Employee capitalism or corporate socialism? Broad-based employee stock ownership

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Employee capitalism or corporate socialism? Broad-based employee stock ownership"

Transcription

1 Employee capitalism or corporate socialism? Broad-based employee stock ownership E. Han Kim and Paige Ouimet 1 Abstract Adopting employee share ownership (ESO) plans leads to an increase in firm value only when the plan is small, i.e., less than 5% of outstanding shares. When the plan is larger, there is no value gain. This inverse U-shaped relation between shareholder value and ESO size is robust to firm fixed effects and controls for possible selection biases. Large ESOP adoptions are followed by substantial increases in employee compensation, whereas small ESOPs show no such increases. Compensation increases are smaller when firms have high leverage, which also counteracts the value negating impact of large ESOPs. We conclude that the adoption of an ESOP is generally followed by performance gains, most of which accrue to employees (shareholders) when employees have substantial (small) control rights. November 8, 2007 JEL classification: G32, M52, J54, J33 Keywords: ESOPs, 401-K Plans, Employee Incentives, Worker Compensation 1 Both are at Ross School of Business, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Michigan 48109, with addresses of ehkim@umich.edu and pshelby@bus.umich.edu, respectively. We are grateful for helpful comments/suggestions by Sreedhar Bharath, Amy Dittmar, Francine Lafontaine, Margaret Levenstein, Randall Morck, Clemens Sialm, Jagadeesh Sivadasan, and seminar participants at INSEAD, University of Michigan, and University of Oxford. An earlier version was presented at International Conference on Human Resource Management in Banking Industry sponsored by Korea Institute of Finance. We acknowledge financial support from Mitsui Life Financial Research Center. 1

2 Broad-based employee share ownership (ESO) is an important economic phenomenon. The two most common types of plans which encourage ESO are Employee Stock Ownership Plans (ESOPs) and 401-K plans in which an employer contributes its own stock. According to the National Center for Employee Ownership, ten and one-half million employees participated in 9,650 ESOPs, with combined assets over $675 billion at public and private firms in The corresponding numbers for ESO through 401-Ks are four million participants in 2,200 plans with $75 billion in assets. Both of these plans show an increasing long-term trend; the NCEO estimates the number of participants in ESOPs was one-quarter million in 1975, five million in 1990, and over ten million in ESO through 401-Ks has also become increasing popular since the 1990s. There are a number of studies documenting worker productivity increases subsequent to adoption of ESO plans (Jones and Kato, 1995; FitzRoy and Kraft, 1987; and Beatty, 1995). Studies also show that the announcement of ESOP adoptions, not implemented under takeover pressure, is met with a positive stock price reaction (Gordon and Pound, 1990; Chang and Mayers, 1992; Chaplinsky and Niehaus, 1994; and Beatty, 1995). However, there is little evidence on how ESO plans affect employee compensation. The effect on employee compensation is an important issue, not only because it has employee welfare implications, but also because any change in employee compensation has a direct implication on firm valuation and shareholder value. The issue is especially relevant because share ownership may give employees a stronger bargaining position in compensation negotiations. A typical ESO bestows not only cash flow rights, but also voting or some other forms of control rights to employees. As the size of ESO increases, greater cash flow 2

3 rights may lead to greater productivity gains through improved team effects and collective employee behavior, while greater control rights may lead to higher employee compensation. It is not clear how these two effects offset each other in affecting the shareholder value. This paper attempts to address these questions by investigating how ESO plans affect firm valuation and employee compensation. To illustrate the pertinent issues, define π, V, and C as the value of operating performance gains due to ESO, the change in shareholder value, and the change in costs accompanying ESO, respectively, such that V = π - C. Then, V 0, if C π. The shareholder value effect, V, may depend on the size of ESO. When the size is small, giving employees negligible control rights, most of π may accrue to shareholders. When the size of ESO is sufficiently large to allow employees non-trivial control rights, employees total compensation and benefits (TCB) may increase. When TCB is positive, it will increase C and decrease the fraction of π accruing to shareholders. However, V needs not be smaller because π may be greater due to greater cash flow effects on worker productivity. If the incremental π is bigger than TCB, V will increase as the size of ESO increases; otherwise, an increase in ESO size will decrease V. There is no obvious theoretical prior on which outcome is more likely. Only data can tell. Thus, we conduct an empirical investigation of how the effects of ESO on firm valuation and employee compensation vary with the size of ESO. A positive TCB may materialize if a firm encourages a large ESO hoping for greater improvement in team effects and collective worker behavior, endowing employees with substantial control rights and strengthening their bargaining power in future wage negotiations. Alternatively, managers expecting hostile takeover threats may 3

4 intentionally provide workers substantial voting rights as part of a management-worker alliance, as in Pagano and Volpin (2005). They develop a management-labor collusion model, in which managers pay workers above-market wages to entice them to vote with management. Either way, employee compensation will increase. An undesirable, yet possible outcome associated with substantial employee control rights may occur if TCB > π such that V < 0. This represents the danger of value destroying corporate socialism. When employees possess sufficient control rights, they may extract unearned compensations and benefits at the expense of other stakeholders, increasing the firm s marginal costs and eroding growth opportunities. Such firms will invest less, suffer poor performance, and be valued lower. Faleye, Mehrotra, and Morck (2006) document such phenomena for firms with large ESO. However, they also raise the possibility that poorly managed and badly performing firms may establish large ESO plans to share their misfortune with employees. Thus, whether large ESO indeed leads to value-destroying corporate socialism warrants further investigation. We find that on average firms electing to encourage ESO (ESOPs) realize a 6% (9%) increase in firm valuation, relative to the industry median, where our definition of ESO plans is inclusive of both ESOPs and ESO through 401-K plans. The positive valuation effect persists even when comparing future effects to a baseline estimated two years after an ESOP adoption. For a small ESO plan (ESOP), defined as less than 5% of the outstanding shares, the valuation increase is even higher, estimated at 11% (12%). These estimates, however, represent the upper tail of the distribution of possible gains associated with ESO, as firms not promoting ESO are likely to anticipate smaller gains. 4

5 To examine the relation between value gains and the size of ESO, we define large ESO plans as those estimated to control more than 5% of the shares outstanding. In contrast to small ESO plans, large plans show no positive valuation effects. This difference in valuation effects is related to employee compensation and benefits (TCB). Large ESOPs are followed by significant permanent increases in TCB following their establishments, whereas small ESOPs are not. When TCB reported before the adoption of large ESOPs are compared to those reported by the same firm at least five years later, TCB increases an average $1,038 per employee, which translates to an average aggregate labor cost increase of over $30 million per firm in 2006 dollars. This increase in labor cost is well over the mean value of ESOP shares, $13 million in 2006 dollars, allocated each year for our sample of firms. The inverse U-shaped relation between employee ownership and firm value is not inconsistent with the Himmelberg, Hubbard, and Palia (1999) evidence of no relation between managerial share ownership and firm value with firm fixed effects. Our results are distinct from any underlying relation between managerial share ownership and firm value. The relation between ESO and firm value is significant only for those plans that distribute shares without a bias in favor of management. Our results also do not appear to be an endogenous result of firms choosing to implement an ESO plan. We estimate all regressions controlling for firm fixed effects. Thus, differences in time-invariant characteristics between ESO firms and a control group of firms do not affect our findings. We carefully consider several other possible selection biases: private information, confounding policy changes, and a spurious correlation 5

6 caused by a positive relation between firm performance and new share issues. Our results do not support any of these selection stories as an explanation for our results. Our findings raise the issue of why management would adopt large ESO plans, given the greater shareholder value associated with smaller plans. One possible explanation is the management-labor collusion theorized by Pagano and Volpin (2005), whereby management bribes workers with above-market wages in return for their cooperation in fending off takeover bids. Bribes should be more prevalent in states with business combination statutes (BCS), because ESO plans are more effective deterrents against hostile takeover attempts in BCS states. Consistent with this prediction, compensation increases following the adoption of large ESOPs are concentrated among firms incorporated in BCS states. This finding adds to the Bertrand and Mullainathan (1999, 2003) finding of significant compensation increases following the enactment of BCS; namely, the compensation increases they document occur mainly through establishment of large ESOPs. Thus, the managers pursuit of quiet lives described by Bertrand and Mullainathan seems to be facilitated by management-labor collusion. We also consider cross-sectional variation in compensation increases by firm characteristics. Bronars and Deere (1991) argue that high financial leverage weakens unions bargaining power because of the threat of possible bankruptcy. To test for a similar effect, leverage is interacted with the presence of an ESOP. We find that high leverage reduces employee compensation increases following large ESOPs. Leverage also weakens the negating valuation impact of large ESOPs, which is expected given leverage s counter-balancing effect on compensation. The leverage effect on valuation appears to be unrelated to the unique tax benefits permitted to leveraged ESOPs. When 6

7 we compare valuation impacts between leveraged and unleveraged ESOPs, the tax benefits appear too small to be detected by our regressions. Finally, we examine what happens when financially constrained firms adopt ESOPs that may be designed as a substitute for cash wages. We do not find any significant changes in firm valuation or employee compensation following such ESOPs. Our documented valuation and compensation effects seem to be concentrated at financially unconstrained firms. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section I briefly describes a celebrated case of ESO and surveys the literature. Section II describes the data. Empirical results and tests on selection biases are presented in Section III, followed by additional robustness checks in Section IV. Section V concludes. I. Effects on employees and shareholders The case of United Airlines illustrates the potential benefits and costs of ESO. In July of 1994, United employees who agreed to significant wage concessions were granted equity shares with an aggregate claim to 55% of the firm s cash flow rights. The plan was implemented to catalyze a cultural shift and transform United into a more competitive firm. Employees were also given the right to elect three members to United s twelvedirector board, thereby bestowing employees with substantial influence in electing the CEO. This influence was apparent in the selection of the first CEO brought in after the deal, Gerald Greenwald, who had a long history of being labor-friendly. The first few years under ESO appeared successful. Employee absenteeism and turnover declined, while United s stock performed better than the market. 7

8 When Greenwald retired after four years, employees supported and subsequently elected James Goodwin as CEO. Shortly thereafter, the pilot union began contract renegotiations with their hand-picked CEO. Unsurprisingly, the pilots walked away with a generous deal. They received pay raises of 22% to 29%, becoming the highest paid pilots in the industry. After September 11, 2001, the situation at United became particularly dire. Goodwin wrote an open letter to employees, acknowledging current troubles and asking for help. Presumably, this letter was directed at the mechanics union, which was about to begin contract negotiations. In response, the mechanics union demanded Goodwin s resignation and two weeks later he did. As before, John Creighton, the next CEO approved by the employee-owners, had a reputation for being laborfriendly. The mechanics union entered negotiations and, once again, a United union left the bargaining table with a favorable deal. After this labor agreement, United became the most expensive airline to operate on a per mile basis. The firm declared bankruptcy in December A. Employee compensation As the United Airlines case illustrates, when an ESO plan gives employees sufficient control rights, workers may use their influence to extract higher compensation and benefits. Employee control rights may exacerbate the managerial tendency to acquiesce to worker demands for higher wages when managers desire a quiet life as in Bertrand and Mullainathan (1999, 2003). Large employee ownership may also indicate worker-management collusion as theorized by Pagano and Volpin (2005). Powerful employees with control rights may induce management to shift its allegiance to workers 8

9 as suggested by Atanassov and Kim (2007). A likely result of any of these propositions is higher employee compensation. ESO also cause employees to hold less diversified portfolios and have liquidity concerns. A risk-adverse employee will value a cash equivalent higher than an undiversified stake in her employer s securities. ESOP shares cannot be sold until employees leave the company, with the exception of diversification requirements triggered at 55 or 60 years of age. In 401-K plans, employees are relatively free to sell their company shares, but they face penalties and tax withholdings if they withdraw the proceeds prematurely. In equilibrium, such risks and costs should be priced in the form of higher employee compensation. B. Firm performance The higher costs due to increases in employee compensation may be offset by higher worker productivity due to improved incentive and team effects, tax benefits, and the conservation of cash at financially constrained firms. B.1. Productivity gains The most often stated objective of ESO is to increase firm value by improving employee incentives. Shareholders typically do not monitor non-managerial employees; instead, they delegate the monitoring to management, agents themselves vulnerable to their own incentive problems. As a supplement to delegated monitoring and to better align employee incentives with shareholder values, firms may encourage ESO as an incentive device. However, individual workers may feel they have little impact on stock price, raising doubt on the ability of ESO to alter individual behavior in tasks requiring additional effort or sacrifice. 9

10 Collectively, however, important benefits may arise if ESO provides a proper group-based incentive. Kandel and Lazear (1992) argue that free-rider problems can be mitigated by orientation and indoctrination of new employees about workplace norms, which creates a work environment where peer pressure enforces the group-based incentive. FitzRoy and Kraft (1987) and Blasi, Conte, and Kruse (1996) also argue that group-based incentive schemes such as ESO induce co-monitoring, reducing costly monitoring by managers. Moreover, Jones and Kato (1995) argue that ESOPs induce employees to develop a sense of identity and loyalty to their company; participate more actively in productivity-enhancing activities, such as quality-control circles; and increase the quality of decision making. These arguments are consistent with the claims often made by firms initiating ESOPs that ESO improves team work by fostering a culture of employee involvement. ESO also may help prevent value loss due to labor disputes. Cramton, Mehran, and Tracy (2007) develop a model in which share ownership by unionized workers creates incentives for unions to refrain from costly strikes. In addition, granting stocks to employees may help attract employees with more optimistic views of the firm when potential employees have differing beliefs about future prospects of the firm (Oyer and Schaefer, 2005). This will have a positive effect on firm performance if optimistic workers are more productive, with spillover effects onto their co-workers. 2 These theoretical arguments on productivity are supported by Jones and Kato (1995) who document that an ESOP adoption in Japan leads to a 4-5% increase in 2 Furthermore, more optimistic employees may value shares higher, possibly enabling the firm to hire workers at below-market wages. As pointed out by Bergman and Jenter (2007), however, it requires bounded rationality on the part of employees because employees are able to buy publicly traded shares at market prices. 10

11 productivity, starting about three years after the adoption. They report that 91% of all firms listed on Japanese stock markets had an ESOP in Japanese ESOPs do not provide tax benefits and most shares are allocated to non-executive employees. 3 These results are remarkable because the typical Japanese ESOP is allocated 1% or less of outstanding shares, demonstrating that even very small ESO plans generate substantial productivity gains. In addition, FitzRoy and Kraft (1987) find that profit sharing and workers capital ownership have positive effects on factor productivity for a sample of metal working firms in West Germany. Although there are no comparable studies on worker productivity for U.S. firms, Beatty (1995) finds an increase in sales in the two years after the adoption of an ESOP. B.2. Tax effects ESOPs are often established through a trust which borrows money to buy company stock. Over time, the company repays the loan taken by the trust which, in turn, allocates its shares to employee accounts. These loan payments (interest and principle) are treated as wages and, thus, are tax deductible, within certain payroll limits. Tax benefits unique to leveraged ESOPs arise when dividends paid to stocks, held by the trust, are used to pay down debt. These dividends are effectively deducted twice from the firm s taxable income, once as wages and then again as interest payments. 4 B.3. Cash conservation Core and Guay (2001) find stock option plans for non-executive employees are often used at firms which appear cash-constrained. Likewise, issuing stocks through ESO 3 See an earlier study by Jones and Kato (1993). 4 Prior to November 1989, banks received a tax break to fund leveraged ESOPs, which led to below market interest rates on these loans. The dividend deduction became effective in

12 plans may be the result of financially constrained firms substituting stocks for cash wages. Such ESO plans are likely to lower cash wages without changing total employee compensation. While the decision to substitute equity for cash wages may be optimal for firms facing costly external financing, it is doubtful that such plans will have as strong an uplifting effect on employee morale, team effects, and collective behavior. C. Hypotheses To summarize, we predict that, all else equal, when the size of ESO is small, firm valuation will increase, with little changes in employee compensation. When the size of ESO is sufficiently large to enhance employee bargaining position in wage negotiations, employee compensation will increase. However, a larger ESO also gives employees greater cash flow rights, which may lead to a greater operating performance gains. Thus, the net impact of a larger ESO plan on firm valuation is ambiguous. Only data can tell. II. Data We make use of two data sources on employee ownership, one that we created and the other provided by the U.S. Department of Labor (DOL). The first database, referred to as the ESOP database hereafter, includes data on ESOPs at US public firms from 1980 through This data is hand collected using Factiva. For each year, we search Factiva using the terms ESOP and employee stock ownership plan. We read all articles and note the first date a firm is mentioned as having an ESOP. We identify 756 unique public firms with ESOPs over the sample period. Of these firms, we drop 35 firms with total assets less than $10 million in 2006 dollars. The lack of press coverage on such small firms makes it likely that we missed other similar- sized firms with ESOPs, wrongly 12

13 identifying them as non-esop firms. This potential error is important as our control group is derived from firms in Compustat without identified ESOPs. With the remaining 721 ESOP firms, we run additional Factiva searches using the firm s name and employee stock to locate further information on each firm s ESOP. 5 When available, we record information on whether the ESOP was funded with debt, the ESOP initiation date, the total cash flow and voting rights of the employees, and whether the ESOP was initiated in response to a takeover threat. 6 We are able to identify the year of the ESOP initiation for 360 unique firms. The ESOP database is then matched to Compustat and Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) databases. Our second dataset begins in 1992 and extends through 2004 and includes all ESO through company-sponsored plans, including ESOPs and 401-K plans, as reported on Internal Revenue Service (IRS) Form 5500 files. Obtained from the Department of Labor (DOL), we refer to this dataset as the DOL database. All firms with employee retirement programs are required to file Form We estimate employee ownership using the dollar value of the plan s investment in their company stocks. This database is also matched to Compustat and CRSP databases. The inclusion of the 1980s is a key advantage of the ESOP database. To investigate effects of an ESOP implementation, we need to estimate a baseline, or pre- ESOP firm characteristics, requiring firm-year observations prior to the ESOP initiation. 5 In a few cases, this additional search led us to identify the presence of an ESOP in an earlier year. We exclude these observations because their inclusion introduces a survivorship bias. Information about an ESOP may not have been discovered in our first search process if the firm was small and received limited press coverage. When the firm becomes more profitable and grows larger, press coverage becomes more likely, increasing the probability we observe the ESOP. This could cause a positive correlation between observed ESOPs and firm performance. 6 If a firm underwent a bankruptcy or was dropped from Compustat for a year or more, we assume the ESOP was terminated unless other information is present. We also assume ESOP shares are common voting, unless otherwise specified. 13

14 The DOL database begins coverage in 1992, a serious drawback because over 80% of our ESOP sample was implemented before We, therefore, conduct primary tests using the ESOP database. The DOL database is used to obtain additional information unavailable in our ESOP database, 7 and as a robustness check. Table 1, Panel A, presents summary statistics of both databases including the number of new ESOP adoptions, observation counts, and average employee ownership percentages. 8 The ESOP database identifies 5,872 firm-year observations between 1980 and 2004 with an average employee ownership of 8.23% (the median = 5.30%). 9 The DOL database identifies 5,387 firm-year observations for ESOPs between 1992 and 2004 with an average employee ownership of 9.03% (the median = 4.98%). 10 The DOL database also shows 13,065 firm-year observations of employee ownership not attributed to an ESOP, which we attribute to 401-K plans (see Rauh, 2006). These plans report a substantially smaller average employee ownership of 3.16% (the median = 1.23%). Panel B, of Table 1, provides summary statistics of the relevant firm level variables. The first column details the control group. It summarizes characteristics of pooled time-series observations in Compustat that meet the following criteria: (1) we do 7 Factiva searches are inadequate to identify information on other forms of employee ownership, such as 401-K plans. Thus, when using the ESOP database and comparing firms with ESOPs to firms without ESOPs (the control group), other unobserved forms of employee ownership may or may not be present, adding noise to our tests. 8 There are 957 firm-year observations in our ESOP database (16% of the sample) for which we confirm the presence of an ESOP but do not have adequate information to estimate the percentage of shares held by the ESOP. Because detailed information must be filed in proxy statements when ownership exceeds 5%, we infer from this lack of information that the percentage ownership is less than 5%. 9 The reported means and medians exclude firms that are identified as having ESOPs but do not provide information on the percentage of shares held by employees. As mentioned above, these firms are likely to have employee ownership less than 5%. Thus, the actual mean and median are likely to be smaller. 10 The DOL database covers more firms with ESOPs than our ESOP database for several reasons. First the DOL database does not exclude very small firms, as we do with the ESOP database. Second, the DOL database includes KSOPs, which is a hybrid ESOP K plan, in most aspects resembling a 401-K plan, but with the tax advantages of an ESOP. These plans are rarely reported in newspaper articles. Finally, we may have simply missed firms with ESOPs that are included in the DOL database. 14

15 not confirm an ESOP, (2) the firm has total assets greater than $10 million in 2006 dollars, and (3) the firm has more than 3 years of Compustat data-- our empirical design requires a minimum of 4 years data to estimate ESO effects. The second column describes firms in Compustat for which we identify an ESOP. The third column details firms with large ESOPs that are estimated to control more than 5% of the outstanding common shares. The median and mean ESOP share ownership for this group of firms are 11.00% and 14.10%, respectively. We choose a demarcation point of 5% to separate small versus large ESOPs because it seems a reasonable tradeoff point between what is large enough for the employee-shareholders to exert influence on corporate decisions without making the sample size of large ESOP firms too small. The 5% is also close to the sample median and represents the triggering point at which firms must disclose the size of employee ownership in their proxy statements. Comparing Column 1 with Columns 2 and 3 reveals that firms with ESOPs tend to be larger, more capital intensive, more profitable, less R&D intensive, and more highly levered than firms without ESOPs. Columns 4 and 5 provide the summary statistics for firms in the DOL database, exhibiting similar patterns. III. Empirical results In this section we first estimate the relation between firm value and the presence of ESO, followed by an examination of possible selection biases. Then, we investigate the effects of ESOP adoption on employee compensation, the disciplining role of financial leverage, and alternative benefits to ESOPs not associated with incentives. A. Relation between firm valuation and ESO 15

16 We estimate the relation between firm value and employee ownership by regressing industry adjusted Q on indicator variables for the presence of ESO plans. Our dependant variable Q it is estimated as the market to book value ratio of firm i at time t minus the (2-digit SIC code) industry median market to book value ratio at time t. Our approach is similar to that of Himmelberg et al. (1999). We assume Q depends on the presence of an ESOP, observable firm characteristics, and unobservable firm characteristics. We include firm fixed effects to control for time-invariant unobservable firm characteristics. We also control for time series patterns with year fixed effects. To control for observable firm characteristics, we include the log of total assets (normalized in 2006 dollars), the R&D expenditures to sales ratio, the capital expenditures to assets ratio, and financial leverage. ESOPs are often initiated as leveraged, which adds to a firm s total debt, although any increase can be neutralized by rebalancing other debt obligations. We also control for firm age. Because the indicator variable for an ESO plan is comparing industry adjusted Q following the adoption of the plan to an earlier period, the coefficient on the indicator variable could pick up an age factor, if industry adjusted Q changes with firm age. We define Age as the difference between the current year and the first year the firm is included in Compustat. 11 A.1. ESOPs We first estimate the base regression using the ESOP database over the period 1980 to Column 1 of Table 2 shows that the presence of an ESOP is associated with a statistically positive increase in industry adjusted Q. This positive correlation between employee ownership and Tobin s Q is in sharp contrast to Himmelberg et al. (1999), who find no relation between managerial ownership and Tobin s Q, after the 11 Because Compustat data is not available prior to 1950, the oldest firm in our sample is

17 inclusion of firm fixed effects. One possible explanation for our strong positive association between employee ownership and firm value is the greater time series variation in ESOP holdings at the individual firm level (see Zhou (2001)). The average (median) within-firm standard deviation in employee ownership is (0.012) for firms with ESOPs in our sample, whereas the standard deviation in CEO ownership in Execucomp is (0.003). The difference in within-firm variations between employee and CEO ownership is even more dramatic if we consider an ESOP indicator, which has an average (median) within-firm standard deviation of (0.476), for firms that have an ESOP at one point during the sample period. In addition, we have over 200% more usable observations than Himmelberg et al. Column 1 also shows that the coefficients of the control variables are consistent with our expectations. Larger firms are valued less, firms with more R&D investment and capital expenditures are valued more, and financial leverage is positively related to firm valuation. The negative coefficient on Age indicates that new firms have high valuations, possibly reflecting large growth options. The positive coefficient on Age squared suggests that as firms invest in these growth options, the relative value of the firm declines at a decreasing rate. Viewed in the context of a difference-in-difference approach, the firm fixed effect picks up the before period and ESOP captures the average change experienced in the after period. This interpretation motivates two refinements to our sample. First, the estimate of the value of the firm before an ESOP, as captured in the firm fixed effects, proxies for the expected value of the firm in future years, had the ESOP not been adopted. Thus, we only include those firm-year observations beginning five years prior to the 17

18 ESOP adoption, for the set of firms that later adopt ESOPs. Second, we exclude the year of the announcement of ESOP adoption and the year after, because it may take time for effects associated with the ESOP implementation to be observed, as in Jones and Kato (1995). The sample with these modifications is used in Column 2 and in all subsequent regressions. As a comparison of Columns 1 and 2 indicates, the results are quite robust to the sample refinements. To give a sense of the economic magnitude of the result in Column 2, we note that the median value of Tobin s Q in our sample is Thus a coefficient of implies that the presence of an ESOP is associated with a firm valuation increase of 8.67%, relative to the industry median. The coefficient in Column 3 of implies a firm valuation increase of 11.72% associated with small ESOPs. If ESOPs are implemented to maximize shareholder value, then firms which choose not to encourage ESO may do so in anticipation of benefits being outweighed by costs. Thus, these estimates likely represent the upper tail of the potential distribution of shareholder value creation if all firms were to adopt ESOPs. In Column 3, we include an indicator variable to capture ESOPs with more than 5% of the company shares, ESOPg5. The results show that the positive relation between firm value and an ESOP diminishes if the ESOP controls more than 5% of the outstanding shares. Because the coefficients on the ESOP indicator variables are cumulative, the combined coefficient on ESOPg5 is , or To determine if large ESOPs are associated with an overall firm value effect, we enter 18

19 ESOPg5 alone in Column 4 and find an insignificant coefficient. The relation between firm value and ESO seems to be inverse-u shaped. 12 It is possible that this inverse-u shaped relation is driven by a similar inverse U- shaped relation between managerial share ownership and firm value, as documented by Morck, Schleifer, and Vishney (1988) and McConnell and Servaes (1990), among others. However, Himmelberg et al. (1999) show that this relation with managerial ownership disappears with the inclusion of firm fixed effects. Since our regressions also include firm fixed effects, it is unlikely our results are confounded by managerial share ownership. Nevertheless, we check the robustness by separating ESOPs into high and low levels of managerial participation by using information available in the DOL database regarding the nondiscriminatory coverage requirement (NCR). 13 In general, if a plan satisfies the NCR, the plan does not allocate highly compensated employees, presumably management, a disproportionate fraction of the ESOP shares. In Column 5, we re-estimate the regression by separating the sample according to whether or not the NCR is satisfied, which is virtually time-invariant. 14 The coefficient on ESOP biased towards highly compensated employees is negative and significant 12 A potential source of noise is the age of ESOPs. A firm that initiated an ESOP 15 or 20 years ago has probably not allocated any new shares during the past few years, making the effect of the ESOP weaker in the later years. In an unreported regression we add a new indicator variable, 10 years after the ESOP initiation, which assumes the value of 1 if the firm has had the ESOP for 10 years or more. This variable also is interacted with ESOPg5 to allow the variables ESOP and ESOPg5 to capture the effect of the ESOP within the first 10 years of adoption. Neither the new variable nor the interaction term is significant. The results are virtually identical. 13 Specifically, the test takes into account differences between the coverage ratios for highly and non-highly compensated employees, the percentage of total employees covered, and the compensation of employees covered by the plan as compared to employees excluded by the plan. For more information, see the IRS instructions for completing form 5500 available at The definition of highly compensated employee is contained in Code section 414(q), as amended by section 1431 of SBJPA, those regulations under section 414(q) that reflect current law, and Notice 97-45, I.R.B The mean (median) variance of an indicator variable on whether an ESOP satisfies the NCR is (0.000). 19

20 relative to ESOP. Likewise, the coefficient on ESOPg5 biased towards highly compensated employees is positive and significant relative to ESOPg5. Estimated separately, the coefficients on ESOP and ESOPg5 at firms where the plans are biased toward highly compensated employees are not significantly different from zero. Because whether a firm s ESOP meets the NCR is likely a choice made by the firm, we can only conclude that the inverse U-shaped relation between firm valuation and ESOPs is driven by firms which do not give a disproportionate share of ESOP stocks to managers. A.2. Employee stock ownership through 401-K plans As a robustness check, we repeat the regression analyses with the DOL database in Table 3. In Column 1, we create a new indicator variable, Employee ownership, which assumes the value of 1 if the firm has any type of ESO. Employee ownershipg5 indicates an ESO estimated to control more than 5% of the shares outstanding. The results are consistent with those in Table 2. In Column 2, we distinguish between ESO attributed to an ESOP and not attributed to an ESOP. Because most of the latter type is associated with 401-K plans, we create an indicator variable 401-K, which assumes a value of 1 if the firm has positive ESO not associated with an ESOP. 401-Kg5 indicates the presence of ESO greater than 5% of the shares outstanding. The coefficients on the ESOP and 401- K variables suggest an inverse U-shaped relation for both types of ESO. In Column 3, we include only ESOPg5 and 401-Kg5. The results show that unlike large ESOPs, large ESO through 401-K plans is associated with an overall negative firm valuation. One possible explanation relates to the stylized fact that shares in an ESOP cannot be sold at employees discretion, whereas there are no such restrictions on stocks held in a 401-K plan. Perhaps, the ability to sell stocks in 401-K plans weakens the 20

21 benefits arising from employee incentive and team effects such that the costs and risks associated with large employee control rights dominate the benefits. An alternative explanation for the difference is that the ESOP sample is concentrated in the mid-1980s to early-1990s, whereas most 401-K ESO plans appear after the mid-1990s. It could be that employees have learned over time how to better coordinate their control rights to their maximum advantage. 15 In sum, we find a positive association between employee share ownership and firm value. This positive relation is limited to relatively small ESO, and disappears when the size of ESO becomes large. Our result is not driven by high levels of managerial participation in ESOPs. Finally, there is a difference between large employee ownership through an ESOP and a 401-K plan. Large ESOPs have no association with firm value, but large ESO through 401-K plans seem to be associated with an overall negative firm valuation. So far, we have been careful to describe our results as evidence of a relation between firm value and ESO. We will next make the argument, supported by additional empirical evidence, that these results are consistent with a causal relationship. B. Selection bias To argue for a causal relation between ESOPs and firm value, we first rule out alternative explanations of our findings based on selection biases. The most common selection story argues firms that select the treatment in our case, establish employee 15 It also could be due to employees selling their 401-K shares in their own company stock to lock in the gains after positive stock-price performance and/or to firms offering more employee shares to 401-K accounts when their stock appears to be under-valued. Such behaviors would result in smaller (greater) employee ownership in 401-K plans during years of high (low) stock market valuations. Unfortunately, we are unable to test this hypothesis with our data because we observe only net changes in holdings, not the separate components of new share allocations and employee share sales. 21

22 stock ownership plans are inherently different from firms not selecting the treatment. Such differences may involve firm characteristics which are stationary or evolving over time. Because the inclusion of firm fixed effects in all of our regressions controls for stable firm characteristics, we concentrate on possible selection biases which depend on time-varying characteristics. B.1. Private information story We first consider a story where a firm has private information, predicting higher future permanent profits, and decides to reward its employees through an ESO plan. In such a case, we would expect to find a positive association between firm value and an ESO plan. Industry adjusted Q will increase when the market learns the positive information following the adoption of the ESO plan. We control for this possible selection bias by relying on a stylized fact that ESOPs are often implemented over time. For example, in leveraged ESOPs, a trust temporarily holds all ESOP shares and allocates the shares to employee accounts over time, with regulation dictating that all shares must be allocated within ten years. 16 Some nonleveraged ESOPs also allocate shares over time, especially when firms purchase shares on the open-market. We expect these ESOPs to have relatively modest effects on employee behavior in the first few years following initiation. 17 In addition, Jones and Kato (1995) find productivity increases start to take effect about three years after the adoption of ESOPs for Japanese companies. Thus, we use the second full fiscal year after the announcement of the ESOP as the baseline year (or the before period in the 16 There are no specific legal requirements regarding who can vote ESOP shares held by a trust and, thus, firms are free to set their own rules at the ESOP initiation. The two most common approaches are to vote the shares 1) according to management s preferences or 2) in an identical proportion to the votes cast by employees holding allocated ESOP shares. 17 Data limitations prevent us from identifying specific ESOP observations which allocate shares over time. 22

23 difference-in-difference approach.) We expect these ESOPs to have additional effects in later years, relative to the baseline of the 2 nd year. In Table 4, we use this alternative baseline with our ESOP database. We recode the firm-year observation which falls two fiscal years after the adoption of an ESOP (and thus was originally coded as having an ESOP) as not having an ESOP. We also drop all earlier observations of ESOP firms. Now the ESOP indicator variable in Column 1 will pick up differences in firm characteristics between this second year after an ESOP initiation and the subsequent years. We also exclude firm-year observations after an ESOP is terminated to ensure that our baseline is not picking up post-termination effects. 18 The results reported in Table 4, Panel A, are remarkably similar to their counterparts in Table 2 (Columns 2 and 3). Because the private information is not likely to remain private for more than two years, these results contradict the selection story based on private information held at the time of initiation. We observe no attenuation of the ESOP effect with the alternative baseline. On average, the market seems to have underestimated the positive effect of small ESOPs. Perhaps, this is not too surprising. The complexity of an ESOP makes it difficult to assess its impact in the earlier years, because many details about share allocation and workers response to share ownership are still unknown. A worker s behavioral reaction to becoming an employee owner is highly individual-specific. It is difficult to predict how different individual reactions translate into group behavior in the workplace. The 18 There are 61 ESOP terminations (269 firm-year observations) in our ESOP database. Terminating an ESOP is a complex legal procedure. The firm must be able to legally justify why the ESOP was valueincreasing for the firm in the past but is now value-decreasing; otherwise, it is open to lawsuits from ESOP holders and shareholders. Thus, it is more common to freeze-out an ESOP. A freeze-out is usually not announced officially and thus is hard to identify. In our sample, firms which are electing to freeze-out their ESOP will still be recorded as having an ESOP, which is literally true because the ESOP still exists. There are some firms that have rolled up their ESOP into a 401-K plan. Such 401-K plans may still be recorded in our database as an ESOP, which is not completely off-base because they still represent ESO. 23

24 same can be said about how the newly acquired voting rights or the prospect of getting more will affect employee influence on corporate decisions because the influence depends greatly on their ability to coordinate their votes and how successful shareholders are in countering it. These uncertainties require time to resolve, and the market will reassess the firm value as shares are actually allocated and observable actions materialize. Other information-based selection biases follow if an ESOP is implemented to deter hostile takeovers or to conserve cash. The announcement of an ESOP initiation may reveal private information that the management is concerned about possible takeover bids or about the availability of funds to satisfy wage obligations. This information is likely to be reflected immediately in stock prices, not two fiscal years after initiation. Thus, they are also contradicted by the results in Panel A, of Table 4. Furthermore, even if the market slowly compounds this new information, these stories are unable to explain our non-linear findings. For example, if a signal for potential hostile bids is value-enhancing, it may explain the higher firm value associated with small ESOPs, but cannot explain the negative effect of large ESOPs. Alternatively, if it signals that management is more interested in private benefits of control, it may explain the value negating effect of large ESOPs, but cannot explain the value increases with small ESOPs. B.2. Correlation between firm performance and issuance of new shares In this section we explore a bias which may arise in computing the percentage of shares held by ESOPs, estimated as the number of shares controlled by the ESOP divided by the number of shares outstanding. While the numerator is often constant for a number of years, the denominator fluctuates as the firm issues new shares or repurchases outstanding shares. If high performance firms issue new shares to expand their operations 24

25 or acquire other firms, the denominator will increase, making the relative size of ESOPs smaller. Conversely, poorly performing firms may repurchase outstanding shares because they lack good investment opportunities, making the size of ESOPs larger. To control for this possible spurious correlation between firm performance and the size of ESOPs, we create two additional variables to capture changes in (splitadjusted) shares outstanding. The first variable, share difference 1 y, is estimated as (current shares outstanding - shares outstanding from one year prior) / shares outstanding from one year prior. Share difference 5 y is estimated in a similar manner but with a five year change to shares outstanding. We revert to the original baseline as in Table 2, and compare changes following ESOP adoptions to firm-years which precede the ESOP. Column 3 of Table 4 reports the results with these additional control variables. We observe a positive relation between the one-year share difference and firm value. However, controlling for changes in shares outstanding does not affect our principal finding of a positive coefficient on ESOP and a negative coefficient on ESOPg5. Estimating share difference 5 y requires a minimum of five years of data on shares outstanding in CRSP, which may introduce a new bias by limiting the sample to older firms. Thus, we repeat the regression with a modified definition of share differences. In cases where there is inadequate data to estimate share difference 5 y, we instead code the difference in shares outstanding as zero. This captures the intent of our control. For firms without an earlier time period, we should anticipate no legacy effects from earlier time periods. The results are reported in Column 4. As with Column 3, we find a positive coefficient on ESOP and a negative coefficient on ESOPg5. In unreported tests, we estimate various alternative regressions, including interactions between the change in 25

26 shares outstanding and the ESOP variables. We consistently find a positive and significant coefficient on ESOP and a negative and significant coefficient on ESOPg5. B.3. Confounding policy changes Another alternative story for our findings is that at the time of ESOP initiation, the firm implements other policy changes that affect firm value. To explain the results in Table 4, Panel A, the effects of these policy changes must be slow changing and continue to impact stock prices two fiscal years after the ESOP initiation. An example would be a management team that believes a hostile takeover bid is looming and the best defense is to maximize firm value by increasing efficiency. As a precautionary move, the firm also implements an ESOP. If this were the case for a large portion of our sample firms, we would observe a positive correlation between an ESOP and firm value. Although this story may explain some of our results, it is contradicted by our overall results. First, an efficiency-based story must not only explain the increase in firm value associated with small ESOPs, but also the declining value associated with large ESOPs. To the best of our ability, we cannot think of an efficiency-based story that can explain both. Second, one way to increase efficiency is to cut employee compensation. In the following section we examine employee compensation changes subsequent to ESOP initiations. We find no evidence of a decrease in employee compensation. C. Employee compensation In this section we test the prediction that employees with sizable control rights are more successful in extracting higher total compensation and benefits (TCB). We estimate TCB as the log of the ratio of total compensations and benefits (in thousand dollars, normalized to 2006 dollars) to the number of employees. Because personnel 26

Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes *

Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes * Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes * E. Han Kim and Paige Ouimet This appendix contains 10 tables reporting estimation results mentioned in the paper but not

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Essays on labor power and agency problem :values of cash holdings and capital expenditures, and accounting earnings informativeness

Essays on labor power and agency problem :values of cash holdings and capital expenditures, and accounting earnings informativeness Hong Kong Baptist University HKBU Institutional Repository Open Access Theses and Dissertations Electronic Theses and Dissertations 8-14-2015 Essays on labor power and agency problem :values of cash holdings

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW 2.1 Background on capital structure Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set of assumptions, capital structure is irrelevant. This

More information

THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND THE LINK BETWEEN EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND FIRM PERFORMANCE CHNG BEY FEN

THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND THE LINK BETWEEN EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND FIRM PERFORMANCE CHNG BEY FEN THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND THE LINK BETWEEN EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND FIRM PERFORMANCE CHNG BEY FEN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE 2001 THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE

More information

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Journal of Financial Economics 47 (1998) 219 239 Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Anup Agrawal*, Charles R. Knoeber College of Management, North Carolina State University, Raleigh, NC

More information

This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Sciences Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:

This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Sciences Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: = = = = = = = Working Paper Labor Laws and Corporate Governance: Evidence from restructuring decisions around the world Julian Atanassov Stephen M. Ross School of Business at the University of Michigan

More information

The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings

The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings Soohyung Kim University of Wisconsin La Crosse Hoontaek Seo Niagara University Daniel L. Tompkins Niagara University This

More information

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXVI, NO. 1 MARCH 1991 Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers HENRI SERVAES* ABSTRACT This paper analyzes the relation between takeover gains and the q ratios of targets and

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage Jin-Chuan Duan * and Yun Li (First draft: April 12, 2006) (This version: May 16, 2006) Abstract This paper identifies a key cause for the documented diversification

More information

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg William Paterson University, Deptartment of Economics, USA. KEYWORDS Capital structure, tax rates, cost of capital. ABSTRACT The main purpose

More information

Does portfolio manager ownership affect fund performance? Finnish evidence

Does portfolio manager ownership affect fund performance? Finnish evidence Does portfolio manager ownership affect fund performance? Finnish evidence April 21, 2009 Lia Kumlin a Vesa Puttonen b Abstract By using a unique dataset of Finnish mutual funds and fund managers, we investigate

More information

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan;

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan; University of New Orleans ScholarWorks@UNO Department of Economics and Finance Working Papers, 1991-2006 Department of Economics and Finance 1-1-2006 Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using

More information

Corporate Liquidity. Amy Dittmar Indiana University. Jan Mahrt-Smith London Business School. Henri Servaes London Business School and CEPR

Corporate Liquidity. Amy Dittmar Indiana University. Jan Mahrt-Smith London Business School. Henri Servaes London Business School and CEPR Corporate Liquidity Amy Dittmar Indiana University Jan Mahrt-Smith London Business School Henri Servaes London Business School and CEPR This Draft: May 2002 We are grateful to João Cocco, David Goldreich,

More information

Is Ownership Really Endogenous?

Is Ownership Really Endogenous? Is Ownership Really Endogenous? Klaus Gugler * and Jürgen Weigand ** * (Corresponding author) University of Vienna, Department of Economics, Bruennerstrasse 72, 1210 Vienna, Austria; email: klaus.gugler@univie.ac.at;

More information

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract In this paper we study the market reaction to capital expenditure announcements in the backdrop

More information

Discussion Paper No. 593

Discussion Paper No. 593 Discussion Paper No. 593 MANAGEMENT OWNERSHIP AND FIRM S VALUE: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS USING PANEL DATA Sang-Mook Lee and Keunkwan Ryu September 2003 The Institute of Social and Economic Research Osaka

More information

Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion. Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b

Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion. Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b a Department of Finance, Spears School of Business, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, OK

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV John E. Floyd University of Toronto May 10, 2013 Our major task here is to look at the evidence regarding the effects of unanticipated money shocks on real

More information

Keywords: Equity firms, capital structure, debt free firms, debt and stocks.

Keywords: Equity firms, capital structure, debt free firms, debt and stocks. Working Paper 2009-WP-04 May 2009 Performance of Debt Free Firms Tarek Zaher Abstract: This paper compares the performance of portfolios of debt free firms to comparable portfolios of leveraged firms.

More information

Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance.

Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance. Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance. Guillermo Acuña, Jean P. Sepulveda, and Marcos Vergara December 2014 Working Paper 03 Ownership Concentration

More information

Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership. Robert C. Hanson

Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership. Robert C. Hanson Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership Robert C. Hanson Department of Finance and CIS College of Business Eastern Michigan University Ypsilanti, MI 48197 Moon H.

More information

RISK FACTORS RELATING TO THE CITI FLEXIBLE ALLOCATION 6 EXCESS RETURN INDEX

RISK FACTORS RELATING TO THE CITI FLEXIBLE ALLOCATION 6 EXCESS RETURN INDEX RISK FACTORS RELATING TO THE CITI FLEXIBLE ALLOCATION 6 EXCESS RETURN INDEX The following discussion of risks relating to the Citi Flexible Allocation 6 Excess Return Index (the Index ) should be read

More information

Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks

Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks Robert M. Feinberg Professor of Economics American University With the assistance of: Ataur Rahman Ph.D. Student in Economics American University

More information

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Mehmet E. Akbulut 1 Department of Finance College of Business and Economics California State University Fullerton Abstract This paper examines whether managers

More information

4 managerial workers) face a risk well below the average. About half of all those below the minimum wage are either commerce insurance and finance wor

4 managerial workers) face a risk well below the average. About half of all those below the minimum wage are either commerce insurance and finance wor 4 managerial workers) face a risk well below the average. About half of all those below the minimum wage are either commerce insurance and finance workers, or service workers two categories holding less

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

Effectiveness of macroprudential and capital flow measures in Asia and the Pacific 1

Effectiveness of macroprudential and capital flow measures in Asia and the Pacific 1 Effectiveness of macroprudential and capital flow measures in Asia and the Pacific 1 Valentina Bruno, Ilhyock Shim and Hyun Song Shin 2 Abstract We assess the effectiveness of macroprudential policies

More information

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Jian Liu ** University of Exeter This draft: August 2016 Abstract We examine

More information

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 7, Issue 2, Winter 2009 MANAGERIAL OWNERSHIP, CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND FIRM VALUE

Corporate Ownership & Control / Volume 7, Issue 2, Winter 2009 MANAGERIAL OWNERSHIP, CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND FIRM VALUE SECTION 2 OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE РАЗДЕЛ 2 СТРУКТУРА СОБСТВЕННОСТИ MANAGERIAL OWNERSHIP, CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND FIRM VALUE Wenjuan Ruan, Gary Tian*, Shiguang Ma Abstract This paper extends prior research to

More information

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland The International Journal of Business and Finance Research Volume 6 Number 2 2012 AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University

More information

PUBLIC HEALTH CARE CONSUMPTION: TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS OR

PUBLIC HEALTH CARE CONSUMPTION: TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS OR PUBLIC HEALTH CARE CONSUMPTION: TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS OR A COMMON GOOD? Department of Demography University of California, Berkeley March 1, 2007 TABLE OF CONTENTS I. Introduction... 1 II. Background...

More information

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power? International Journal of Business and Management; Vol. 9, No. 9; 2014 ISSN 1833-3850 E-ISSN 1833-8119 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really

More information

Online Appendix A: Verification of Employer Responses

Online Appendix A: Verification of Employer Responses Online Appendix for: Do Employer Pension Contributions Reflect Employee Preferences? Evidence from a Retirement Savings Reform in Denmark, by Itzik Fadlon, Jessica Laird, and Torben Heien Nielsen Online

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

The Determinants of CEO Inside Debt and Its Components *

The Determinants of CEO Inside Debt and Its Components * The Determinants of CEO Inside Debt and Its Components * Wei Cen** Peking University HSBC Business School [Preliminary version] 1 * This paper is a part of my PhD dissertation at Cornell University. I

More information

BUILDING INVESTMENT PORTFOLIOS WITH AN INNOVATIVE APPROACH

BUILDING INVESTMENT PORTFOLIOS WITH AN INNOVATIVE APPROACH BUILDING INVESTMENT PORTFOLIOS WITH AN INNOVATIVE APPROACH Asset Management Services ASSET MANAGEMENT SERVICES WE GO FURTHER When Bob James founded Raymond James in 1962, he established a tradition of

More information

Capital Gains Taxation and the Cost of Capital: Evidence from Unanticipated Cross-Border Transfers of Tax Bases

Capital Gains Taxation and the Cost of Capital: Evidence from Unanticipated Cross-Border Transfers of Tax Bases Capital Gains Taxation and the Cost of Capital: Evidence from Unanticipated Cross-Border Transfers of Tax Bases Harry Huizinga (Tilburg University and CEPR) Johannes Voget (University of Mannheim, Oxford

More information

MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM

MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM ) MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM Ersin Güner 559370 Master Finance Supervisor: dr. P.C. (Peter) de Goeij December 2013 Abstract Evidence from the US shows

More information

The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1

The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1 Preservation The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1 Kenneth R. Spong Senior Policy Economist, Banking Studies and Structure, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Richard J. Sullivan Senior

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

Labor Market Protections and Unemployment: Does the IMF Have a Case? Dean Baker and John Schmitt 1. November 3, 2003

Labor Market Protections and Unemployment: Does the IMF Have a Case? Dean Baker and John Schmitt 1. November 3, 2003 cepr Center for Economic and Policy Research Briefing Paper Labor Market Protections and Unemployment: Does the IMF Have a Case? Dean Baker and John Schmitt 1 November 3, 2003 CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY

More information

CORPORATE OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE AND FIRM PERFORMANCE IN SAUDI ARABIA 1

CORPORATE OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE AND FIRM PERFORMANCE IN SAUDI ARABIA 1 Abstract CORPORATE OWNERSHIP STRUCTURE AND FIRM PERFORMANCE IN SAUDI ARABIA 1 Dr. Yakubu Alhaji Umar Dr. Ali Habib Al-Elg Department of Finance & Economics King Fahd University of Petroleum & Minerals

More information

CORPORATE CASH HOLDING AND FIRM VALUE

CORPORATE CASH HOLDING AND FIRM VALUE CORPORATE CASH HOLDING AND FIRM VALUE Cristina Martínez-Sola Dep. Business Administration, Accounting and Sociology University of Jaén Jaén (SPAIN) E-mail: mmsola@ujaen.es Pedro J. García-Teruel Dep. Management

More information

Risk changes around convertible debt offerings

Risk changes around convertible debt offerings Journal of Corporate Finance 8 (2002) 67 80 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Risk changes around convertible debt offerings Craig M. Lewis a, *, Richard J. Rogalski b, James K. Seward c a Owen Graduate

More information

Do Auditors Use The Information Reflected In Book-Tax Differences? Discussion

Do Auditors Use The Information Reflected In Book-Tax Differences? Discussion Do Auditors Use The Information Reflected In Book-Tax Differences? Discussion David Weber and Michael Willenborg, University of Connecticut Hanlon and Krishnan (2006), hereinafter HK, address an interesting

More information

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect?

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? Yi Jiang Department of Finance, California State University, Fullerton SGMH 5160, Fullerton, CA 92831 (657)278-4363 yjiang@fullerton.edu Yiming Qian

More information

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck

More information

Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence

Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence Anup Agrawal Culverhouse College of Business University of Alabama Tuscaloosa, AL 35487-0224 Jeffrey F. Jaffe Department

More information

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Introduction to "Pensions in the U.S. Economy"

Volume URL:  Chapter Title: Introduction to Pensions in the U.S. Economy This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Pensions in the U.S. Economy Volume Author/Editor: Zvi Bodie, John B. Shoven, and David A.

More information

How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University

How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University Colin Mayer Saïd Business School University of Oxford Oren Sussman

More information

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 17. Stabilization in an Integrated World Economy

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 17. Stabilization in an Integrated World Economy Chapter 17 Stabilization in an Integrated World Economy Introduction For more than 50 years, many economists have used an inverse relationship involving the unemployment rate and real GDP as a guide to

More information

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information Critical Finance Review, 2016, 5: 165 175 Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information Kent Daniel Sheridan Titman 1 Columbia Business School, Columbia University, New York,

More information

How do business groups evolve? Evidence from new project announcements.

How do business groups evolve? Evidence from new project announcements. How do business groups evolve? Evidence from new project announcements. Meghana Ayyagari, Radhakrishnan Gopalan, and Vijay Yerramilli June, 2009 Abstract Using a unique data set of investment projects

More information

One COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. Performance PART

One COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. Performance PART PART One Performance Chapter 1 demonstrates how adding managed futures to a portfolio of stocks and bonds can reduce that portfolio s standard deviation more and more quickly than hedge funds can, and

More information

The determinants of managerial ownership and the ownershipperformance

The determinants of managerial ownership and the ownershipperformance The determinants of managerial ownership and the ownershipperformance relation Student name: Huib Raterink Administration number: 664727 Faculty: Economics and Management Department: Finance Supervisor:

More information

Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts

Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts We replicate Tables 1-4 of the paper relating quarterly earnings forecasts (QEFs) and long-term growth forecasts (LTGFs)

More information

Family Control and Leverage: Australian Evidence

Family Control and Leverage: Australian Evidence Family Control and Leverage: Australian Evidence Harijono Satya Wacana Christian University, Indonesia Abstract: This paper investigates whether leverage of family controlled firms differs from that of

More information

Capital structure and the financial crisis

Capital structure and the financial crisis Capital structure and the financial crisis Richard H. Fosberg William Paterson University Journal of Finance and Accountancy Abstract The financial crisis on the late 2000s had a major impact on the financial

More information

Performance persistence and management skill in nonconventional bond mutual funds

Performance persistence and management skill in nonconventional bond mutual funds Financial Services Review 9 (2000) 247 258 Performance persistence and management skill in nonconventional bond mutual funds James Philpot a, Douglas Hearth b, *, James Rimbey b a Frank D. Hickingbotham

More information

Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation

Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation University of Massachusetts Boston From the SelectedWorks of Atreya Chakraborty January 1, 2010 Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation

More information

Boards of directors, ownership, and regulation

Boards of directors, ownership, and regulation Journal of Banking & Finance 26 (2002) 1973 1996 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Boards of directors, ownership, and regulation James R. Booth a, Marcia Millon Cornett b, *, Hassan Tehranian c a College

More information

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK Scott J. Wallsten * Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research 579 Serra Mall at Galvez St. Stanford, CA 94305 650-724-4371 wallsten@stanford.edu

More information

Do Investors Value Dividend Smoothing Stocks Differently? Internet Appendix

Do Investors Value Dividend Smoothing Stocks Differently? Internet Appendix Do Investors Value Dividend Smoothing Stocks Differently? Internet Appendix Yelena Larkin, Mark T. Leary, and Roni Michaely April 2016 Table I.A-I In table I.A-I we perform a simple non-parametric analysis

More information

The Financial Engines National 401(k) Evaluation. Who benefits from today s 401(k)?

The Financial Engines National 401(k) Evaluation. Who benefits from today s 401(k)? 2010 The Financial Engines National 401(k) Evaluation Who benefits from today s 401(k)? Foreword Welcome to the 2010 edition of The Financial Engines National 401(k) Evaluation. When we first evaluated

More information

RECURSIVE RELATIONSHIPS IN EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION. Shane Moriarity University of Oklahoma, U.S.A. Josefino San Diego Unitec New Zealand, New Zealand

RECURSIVE RELATIONSHIPS IN EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION. Shane Moriarity University of Oklahoma, U.S.A. Josefino San Diego Unitec New Zealand, New Zealand RECURSIVE RELATIONSHIPS IN EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION Shane Moriarity University of Oklahoma, U.S.A. Josefino San Diego Unitec New Zealand, New Zealand ABSTRACT Asian businesses in the 21 st century will learn

More information

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings Abstract This paper empirically investigates the value shareholders place on excess cash

More information

Union Strikes and the Impact of Non-financial Stakeholders on Capital Structure

Union Strikes and the Impact of Non-financial Stakeholders on Capital Structure Union Strikes and the Impact of Non-financial Stakeholders on Capital Structure Brett W. Myers The Krannert School of Management Purdue University Alessio Saretto The Krannert School of Management Purdue

More information

Pension fund investment: Impact of the liability structure on equity allocation

Pension fund investment: Impact of the liability structure on equity allocation Pension fund investment: Impact of the liability structure on equity allocation Author: Tim Bücker University of Twente P.O. Box 217, 7500AE Enschede The Netherlands t.bucker@student.utwente.nl In this

More information

NCER Working Paper Series

NCER Working Paper Series NCER Working Paper Series Momentum in Australian Stock Returns: An Update A. S. Hurn and V. Pavlov Working Paper #23 February 2008 Momentum in Australian Stock Returns: An Update A. S. Hurn and V. Pavlov

More information

Automatic enrollment, employer match rates, and employee compensation in 401(k) plans

Automatic enrollment, employer match rates, and employee compensation in 401(k) plans ARTICLE MAY 2015 Automatic enrollment, employer match rates, and employee compensation in 401(k) plans This article uses restricted-access employer-level microdata from the National Compensation Survey

More information

Executive Financial Incentives and Payout Policy: Firm Responses to the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut

Executive Financial Incentives and Payout Policy: Firm Responses to the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXII, NO. 4 AUGUST 2007 Executive Financial Incentives and Payout Policy: Firm Responses to the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut JEFFREY R. BROWN, NELLIE LIANG, and SCOTT WEISBENNER ABSTRACT

More information

Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada Operating Cash Flows: Sales $682,500 $771,750 $868,219 $972,405 $957,211 less expenses $477,750 $540,225 $607,753 $680,684 $670,048 Difference $204,750 $231,525 $260,466 $291,722 $287,163 After-tax (1

More information

Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies

Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies Prepared on behalf of the Organization for International Investment June 2015 (Page intentionally left

More information

Does R&D Influence Revisions in Earnings Forecasts as it does with Forecast Errors?: Evidence from the UK. Seraina C.

Does R&D Influence Revisions in Earnings Forecasts as it does with Forecast Errors?: Evidence from the UK. Seraina C. Does R&D Influence Revisions in Earnings Forecasts as it does with Forecast Errors?: Evidence from the UK Seraina C. Anagnostopoulou Athens University of Economics and Business Department of Accounting

More information

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Yongsik Kim * Abstract This paper provides empirical evidence that analysts generate firm-specific

More information

Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance

Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance Manohar Singh The Pennsylvania State University- Abington Reporting a positive relationship between institutional ownership on one hand and capital expenditures

More information

Corporate Ownership Structure in Japan Recent Trends and Their Impact

Corporate Ownership Structure in Japan Recent Trends and Their Impact Corporate Ownership Structure in Japan Recent Trends and Their Impact by Keisuke Nitta Financial Research Group nitta@nli-research.co.jp The corporate ownership structure in Japan has changed significantly

More information

Can Firms Build Capital-Market Reputation to Compensate for Poor Investor Protection? Evidence from Dividend Policies. Jie Gan, Ziyang Wang 1,2

Can Firms Build Capital-Market Reputation to Compensate for Poor Investor Protection? Evidence from Dividend Policies. Jie Gan, Ziyang Wang 1,2 Can Firms Build Capital-Market Reputation to Compensate for Poor Investor Protection? Evidence from Dividend Policies Jie Gan, Ziyang Wang 1,2 1 Gan is from Cheung Kong Graduate School of Business, Email:

More information

Construction Site Regulation and OSHA Decentralization

Construction Site Regulation and OSHA Decentralization XI. BUILDING HEALTH AND SAFETY INTO EMPLOYMENT RELATIONSHIPS IN THE CONSTRUCTION INDUSTRY Construction Site Regulation and OSHA Decentralization Alison Morantz National Bureau of Economic Research Abstract

More information

Qualified Research Activities

Qualified Research Activities Page 15 Qualified Research Activities ORS 317.152, 317.153 Year Enacted: 1989 Transferable: No ORS 317.154 Length: 1-year Means Tested: No Refundable: No Carryforward: 5-year TER 1.416, 1.417 Kind of cap:

More information

The Effects of Ownership Concentration and Identity on Investment Performance: An. International Comparison *

The Effects of Ownership Concentration and Identity on Investment Performance: An. International Comparison * The Effects of Ownership Concentration and Identity on Investment Performance: An International Comparison * Klaus Gugler, Dennis C. Mueller and B. Burcin Yurtoglu University of Vienna, Department of Economics

More information

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality DORON NISSIM* Corporate disclosures are an important source of information for investors. Many studies have documented strong price

More information

The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales

The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales VV Chari, LJ Christiano and P Kehoe January 2, 27 In this note, we examine the findings of Gertler and Gilchrist, ( Monetary Policy, Business

More information

Giraffes, Institutions and Neglected Firms

Giraffes, Institutions and Neglected Firms Cornell University School of Hotel Administration The Scholarly Commons Articles and Chapters School of Hotel Administration Collection 1983 Giraffes, Institutions and Neglected Firms Avner Arbel Cornell

More information

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva* The Role of Credit Ratings in the Dynamic Tradeoff Model Viktoriya Staneva* This study examines what costs and benefits of debt are most important to the determination of the optimal capital structure.

More information

Asset Pricing Implications of Social Networks. Han N. Ozsoylev University of Oxford

Asset Pricing Implications of Social Networks. Han N. Ozsoylev University of Oxford Asset Pricing Implications of Social Networks Han N. Ozsoylev University of Oxford 1 Motivation - Communication in financial markets in financial markets, agents communicate and learn from each other this

More information

Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time,

Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time, 1. Introduction Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time, many diversified firms have become more focused by divesting assets. 2 Some firms become more

More information

Union Strikes and the Impact of Non-financial Stakeholders on Capital Structure

Union Strikes and the Impact of Non-financial Stakeholders on Capital Structure Union Strikes and the Impact of Non-financial Stakeholders on Capital Structure Brett W. Myers The Krannert School of Management Purdue University Alessio Saretto The Krannert School of Management Purdue

More information

CEO Centrality. NELLCO Legal Scholarship Repository NELLCO. Lucian Bebchuk Harvard Law School. Martijn Cremers. Urs Peyer

CEO Centrality. NELLCO Legal Scholarship Repository NELLCO. Lucian Bebchuk Harvard Law School. Martijn Cremers. Urs Peyer NELLCO NELLCO Legal Scholarship Repository Harvard Law School John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and Business Discussion Paper Series Harvard Law School 11-6-2007 CEO Centrality Lucian Bebchuk Harvard

More information

The evaluation of the performance of UK American unit trusts

The evaluation of the performance of UK American unit trusts International Review of Economics and Finance 8 (1999) 455 466 The evaluation of the performance of UK American unit trusts Jonathan Fletcher* Department of Finance and Accounting, Glasgow Caledonian University,

More information

Market Overreaction to Bad News and Title Repurchase: Evidence from Japan.

Market Overreaction to Bad News and Title Repurchase: Evidence from Japan. Market Overreaction to Bad News and Title Repurchase: Evidence from Japan Author(s) SHIRABE, Yuji Citation Issue 2017-06 Date Type Technical Report Text Version publisher URL http://hdl.handle.net/10086/28621

More information

Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity

Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity Anders Karlsson and Lars Nordén 1 Department of Corporate Finance, School of Business, Stockholm University, S-106 91 Stockholm, Sweden Abstract

More information

The unprecedented surge in tax receipts beginning in fiscal

The unprecedented surge in tax receipts beginning in fiscal Forecasting Federal Individual Income Tax Receipts Challenges and Uncertainties in Forecasting Federal Individual Income Tax Receipts Abstract - Forecasting individual income receipts has been greatly

More information

Does Insider Ownership Matter for Financial Decisions and Firm Performance: Evidence from Manufacturing Sector of Pakistan

Does Insider Ownership Matter for Financial Decisions and Firm Performance: Evidence from Manufacturing Sector of Pakistan Does Insider Ownership Matter for Financial Decisions and Firm Performance: Evidence from Manufacturing Sector of Pakistan Haris Arshad & Attiya Yasmin Javid INTRODUCTION In an emerging economy like Pakistan,

More information