Economic Growth in Thailand: The Macroeconomic Context

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Economic Growth in Thailand: The Macroeconomic Context"

Transcription

1 Economic Growth in Thailand: The Macroeconomic Context By Barry Bosworth August, 2005 This survey of economic growth accounting in Thailand was prepared for a World Bank project on the investment climate, firm competitiveness and growth in Thailand.

2 Economic Growth in Thailand: The Macroeconomic Context By Barry Bosworth 1 Thailand has long been included with a group of economies in East and Southeast Asia, who, because of their outstanding growth performance, have been at the center of the research and discussion of the determinants of economic growth. Much of the debate has revolved around an effort to partition growth between the contributions of increased factor inputs (extensive growth) and improvements in the efficiency with which those factors are employed (intensive growth). This issue is important to resolving questions of the future sustainability of the growth process, and the direction that should be taken by government policies. How important are efforts to stimulate innovation and competition, which are believed to be linked to gains in the efficiency of resource use, versus expansion of educational opportunities and incentives for greater capital formation. A concern with these issues has stimulated a large body of economic research aimed at identifying the proximate sources of growth, in both Thailand and other economies of the region. This research has included studies that use an econometric approach of estimating the parameters of an aggregate production function and those that rely on growth accounting to decompose the growth in output into the contributions of increased quantities of the factor inputs and a residual measure of improvements in total factor productivity (TFP). Both of these methodologies have been applied to Thailand s situation, but one consequence has been a wide variation in the conclusions of the individual studies. The purpose of this paper is to review some of the major productivity studies of Thailand and attempt to identify the sources of their differences. The chapter also includes the construction of a set of growth accounts at the level of the total economy and three major sectors -- agriculture, industry and services. These growth accounts provide the framework for a discussion of the data issues that arise in the context of efforts to measure Thailand s productivity performance. 1 I am indebted to Kirida Bhaopichitr of the World Bank and Piyanuch Wuttisorn and Khun Suppasit of the National Economic and Social Board for their extensive efforts to obtain the data used in this report. Starynee Adams, Lisa Bell, and Dan Theisen of the Brookings Institution provided computational assistance.

3 The following section contains a brief overview of Thai economic growth and the structural changes that have occurred. The second section presents a short summary of the primary methodological approaches to productivity analysis. Section 3 presents a review and comparison of the major growth studies of Thailand that have been completed over the past decade. The fourth section uses the results and lessons from the prior analyses to present a consistent set of growth accounts for the period of 1977 to 2002 using the most recent data. 1. Growth and Structural Change, Thailand s economic growth averaged 7.5 percent per year in the quarter century that preceded the 1997 financial crisis (table 1). However, output fell sharply in both 1997 and 1998 and did not recover to its 1996 level until The severity of the crisis will have a major effect on any analysis of Thailand s growth experience. As shown in figure 1, the output losses, relative to Thailand s prior growth path, appear to be permanent; that is, the growth rate has recovered but along a lower path than existed prior to Furthermore, a long term growth in employment averaging less than half that of output implied substantial labor productivity gains in the years prior to the 1997 crisis, but evidence of significant productivity improvement in subsequent years is largely absent. Over the period, output growth averaged 1.5 percent per year and employment growth was 1.3 percent. Like many other economies of the region, Thailand s growth has been relatively capital intensive: the growth of the capital stock has consistently exceeded that of output, but by a relatively modest margin, and the capital-output ratio is still low relative to the industrial economies. Finally, figure 1 highlights the extent to which the output collapse was concentrated in capital investment, and the lack of any significant recovery in the following years. The investment rate averaged 40 percent of GDP in the first half of the 1990s; it has been half that since the crisis. Thailand s growth has also been accompanied by sizable changes in the structure of the economy, as shown in figure 2. The share of GDP accounted for by industry has doubled from 21 percent in 1970 to 44 percent in In contrast, the share coming from the agricultural sector fell from 23 to 10 percent. Surprisingly, the role of services, as measured by its output share, has declined slightly. The general picture is one of resources moving out of agriculture and into industry. 2

4 A somewhat different perspective is provided by a focus on employment shares in figure 3. Again, the share of employment in industry has roughly doubled since 1977, but it has a far less dominant role than implied by the output share, only 21 percent of total employment in There are also substantial employment gains in services, implying a drop in labor productivity relative to that in industry. Furthermore, agriculture has a far larger role in the economy when viewed from the employment perspective, but its secular decline is even more evident. It is also useful to evaluate Thailand s progress in terms of the improvement in labor productivity (GDP per worker) and ultimately living standards as measured by income per capita, and its convergence to the levels of the high-income countries. Both the productivity and income measures are reported in international dollars (PPP) in table 2, and they are also shown relative to the United States to highlight the extent of convergence. As shown below, the gap between output per worker and income per capita can also be related to underlying differences in the proportion of income that accrues to residents, the utilization of the workforce, and the age structure of the population: GNI = capita ( GDP ) ( GNI ) E Plf E GDP P lf P, where GDP = production per worker, E GNI = the proportion of income from production that accrues to residents, GDP E = the proportion of the population age 16 and over that is employed, and P lf P lf = the proportion of the population that is age 16 and over (demographics). P These determinants of income per capita are reported in international prices for 1975 (column 1) and 2003 (column 2). 2 The average annual rate of change is shown in column (3). The same concepts are reported again in columns 4-6, but relative to the corresponding value for the United States. The progress that Thailand has made is particularly evident in the comparison 2 The measures of GDP and GNI at international prices are those of the 2004 World Development Indicators. All values are converted to 2000 prices. 3

5 to the United States: GDP per worker has increased from 10 percent of the U.S. level in 1975 to 17.5 percent in In 1975, Thailand s population was also very young. Only about half of the population was of labor force age (15+), compared to about 70 percent for the United States. Today, the proportion of the population that is of working age is nearly identical to that of the United States. The participation rate for those of labor force age is also very high in Thailand, although it has not increased as much as in the United States. The high employment rate is largely due to the very high employment of women. Finally, Thailand has largely financed it s growth out of it own resources with the consequence that Gross National Income (GNI) has remained in the range of percent of GDP. Income payments on FDI and foreign debt have been largely offset by wages and remittances of overseas workers. The overall result is a growth in income per capita that has been slightly faster than that of output per worker. The level of GDP per worker and GNI per capita, relative to U.S. values, are also shown in figure 4 to highlight the severity and importance of the 1997 crisis. By 1996, Thailand had actually succeeded in more that doubling its 1975 relative income position; GNI per capital had reached 21 percent of the U.S. level, but it fell back to 17 percent Since then, growth in GDP per worker has only matched that of the United States, but there has been some recovery in income per capita due to a rise in the employment to population rate. 2. Basic Methodology of Productivity Analysis Studies of productivity growth have used a variety of different methodologies, but the research has evolved along two primary paths: growth accounting and direct econometric estimation. Both are based on an underlying concept of an aggregate production function. Growth accounting combines the production function with an assumption of competitive markets that leads to the use of income shares to measure the contribution of the input factors. This method focuses on identifying the contributions of the individual factor inputs and a residual of TFP. In contrast, the econometric approach avoids any assumption about competitive markets, and focuses on exploring alternative functional forms of the production function. Furthermore, most empirical studies have focused on what might be labeled the proximate causes of growth: measuring the quantity and quality of the capital and labor inputs, and viewing the residual of TFP as representing a combination of changes in efficiency and the production technology. More recently, some researchers have sought to go beyond the 4

6 proximate cause to associate the fundamental sources of long-term differences in living standards with differences in institutional and legal arrangements and geography. In these studies, TFP is perceived as the driving force -- the accumulation of physical capital and labor skills is largely endogenous and ultimately induced by changes in TFP and the focus is on developing a theory of TFP. 3 The focus of this paper is on the proximate causes in that it is primarily concerned with the measurement of the factor inputs and their relative contribution to growth over the past quarter century. Growth Accounts. Modern productivity analysis follows from the contribution of Solow (1957) that begins with a concept of an aggregate production function that relates output to the contribution of the factor inputs, capital and labor, and a Hicks-neutral shift in the production function: (1) Q A F( K, L ) t =. t t t By combining the notion of a production function with the assumption of competitive markets where the factors are paid their marginal products, it is possible to derive a simple index number formulation that relates the growth in output to increases in the factor inputs and a residual shift term that is identified with TFP: (2) d ln Q = s d ln( K) + s d ln( L) + lntfp, k l where s k and s l are the shares of capital and labor income, respectively. 4 It is also possible to extend this formulation to incorporate factor-augmenting improvements in the quality of the factor inputs, such as improved educational skills of the workforce. As discussed more fully below, it is often difficult to obtain meaningful time series estimates of factor income shares. Thus, many studies adopt a more restricted Cobb-Douglas production function in which the contribution of each factor is assumed to be constant: α 1 α (3) ( ) γ Q = A K L. t ( t t 3 Examples of this literature are provided by Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare (1997) and Easterly and Levine (2001). In the Thai context, see Ahuja and Moenjak (2002). 4 The use of income share weights is critical in that it makes it possible to avoid imposing restrictions on the possible functional forms of the production function. In empirical applications, the factor shares are replaced by average between period shares in a Tornqvist discrete time approximation. Thus s k is replaced by (s kt + s kt-1 ) / 2. A summary of the literature is provided in Hulten (2001), and a detailed manual that elaborates on the major issues is available in OECD (2001). 5

7 Again, A represents TFP and γ measures the extent of returns to scale. In this restricted formulation, the s k and s l of equation (2) are replaced with constants and many studies have simply assumed returns to scale of unity. It has also become quite standard to adjust the factor inputs, particularly labor, to reflect changes in quality. There are two common approaches that have been employed. The first seeks to cross-classify the workforce by a number of differentiating characteristics, such as education, age, occupation and gender. This information is combined with data on wage rates to compute each subgroup s share of total compensation, v i. An adjusted measure of the labor input is then computed as (4) d ln L * = vid ln Li i This is a very data intensive process and some analysts object that the wage differentials may measure factors other than productivity differences, such as gender or age discrimination. The alternative is to use a simple index of educational attainment to adjust for skill differences. For example, an index of the form: * as (5) L = e L assumes that each year of schooling, s, raises the average worker s productivity by a constant percentage, a. This formulation also has a ready parallel with a vast number of empirical studies that have used Mincer regressions to measure the relationship between wage rates and years of schooling. These studies have been carried out around the world with typical findings on the return to education in the range of 7 to 12 percent. 5 Quality adjustments can also be made to the capital input although in most cases they are more properly identified as reflecting changes in the composition of the capital stock. The development of Jorgenson s neoclassical investment theory clarified the distinction between the capital stock and capital services. Using his concept of user cost, the rental price of capital services is give by s (6) P k = ( i + δ P& k ) Pk, where i represents the rate of return, δ the rate of depreciation, and P & k the rate of price change. This formulation makes it clear that the flow of capital services will vary with difference in the 5 Summaries of many of these international studies are available in Psacharopoulos and Patrinos (2002). A specific example for Thailand is provided by Blunch (2004). 6

8 rate of capital asset depreciation. Assuming that the real rate of return is constant across asset classes, the capital service term can be used to compute capital income shares with which to aggregate capital of different service lives in a fashion that parallels that of equation (4). The growing importance of short-lived, high-tech capital has made this issue of compositional changes in the capital stock more important. Unfortunately, most countries do not have sufficiently detailed information particularly at the level of individual industries -- to make these compositional adjustments. Thus, it is common to use an estimate of the capital stock as the index of capital services. The essential difference is that the aggregate of the capital stock is constructed using purchase prices as the relevant weights, while the aggregate of capital services is weighted by the rental prices. Econometric Analysis. The major alternative to growth accounts is the use of econometric techniques to estimate the parameters of the production function directly. This is fueled in part by the increased flexibility of the functional forms associated with the trans-log production function. It is also stimulated by the development of new growth theories that interpret innovation as an endogenous part of the growth process, in contrast to the neoclassical assumption of exogenous change. Econometric analysis is also more easily adapted to deal with shocks, such as bad weather and financial crises, which distort the production process. However, the estimation of complex production functions normally requires large numbers of observations, and it raises difficult statistical issues. Several of the available studies of productivity growth in Thailand have relied on econometric techniques, but most of the studies that are reviewed below are based on growth accounting. 3. Review of Recent Studies There have been many studies of Thailand s growth performance. Researchers have used both the growth accounting methodology and a regression analysis. In reviewing the various results it is clear that the most important sources of variation among the studies are in the factor income shares that are attributed to capital and labor and whether or not the studies have included quality change in the measure of the labor input. Most of the aggregate studies of growth have relied on a common set of data on output and the capital stock from the National Economic and Social Development Board (NESDB). 7

9 These data are available with some degree of industry disaggregation; and beyond issues of adjusting for breaks in the data due to the change to the adoption of Revision 3 of the International Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC) in 2001, they are not a significant source of difference in the studies. Similarly, the employment data must be obtained from a household survey of the labor force; but because the within-year frequency (rounds) of the survey has varied over the years, the studies have differed in their construction of a measure of annual employment. In addition, the survey changed the age definition of the workforce from age 13+ to 15 and over in 2001, and it was also influenced by a 2001 change in the industrial classification. 6 The variation in the frequency of the survey is a more significant problem because the labor force has a pronounced seasonal aspect, peaking in the fall growing season. The household responses as to industry of employment are also probably unreliable below the level of the broad sectors. Thailand s national accounts include estimates of factor incomes only at the level of the total economy; and because the number of self-employed can equal or exceed the number of employees, a means must be found to allocate the mixed income of the self-employed between their labor and capital income components. The method used to make this adjustment has differed widely and is responsible for most of the wide variation in the relative weights applied to the indexes of growth in the factor inputs. National Economic and Social Development Board (NESDB). The macroeconomics division of the NESDB regularly prepares growth accounts using their estimates of GDP and the capital stock and employment numbers from the Labor Force Survey of the National Statistical Office. The methodology closely follows that shown in equation (2) above, but for their inclusion of a role for land in the agricultural sector. Estimates are compiled using net and gross measures of the capital stock as well a composite index (with a 75 percent weight on the gross stock). The calculations reported in table 3 are based on the net capital stock. The labor input is not adjusted for quality changes, and the factor shares are computed from the national accounts, assigning all of proprietors income to capital. The share estimates are smoothed with a 3-year moving average. The result is a very low estimate for the labor share (an average of 31 percent 6 Thailand s statistical programs shifted to the third revision of the International Standard Industrial Classification (1989). 8

10 over the period) and the assignment of the largest weight to the fast-growing capital input (68 percent). As shown in the first two columns of table 3, capital accumulation accounts for over 80 percent of the growth in aggregate output since 1980, the contribution of labor is about 10 percent, and improvements in TFP account for less than 10 percent of the gains. Because the quantity of cultivated land has not increased over the period, it has no significant effect on the rate of output growth. Accounts are also constructed at the level of the three major sectors (agriculture, industry and services). Again, they are based on the estimates of GDP and the net capital stock from the NESDB and employment estimates from the labor force survey. However, in the case of agriculture, the calculation of the factor shares is extreme because employment is dominated by the self-employed and unpaid family workers, but their income is assigned to capital. The labor share of value added averages only 11 percent, while that of capital is 85 percent. As a result, increases in capital account for 114 percent of output growth and changes in the residual of TFP are negative. There is not net growth of employment in agriculture. The accounts for industry and services also indicate a dominant role for the capital factor because its share of factor income is in excess of 60 percent in each case. Over the period, the contribution of capital accounts for 72 percent of the output growth in industry and 90 percent in services. Improvements in TFP remain positive in the industry sector, but they are consistently negative for services. Thailand Development Research Institute (TDRI) Study. This study, conducted by Pranee Tinakorn and Chalongphop Susangkarn, was published in 1996, and covers the period It develops a set of growth accounts that cover the total economy and three broad sectors of agriculture, industry and services. The study stands out for the detailed nature of the adjustments that were made to incorporate changes in the quality of labor inputs, reflecting changes in educational attainment, experience (age) and gender. In addition, the authors developed a methodology for allocating proprietors incomes between capital and labor. This is the most elaborate of the studies that have analyzed Thailand s growth experience. Over the period of , GDP growth averaged 7.6 percent annually (see table 4). They attribute 38 percent of that growth to increases in capital and land, 46 percent to growth in 9

11 the labor input (of which 20 percentage points were traced to quality improvements), and only 16 percent to a residual estimate of improvement in TFP. The results are significantly different from the NESDB calculations in allocating a much larger role to the labor input, but improvements in TFP are still quite modest. In addition, the relative contributions varied substantially across subperiods. At the sector level, improvements in TFP were important for agriculture, but were actually negative for industry and services. Increased capital played a large role in industry and services, but not agriculture. Gains in labor quality were most pronounced in services and agriculture. The authors conclude that their results for Thailand are similar to those for other East Asian economies, such as Korea, in finding that a large portion of overall growth was due to increases in the factor inputs rather than TFP. In addition, larger gains in TFP at the aggregate level than for individual sectors suggests that the reallocation of resources across sectors was also an important contributor to growth. Much of the data used in this study came from the standard government sources. The output measures were from the national accounts. The capital stocks were also those compiled by the NESDB. The study used both changes in the net capital stock and changes in a composite index to measure the flow of capital services. The composite index has a 75 percent weight on the gross capital stock and 25 percent weight on the net stock. The index of land input is based on the amount of land under cultivation, and because this has changed only modestly over the years, land contributes relatively little to the change in output. The employment data were from the household labor force surveys. The TDRI study used the employment estimate from the July-September round of the survey, which represents a seasonal peak in agricultural employment. Their employment measure also included individuals age 11 and over compared with the current cutoff of age 15. In some portions of the analysis they converted the labor input measures to hours. Changes in average hours worked had no significant effect on the measure of the change in the labor input over the full period, but the changes in average hours are substantial in some subperiods. The TDRI study includes two important extensions of the prior research. The first contribution was the construction of an index of changes in the quality of labor. The labor force survey is used to separate workers cross-classified by age, gender and education; and for each of these groups they are able to calculate an average wage rate. With that information, they 10

12 construct an index of labor quality that uses relative wages to value changes in the gender, age, and educational level of the workforce. Their calculations imply an improvement in the quality of the labor input for the total economy of 38 percent between 1977 and 1990, or 2.5 percent per year. This is an extraordinary rate of increase, which comes on top of an average rate of growth in labor hours of 3.3 percent annually. When this rapid growth in the adjusted labor input is combined with an 8.9 percent rate of growth in the capital input, the small estimated gains in TFP are not a surprise. Their results for the three major sectors shows the expected pattern of the largest educational gains being outside of agriculture, but the estimated improvements in labor quality within the services sector are extraordinary, 3.8 percent per year. That translates into a 2.2 percentage point contribution to the growth in output. Again, the very high rates of gain in labor quality are an important reason for the finding of a small residual contribution for improvements in TFP. The second contribution was in the estimate of the factor-income shares. For most growth accounting exercises, the derivation of factor income shares is very difficult. In Thailand, as in many developing countries, a very large proportion of income accrues to unincorporated enterprises, the self-employed. The income of unincorporated businesses averaged about 60 percent of national income in the 1970s, and has remained in the range of percent in recent years. It is a mixed income category that includes the returns to capital and entrepreneurship as well as labor. The authors imputed to the self-employed the average wage rate of employees, and computed capital income as a residual. They benchmarked their measures of the wage bill to the 1987 social accounting matrix (SAM). The inclusion of a wage for the self-employed raised the share of labor compensation in aggregate GDP from 24 to 60 percent in 1977, but the labor share declines sharply between 1984 and 1990, from 63 to 49 percent. 7 Their methodology also allowed them to capture the large difference between the wage rates of workers in agriculture and non-agriculture. The authors of the TDRI study provided an updated analysis in a 1998 report to the NESDB (Tinakorn and Sussangkarn, 1998) that replicated the prior analysis using the new series of GDP based on 1988 prices and covering the period. The basic results are summarized in table 5. In their revision, they significantly lowered the estimate of the labor 7 The magnitude of the adjustment declines over time as employees grow to represent a larger share of total employment. 11

13 income share in agriculture and services, assigning a larger weight to capital. Presumably, that is the result of a switch to the 1995 SAM as the benchmark for their wage calculations. The overall patterns are very similar to the analysis, reporting a negative contribution of TFP growth in both industry and services. However, there is an expanded contribution of capital and a somewhat diminished rate of improvement in labor quality. Asian Productivity Organization (APO). This study was authored by A. Chandrachai, T. Bangorn and K. Chockpisansin, all of Chulalongkorn Unitversity, and it was published as a chapter in a report of the Asian Productivity Organization in In most respects, it is an update and extension of the TDRI study with results covering the period of It followed the earlier study in incorporating a quality adjustment for the labor input that adjusts for changes in educational attainment, age, and gender, using wage rates from the Labor Force Survey. In addition, it uses the composite index of growth in the gross and net capital stocks to measure the flow of capital services. The computation of the factor shares is also similar to that in the TDRI study, and, while the actual values are not published, the average value of the labor share is said to be slightly higher than those of the 1978 TDRI study. They ignore any role for change in the input of land. The basic results of the APO analysis are summarized for over three different periods in table 6. A simple comparison with the original TDRI study is available in column (3) for the period. Outside of some downward revisions in the estimated output growth rate, the most significant change was in the estimate of quality improvements for the labor input; they find a contribution of 0.7 percent per year to growth compared to 1.5 percent in the TDRI study. While the methodologies are similar, the APO group s result seems more plausible. No explanation for the differences is provided in the paper. The change falls through to the estimate of TFP growth which is increased from 1.2 percent per year in the TDRI study to an average of 1.8 percent. The extension of the analysis to include the 1990s has little impact on the estimated contribution of labor and capital; but the 1997 financial crisis greatly alters the estimate of TFP, which falls to 0.5 percent per year if the analysis is extended through The authors attempt to adjust for the recession by constructing an index of capacity utilization, and they use it to derive a new measure of the effective capital stock. However, these calculations are shown only 12

14 for a separate analysis of eight industries. An alternative is to focus on the period preceding the crisis, as in column (2). Prior to the crisis, the contribution of TFP, 1.6 percent per year, was very much in line with their estimate for the earlier period. Inclusion of the last three years of the 1990s cuts the 22-year average growth of TFP by a full percentage point. The authors also include an analysis of the performance of productivity at the level of eight industries. However, they do not attempt to adjust for labor quality as with the TDRI study. To make some comparison to the TDRI study, their results are aggregated up to the sector level in columns (4)-(6) of table 6. A comparison with table 4 shows that the extension through to the end of 1990s yields very similar results for TFP growth, but a larger contribution is attributed to capital, which now stands out as the dominant source of growth in industry and services. 8 Finally, the productivity estimates from the eight industries are used to compute an industry shift effect that will be positive if labor is growing most rapidly in industries with the highest productivity growth. The wage rate is used as a proxy for the productivity of workers in each sector, and they compute a measure of the labor input in efficiency units. They find that the shift effect added almost one percent per year to the growth of output. Since this is an partial alternative to their quality adjustment for labor in the aggregate, the residual estimate of TFP growth is only a few tenths lower than the values reported in columns (1)-(3) of table 6. 9 Fiscal Policy Research Institute (FPRI) Study. The FPRI report was carried out in Like the TDRI and APO studies, it examines productivity growth both at the aggregate level and for the major sectors. However, it differs in its measure of capital services, the quality of labor inputs, and the method used to aggregate the contributions of the factor inputs. It also focuses on a very short historical time period, , and uses the results of the historical analysis to make alternative projections of economic growth over the period of The output measures are taken directly from the national accounts. The study recognizes a special role for high technology capital by separating computers from other types of capital in a 8 The authors make reference to a 2001 paper by Pranee Tinakorn, which I could not locate. I believe that paper is basically the same as Tinakorn and Sussangkarn (1998). 9 From a conceptual perspective, the wage rate should reflect economy-wide gains in productivity, not productivity in the specific sector. 13

15 production function framework that incorporates constant returns to scale and two types of capital (7) Y = A K (Non-ICT) α1 K (ICT) α2 L β. The flows of capital services are measured by depreciation. In addition, the study adjusts the workforce for quality changes, but in a very idiosyncratic fashion. The index of labor inputs is constructed by multiplying the number of hours (H) by the average years of schooling (EDU) and the average age of the workforce (EXP): (8) L = H*EDU*EXP. This assumption of a proportionate relationship between years of education and labor quality implies a very large return to education at low levels of attainment, but a rapid falloff of the marginal gain at higher levels. A more common assumption would infer a relatively constant rate of return to an additional year of schooling. The production relationship is estimated by regression using quarterly data over the period. Thus, unlike that of TDRI and AFO, this study incorporates a more restricted production function framework of fixed coefficients with no allowance for a secular component of TFP growth. The result for the aggregate economy is a relationship that assigns a weight of 0.51 to non-it capital, 0.13 to IT-capital, and 0.36 to labor. The relatively large weight attached to capital is virtually guaranteed by the exclusion of any independent trend or other allowance for changes in TFP: capital is the only right-hand-side variable that is growing at a rate approaching that of output. As shown in table 7, the results for the major sectors imply an even smaller role for labor inputs in the industry and services sectors. Instead of measuring labor quality with the product of average years of schooling and average age of workers, the sector equations multiply the number of hours by an average nominal wage rate within the sector (a proxy for quality change). 10 In effect, real output of the sector is related to two measures of the real capital input and an estimate of the nominal wage bill. The result is an extremely low elasticity of output with respect to the labor input of only 0.16 for both industry and services. 10 The sector wage rate is too broad to serve as an effective index of labor quality. Changes in average wage rates reflect a wide range of factors in additional to the quality of the workforce. These include general inflation, economy-wide productivity gains, and shifts in the relative demand and supply of labor at the sector level. 14

16 In one respect, this study is similar to that for TDRI in arguing for a relatively minor role for TFP improvement; but in this case, it is by assumption: the formulation of the production function attributes all of the output growth to changes in the factor inputs. This study also greatly expands the relative role of capital accumulation, with the sum of the coefficients on the two forms of capital ranging from 62 percent in agriculture to 84 percent in industry and services. There is no significant change in the average age of the workforce; and improvements in educational attainment are responsible for a cumulative rise in the effective labor supply of 22 percent over the 10-year period or about 2 per year. However, due to the small overall coefficient on the labor input, the net effect on output is in the range of percent. Bank of Thailand. Several studies published by the Bank of Thailand have included the construction of growth accounts. The most detailed is by Katharit (2001), and it provides calculations of TFP for the total economy, agriculture, non-agriculture, and manufacturing for the period of The growth in the capital input is measured by changes in the net capital stock. The labor input is total work hours as estimated from the survey of the labor force. The author uses the real wage rate in each sector as a proxy for changes in labor quality, multiplying it by hours to obtain an index of total labor input. The result is extraordinary estimates of the improvement in labor quality ranging from 2.6 percent per year in agriculture to 3.6 percent for the overall economy. 11 The factor shares in each sector are constructed, as in the TDRI and APO studies, by multiplying the number of workers by an estimate of the wage rate. However, the full details of the calculation are not available. The estimated wage shares differ significantly among the studies for the total economy, The BOT study reports a wage share near 60 percent in the late 1970s declining to 44 percent by 1995, whereas the TDRI study uses an wage share that averages 39 percent and rises slightly over the period. The BOT study also uses a higher labor share for agriculture, but the two studies have similar shares for manufacturing. The resulting growth accounts are shown in Table 8; and, despite the differences in the factor shares, they are quite similar to the previous conclusions from the TDRI and APO studies. 11 The quality gains are more rapid for the aggregate economy than for any sector because of the compositional shift toward the higher wage industries. 15

17 Capital accounts for the largest contribution to output growth, and the growth of TFP is a small positive for the total economy and it is negative in the non-agricultural sectors. The low value for the contribution of TFP is attributable to the high estimate of improvements in labor quality and the assignment of a large weight to growth in the capital input. As with the FPRI study, the use of the wage rate to measure quality change (although it is a real rather than a nominal concept) seems inappropriate. Second, a 2003 study of the investment situation by BOT staff (Mallikamas and others, 2003) included a set of aggregate growth accounts aimed at evaluating changes in the marginal productivity of capital. The study is notable for its application of two alternative means of estimating the labor share. Their first estimate is based on simply excluding income of the selfemployed in calculating the factor income shares from the national accounts. The result is a capital share that rises from about 30 percent in the early 1980s to 44 percent in the mid-1990s before collapsing back to percent in the aftermath of the 1997 crisis. This pattern of change in the share is much different, for example, than reported in the TDRI study. The second alternative is based on a method developed by Sarel (1997). He used cross-national data to compute capital shares for sectors with similar capital intensities. These internationallydetermined shares are then applied to the sector composition of individual countries. For Thailand this yields a capital share that is basically constant over the period of at 35 percent. Using the capital shares from applying Sarel s method, the study of Mallikamas and others finds a strong rise in TFP growth throughout the 1980s (reaching percent per year by the end of the decade), and a gradual decline in the 1990s prior to the financial crisis (averaging 3.3 percent in ). They attribute the decline to excess investment in the years leading up to the financial crisis. They report a recovery to a rate near 2 percent in The high TFP growth compared to the other studies is the result of the relatively low weight assigned to capital and the exclusion of any adjustment for improvements in labor quality. Summary. In recent years, a substantial number of studies of Thailand s economic growth experience have been published. While they differ in the details, some consistent themes do emerge. Most of the studies argue that, in common with other high-growth economies of East Asia, Thailand s economic advancement has been dominated by exceptionally strong rates of 16

18 capital formation. The contribution of improvements in TFP is generally found to be modest, but this is an area of some variation among the research reports. The divergent results can be traced in turn to two major issues. First, there are large differences among the studies in the extent of adjustment of the labor input for improvements in educational and skill quality. Those studies that do incorporate a measure of changes in labor quality show extraordinary large improvements. I remain puzzled about the precise source of those gains because Thailand is normally perceived as having achieved only average improvements in educational attainment. Second, in accounting for the contribution of growth in the factor inputs there is a wide variation in the relative weight assigned to the fast-growing capital input versus slow-growing labor. This last issue revolves around the question of how to allocate the incomes of the selfemployed between their own labor effort and the capital that they may bring to the business. Since the total income of the self-employed is nearly equal to that of employees, and exceeded it by a factor of two in the 1970s, the treatment of the mixed income of proprietors is crucial to the derivation of appropriate factor share weights. Somewhat surprisingly, the studies agree that the largest improvements in TFP have occurred in agriculture, and that TFP growth in services is frequently negative. 4. The Construction of Growth Accounts The prior literature review provides the basis for a systematic examination of the issues that arise in the construction of growth accounts for the overall economy, the three major sectors (agriculture, industry, and services), and a specific focus on manufacturing, which has played such a large role in Thailand s recent growth. Output. Thailand s national accounts provide the basis for all of the estimates of production. The national accounts are constructed using a mixture of different methodologies, including expenditures, production and income; but most of the problems of measuring real output are associated with the services sector. In several industries, real output is estimated by projecting employment or by deflation of the nominal values with an estimate of the wage rate. In both instances, significant changes in output per worker are ruled out. This is a particular problem in services. In addition, the inclusion of the imputed estimate of value added from homeownership results in a large output value for which there is little or no associated labor 17

19 input and a large capital input. In studies of productivity within OECD countries, the value added of owner occupied housing is often excluded to avoid biasing the conclusions. These concerns about the output measures however, would appear to be no more important in Thailand than in many other countries. The estimates of output growth should be comparable to those of other countries in the region. All of the output data are from table 4 of the national accounts, at 1988 prices. Capital Services. As discussed earlier, the ideal method for computing an index of capital services would rely on aggregating across the different types of capital using estimates of the user costs as the weights. This cross-classification of capital by type and industry, however, is not available for Thailand. On the other hand, the NESDB does produce annual estimates of the gross and net capital stock and annual depreciation by economic activity. That suggests that estimates of the user cost by industry and asset could be produced from unpublished data. Estimates of the gross and net capital stock and annual depreciation have been used to represent the growth in capital services, as well as a composite index based on a weighted average of growth in the gross and net capital stocks. As shown in figure 6, the differences among the various measures was not large prior to the 1997 financial crisis; but it is evident that depreciation is the most sensitive to variations in the rate of capital accumulation. Evidently, the post-1997 decline in investment was concentrated in assets with relatively high rates of depreciation (equipment). Depreciation is generally viewed a poor index of capital services because it ignores half of the user cost, the net return to capital. 12 Until it is possible to develop more elaborate indexes of capital services, an index based on changes in the net or gross capital stock or a composite of the two seems most reasonable. The remainder of this report uses a composite index with a weight of 75 percent on growth in the gross stock and 25 percent on the net stock. Labor. The labor force survey (LFS) has undergone considerable expansion to the point that it is now conducted on a monthly basis. Since Thailand does not produce an establishmentbased survey of employment, all of the information on employment must be obtained from the 12 The ratio of depreciation to the net capital stock has gradually declined over time, implying that Thailand s capital stock is becoming longer lived. This is contrary to the trend in many other countries where the role of ITC capital, which has a rapid rate of obsolescence, has been expanding. 18

20 LFS. The major problems with the use of the survey result from the limited within-year frequency of the survey in the years prior to For those years, it is difficult to compute an employment estimate that is consistent with the annual average perspective of the national accounts. The studies by TDRI and the APO used the August survey, when agricultural employment is at a seasonal peak; but the studies by the NESDB more frequently relied on an average of the February and August surveys. In census years, there was only the fall estimate. I have followed the NESDB method where possible. The lack of an establishment survey does raise some concern about the consistency of the employment estimates with the measures of output that are obtained from other sources. The potential inconsistencies are increased at the more detailed industry level because workers may not be knowledgeable about the industrial classification of their employer. For some statistical purposes, however, the independent sources for output and employment data are a distinct advantage. The LFS also collects information on hours of work, and it has been used in some of the studies to convert the labor input to hours. However, I chose not to use the hours data. There is no major trend change in hours worked per person in Thailand, and for most of the period the measure of hours is restricted to one or two surveys per year, making it a questionable estimate of the annual average. Educational Attainment. As discussed earlier, divergent estimates of the improvement in labor quality account for much of the difference among prior growth accounting studies. The LFS provides information on educational attainment, gender, and age of the workforce. However, there is considerable doubt about the meaning of the gender and age differences in wage rates, since they could easily be related to discrimination rather than productivity differences. For this reason, many statistical studies limit the adjustment of labor quality to changes in educational attainment and work experience (age). The TDRI and APO studies used the LFS data to compute indexes of labor quality. The source of the large increases that they report is puzzling, however, because Thailand has not had a particularly rapid increase in the educational attainment of its workforce, and there are only modest changes in the average age and gender composition of the workforce. Average levels of educational attainment are available from the LFS since Years of schooling of the 19

21 employed population have risen from an average of 5 years in 1977 to 8 years in However, it has been suggested that the return to education may have changed substantially over the period under study. Empirical studies of the relationship between earnings and educational attainment are widely available. Psacharopoulos and Patrinos (2002) report a range of returns between 7 and 12 percent for a large number of country studies. Those studies typically use micro survey data to estimate the impact of years of schooling on wage rates. Blunch (2004) and Hawley (2004) obtain estimates of the return to education in Thailand in the upper portion of that range using the data from the Social Economic Survey and the LFS for several years in the 1980s and 1990s. I used the micro data sets from the August LFS of each year from 1977 to 2004 to explore the relationship between education and earnings in greater detail. The surveys vary in size and information on monthly earnings is only available for employees. The usable sample size ranged between 11 and 36 thousand observations. Regressions were estimated for each survey: the log of the monthly wage was related to age, age 2, gender, and years of schooling. A set of categorical variables was also include to adjust for frequency of pay periods (daily weekly, monthly, and other) because of uncertainty about how to convert to a monthly wage. The coefficient on years of schooling is reported in the top panel of figure 5 for the years of The return to schooling averages about 9 percent in the late 1970s and the 1980s, and rises to above 10 percent in the early 1990s, before declining back to 9 percent by There is a change in the coding of the education variable beginning with the 2001 survey, and the reported jump in the return is probably not meaningful. A second formulation used a set of categorical variables to represent the various levels of education, thus dropping the assumption of a linear relationship with years of schooling. The results are reported in the lower panel of figure 5. The excluded category is workers with less than an elementary education, so that university graduates are shown as earning about 140 percent more than those workers. Again, there is some evidence of a modest decline in the return during the 1990s, but the differential between the earnings of secondary and university graduates has remained very stable. The 13 This measure is computed by assigning the years of schooling shown in the FPRI study to the educational categories of the LFS. However, the number of years associated with a university education was lowered from 18 to 16 and the calculations exclude a small number of individuals in the categories of other and unknown. The NSO and K. Suppasit of the NESDB provided tabulations of educational attainment from the labor force surveys for the period of

Getting Mexico to Grow With NAFTA: The World Bank's Analysis. October 13, 2004

Getting Mexico to Grow With NAFTA: The World Bank's Analysis. October 13, 2004 cepr CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH Issue Brief Getting Mexico to Grow With NAFTA: The World Bank's Analysis Mark Weisbrot, David Rosnick, and Dean Baker 1 October 13, 2004 CENTER FOR ECONOMIC

More information

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model T.Huw Edwards Dept of Economics, Loughborough University and CSGR Warwick UK Tel (44)01509-222718 Fax 01509-223910 T.H.Edwards@lboro.ac.uk

More information

Challenges For the Future of Chinese Economic Growth. Jane Haltmaier* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. August 2011.

Challenges For the Future of Chinese Economic Growth. Jane Haltmaier* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. August 2011. Challenges For the Future of Chinese Economic Growth Jane Haltmaier* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System August 2011 Preliminary *Senior Advisor in the Division of International Finance. Mailing

More information

Chapter 4: Micro Kuznets and Macro TFP Decompositions

Chapter 4: Micro Kuznets and Macro TFP Decompositions Chapter 4: Micro Kuznets and Macro TFP Decompositions This chapter provides a transition from measurement and the assemblage of facts to a documentation of ey underlying drivers of the Thai economy. The

More information

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence ISSN 2029-4581. ORGANIZATIONS AND MARKETS IN EMERGING ECONOMIES, 2012, VOL. 3, No. 1(5) Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence from and the Euro Area Jolanta

More information

ECO 4933 Topics in Theory

ECO 4933 Topics in Theory ECO 4933 Topics in Theory Introduction to Economic Growth Fall 2015 Chapter 2 1 Chapter 2 The Solow Growth Model Chapter 2 2 Assumptions: 1. The world consists of countries that produce and consume only

More information

CHAPTER 2. Hidden unemployment in Australia. William F. Mitchell

CHAPTER 2. Hidden unemployment in Australia. William F. Mitchell CHAPTER 2 Hidden unemployment in Australia William F. Mitchell 2.1 Introduction From the viewpoint of Okun s upgrading hypothesis, a cyclical rise in labour force participation (indicating that the discouraged

More information

Productivity Trends of New Zealand Electricity Distributors

Productivity Trends of New Zealand Electricity Distributors Productivity Trends of New Zealand Electricity Distributors Productivity Trends of New Zealand Electricity Distributors June 2014 Larry Kaufmann, Ph.D. Senior Advisor David Hovde, M.S. Vice President PACIFIC

More information

ECON 450 Development Economics

ECON 450 Development Economics ECON 450 Development Economics Classic Theories of Economic Growth and Development The Empirics of the Solow Growth Model University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign Summer 2017 Introduction This lecture

More information

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market An overview of the South African labour market for the Year ending 2011 5 May 2012 Contents Recent labour market trends... 2 A labour market

More information

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market An overview of the South African labour market from 3 of 2010 to of 2011 September 2011 Contents Recent labour market trends... 2 A brief labour

More information

CRS Report for Congress

CRS Report for Congress Order Code RL33519 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Why Is Household Income Falling While GDP Is Rising? July 7, 2006 Marc Labonte Specialist in Macroeconomics Government and Finance

More information

Additional Evidence and Replication Code for Analyzing the Effects of Minimum Wage Increases Enacted During the Great Recession

Additional Evidence and Replication Code for Analyzing the Effects of Minimum Wage Increases Enacted During the Great Recession ESSPRI Working Paper Series Paper #20173 Additional Evidence and Replication Code for Analyzing the Effects of Minimum Wage Increases Enacted During the Great Recession Economic Self-Sufficiency Policy

More information

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Linda Goldberg and Joseph Tracy Federal Reserve Bank of New York and NBER April 2001 Abstract Although the dollar has been shown to influence

More information

Technical change is labor-augmenting (also known as Harrod neutral). The production function exhibits constant returns to scale:

Technical change is labor-augmenting (also known as Harrod neutral). The production function exhibits constant returns to scale: Romer01a.doc The Solow Growth Model Set-up The Production Function Assume an aggregate production function: F[ A ], (1.1) Notation: A output capital labor effectiveness of labor (productivity) Technical

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Developing a unit labour costs indicator for the UK

Developing a unit labour costs indicator for the UK Economic & Labour Market Review Vol 3 No 6 June 29 FEATURE Alex Turvey Developing a unit labour costs indicator for the UK SUMMARY This article showcases ongoing work within ONS to develop a new unit labour

More information

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018 Summary of Keister & Moller 2000 This review summarized wealth inequality in the form of net worth. Authors examined empirical evidence of wealth accumulation and distribution, presented estimates of trends

More information

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve

The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve Capacity Utilization As a Real-Time Predictor of Manufacturing Output Evan F. Koenig Research Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas The use of real-time data is critical, for the Federal Reserve indices

More information

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market An overview of the South African labour market for the Year Ending 2012 6 June 2012 Contents Recent labour market trends... 2 A labour market

More information

READING 20: DREAMING WITH BRICS: THE PATH TO

READING 20: DREAMING WITH BRICS: THE PATH TO READING 20: DREAMING WITH BRICS: THE PATH TO 2050 Dreaming with BRICs: The Path to 2050, by Dominic Wilson and Roopa Purushothaman, reprinted from Global Economics Paper Number 99. Copyright 2003. Reprinted

More information

Average income from employment in 1995 was

Average income from employment in 1995 was Abdul Rashid Average income from employment in 1995 was $26,500. It varied widely among different occupations, from $4,300 for sports officials and referees to $120,600 for judges (Statistics Canada, 1999).

More information

Growth and Productivity in Belgium

Growth and Productivity in Belgium Federal Planning Bureau Kunstlaan/Avenue des Arts 47-49, 1000 Brussels http://www.plan.be WORKING PAPER 5-07 Growth and Productivity in Belgium March 2007 Bernadette Biatour, bbi@plan.b Jeroen Fiers, jef@plan.

More information

The Theory of Economic Growth

The Theory of Economic Growth The Theory of The Importance of Growth of real GDP per capita A measure of standards of living Small changes make large differences over long periods of time The causes and consequences of sustained increases

More information

The Theory of Economic Growth

The Theory of Economic Growth The Theory of 1 The Importance of Growth of real GDP per capita A measure of standards of living Small changes make large differences over long periods of time The causes and consequences of sustained

More information

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Petra Gerlach-Kristen Hong Kong Institute of Economics and Business Strategy May, Abstract This paper uses unobserved components analysis to estimate

More information

The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital

The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital Audra Bowlus and Chris Robinson University of Western Ontario Presentation at Craig Riddell s Festschrift UBC, September 2016 Introduction and Motivation

More information

Growth Accounting: A European Comparison

Growth Accounting: A European Comparison Cyprus Economic Policy Review, Vol. 6, No. 2, p.p. 67-79 (212) 145-4561 67 Growth Accounting: A European Comparison Theofanis Mamuneas and Elena Ketteni Department of Economics and Economic Research Centre

More information

Indiana Lags United States in Per Capita Income

Indiana Lags United States in Per Capita Income July 2011, Number 11-C21 University Public Policy Institute The IU Public Policy Institute (PPI) is a collaborative, multidisciplinary research institute within the University School of Public and Environmental

More information

Demographic Transition in Asia: Risk of Growing Old Before Becoming Rich

Demographic Transition in Asia: Risk of Growing Old Before Becoming Rich Demographic Transition in Asia: Risk of Growing Old Before Becoming Rich Minsuk Kim International Monetary Fund Asia and Pacific Department 2017 Asia and Pacific Regional Economic Outlook May 12, 2017

More information

LEC 2: Exogenous (Neoclassical) growth model

LEC 2: Exogenous (Neoclassical) growth model LEC 2: Exogenous (Neoclassical) growth model Development of the model The Neo-classical model was an extension to the Harrod-Domar model that included a new term productivity growth The most important

More information

The International Comparison Program (ICP) provides estimates of the gross domestic product

The International Comparison Program (ICP) provides estimates of the gross domestic product CHAPTER 18 Extrapolating PPPs and Comparing ICP Benchmark Results Paul McCarthy The International Comparison Program (ICP) provides estimates of the gross domestic product (GDP) and its main expenditure

More information

Potential Output in Ireland Presentation at TCD-DEW Conference

Potential Output in Ireland Presentation at TCD-DEW Conference Potential Output in Ireland Presentation at TCD-DEW Conference Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD May 20, 2009 Karl Whelan (UCD) Potential Output May 20, 2009 1 / 22 Plan for this Talk 1 Conceptual Issues:

More information

Comment on Counting the World s Poor, by Angus Deaton

Comment on Counting the World s Poor, by Angus Deaton Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Comment on Counting the World s Poor, by Angus Deaton Martin Ravallion There is almost

More information

Testing the Solow Growth Theory

Testing the Solow Growth Theory Testing the Solow Growth Theory Dilip Mookherjee Ec320 Lecture 4, Boston University Sept 11, 2014 DM (BU) 320 Lect 4 Sept 11, 2014 1 / 25 RECAP OF L3: SIMPLE SOLOW MODEL Solow theory: deviates from HD

More information

to 4 per cent annual growth in the US.

to 4 per cent annual growth in the US. A nation s economic growth is determined by the rate of utilisation of the factors of production capital and labour and the efficiency of their use. Traditionally, economic growth in Europe has been characterised

More information

FIGURE I.1 / Per Capita Gross Domestic Product and Unemployment Rates. Year

FIGURE I.1 / Per Capita Gross Domestic Product and Unemployment Rates. Year FIGURE I.1 / Per Capita Gross Domestic Product and Unemployment Rates 40,000 12 Real GDP per Capita (Chained 2000 Dollars) 35,000 30,000 25,000 20,000 15,000 10,000 5,000 Real GDP per Capita Unemployment

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender

Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender IFS Working Paper W15/03 Guy Laroque Sophie Osotimehin Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across ages and gender Guy Laroque

More information

Monitoring the Performance

Monitoring the Performance Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market An overview of the Sector from 2014 Quarter 1 to 2017 Quarter 1 Factsheet 19 November 2017 South Africa s Sector Government broadly defined

More information

Learning the Right Lessons from the Current Account Deficit and Dollar Appreciation

Learning the Right Lessons from the Current Account Deficit and Dollar Appreciation Learning the Right Lessons from the Current Account Deficit and Dollar Appreciation Alan C. Stockman Wilson Professor of Economics University of Rochester 716-275-7214 http://www.stockman.net alan@stockman.net

More information

Mixed Income in the Total Factor productivity, KLEMS Model.

Mixed Income in the Total Factor productivity, KLEMS Model. Mixed Income in the Total Factor productivity, KLEMS Model. Introduction The main objective of this document is to articulate the mixed income of the System of national accounts of Mexico with the published

More information

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Are Government Spending Multipliers Greater During Periods of Slack? Evidence from 2th Century Historical Data Michael T. Owyang

More information

Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORA SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT CENTRE

Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORA SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT CENTRE Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORA SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT CENTRE Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORAMA Haroon

More information

Emerging Asia s Impact on Australian Growth: Some Insights From GEM

Emerging Asia s Impact on Australian Growth: Some Insights From GEM WP/1/ Emerging Asia s Impact on Australian Growth: Some Insights From GEM Ben Hunt 1 International Monetary Fund WP/1/ IMF Working Paper Asia and Pacific Emerging Asia s Impact on Australian Growth: Some

More information

Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks

Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks Robert M. Feinberg Professor of Economics American University With the assistance of: Ataur Rahman Ph.D. Student in Economics American University

More information

The Empirics of Growth: An Update

The Empirics of Growth: An Update 1790-02_Bosworth.qxd 01/06/04 10:31 Page 113 BARRY P. BOSWORTH Brookings Institution SUSAN M. COLLINS Brookings Institution and Georgetown University The Empirics of Growth: An Update The past decade has

More information

Automated labor market diagnostics for low and middle income countries

Automated labor market diagnostics for low and middle income countries Poverty Reduction Group Poverty Reduction and Economic Management (PREM) World Bank ADePT: Labor Version 1.0 Automated labor market diagnostics for low and middle income countries User s Guide: Definitions

More information

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation" Valerie A. Ramey University of California, San Diego and NBER June 30, 2011 Abstract This brief note challenges

More information

About 80% of the countries have GDP per capita below the average income per head

About 80% of the countries have GDP per capita below the average income per head ECON 7010: Economics of Development Introduction to Economics Development Why poor countries consume less? Because they produce less Lack of physical capital (no tools and machinery) Lack of necessary

More information

Trade and Development

Trade and Development Trade and Development Table of Contents 2.2 Growth theory revisited a) Post Keynesian Growth Theory the Harrod Domar Growth Model b) Structural Change Models the Lewis Model c) Neoclassical Growth Theory

More information

Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis Fed, IGIER, CEPR and NBER October 2012

Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis Fed, IGIER, CEPR and NBER October 2012 Comment on: Structural and Cyclical Forces in the Labor Market During the Great Recession: Cross-Country Evidence by Luca Sala, Ulf Söderström and Antonella Trigari Fabrizio Perri Università Bocconi, Minneapolis

More information

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth The analysis of why some countries have achieved a high and rising standard of living, while others have

More information

Socio-economic Series Changes in Household Net Worth in Canada:

Socio-economic Series Changes in Household Net Worth in Canada: research highlight October 2010 Socio-economic Series 10-018 Changes in Household Net Worth in Canada: 1990-2009 introduction For many households, buying a home is the largest single purchase they will

More information

WORKING PAPER SERIES

WORKING PAPER SERIES ISSN 1503-299X WORKING PAPER SERIES No. 22/2002 INTERNATIONAL SPILLOVERS, PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH AND OPENNESS IN THAILAND: AN INTERTEMPORAL GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS Xinshen Diao Jørn Rattsø Hildegunn

More information

MACROECONOMICS. Solow Growth Model Applications and Extensions. Zongye Huang ISEM, CUEB

MACROECONOMICS. Solow Growth Model Applications and Extensions. Zongye Huang ISEM, CUEB MACROECONOMICS Solow Growth Model Applications and Extensions Zongye Huang ISEM, CUEB Kaldor Stylized Facts Kaldor (1957) proposed six statements about economic growth as "a stylized view of the facts".

More information

Olivier Blanchard. July 7, 2003

Olivier Blanchard. July 7, 2003 Comments on The case of missing productivity growth; or, why has productivity accelerated in the United States but not the United Kingdom by Basu et al Olivier Blanchard. July 7, 2003 NBER Macroeconomics

More information

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth J.R. Walker U.W. Madison Econ448: Human Resources and Economic Growth Summary Solow Model [Pop Growth] The simplest Solow model (i.e., with exogenous population

More information

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1 Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1 Abstract: The main purpose of this study 2 is to analyze whether the Organization of Islamic Cooperation (OIC) countries show a regional economic

More information

SOCIAL ACCOUNTING MATRIX (SAM) AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR MACROECONOMIC PLANNING

SOCIAL ACCOUNTING MATRIX (SAM) AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR MACROECONOMIC PLANNING Unpublished Assessed Article, Bradford University, Development Project Planning Centre (DPPC), Bradford, UK. 1996 SOCIAL ACCOUNTING MATRIX (SAM) AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR MACROECONOMIC PLANNING I. Introduction:

More information

Employment from the BLS household and payroll surveys: summary of recent trends

Employment from the BLS household and payroll surveys: summary of recent trends Employment from the BLS household and payroll surveys: summary of recent trends Overview The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) has two monthly surveys that measure employment levels and trends: the Current

More information

The labor market in South Korea,

The labor market in South Korea, JUNGMIN LEE Seoul National University, South Korea, and IZA, Germany The labor market in South Korea, The labor market stabilized quickly after the 1998 Asian crisis, but rising inequality and demographic

More information

ENTITY CHOICE AND EFFECTIVE TAX RATES

ENTITY CHOICE AND EFFECTIVE TAX RATES ENTITY CHOICE AND EFFECTIVE TAX RATES UPDATED NOVEMBER, 2013 Prepared by Quantria Strategies, LLC for the National Federation of Independent Business and the S Corporation Association ENTITY CHOICE AND

More information

CASEN 2011, ECLAC clarifications Background on the National Socioeconomic Survey (CASEN) 2011

CASEN 2011, ECLAC clarifications Background on the National Socioeconomic Survey (CASEN) 2011 CASEN 2011, ECLAC clarifications 1 1. Background on the National Socioeconomic Survey (CASEN) 2011 The National Socioeconomic Survey (CASEN), is carried out in order to accomplish the following objectives:

More information

POST-CRISIS GLOBAL REBALANCING CONFERENCE ON GLOBALIZATION AND THE LAW OF THE SEA WASHINGTON DC, DEC 1-3, Barry Bosworth

POST-CRISIS GLOBAL REBALANCING CONFERENCE ON GLOBALIZATION AND THE LAW OF THE SEA WASHINGTON DC, DEC 1-3, Barry Bosworth POST-CRISIS GLOBAL REBALANCING CONFERENCE ON GLOBALIZATION AND THE LAW OF THE SEA WASHINGTON DC, DEC 1-3, 2010 Barry Bosworth I. Economic Rise of Asia Emerging economies of Asia have performed extremely

More information

2014/2015, week 4 Cross-Country Income Differences. Romer, Chapter 1.6, 1.7, 4.2, 4.5, 4.6

2014/2015, week 4 Cross-Country Income Differences. Romer, Chapter 1.6, 1.7, 4.2, 4.5, 4.6 2014/2015, week 4 Cross-Country Income Differences Romer, Chapter 1.6, 1.7, 4.2, 4.5, 4.6 Growth Accounting How can we test for the determinants of growth and, thereby, of income differences across countries?

More information

ECON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University. J.Jung Chapter 8 - Economic Growth Towson University 1 / 64

ECON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University. J.Jung Chapter 8 - Economic Growth Towson University 1 / 64 ECON 202 - MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University J.Jung Chapter 8 - Economic Growth Towson University 1 / 64 Disclaimer These lecture notes are customized for the Macroeconomics

More information

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics PhD Topics in Macroeconomics Lecture 12: misallocation, part four Chris Edmond 2nd Semester 2014 1 This lecture Buera/Shin (2013) model of financial frictions, misallocation and the transitional dynamics

More information

Vertical Linkages and the Collapse of Global Trade

Vertical Linkages and the Collapse of Global Trade Vertical Linkages and the Collapse of Global Trade Rudolfs Bems International Monetary Fund Robert C. Johnson Dartmouth College Kei-Mu Yi Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Paper prepared for the 2011

More information

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market An overview of the South African labour market from 1 of 2009 to of 2010 August 2010 Contents Recent labour market trends... 2 A brief labour

More information

Svante Öberg: GDP growth and resource utilisation

Svante Öberg: GDP growth and resource utilisation Svante Öberg: GDP growth and resource utilisation Speech by Mr Svante Öberg, First Deputy Governor of the Sveriges Riksbank, at Statistics Sweden s annual conference, Saltsjöbaden, October 11. * * * It

More information

Department of Economics Queen s University. ECON835: Development Economics Instructor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis

Department of Economics Queen s University. ECON835: Development Economics Instructor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis Department of Economics Queen s University ECON835: Development Economics Instructor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis ssignment # nswer Key Due Date: Friday, November 30, 001 Section (40 percent): Discuss the validity

More information

Progress Evaluation of the Transformation of China's Economic Growth Pattern 1 (Preliminary Draft Please do not quote)

Progress Evaluation of the Transformation of China's Economic Growth Pattern 1 (Preliminary Draft Please do not quote) Progress Evaluation of the Transformation of China's Economic Growth Pattern 1 (Preliminary Draft Please do not quote) Si Joong Kim 2 China has been attempting to transform its strategy of economic

More information

Potential Output in Denmark

Potential Output in Denmark 43 Potential Output in Denmark Asger Lau Andersen and Morten Hedegaard Rasmussen, Economics 1 INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY The concepts of potential output and output gap are among the most widely used concepts

More information

How Rich Will China Become? A simple calculation based on South Korea and Japan s experience

How Rich Will China Become? A simple calculation based on South Korea and Japan s experience ECONOMIC POLICY PAPER 15-5 MAY 2015 How Rich Will China Become? A simple calculation based on South Korea and Japan s experience EXECUTIVE SUMMARY China s impressive economic growth since the 1980s raises

More information

). In Ch. 9, when we add technological progress, k is capital per effective worker (k = K

). In Ch. 9, when we add technological progress, k is capital per effective worker (k = K Economics 285 Chris Georges Help With Practice Problems 3 Chapter 8: 1. Questions For Review 1,4: Please see text or lecture notes. 2. A note about notation: Mankiw defines k slightly differently in Chs.

More information

Macroeconomics Lecture 2: The Solow Growth Model with Technical Progress

Macroeconomics Lecture 2: The Solow Growth Model with Technical Progress Macroeconomics Lecture 2: The Solow Growth Model with Technical Progress Richard G. Pierse 1 Introduction In last week s lecture we considered the basic Solow-Swan growth model (Solow (1956), Swan (1956)).

More information

Testing the Solow Growth Theory

Testing the Solow Growth Theory Testing the Solow Growth Theory Dilip Mookherjee Ec320 Lecture 5, Boston University Sept 16, 2014 DM (BU) 320 Lect 5 Sept 16, 2014 1 / 1 EMPIRICAL PREDICTIONS OF SOLOW MODEL WITH TECHNICAL PROGRESS 1.

More information

The global economic landscape has

The global economic landscape has How Much Decoupling? How Much Converging? M. Ayhan Kose, Christopher Otrok, and Eswar Prasad Business cycles may well be converging among industrial and emerging market economies, but the two groups appear

More information

Measuring the Allocation of Australia Post s Reserved Service Productivity Dividend

Measuring the Allocation of Australia Post s Reserved Service Productivity Dividend Measuring the Allocation of Australia Post s Reserved Service Productivity Dividend Report prepared for Australia Post 6 July 2009 Denis Lawrence Economic Insights Pty Ltd 6 Kurundi Place, Hawker, ACT

More information

Technical information: Household data: (202) USDL

Technical information: Household data: (202) USDL 2 Technical information: Household data: (202) 691-6378 http://www.bls.gov/cps/ Establishment data: 691-6555 http://www.bls.gov/ces/ Media contact: 691-5902 USDL 07-1015 Transmission of material in this

More information

Production volume Total Factor Productivity (TFP) =

Production volume Total Factor Productivity (TFP) = Part I Productivity improvement and international business development To achieve improvements in required productivity for both medium and long term economic growth in Japan, this part analyzes the current

More information

Income Inequality in Korea,

Income Inequality in Korea, Income Inequality in Korea, 1958-2013. Minki Hong Korea Labor Institute 1. Introduction This paper studies the top income shares from 1958 to 2013 in Korea using tax return. 2. Data and Methodology In

More information

Six-Year Income Tax Revenue Forecast FY

Six-Year Income Tax Revenue Forecast FY Six-Year Income Tax Revenue Forecast FY 2017-2022 Prepared for the Prepared by the Economics Center February 2017 1 TABLE OF CONTENTS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY... i INTRODUCTION... 1 Tax Revenue Trends... 1 AGGREGATE

More information

Why thinking about economic growth? Kaldor facts old and new Basic tools and concepts

Why thinking about economic growth? Kaldor facts old and new Basic tools and concepts Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Economic Growth Lecture WS 13/14 1. Motivation and Basic Concepts Why thinking about economic growth? Kaldor facts old and new Basic tools and concepts Why thinking about economic

More information

Growth 2. Chapter 6 (continued)

Growth 2. Chapter 6 (continued) Growth 2 Chapter 6 (continued) 1. Solow growth model continued 2. Use the model to understand growth 3. Endogenous growth 4. Labor and goods markets with growth 1 Solow Model with Exogenous Labor-Augmenting

More information

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS LECTURE 5 Douglas Hanley, University of Pittsburgh ENDOGENOUS GROWTH IN THIS LECTURE How does the Solow model perform across countries? Does it match the data we see historically?

More information

UPDATE OF QUARTERLY NATIONAL ACCOUNTS MANUAL: CONCEPTS, DATA SOURCES AND COMPILATION 1 CHAPTER 4. SOURCES FOR OTHER COMPONENTS OF THE SNA 2

UPDATE OF QUARTERLY NATIONAL ACCOUNTS MANUAL: CONCEPTS, DATA SOURCES AND COMPILATION 1 CHAPTER 4. SOURCES FOR OTHER COMPONENTS OF THE SNA 2 UPDATE OF QUARTERLY NATIONAL ACCOUNTS MANUAL: CONCEPTS, DATA SOURCES AND COMPILATION 1 CHAPTER 4. SOURCES FOR OTHER COMPONENTS OF THE SNA 2 Table of Contents 1. Introduction... 2 A. General Issues... 3

More information

Sources for Other Components of the 2008 SNA

Sources for Other Components of the 2008 SNA 4 Sources for Other Components of the 2008 SNA This chapter presents an overview of the sequence of accounts and balance sheets of the 2008 SNA. It is designed to give the compiler of the quarterly GDP

More information

Topic 2. Productivity, technological change, and policy: macro-level analysis

Topic 2. Productivity, technological change, and policy: macro-level analysis Topic 2. Productivity, technological change, and policy: macro-level analysis Lecture 3 Growth econometrics Read Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992, QJE); Durlauf et al. (2004, section 3-7) ; or Temple, J. (1999,

More information

Productivity and Misallocation in General Equilibrium by David Baqaee and Emmanuel Farhi

Productivity and Misallocation in General Equilibrium by David Baqaee and Emmanuel Farhi Productivity and Misallocation in General Equilibrium by David Baqaee and Emmanuel Farhi Discussion by Charles Hulten University of Maryland and NBER at the April 6-7 2018 INET Conference on The Macroeconomics

More information

Sustained Growth of Middle-Income Countries

Sustained Growth of Middle-Income Countries Sustained Growth of Middle-Income Countries Thammasat University Bangkok, Thailand 18 January 2018 Jong-Wha Lee Korea University Background Many middle-income economies have shown diverse growth performance

More information

Economic Perspectives

Economic Perspectives Economic Perspectives What might slower economic growth in Scotland mean for Scotland s income tax revenues? David Eiser Fraser of Allander Institute Abstract Income tax revenues now account for over 40%

More information

Theory of the rate of return

Theory of the rate of return Macroeconomics 2 Short Note 2 06.10.2011. Christian Groth Theory of the rate of return Thisshortnotegivesasummaryofdifferent circumstances that give rise to differences intherateofreturnondifferent assets.

More information

1 The Solow Growth Model

1 The Solow Growth Model 1 The Solow Growth Model The Solow growth model is constructed around 3 building blocks: 1. The aggregate production function: = ( ()) which it is assumed to satisfy a series of technical conditions: (a)

More information

Conditional Convergence Revisited: Taking Solow Very Seriously

Conditional Convergence Revisited: Taking Solow Very Seriously Conditional Convergence Revisited: Taking Solow Very Seriously Kieran McQuinn and Karl Whelan Central Bank and Financial Services Authority of Ireland March 2006 Abstract Output per worker can be expressed

More information

THE U.S. ECONOMY IN 1986

THE U.S. ECONOMY IN 1986 of women in the labor force. Over the past decade, women have accounted for 62 percent of total labor force growth. Increasing labor force participation of women has not led to large increases in unemployment

More information

Citation for published version (APA): Shehzad, C. T. (2009). Panel studies on bank risks and crises Groningen: University of Groningen

Citation for published version (APA): Shehzad, C. T. (2009). Panel studies on bank risks and crises Groningen: University of Groningen University of Groningen Panel studies on bank risks and crises Shehzad, Choudhry Tanveer IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish to cite from it.

More information

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth J.R. Walker U.W. Madison Econ448: Human Resources and Economic Growth Course Roadmap: Seemingly Random Topics First midterm a week from today. What have we covered

More information

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016)

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016) Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016) 68-131 An Investigation of the Structural Characteristics of the Indian IT Sector and the Capital Goods Sector An Application of the

More information