Macroeconomic Theory Date of exam: Wednesday, January 11, 2017 Time for exam: 09:00 a.m. 12:00 noon The problem set covers 13 pages (incl.

More information

The Fundamental Surplus in Matching Models. European Summer Symposium in International Macroeconomics, May 2015 Tarragona, Spain

The Fundamental Surplus in Matching Models. European Summer Symposium in International Macroeconomics, May 2015 Tarragona, Spain The Fundamental Surplus in Matching Models Lars Ljungqvist Stockholm School of Economics New York University Thomas J. Sargent New York University Hoover Institution European Summer Symposium in International

More information

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Phuong V. Ngo,a a Department of Economics, Cleveland State University, 22 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland,

More information

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Vipin Arora Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Junsang Lee U.S. EIA Deakin Univ. SKKU December 16, 2013 GRIPS Junsang Lee (SKKU) Oil Price Dynamics in

More information

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism Árpád Ábrahám João Brogueira de Sousa Ramon Marimon Lukas Mayr European University Institute Lisbon Conference on Structural Reforms, 6 July

More information

Evaluating the Macroeconomic Effects of a Temporary Investment Tax Credit by Paul Gomme

Evaluating the Macroeconomic Effects of a Temporary Investment Tax Credit by Paul Gomme p d papers POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS Evaluating the Macroeconomic Effects of a Temporary Investment Tax Credit by Paul Gomme POLICY DISCUSSION PAPER NUMBER 30 JANUARY 2002 Evaluating the Macroeconomic Effects

More information

Theory. 2.1 One Country Background

Theory. 2.1 One Country Background 2 Theory 2.1 One Country 2.1.1 Background The theory that has guided the specification of the US model was first presented in Fair (1974) and then in Chapter 3 in Fair (1984). This work stresses three

More information

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication.

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication. Online Appendix Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle Not intended for publication Alexander Bick Arizona State University Sekyu Choi Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona,

More information

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims FINAL EXAM. β t 1 2 φτ2 t subject to (1)

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims FINAL EXAM. β t 1 2 φτ2 t subject to (1) Eco54 Spring 21 C. Sims FINAL EXAM There are three questions that will be equally weighted in grading. Since you may find some questions take longer to answer than others, and partial credit will be given

More information

Without Looking Closer, it May Seem Cheap: Low Interest Rates and Government Borrowing *

Without Looking Closer, it May Seem Cheap: Low Interest Rates and Government Borrowing * Without Looking Closer, it May Seem Cheap: Low Interest Rates and Government Borrowing * Julio Garín Claremont McKenna College Robert Lester Colby College Jonathan Wolff Miami University Eric Sims. University

More information

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far. We first introduce and discuss the intertemporal budget

More information

(a) Is it possible for the rate of exit from OLF into E tobethesameastherateof exit from U into E? Why or why not?

(a) Is it possible for the rate of exit from OLF into E tobethesameastherateof exit from U into E? Why or why not? Final (Take-Home) Exam The Formulation and Estimation of Equilibrium Models of Household and Labor Market Behavior Department of Economics, TAU Professor C. Flinn Please answer five (5) of the following

More information

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far.

More information

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis University of Western Ontario February 2013 Question Main Question: what is the welfare cost/gain of US social safety

More information

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits Day Manoli UCLA Andrea Weber University of Mannheim February 29, 2012 Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence

More information