Dynamics of Displaced Worker Earnings and Aggregate Labor Market Fluctuations

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Dynamics of Displaced Worker Earnings and Aggregate Labor Market Fluctuations"

Transcription

1 Dynamics of Displaced Worker Earnings and Aggregate Labor Market Fluctuations Pawel Michal Krolikowski University of Michigan, Ann Arbor September 29, 2012 Preliminary and incomplete: Please do not cite without permission Abstract Previous literature documents large and persistent earnings losses of displaced workers. This paper proposes a sophisticated search and matching model that explains the robust empirical findings pertaining to displaced workers. The model explains persistent earnings losses after displacement with poor match-quality among first jobs in conjunction with a job ladder. Persistent low quality matches in post-displacement employment relationships explain serially correlated displacement spells, which previous empirical studies have found to be an important explanation for the persistence of earnings losses. The model sheds light on the empirically inconclusive movement of earnings prior to displacement. The experience of displaced workers seems to contribute little to the amplification and propagation of productivity shocks at the aggregate level. Nevertheless, recessions have a temporary cleansing effect, and within a year cause average match-quality to fall. JEL Codes: D83, E24, J62, J64. Key words: displacement, earnings, search, match-quality, propagation. Contact information: University of Michigan Department of Economics, 611 Tappan Street, Ann Arbor, MI pawelk@umich.edu. Special thanks go to my committee: Michael W. L. Elsby, Dmitriy Stolyarov, Matthew D. Shapiro and Brian P. McCall, for their constant encouragement, support, critique and commitment to my work. This project would not be what it is without my committee s dedication. I would like to thank University of Michigan s Rackham Graduate School for funding via the Predoctoral Fellowship Program and University of Michigan s Economics Department for funding through the Robert V. Roosa Dissertation Fellowship. I would also like to thank Christopher L. House for his input and intuition throughout this project. I would like to thank Ruediger Bachmann and Alexander Ludwig for featuring my work at the poster session of the 2010 Cologne Workshop on Macroeconomics, and Kenneth L. Judd for enabling me to present my work at the poster session of the 2010 Institute on Computational Economics hosted by the University of Chicago. I want to thank my friends and colleagues Andrew H. McCallum, Daniel P. Murphy, David Ratner, Gabe Ehrlich, David Knapp, and Ryan Nunn for their insights and feedback as I worked through the details of this project, as well as William F. Lincoln, Italo Gutierrez, Ana Mocanu and Andrew Goodman-Bacon for their help at early stages of this work. Finally, I would like to thank all the Michigan Macro-International Lunch and Labor Seminar participants for their comments. I am responsible for any remaining errors.

2 1 Introduction Displacements affect many participants of the United States labor market. 1 According to the Displaced Worker Supplement to the Current Population Survey (CPS), 6.9 million workers with at least three years of tenure experienced job loss due to layoff from 2007 to 2009 (BLS (2010)). An additional 8.5 million persons were displaced from jobs they had held for less than 3 years. As another example, Davis and von Wachter (2011) find that 16 percent of prime-aged males with three or more years of job tenure experienced a job displacement event from 1980 to In conjunction with the high incidence of displacement, there now exists a long and distinguished literature documenting the earnings experience of displaced workers. Although the point estimates differ, economists typically find that displaced workers with three to six years of tenure incur large earnings losses in the year of displacement, and that these losses persist for many years following the displacement event. I present details on this extended literature in Appendix (A), and I point the reader to work by Jacobson et al. (1993), von Wachter et al. (2007) and Schmieder et al. (2009). As an example, Davis and von Wachter (2011) find that prior to displacement, on average, workers experience a slight increase in real earnings: in the year prior to displacement earnings are two percent above the annual earnings of the control group. The authors show that at the time of displacement, real earnings fall sharply, and even twenty years after the time of displacement annual earnings are 15 percent below pre-displacement earnings. The presence of these large and persistent earnings losses for displaced workers has been documented time and time again. The model presented in this paper explains the magnitude and persistence of earnings losses among displaced workers. The first part of the explanation coincides with work by Stevens (1997) who finds that multiple additional job losses are an important part of a workers post-displacement experiences and in the years following an initial displacement serially correlated displacements explain much of the persistence and magnitude in lowered earnings. The model presented here mimics this finding and displays serially correlated displacement spells. The model captures the following intuition: compared to their job prior to displacement, workers might not be as well matched in their first job coming out of unemployment. This poor fit results in tentative new employment relationships as small downward movements in productivity (demand) can cause these relationships to terminate. The second part of the explanation is the presence of a substantial job ladder through the presence of (persistent) match-specific human capital. The job ladder captures the idea that workers suit some jobs better than other jobs, and it takes time for workers to find the jobs for which they are well suited. In conjunction with poor quality matches among first jobs, the job ladder prolongs the earnings recovery path after displacement as unemployed workers enter poor employment relationships and search for better matches while employed. 1 Economists typically define displacement as job loss that results from a firm decision, and not a worker s decision. For example, reasons for job loss that are classified as displacement include layoff, slack work/demand, a plant closing or a position/shift abolished. With administrative data, where reason for job loss is unavailable, researchers often use mass layoffs to identify displacements. 2

3 This paper also sheds some light on movements in earnings prior to displacement. In the baseline estimation, I follow the empirical literature and analyze workers with at least three years of tenure at the time of displacement. This specification implies that agents do not experience any displacements in a three-year window prior to separation. Since the model features idiosyncratic productivity (demand) and endogenous separations, this means that earnings tend to rise prior to displacement, relative to a control, as the three-year tenure requirement restricts the analysis to employment relationships that perform better than average. The empirical literature appears inconclusive on the time-path of earnings prior to displacement, but, as an example, Davis and von Wachter (2011) find that workers experience a slight increase in real earnings prior to displacement. Without conditioning on tenure, the model implies that earnings prior to displacement should fall, due to the serially correlated displacements highlighted in the previous paragraph. This serial correlation implies that agents tend to experience above-average rates of separation prior to displacement. This implies that their average match-quality tends to fall below average, and hence displaced workers experience falling earnings prior to displacement. With a partial equilibrium model that features persistent earnings losses of displaced workers, I use the steady state features of the model to assess the implications of the experience of displaced workers for the cyclical dynamics of job flows. The model provides a novel way to calibrate the match-quality process, using the earnings time-path of displaced workers. Along with an otherwise standard calibration the theory delivers the procyclicality of the job-finding rate for both the unemployed and the employed, as well as the countercyclicality of the employment to unemployment transition rate in the United States. The model also delivers some persistence in unemployment, although the partial equilibrium mechanisms seem to contribute little to the amplification and propagation of aggregate labor productivity shocks. The literature has rarely applied search models to the experience of displaced workers. Davis and von Wachter (2011) come closest to the work presented here. They show that a standard Mortensen-Pissarides model, and a slightly more sophisticated model found in Burgess and Turon (2010), cannot explain the extent of losses observed in the data. The model presented in this paper differs from Burgess and Turon (2010) in a crucial way: the unemployed enter work towards the bottom of the job ladder and workers in first jobs face higher hazard rates of separation into unemployment than workers in established employment relationships. This serial correlation causes cycles of job loss and can significantly raise the costs of one displacement. Although the model presented by Burgess and Turon (2010) also has low idiosyncratic productivity among first jobs, the hazard rate into unemployment is the same for all workers, whereas the model presented here features very fragile new employment relationships. In addition to differing hazard rates into unemployment post displacement, the model presented here features persistent match-quality. This captures the idea that individuals rarely move from being poorly suited for a job to being very well suited for a job. This job-search process usually takes time and the quality of job offers tends to cluster around an individual s current match-quality. Persistent match-quality significantly slows down the recovery of earnings of displaced workers, and provides an improvement over the 3

4 model of Burgess and Turon (2010). Pries (2004) stands as another closely related paper. The work presented here differs in two ways. First, I present a quantitative exercise that matches well the empirical results on displaced worker earnings and provides calibrated values for parameters of interest, whereas Pries (2004) provides only a qualitative discussion about displaced worker earnings. Second, my story hinges on a job ladder and on-the-job search, both of which Pries (2004) omits. Hence, my model can speak to issues, like employer-to-employer (E-E) flows before and after separations, and the extent to which job switches account for the recovery in earnings post displacement. Pries model cannot speak to these dimensions of the data. In particular, my model suggests decreased E-E flows prior to displacement as workers get trapped in failing firms, as well as increased E-E flows after displacement as workers climb the job ladder in search for a better suited job. In Section (5) I present evidence from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) that weakly corroborates the post-displacement E-E flows suggested by the model, but refutes the E-E flows prior to separation. After using the partial equilibrium model to capture the time-path of displaced worker earnings, I next turn to the implications of the model for the aggregate dynamics of vacancies and unemployment. I close the model by introducing the vacancy-posting decision of the firm, which in turn depends on the steady state distribution of idiosyncratic productivity (demand) and match-quality among employed workers. This distribution exhibits slowmoving behavior following a negative aggregate productivity shock as low quality matches are destroyed, and it takes workers time to find new jobs and slowly climb up the job ladder. The implications of this slow moving distribution are relatively limited for aggregate dynamics. Although average match-quality and idiosyncratic productivity (demand) move over the cycle, they have little affect on the expected payoff from meeting an employed worker and therefore relatively little influence on the aggregate vacancy rate and unemployment. These results dovetail with results found in Barlevy (2002), who finds that in a similar model to the one described in this paper, a 72 percent downward, permanent shock to aggregate productivity induces movements in average match-quality of less than one percent. I organize the rest of the paper as follows. Section (2) outlines the quantitative framework and provides some intuition for the dynamics of the model. Section (3) outlines the solution to the theoretical model, and discusses the calibration and identification of key model parameters. The main results of the paper regarding the earnings of displaced workers appear in Section (4). Section (5) discusses external validity of the model. Section (6) presents a discussion about the inadequacy of alternative versions of the model. Section (7) closes the partial equilibrium model by introducing the aggregate vacancy creation condition. Section (8) presents aggregate implications of the partial equilibrium model for aggregate transitions. Section (9) concludes. 4

5 2 The Model 2.1 Model Introduction This paper uses the search and matching framework developed by Mortensen, Diamond and Pissarides. This model extends Mortensen and Pissarides (1994) and Pissarides (2000) by incorporating match specific quality with endogenous job destruction. In other words, two quantities characterize every match: the quality of the match and idiosyncratic productivity (demand). Although the model features undirected on-the-job search, it does not feature intensity of search or search costs. The model features privately efficient separations, which means that worker and firm act to maximize their joint value, as well as exogenous separations. In this model all unemployed workers are equivalent. Their idiosyncratic productivity (demand) does not follow them into unemployment. I assume linear utility (risk-neutrality) throughout. 2.2 Setup This paper presents a partial equilibrium search model. Workers look for jobs and firms post vacancies to attract workers. I assume that each firm only has one vacancy and thus can hire at most one worker. Unemployed workers receive utility from leisure and encounter vacancies at an exogenous probability p U. Employed workers receive a flow payment w and produce a flow output. Employed workers participate in on-the-job search and contact vacancies at a different probability p E. 2 All employer-employee matches are characterized by two state variables: match-quality denoted by y, and an idiosyncratic component denoted by x, which can be interpreted as either productivity or demand. The product of x and y provides the flow output of the match. When an unemployed worker contacts a firm, the match draws an initial, non-stochastic, match-quality equal to y 0. 3 Match-quality remains constant within a job. If the worker encounters a firm via on-the-job search, match-quality is drawn from distribution F y (y y). All initial idiosyncratic productivities (demands) are fixed at a deterministic value, x 0, and then exhibit persistence within a match and evolve according to F x (x x). The model would deliver very similar qualitative results with identically and independently distributed idiosyncratic productivity as in Mortensen and Pissarides (1994). I choose this process for idiosyncratic productivity for calibration purposes. Setting x to x 0 in all new matches follows Mortensen and Pissarides (1994). 4 2 The differing job contact probabilities on and off the job may result from differing levels of search intensity exhibited by the employed and the unemployed. I abstract from the reason behind this difference in the model. 3 Setting match-quality to y 0 in all new matches makes the work focus on what Doeringer and Piore (1971) call port-of-entry jobs. More recently, Martins et al. (2010) similarly focus on jobs that repeatedly show new hires. Assuming the same match-quality in all new jobs suggests there exist a set of entry-level jobs that involve the same amount of job-specific human capital. On a more technical note, with variation in initial y, unemployed individuals reject offers and thus the job finding rate is not equal to the unemployment-toemployment rate. The data do not help us distinguish unemployed individuals who have rejected petty offers and those who have not received any offers. I take the stance that all unemployment is frictional. 4 Alternative versions of the model presented a tension between matching the unemployment-toemployment rate consistent with the size of the earnings dip in the year of displacement and the employmentto-unemployment rate consistent with recovery. This results from a large number of offers evaluating to 5

6 In this model the match-quality, y, can be interpreted as human capital. y provides a mean productivity level and x provides some variance around this mean productivity. Over time on-the-job search results in offers to the employed with match-quality drawn from y F y (y y). This induces a job-ladder which agents climb over time as they acquire human capital. This can be interpreted as finding more suitable jobs within the same firm (promotions) or simply learning specific skills and moving onto jobs that are better suited for the worker. Notice that match-quality exhibits persistence. This captures the idea that individuals rarely move from poor match-qualities to excellent match-qualities. Climbing the job usually takes time and the quality of job offers tends to cluster around your current match-quality. I must note here that the persistence in match-quality is admittedly reduced form. One interpretation may be that y incorporates both general and job-specific human capital, thus exhibiting persistence from job to job. However, the fact that all first jobs start at match-quality equal to y 0 implies that agents lose all their general human capital during unemployment. Although there does exist a literature documenting a reduction in general human capital during unemployment (see for example, Ljungqvist and Sargent (2008) and citations within), the loss of all general human capital seems unrealistic. The idiosyncratic component delivers endogenous flows into unemployment; when the idiosyncratic random variable gets low enough, the worker and the firm decide to part ways. The worker prefers to flow into unemployment and search for a new vacancy, and the firm wants to let the worker go and find a new worker from the pool of searchers. This endogenous separation occurs when the surplus from the match dips below zero. Involuntary separations on either side of the market do not occur in this model. Whenever there exists positive surplus in a match, the worker and firm can negotiate a wage both parties find agreeable. Whenever the surplus from a match is exhausted, firm and worker both want to terminate the current employment relationship. 2.3 Timing of Events within a Period Within each period, events among unemployed workers unfold according to the following timing. At the outset of a period firms post vacancies to recruit unemployed workers and workers look for jobs. When workers contact open vacancies the idiosyncratic productivity (demand) level and match-quality are realized and the worker and firm decide whether to consummate the match. New matches wait until next period to produce. For established employment relationships, or among employed workers, the timing for workers and firms is as follows. First, firm and worker bargain over the wage. Second, production occurs and the firm pays the worker. Third, the idiosyncratic component undergoes a shock. Finally, workers receive outside offers with some probability. If an employed worker receives a favorable outside offer, he moves to the poaching firm. If an employed worker receives no outside offer, below b (the value of leisure) because the variance of the initial x is large (agents prefers to wait because they might draw a really good x). This implies that the variance of the initial x is less than the variance of the x once a match is consummated. Here I take a particularly stark version where x = x 0. This allows the unemployment-to-employment rate to be high and the employment-to-unemployment rate to be high. This assumption suggests that workers start with the same level of productivity (demand) in all jobs. 6

7 the firm and the employee decide to preserve the match or separate (separation may occur because of negative surplus or the exogenous separation shock). 2.4 Bargaining At the beginning of each period, every worker-firm pair bargains over the wage, w(x, y), that the firm pays the worker for production. I assume a standard generalized Nash bargaining rule over the total surplus of the match, so that the worker receives a fraction β of the total surplus and the firm receives a fraction (1 β) of the total match surplus. 2.5 Intuition for the Partial Equilibrium Model Before I discuss the formal model equations, I want to provide a simple description of the model dynamics and give the reader intuition for the mechanics of the model. The model delivers a slow recovery in earnings post-displacement for three reasons. First, immediately post-displacement, the calibrated model suggests that workers take jobs with lower matchqualities, compared to their pre-displacement jobs, and the average match-quality among employed workers. Second, in conjunction with a low match quality among first jobs, the job ladder effect introduces persistence in earnings; it takes time for employed workers to find good quality matches. Third, low post-displacement match-qualities mean that newly created jobs are likely close to the job destruction threshold. This makes it more likely that these matches will be destroyed, resulting in multiple displacements and serial unemployment. This serial unemployment effect dovetails with work by Stevens (1997) who finds that multiple job losses are an important explanation for the persistence of earnings losses. Prior to separation the model provides the following intuition about earnings. Without any tenure requirements, earnings tend to fall even prior to displacement due to the serial correlation in displacements outlined in the previous paragraph. This serial correlation implies that workers tend to experience above-average rates of separation prior to displacement. This implies that their average match-quality tends to fall below average, as the calibrated value of match-quality in first jobs, y 0, lies below the average match-quality in the economy. Due to this decline in average match-quality prior to displacement, average earnings tend to fall even prior to displacement. Although the empirical evidence on the movements of earnings prior to displacement remain inconclusive, some displaced workers experience declining earnings prior to displacement (see, for example, Jacobson et al. (1993)). In order to follow the empirical literature, in the baseline results I estimate the earnings losses associated with displacement using workers who have at least three years of tenure at the time of displacement. This treatment group, therefore, experiences no displacements during the three years prior to their displacement. Since the model features idiosyncratic productivity (demand) and endogenous separations, this implies that the average idiosyncratic component for this restricted sample must exceed the average idiosyncratic component for the average worker. This implies that earnings tend to rise prior to displacement, relative to a control group, as the three-year tenure requirement restricts the analysis to employment relationships that perform better than average. 7

8 2.6 Bellman Equations Joint Value of a Match Define the continuation value of employed workers and firms as W (x, y, w) and J(x, y, w) respectively. Let U be the continuation value of unemployed workers. Free entry into vacancies implies that the firm s value of a vacancy is zero. For notational convenience, define the joint value as the sum of the value of a match to the worker and the firm: V (x, y) = W (x, y, w) + J(x, y, w) Notice that w does not change the joint value of a match V ; it merely determines the allocation of the joint value between worker and firm. A higher w implies that the worker receives more of the match value. The joint value function satisfies: V (x, y) = x y + δ (1 p E ) (1 p }{{} s ) }{{} No outside No + δ p }{{} E (1 p s ) Outside offer + δp s U offer separation shock max{u, V (x, y) }{{} Match continues max{v (x, y), U} df }{{} x (x x) Match continues or terminates, V (x 0, y )} }{{} Worker moves to poaching firm }df x (x x)df y (y y) where p E is the probability of contacting an outside firm, p s is the probability of an exogenous separation shock, δ stands for the discount factor and β represents the bargaining power of the worker. The flow payoff from the match equals x y, the product of productivity and matchquality. Every period a shock to productivity arrives. In the event of no outside job offer (occurs with probability 1 p E ), and no exogenous separations shock (occurs with probability p s ) the employment relationship either continues with joint value V (x, y), or a separation occurs. In the event of separation, the worker receives continuation value U and the firm is left with nothing (remember that the value of a vacancy is zero in equilibrium), which makes the joint continuation value U. Notice that the V (x, y) term captures renegotiation: the employment relationship continues, but a new wage, w, divides the surplus differently. When a productivity shock occurs and the worker contacts an outside firm, three things can happen. 5 First, the outside offer could be worse than the current match, and the productivity shock makes the current match unbearable. This causes a separation, which leaves the worker with U and the firm with zero. Second, the current employment relationship continues with V (x, y). Third, the outside offer induces renegotiation and the worker leaves the current firm (V (x 0, y ) exceeds V (x, y)). In this case, I assume that the workers use unemployment as their outside offer and the continuation value is simply V (x 0, y ), the joint value at the new firm. In particular, I assume that workers cannot use their current offer as a starting point for bargaining. 5 Note that separation shocks occur prior to outside offers so that receiving a separation shock implies workers move into unemployment whether they have an outside offer or not. 8 (1)

9 Finally, if the match receives an exogenous separation shock, the worker flows into unemployment and the match value equals U Value of Work to the Employee The value of work satisfies the following equation: W (x, y) = w + δ(1 p E )(1 p s ) + δp E (1 p s ) + δp s U max{u, W (x, y), W (x 0, y )} }{{} Worker moves to unemployment, stays at current firm, or goes to new firm max{w (x, y), U} }{{} Match continues or terminates df x (x x)df y (y y) df x (x x) (2) The value of work is a function of two state variables: the idiosyncratic productivity x and the match-quality y. The first term on the right-hand side is the flow payoff from working, which is the current wage: w. Note that I assume a linear utility function (risk-neutrality). The second term on the right-hand side corresponds to the event of no outside job offer. Since I assume the productivity shock arrives every period, I need to consider what happens when the productivity changes. If W (x, y) > U the relationship is still viable (there is positive surplus), and the worker and firm immediately re-bargain to obtain the new wage. If V (x, y) < U the relationship is no longer viable. The employment partnership comes to an end. The third term on the right-hand side corresponds to the worker contacting an outside firm (and a productivity shock). The worker leaves the current employment relationship only if the match value of the new match exceeds the value at the current firm. The timing here is important: the value from the current match and the value at the poaching firm are compared after the shock to current productivity (demand) arrives. In this case, the worker chooses between two options: unemployment and working at the new firm. In the latter case, the worker bargains with the outside firm using unemployment as his outside option. In the event that the match value at the current firm exceeds both the value of unemployment and and the match value at the outside firm, the worker remains at the current firm receiving value W (x, y). If U > max{w (x, y), W (x x 0, y )), the surplus at the current firm and the outside offer falls below zero, and so the worker moves to unemployment receiving continuation value U. Finally, if the match receives an exogenous separation shock, the worker flows into unemployment and the continuation value equals U. 9

10 Given the previous definitions, the value of a filled job to the firm is simply: J(x, y, w) = V (x, y) W (x, y, w) (3) Value of Unemployment The value of unemployment satisfies: U = b + δ(1 p U )U + δp U max{u + β[v (x 0, y 0 ) U], U} }{{} Match consummates or not (4) where p U is the probability of making a contact with a vacancy for unemployed workers. The first term captures the flow payoff from unemployment: b. The second term corresponds to no outside job offer. In this case the worker simply remains unemployed. The third term corresponds to an outside job offer. In this case the worker chooses between working at the contacting firm and unemployment. The payoff from working at the firm is the outside option, U, plus β times the surplus, which is [V (x 0, y 0 ) U]. 2.7 Solving the Partial Equilibrium Model I derive one central functional equation in the surplus from a match, S(x, y). Appendix (B) provides the details of this derivation. Here I simply present the result: S(x, y) = x y + δ (1 p E ) (1 p }{{} s ) max{0, S(x, y) }df }{{}}{{} x (x x) No outside No Match + δp E (1 p s ) offer separation shock max{0, S(x, y) }{{} Match [b + δp U β max{0, S(x 0, y 0 )}] }{{} Worker s outside option continues continues, S(x 0, y ) }{{} Worker moves to poaching firm }df x (x x)df y (y y) The first part of the right hand side is the flow payoff from a match, x y. The second piece captures the event of no outside job offer, no exogenous separation shock and the continuation value of the match. In this case, the match either comes to an end or the match continues with the new idiosyncratic productivity (demand). The third piece captures the event of the worker receiving an outside offer and potentially moving to the poaching firm. When the worker moves to the poaching firm he uses unemployment as a threat point. The final piece is the outside option of an employed worker: he forgoes the value of unemployment, b, and the possibility of finding a job at a new firm with surplus S(x 0, y 0 ) and receiving β of this surplus. Notice that equation (5) is a functional equation in only S(x, y). Value function iteration yields a close approximation to this function, denoted by Ŝ(x, y). (5) 10

11 Assuming a Nash bargain for the wage pins down the equilibrium wage equation as a function of (x, y). I present the details in Appendix (B), and here I state the result: w(x, y) = βs(x, y) + [b + δp U β max{0, S(x 0, y 0 )}] }{{} δ (1 p E ) (1 p }{{} s ) β }{{} No outside No offer separation shock δp E (1 p s )β Worker s outside option max{0, S(x, y) }df }{{} x (x x) Match max{0, S(x, y) }{{} Match continues continues, S(x 0, y ) }{{} Worker moves to poaching firm }df x (x x)df y (y y) (6) The worker receives a fraction β of the total surplus along with the value of his outside option, which incorporates the possibility of finding a new job. The wage must also reflect the possible changes in future idiosyncratic productivity, the possibility of poaching by an outside firm, and the event of an exogenous separation. 3 Estimation Strategy 3.1 Processes for x and y I set the model period length to one month. I assume that idiosyncratic productivity starts out at a fixed and deterministic level x 0 in all matches, and then within the match follows a log AR(1) process: ln x = ρ x ln x + ɛ x (7) where ɛ x N (0, σ 2 ɛ x ). Match-quality follows the following distribution: ln y 0 for jobs out of unemployment (U E) ln y = ln y if no job change ρ y ln y + ɛ y if changes jobs (E E) where ɛ y N (0, σ 2 ɛ y ). In other words, match-quality remains constant within a job, and is distributed according to a log AR(1) process when a worker meets a new firm. In the first job coming out of unemployment, match-quality is set to y Estimation Methodology I refer the reader to Appendix (C.1) for details regarding value function iteration. Given the optimal decisions of workers and firms, the model generates simulated data at a monthly frequency. In particular, I simulate 15,000 agents for 480 months (40 years). To remove the effects of initial conditions, I simulate the model for 1280 months and then discard the 11

12 first 800 months of the sample. This simulation provides a time-path of wages and annual earnings, as well as an employment history. I compare the earnings of displaced workers in the model-generated data with the earnings of displaced workers observed in live data. I calibrate the parameters of the model using simulated method of moments. Certain key moments summarize the simulated data; among others, these moments include gross flows between employment and unemployment, establishment-level productivity processes, and the time-path of earnings for displaced workers. Simulated method of moments estimation minimizes the distance between the summary statistics of the simulated data and the summary statistics of real data. Specifically, if θ represents the vector of structural parameters, ĝ represents the moments of the actual data, and g(θ) represents the moments of simulated data then the simulated minimum distance estimator is defined as ˆθ = arg min L(θ) = arg min[g(θ) ĝ] [g(θ) ĝ] (8) θ θ Here g(θ) represents a non-linear transformation of the structural parameters by the model, as well as an analysis of the simulated data to achieve a moment that is comparable to the moment from the real data. Some of the targeted moments are parameters of an auxiliary model, such as coefficients from an estimated equation using the observed data. In this sense, the approach here implements a technique called indirect inference. 3.3 Calibration/Identification In this section I present the key moments of the data and discuss the identification strategy. When discussing the identification strategy I describe how changes in parameters effect moments of the simulated data. Due to the high non-linearity of the model, no one moment pins down identification of a parameter. Nevertheless elucidating the identification of key components of the model is a worthwhile exercise. Table (1) summarizes the baseline parameters. Table (2) shows that the model gets close to matching the calibration targets. Parameter Meaning Value Reason (θ) (ˆθ) ρ x Productivity persistence 0.99 (M) Persistence of plant productivity σ ɛx Std. dev. of productivity 0.04 Std. dev. of plant productivity ρ y Match-quality persistence 0.93 (M) Recovery of displacement earnings σ ɛy Std. dev. of match-quality 0.15 On-impact dip of annual earnings p E Contact probability (E) Employer-to-Employer flow probability p U Contact probability (U) 0.45 Aggregate job-finding probability b Value of leisure 0.71 APL Hall and Milgrom(2008) x 0 Starting productivity 1.13 E[x match] Employment-to-Unemployment flow probability p s Exogenous separation probability Pre-displacement earnings y 0 Match-quality in first jobs E[y] 1 Normalization Table 1: Calibrated Model Parameters The x y process represents movements in total factor productivity. Foster et al. (2008) use the Census of Manufacturers to estimate the annual persistence in establishment-level 12

13 persistence to be I choose ρ x to match this observed persistence in establishmentlevel productivity. More explicitly, I choose ρ x and then estimate the following equation via OLS using the simulated data: x t+1 y t+1 = β 0 + β 1 x t y t + ξ t+1 (9) where x y represents TFP in my model, and Foster et al. (2008) find that ˆβ 1 [0.75, 0.8]. β 1 depends positively on ρ x, because raising ρ x increases the persistence of the idiosyncratic productivity process, which in turn increases the observed persistence of idiosyncratic total factor productivity in the simulated data. The variance of ɛ x is set to match the standard deviation of plant-level productivity. Foster et al. (2008) estimate the standard deviation for plant level productivity (in logs) to be between 0.21 and 0.26 (table (1) of their paper). They take the log of the product of productivity at all plants, and calculate the standard deviation. I follow an equivalent procedure with the simulated and take the log of the product of x and y among all matches and calculate the standard deviation. In the calibration, this value is a little higher than in the data. The starting idiosyncratic productivity for unemployed individuals, x 0, is targeted to generate the employment to unemployment (E-U) instantaneous transition rate found in the United States gross flows data. As I raise x 0, unemployment becomes more and more appealing because the first job coming out of unemployment has higher productivity. This induces a larger fraction of the employed to flow into unemployment every period. Elsby et al. (2010) find the layoff inflow rate is around 1.5 percent (table 9). This is similar to the E-U transition rate, which is around 1.7 percent (table 10). Since most displacements occur through no fault of the worker using the layoff inflow rate is an appropriate target. The calibrated value of x 0 lies above the steady state expectation of x, which implies, on average, a downward drift in productivity after match consummation. Further, this suggests that agents sometimes switch to jobs with lower match qualities in order to reset the idiosyncratic productivity to x 0. Intuitively, this suggests that sometimes workers leave behind good quality matches and move to jobs with very high idiosyncratic productivity. Nevertheless, on average, workers match-qualities and wages rise over their lifetime. The standard deviation of match-quality is difficult to quantify in the data. The model provides a convenient way of calibrating this parameter: the on-impact dip in earnings resulting from displacement. Increasing the dispersion in y implies that agents on average move further up the job ladder, and have more earnings to lose, when they experience a displacement. This increases the on-impact dip in earnings resulting from displacements. The resulting estimate of σ ɛy seems reasonable. As an alternative, in a very similar model to the one presented here, Low et al. (2010) estimate the standard deviation of match-quality at My estimate lies at around 70 percent of this value. I target the trajectory of the post-displacement earnings recovery using the persistence of match-quality. In particular, raising the dependence of outside offers on current offers implies 13

14 that workers move slowly up the job ladder and therefore post-displacement earnings tend to recover slowly. As an extreme example, suppose that match-quality followed a random walk. Then, in expectation, worker s match-quality would move up very slowly as the current match-quality would serve as the best predictor of the worker s match-quality at an outside offer. With this process for match-quality, after being displaced, a worker would move up the job ladder very slowly, rarely encountering offers better than his current offer. This would significantly slow down the recovery of earnings. I use p E to generate the observed E-E transition rate. This relationship is quite obvious. Raising the number of contacts employed workers have with outside firms raises the probability that workers experience E-E switches. Intuitively, this implies that E-E flows in the model are monotonically increasing in p E. Fallick and Fleischman (2004) use data from the basic monthly Current Population Survey (CPS) from January 1994 to December They find that an average of 2.6 percent of employed persons change employers each month. More recently Nagypal (2008) finds similar results using the CPS: 2.88 percent for all observations and 2.5 percent for all observations of age She finds using the SIPP that the E-E rate is about 25 percent lower than in the CPS: 2.2 percent. I target a monthly E-E transition rate of 2.6 percent. The contact probability for the unemployed, p U, is determined by targeting the aggregate job-finding probability. Increasing the job-contact rate means that unemployed workers experience more frequent contacts and since workers accept all first offers in this model, the unemployment-to-employment (U-E) probability rises. Following Shimer (2005) I target a monthly job-finding probability of I choose p s, the exogenous separation rate, to target a slight increase in earnings for hightenured workers prior to displacement. There appears to be no empirical consensus on the movement of earnings prior to displacement. Some studies, such as Jacobson et al. (1993) or von Wachter et al. (2007), find a large reduction in earnings even prior to displacement. Other studies, such as Davis and von Wachter (2011) or Couch and Placzek (2010), find a rise in earnings prior to displacement. The calibration of p s does not make a significant difference to the results that I present in the rest of this paper, so I decide to target the most recent, comprehensive study on displaced worker earnings, Davis and von Wachter (2011), using Social Security Administration data in the United States. As a comparison, with only exogenous separations (p s = 0.015) in the model there would be no movement, on average, in earnings prior to displacement because exogenous separations occur randomly. Alternatively, if all the displacements in the model were endogenous (p s = 0) then, conditioning on three years of tenure at the time of displacement, earnings will rise in the three years prior to displacement. This follow because match-quality is fixed due to the tenure restriction and idiosyncratic productivity rises as the agents do not experience any separations in three years and therefore their idiosyncratic productivity must rise relative to the control group. 14

15 Moments in the data Data Model (ĝ) (g(ˆθ)) Pesistence of Foster et al.(2008): plant productivity (A) 0.58 (A) Annual std. dev. of Foster et al.(2008): plant productivity (logs) Recovery of post- Davis and von Wachter(2011): displacement earnings 20% 20% On-impact dip of Davis and von Wachter(2011): annual earnings 30% 28% Employer-to- Fallick and employer flows Fleischman(2004): Job-finding rate Shimer(2005): Value of leisure Hall and Milgrom(2008): 0.71 AP L 0.71 AP L Employment-to- Elsby et al. (2010): Unemployment flows Pre-displacement Davis and von Wachter(2011): rise in earnings 3% 2% Table 2: Calibration Targets I set b to be consistent with the value found in Hall and Milgrom (2008): 0.71 of average productivity of labor (APL). 6 Previous literature, such as Hagedorn and Manovskii (2008), show that that the calibration of this parameter is important for the volatility of unemployment and the job finding rate predicted by the model. The emphasis of this paper is not the cyclical behavior of unemployment and vacancies over the business cycle, so the calibration of this parameter is less crucial. The value found in Hall and Milgrom (2008) serves as a benchmark. I calibrate the bargaining power of the worker, β, to 0.5. This serves as a benchmark, and is close to the calibrated figure used by Elsby and Michaels (2010). The literature provides little guidance in terms of how to calibrate this parameter. In the partial equilibrium context, I cannot use the Hosios (1990) result and impose efficiency by equating the worker s bargaining power with the elasticity of the matching function with respect to the unemployment rate. The results presented below are robust to the choice of β. Finally, I choose r to target a five percent annual interested rate. 6 Calculating the average labor productivity analytically involves integrating x y against the joint density of (x, y) among matches. This joint distribution differs from F x and F y because of selection in the model. Solving for this joint distribution involves equating outflow and inflows from regions of this joint distribution, much like in Burdett and Moretensen (1998) and solving explicitly for this distribution involves iterating on functional equations, which involve the value functions of this model. Hence, solving numerically for this distribution makes the computational burden of the algorithm overwhelming. To avoid this, I simply set b to be a fraction of the unconditional average labor productivity and then find after simulating the data because with the simulated data I can simply compute the ALP by averaging x y over all workers and all time periods. b ALP 15

16 4 Results 4.1 Earnings Dynamics Around Displacement To compare the simulated data to the observed data, I aggregate the simulated monthly wage data into annual earnings data and estimate an equivalent equation to the one found in Davis and von Wachter (2011): 7 e it = α i + 20 k= 6 D k itδ k + ɛ it (10) where the outcome variable e it is annual earnings of individual i in year t, α i represent individual fixed effects, and D k it are dummy variables equal to one in the worker s kth year before or after his displacement, and zero otherwise. Davis and von Wachter (2011) estimate: e y it = αy i + γy t + ē y i λy t + βx it + 20 k= 6 D k itδ k + u y it (11) where the new variables γ y t are coefficients on calender-year fixed effects, X it is a quartic polynomial in the age of worker i at year t, the error u y it represents random factors, and λy t allows annual earnings increments to differ by a worker s initial level of earnings, calculated using the years y 5 to y 1 (ē y i ). My model does not feature time variation that needs to be controlled by using time fixed effects hence I omit γ y t and λ y t from the estimated equation. As expected, including these variables in the regression has no impact on the estimated coefficients. Furthermore, I omit the y superscript because all years in my model are identical, so I fix y at an arbitrary year. As in Davis and von Wachter (2011), I restrict my sample to individuals who have at least three years of tenure at the time of displacement. Figure (1) presents a comparison between the results from my model and the results from Davis and von Wachter (2011). 8 The model captures the time-path of earnings so well that its implied movements in earnings are difficult to differentiate from the results based on real data. It seems that the search model outlined in this paper can account for the time-path of displaced worker earnings. in particular, the model outlined in this paper suggests that luck can account for all the earnings losses associated with displacement. 7 A non-trivially different specification can be found in Stevens (1997) or Jacobson et al. (1993). These studies focus on the earnings losses around the first displacement. In a short accompanying paper (Krolikowski (2012)) I explicitly show that the distributed lag models initially implemented in Jacobson et al. (1993), and used in the literature for the last 20 years, measure the losses associated with displacement relative to a time when the treated workers experience no displacements, i.e. prior to their first displacement. It comes as no surprise that workers who intermittently experience displacement have persistently lower earnings than they had when they did not experience any job loss. In alternate versions of this model, including versions with no persistence in match-quality, the model was able to deliver losses using these alternate specifications, but could not target the losses from the specification found in Davis and von Wachter (2011), which measures the earnings losses with respect to any displacement, not just the first displacement. 8 As in Davis and von Wachter (2011) I plot the estimated δ k coefficients, which are earnings losses relative to a non-displaced control group with the same tenure requirement as the displaced treatment group, relative to the average pre-displacement earnings of the treatment group in the 4 years prior to displacement. 16

17 Figure 1: Annual Earnings Losses: Model vs. Data The model captures the slight movement in earnings prior to displacement well, except for the downward movement in earnings in years -6, -5 and -4. On impact the model predicts well the losses in annual earnings: around 30 percent. Additionally, the model captures the movements in earnings post-displacement very well. After 20 years the model delivers similar losses to those found in the data. The downward movement in earnings in years -6, -5 and -4 results from serial correlation in displacements, which implies that workers displaced in time period 0 experience displacements before this time, and this lowers the average match-quality and therefore average earnings. This downward movement in earnings also results from the fact that, relative to a control group, those displaced in time period 0 experience fewer job offers while employed. This captures the notion that workers that experience displacement get trapped at failing firms without an outside offer. Loss in match-quality results in the on-impact dip in earnings, as workers fall from higher rungs of the job ladder, to a low job rung in their first job out of unemployment. On-impact, idiosyncratic productivity rises because x 0 > E[x match]. Earnings fall slightly in the year following displacement because some workers get displaced late in the 0 year and so have a substantial amount of earnings in the year of displacement. Since it takes unemployed workers time to find jobs, and y 0 < E[y match] so that first jobs pay very little, in the year immediately following displacement workers may actually experience a small dip in earnings. In addition to this timing issue, the high serial correlation in displacements implies that in the year following the investigated displacement, the worker may experience subsequent displacements which reduce his annual earnings even further. The slow recovery in earnings represents the slow move up the job ladder for recently displaced workers, which in turn manifests the persistence of match-quality and serial correlation in displacements. In particular, due to persistent match-quality agents receive outside offers which closely resemble their current job. Agents experience serially correlated displacements because match-quality remains low in first jobs and therefore only small movements in idiosyncratic productivity cause further displacements. 17

Equilibrium Dynamics of Displaced Worker Earnings

Equilibrium Dynamics of Displaced Worker Earnings Equilibrium Dynamics of Displaced Worker Earnings Pawel Michal Krolikowski Department of Economics, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI 48109-1220, USA Abstract Previous literature documents large and

More information

Job Heterogeneity and Aggregate Labor Market Fluctuations

Job Heterogeneity and Aggregate Labor Market Fluctuations Job Heterogeneity and Aggregate Labor Market Fluctuations Pawel Krolikowski University of Michigan PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE; PLEASE DO NOT CITE OR CIRCULATE Abstract Individual data show that workers

More information

Job Ladders and Earnings of Displaced Workers

Job Ladders and Earnings of Displaced Workers w o r k i n g p a p e r 15 14 Job Ladders and Earnings of Displaced Workers Pawel Krolikowski FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland are preliminary materials

More information

Labor-market Volatility in a Matching Model with Worker Heterogeneity and Endogenous Separations

Labor-market Volatility in a Matching Model with Worker Heterogeneity and Endogenous Separations Labor-market Volatility in a Matching Model with Worker Heterogeneity and Endogenous Separations Andri Chassamboulli April 15, 2010 Abstract This paper studies the business-cycle behavior of a matching

More information

Choosing a Control Group for Displaced Workers

Choosing a Control Group for Displaced Workers w o r k i n g p a p e r 16 05 Choosing a Control Group for Displaced Workers Pawel Krolikowski FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND Working papers of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland are preliminary

More information

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2521 Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model Vincent Bodart Olivier Pierrard Henri R. Sneessens December 2006 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for

More information

Comparative Advantage and Labor Market Dynamics

Comparative Advantage and Labor Market Dynamics Comparative Advantage and Labor Market Dynamics Weh-Sol Moon* The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the official views of the Bank of Korea. When reporting or

More information

New Business Start-ups and the Business Cycle

New Business Start-ups and the Business Cycle New Business Start-ups and the Business Cycle Ali Moghaddasi Kelishomi (Joint with Melvyn Coles, University of Essex) The 22nd Annual Conference on Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies Banking Supervision

More information

The Fundamental Surplus in Matching Models. European Summer Symposium in International Macroeconomics, May 2015 Tarragona, Spain

The Fundamental Surplus in Matching Models. European Summer Symposium in International Macroeconomics, May 2015 Tarragona, Spain The Fundamental Surplus in Matching Models Lars Ljungqvist Stockholm School of Economics New York University Thomas J. Sargent New York University Hoover Institution European Summer Symposium in International

More information

Collective bargaining, firm heterogeneity and unemployment

Collective bargaining, firm heterogeneity and unemployment Collective bargaining, firm heterogeneity and unemployment Juan F. Jimeno and Carlos Thomas Banco de España ESSIM, May 25, 2012 Jimeno & Thomas (BdE) Collective bargaining ESSIM, May 25, 2012 1 / 39 Motivation

More information

Lecture 24 Unemployment. Noah Williams

Lecture 24 Unemployment. Noah Williams Lecture 24 Unemployment Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 702 Basic Facts About the Labor Market US Labor Force in March 2018: 161.8 million people US working age population on

More information

The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation

The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation Chung Gu Chee The Ohio State University November 10, 2012 Abstract In this paper, I investigate the role of operative labor supply margin in explaining

More information

The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation

The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation The Effect of Labor Supply on Unemployment Fluctuation Chung Gu Chee The Ohio State University November 10, 2012 Abstract In this paper, I investigate the role of operative labor supply margin in explaining

More information

Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil

Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil Niklas Engbom June 16, 2016 Christian Moser World Bank-Bank of Spain Conference This project Shed light on drivers of earnings inequality

More information

Financial Risk and Unemployment

Financial Risk and Unemployment Financial Risk and Unemployment Zvi Eckstein Tel Aviv University and The Interdisciplinary Center Herzliya Ofer Setty Tel Aviv University David Weiss Tel Aviv University PRELIMINARY DRAFT: February 2014

More information

Comment. John Kennan, University of Wisconsin and NBER

Comment. John Kennan, University of Wisconsin and NBER Comment John Kennan, University of Wisconsin and NBER The main theme of Robert Hall s paper is that cyclical fluctuations in unemployment are driven almost entirely by fluctuations in the jobfinding rate,

More information

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters A. Kerem Coşar Davide Suverato kerem.cosar@chicagobooth.edu davide.suverato@econ.lmu.de University of Chicago Booth School of Business

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home midterm exam. 1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility The purpose of this question is to explore a labor market puzzle that has bedeviled business

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt WORKING PAPER NO. 08-15 THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt Keith Kuester Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Final version

More information

Lecture 6 Search and matching theory

Lecture 6 Search and matching theory Lecture 6 Search and matching theory Leszek Wincenciak, Ph.D. University of Warsaw 2/48 Lecture outline: Introduction Search and matching theory Search and matching theory The dynamics of unemployment

More information

Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment

Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment Political Lobbying in a Recurring Environment Avihai Lifschitz Tel Aviv University This Draft: October 2015 Abstract This paper develops a dynamic model of the labor market, in which the employed workers,

More information

Lecture Notes. Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2015, Endogenous Disasters) Lu Zhang 1. BUSFIN 8210 The Ohio State University

Lecture Notes. Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2015, Endogenous Disasters) Lu Zhang 1. BUSFIN 8210 The Ohio State University Lecture Notes Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2015, Endogenous Disasters) Lu Zhang 1 1 The Ohio State University BUSFIN 8210 The Ohio State University Insight The textbook Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 7 - Labor markets: Introduction & the search model March. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 7 - Labor markets: Introduction & the search model March. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 7 - Labor markets: Introduction & the search model Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 March The neoclassical model of the labor market central question for macro and labor: what

More information

The Employment and Output Effects of Short-Time Work in Germany

The Employment and Output Effects of Short-Time Work in Germany The Employment and Output Effects of Short-Time Work in Germany Russell Cooper Moritz Meyer 2 Immo Schott 3 Penn State 2 The World Bank 3 Université de Montréal Social Statistics and Population Dynamics

More information

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl) University of California, Davis Date: September 1, 2011 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Macroeconomics Reading Time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Directions: Answer all

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Economics 3307 - Intermediate Macroeconomics Aaron Hedlund Baylor University Fall 2013 Econ 3307 (Baylor University) The Real Business Cycle Model Fall 2013 1 / 23 Business

More information

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims FINAL EXAM. β t 1 2 φτ2 t subject to (1)

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims FINAL EXAM. β t 1 2 φτ2 t subject to (1) Eco54 Spring 21 C. Sims FINAL EXAM There are three questions that will be equally weighted in grading. Since you may find some questions take longer to answer than others, and partial credit will be given

More information

Macroeconomics of the Labour Market Problem Set

Macroeconomics of the Labour Market Problem Set Macroeconomics of the Labour Market Problem Set dr Leszek Wincenciak Problem 1 The utility of a consumer is given by U(C, L) =α ln C +(1 α)lnl, wherec is the aggregate consumption, and L is the leisure.

More information

Wage Posting and Business Cycles

Wage Posting and Business Cycles Wage Posting and Business Cycles By GIUSEPPE MOSCARINI AND FABIEN POSTEL-VINAY The canonical framework of Burdett and Mortensen (1998) derives wage dispersion as the unique equilibrium outcome in a stationary

More information

Costly Commuting and the Job Ladder

Costly Commuting and the Job Ladder Costly Commuting and the Job Ladder [preliminary and incomplete] Jean Flemming University of Oxford ESEM Lisbon August 23, 2017 Motivating Facts Job-to-job (J2J) transitions are important for wage growth

More information

Applications and Interviews

Applications and Interviews pplications and Interviews Firms Recruiting Decisions in a Frictional Labor Market Online ppendix Ronald Wolthoff University of Toronto May 29, 207 C Calibration Details C. EOPP Data Background. The Employment

More information

Employment, Unemployment and Turnover

Employment, Unemployment and Turnover Employment, Unemployment and Turnover D. Andolfatto June 2011 Introduction In an earlier chapter, we studied the time allocation problem max { ( ) : = + + =1} We usually assume an interior solution; i.e.,

More information

LABOR-MARKET VOLATILITY IN A MATCHING MODEL WITH WORKER HETEROGENEITY AND ENDOGENOUS SEPARATIONS

LABOR-MARKET VOLATILITY IN A MATCHING MODEL WITH WORKER HETEROGENEITY AND ENDOGENOUS SEPARATIONS DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS LABOR-MARKET VOLATILITY IN A MATCHING MODEL WITH WORKER HETEROGENEITY AND ENDOGENOUS SEPARATIONS Andri Chassamboulli Discussion Paper 2010-13 P.O. Box 20537,

More information

A Quantitative Analysis of Unemployment Benefit Extensions

A Quantitative Analysis of Unemployment Benefit Extensions A Quantitative Analysis of Unemployment Benefit Extensions Makoto Nakajima February 8, 211 First draft: January 19, 21 Abstract This paper measures the effect of extensions of unemployment insurance (UI)

More information

Small Sample Bias Using Maximum Likelihood versus. Moments: The Case of a Simple Search Model of the Labor. Market

Small Sample Bias Using Maximum Likelihood versus. Moments: The Case of a Simple Search Model of the Labor. Market Small Sample Bias Using Maximum Likelihood versus Moments: The Case of a Simple Search Model of the Labor Market Alice Schoonbroodt University of Minnesota, MN March 12, 2004 Abstract I investigate the

More information

Aggregate Demand and the Dynamics of Unemployment

Aggregate Demand and the Dynamics of Unemployment Aggregate Demand and the Dynamics of Unemployment Edouard Schaal 1 Mathieu Taschereau-Dumouchel 2 1 New York University and CREI 2 The Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania 1/34 Introduction

More information

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application Russell Cooper, John Haltiwanger and Jonathan Willis January 2005 Abstract This paper studies capital adjustment costs. Our goal here

More information

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism RIETI Discussion Paper Series 09-E-05 Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism INABA Masaru The Canon Institute for Global Studies KOBAYASHI Keiichiro RIETI The

More information

TFP Decline and Japanese Unemployment in the 1990s

TFP Decline and Japanese Unemployment in the 1990s TFP Decline and Japanese Unemployment in the 1990s Julen Esteban-Pretel Ryo Nakajima Ryuichi Tanaka GRIPS Tokyo, June 27, 2008 Japan in the 1990s The performance of the Japanese economy in the 1990s was

More information

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment Chapter 6 Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment In Romer s IS/MP/IA model, we assume prices/inflation adjust imperfectly when output changes. Empirically, there is a negative relationship

More information

Aggregate Implications of Indivisible Labor, Incomplete Markets, and Labor Market Frictions

Aggregate Implications of Indivisible Labor, Incomplete Markets, and Labor Market Frictions Aggregate Implications of Indivisible Labor, Incomplete Markets, and Labor Market Frictions Per Krusell Toshihiko Mukoyama Richard Rogerson Ayşegül Şahin October 2007 Abstract This paper analyzes a model

More information

Chapter II: Labour Market Policy

Chapter II: Labour Market Policy Chapter II: Labour Market Policy Section 2: Unemployment insurance Literature: Peter Fredriksson and Bertil Holmlund (2001), Optimal unemployment insurance in search equilibrium, Journal of Labor Economics

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

Lecture 3: Employment and Unemployment

Lecture 3: Employment and Unemployment Lecture 3: Employment and Unemployment Anna Seim (with Paul Klein), Stockholm University September 26, 2016 Contents Dierent kinds of unemployment. Labour market facts and developments. Models of wage

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

A Quantitative Analysis of Unemployment Benefit Extensions

A Quantitative Analysis of Unemployment Benefit Extensions A Quantitative Analysis of Unemployment Benefit Extensions Makoto Nakajima November 8, 2011 First draft: January 19, 2010 Abstract This paper measures the effect of the ongoing extensions of unemployment

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions. Suppose that a representative consumer receives an endowment of a non-storable consumption good. The endowment evolves exogenously according to ln

More information

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017 ECON 459 Game Theory Lecture Notes Auctions Luca Anderlini Spring 2017 These notes have been used and commented on before. If you can still spot any errors or have any suggestions for improvement, please

More information

7 Unemployment. 7.1 Introduction. JEM004 Macroeconomics IES, Fall 2017 Lecture Notes Eva Hromádková

7 Unemployment. 7.1 Introduction. JEM004 Macroeconomics IES, Fall 2017 Lecture Notes Eva Hromádková JEM004 Macroeconomics IES, Fall 2017 Lecture Notes Eva Hromádková 7 Unemployment 7.1 Introduction unemployment = existence of people who are not working but who say they would want to work in jobs like

More information

Do labor market programs affect labor force participation?

Do labor market programs affect labor force participation? Do labor market programs affect labor force participation? Kerstin Johansson WORKING PAPER 2002:3 Do labor market programs affect labor force participation? * by Kerstin Johansson + January 30, 2002 Abstract

More information

On the coexistence of different personnel policies: The role of unions

On the coexistence of different personnel policies: The role of unions On the coexistence of different personnel policies: The role of unions Christian Holzner July 23, 2014 Abstract This paper explains the coexistence of unionized and non-unionized personnel policies in

More information

Do job destruction shocks matter in the theory of unemployment?

Do job destruction shocks matter in the theory of unemployment? Do job destruction shocks matter in the theory of unemployment? Melvyn G. Coles, University of Essex Ali Moghaddasi Kelishomi University of Warwick July 2017 Abstract. Because the data show that market

More information

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Joan Llull Structural Micro. IDEA PhD Program I. Dynamic Discrete Games with Imperfect Information A. Motivating example: firm entry and

More information

Business Cycles in the Equilibrium Model of Labor Market Search and Self-Insurance

Business Cycles in the Equilibrium Model of Labor Market Search and Self-Insurance Business Cycles in the Equilibrium Model of Labor Market Search and Self-Insurance Makoto Nakajima University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign May 2007 First draft: December 2005 Abstract The standard Mortensen-Pissarides

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 Section 1. Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training

Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training Career Progression and Formal versus on the Job Training J. Adda, C. Dustmann,C.Meghir, J.-M. Robin February 14, 2003 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper evaluates the return to formal

More information

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates Introduction 3 The unemployment rate in the Baltic States is volatile. During the last recession the trough-to-peak increase in the unemployment

More information

Jaime Frade Dr. Niu Interest rate modeling

Jaime Frade Dr. Niu Interest rate modeling Interest rate modeling Abstract In this paper, three models were used to forecast short term interest rates for the 3 month LIBOR. Each of the models, regression time series, GARCH, and Cox, Ingersoll,

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis Answer each question in three or four sentences and perhaps one equation or graph. Remember that the explanation determines the grade. 1. Question

More information

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Part A (Prof. Laibson): 60 minutes Part B (Prof. Barro): 60

More information

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES KRISTOFFER P. NIMARK Lucas Island Model The Lucas Island model appeared in a series of papers in the early 970s

More information

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Michael Schürle Institute for Operations Research and Computational Finance, University of St. Gallen, Bodanstr. 6, CH-9000 St. Gallen, Switzerland

More information

Is the Affordable Care Act s Individual Mandate a Certified Job-Killer?

Is the Affordable Care Act s Individual Mandate a Certified Job-Killer? Is the Affordable Care Act s Individual Mandate a Certified Job-Killer? Cory Stern Macalester College May 8, 216 Abstract: Opponents of the Affordable Care Act argue that its individual mandate component

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Lecture note on moral hazard explanations of efficiency wages

Lecture note on moral hazard explanations of efficiency wages Lecture note on moral hazard explanations of efficiency wages (Background for this lecture is the article by Shapiro and Stiglitz, in the reading list) The value function approach. This approach is used

More information

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 26/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case

More information

Financial markets and unemployment

Financial markets and unemployment Financial markets and unemployment Tommaso Monacelli Università Bocconi Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California Antonella Trigari Università Bocconi October 14, 2010 PRELIMINARY Abstract We

More information

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles? Rui Cui May 31, 2014 Introduction Credit cycles are growth cycles Cyclicality in the amount of new credit Explanations: collateral constraints, equity constraints, leverage

More information

Labor market programs, the discouraged-worker effect, and labor force participation

Labor market programs, the discouraged-worker effect, and labor force participation Labor market programs, the discouraged-worker effect, and labor force participation Kerstin Johansson WORKING PAPER 2002:9 Labor market programs, the discouraged-worker effect, and labor force participation

More information

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration Takashi Kano Hitotsubashi University @HIAS, IER, AJRC Joint Workshop Frontiers in Macroeconomics and Macroeconometrics November 3-4, 2017

More information

Liquidity and Risk Management

Liquidity and Risk Management Liquidity and Risk Management By Nicolae Gârleanu and Lasse Heje Pedersen Risk management plays a central role in institutional investors allocation of capital to trading. For instance, a risk manager

More information

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell National Institute of Economic and Social Research 1. Introduction

More information

1 Introduction. is finer than the data sampling interval, it does involve some complications.

1 Introduction. is finer than the data sampling interval, it does involve some complications. Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home final exam, due Friday evening, December 12. Instructions: I would like each person to do the exam on their own. Each question asks for computational

More information

EE266 Homework 5 Solutions

EE266 Homework 5 Solutions EE, Spring 15-1 Professor S. Lall EE Homework 5 Solutions 1. A refined inventory model. In this problem we consider an inventory model that is more refined than the one you ve seen in the lectures. The

More information

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Petra Gerlach-Kristen Hong Kong Institute of Economics and Business Strategy May, Abstract This paper uses unobserved components analysis to estimate

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Vipin Arora Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Junsang Lee U.S. EIA Deakin Univ. SKKU December 16, 2013 GRIPS Junsang Lee (SKKU) Oil Price Dynamics in

More information

Really Uncertain Business Cycles

Really Uncertain Business Cycles Really Uncertain Business Cycles Nick Bloom (Stanford & NBER) Max Floetotto (McKinsey) Nir Jaimovich (Duke & NBER) Itay Saporta-Eksten (Stanford) Stephen J. Terry (Stanford) SITE, August 31 st 2011 1 Uncertainty

More information

PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE. Labor Market Flows in the Cross Section and Over Time

PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE. Labor Market Flows in the Cross Section and Over Time PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Labor Market Flows in the Cross Section and Over Time 13 September 2010 by Steven J. Davis, Chicago Booth School of Business and NBER R. Jason Faberman, Federal Reserve Bank

More information

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) Monetary Policy, 16/3 2017 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 ) 1. Money in the short run: Incomplete

More information

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Linda Goldberg and Joseph Tracy Federal Reserve Bank of New York and NBER April 2001 Abstract Although the dollar has been shown to influence

More information

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University March 2013 Idiosyncratic risk and the business cycle How much and what types

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

Demographics and the behavior of interest rates

Demographics and the behavior of interest rates Demographics and the behavior of interest rates (C. Favero, A. Gozluklu and H. Yang) Discussion by Michele Lenza European Central Bank and ECARES-ULB Firenze 18-19 June 2015 Rubric Persistence in interest

More information

Labor Economics. Basic Job Search Model. Winter 2014/2015. Bonn University

Labor Economics. Basic Job Search Model. Winter 2014/2015. Bonn University Labor Economics Basic Job Search Model Petr Sedláček Bonn University Winter 2014/2015 1 / 32 Motivation Up until now focused on the classical theory of the labor market several important critiques most

More information

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 2013 North American Summer Meeting Ralph Lütticke 13.06.2013 1 Joint-work with Christian Bayer, Lien Pham, and Volker Tjaden 1 / 30 Research

More information

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment Eduardo Engel Cowles Lunch. March 3rd, 2010 Eduardo Engel 1 1. Motivation Micro adjustment is lumpy for many aggregates of interest: stock of durable good nominal

More information

Labor Force Participation Dynamics

Labor Force Participation Dynamics MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Labor Force Participation Dynamics Brendan Epstein University of Massachusetts, Lowell 10 August 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/88776/ MPRA Paper No.

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits Day Manoli UCLA Andrea Weber University of Mannheim February 29, 2012 Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence

More information

Debt Constraints and Employment. Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan and Elena Pastorino

Debt Constraints and Employment. Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan and Elena Pastorino Debt Constraints and Employment Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan and Elena Pastorino Motivation: U.S. Great Recession Large, persistent drop in employment U.S. Employment-Population, aged 25-54 82 Employment

More information

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation Internet Appendix A. Participation constraint In evaluating when the participation constraint binds, we consider three

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29 Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29 Time-Series Time-series is a sequence fx 1, x 2,..., x T g or fx t g, t = 1,..., T, where t is an index denoting

More information