A General Equilibrium Model of the Consumption. Response to Government Expenditures

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A General Equilibrium Model of the Consumption. Response to Government Expenditures"

Transcription

1 A General Equilibrium Model of the Consumption Response to Government Expenditures Carol Cui Job Market Paper This Version: October 21, 213 Abstract In this paper, I develop a structural model to examine how an economy responds to an increase in government spending. The model economy is populated with finitely-lived households who smooth their consumption using two assets. The first asset is a low-return free-to-adjust asset lent by the households to the government; the second asset is a high-return costly-to-adjust asset used as capital by a representative firm. Working-age households also supply a fixed amount of labor to the firm. The government raises taxes to finance its spending and thus maintains a balanced budget. Prices are perfectly flexible and adjust to clear all the markets. The model generates an interesting result: the rise in government spending crowds out investment, leading to a drop in capital which drives down the total output. Therefore, in contrast to some recent New Keynesian models, this paper shows that the government expenditure multiplier can be negative in a general equilibrium model with capital, flexible prices and a fixed labor supply. Moreover, the multiplier becomes positive if I endogenize labor supply by making households choose their hours of work. Specifically, a substantial decrease in consumption causes aggregate labor supply to rise on the impact date. Since capital is predetermined, total output increases. Department of Economics, The Ohio State University, 1945 North High Street, Columbus, OH 4321 USA, cui.45@osu.edu, Tel:+1(614) , Fax:+1(614)

2 1 Introduction Recent events, such as the enactment of American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 29, 1 have rekindled interests among economists in studying the impact of rising government spending on the aggregate economy. Moreover, the rise in government spending has long been an important feature in the U.S. economy (Figure 1A). In the past seven decades, total government expenditures have increased from 1% of GDP in 1929 to 2% of GDP in 212 (Figure 1B). At the same time, a ten percentage points increase in total tax receipts as a fraction of GDP is observed because of the expanding government expenditures (Figure 2). In addition to the increase of total taxes, Figure 2 shows that the composition of tax revenues has also changed. Receipts from personal taxes have become the most important component of the U.S. taxation, increasing from less than 2% of the total receipts in 1929 to around 5% of the total receipts in 212. There is an abundant collection of studies that develop general equilibrium models to examine the effects of government spending on an aggregate economy. Compared to Neoclassical models (Aiyagari, Christiano and Eichenbaum 1992; Baxter and King 1993; Burnside, Eichenbaum and Fisher 24), increases in government expenditures typically generate more prominent increases in output in New Keynesian models (Gali, López-Salido and Vallés 27; Monacelli and Perotti 28; Christiano, Eichenbaum and Rebelo 211; Woodford 211). The majority of these models feature an infinitely-lived representative household who smooths its consumption using a single asset. 2 I find the single asset setting and lack of heterogeneity in these models unsatisfying. First, it is through a household s decision on saving, consumption and hours of work that the effects of rising government spending propagate and eventually give rise to an impact on the aggregate economy. A number of empirical studies have shown that households consumption response to fiscal policy changes is significantly associated with age, income and wealth liquidity. Specifically, households who are older or have low 1 According to the Recovery Act, the latest estimated spending for the Senate is $552 billion and $545 billion for the House. 2 Gali, López-Salido and Vallés (27) have two types of households: rule-of-thumb and traditional Ricardian. 2

3 income and low liquid wealth are more likely to spend all the extra money after receiving fiscal stimulus payments (Johnson et al. 26; Misra and Surico 211; Parker et al. 211). However, an infinitely-lived representative household model not only does not have the age dimension but only generates a single income and wealth level. Therefore, the aggregate consumption response resulted from such models might not be empirically plausible. Second, a single asset setting assumes that all households in the economy hold only one type of assets. This is a strong assumption given that in reality people tend to make different saving decisions depending on the type of assets they are considering. The decision of how much to save for retirement is certainly different from the decision of how much cash to hold on hand. The type of asset they own also influences their consumption behaviors. For example, a cash-constrained household might choose to cut down its consumption when facing a temporary tax increase, even though the household owns a house. Moreover, Lusardi et al. (211) find from their data that almost half of U.S. households probably do not have the financial capacity to come up with $2, within a month. This finding is hard to reconcile with the fact that the median net worth of a U.S. household was around $89, 5 in 21 (Table 1). However, the finding is consistent with the household portfolio data if we look through the lens of liquid and illiquid wealth. In particular, the median liquid wealth for a typical American household was less than $3, 5 in 21. The majority of a household s wealth was actually held in illiquid form rather than in liquid form (Figure 3). Lastly, it is a known fact that singleasset models fail to generate a big enough aggregate consumption response that is in line with the data (Deaton 1991). A two-asset setting is able to resolve this issue (Kaplan and Violante 211, hereafter KV). Therefore, it would be informative to see whether the addition of a second asset could change the response dynamics of a model. Last, as pointed out in Heathcote et al. (29), heterogeneity has non-trivial effects on aggregate equilibrium quantities and prices. For example, Huggett (1993) finds that the precautionary saving motive resulted from idiosyncratic uninsurable income risk reduces the equilibrium real interest rate. Heathcote (25) shows that changes in the timing of 3

4 taxes is neutral in a representative household model because of Ricardian equivalence, but have significant real effects in a heterogeneous-agent incomplete-market model. Hence, in this paper I develop a general equilibrium model where the economy is populated with finitely-lived households. These households smooth their consumption using two assets. The first asset (i.e. liquid asset) is a low-return free-to-adjust asset lent by the households to the government; the second asset (i.e. illiquid asset) is a highreturn costly-to-adjust asset used as capital by a representative firm. All households draw an adjustment cost from the same i.i.d distribution at the beginning of each period before deciding whether to adjust the illiquid asset. Working-age households also face idiosyncratic labor productivity risks and supply labor to the representative firm. The government raises labor income taxes to finance its spending and thus maintains a balanced budget. Prices are perfectly flexible and adjust to clear all the markets. I refer to this model as the two-asset model. The two-asset model can be easily modified to a model which I refer to as the oneasset model. In particular, the two assets are only differentiated by an adjustment cost. When the adjustment cost is set to zero, the economy essentially only has one asset (i.e. the liquid asset). In other words, the one-asset model is an economy where there is only the liquid asset. I subject both the two-asset and the one-asset model to the same fiscal stimulus shock, namely a transient rise in government spending. As a result, my main findings can be summarized as follows. First, if I assume fixed labor supply for working-age households, the addition of a second asset does not affect the qualitative result generated by the oneasset model. The rise in government spending crowds out investment, leading to a drop in capital which drives down the total output in both economies. Therefore, this paper shows that the government expenditure multiplier can be negative in general equilibrium models with capital, flexible prices and a fixed labor supply. Second, if I endogenize labor supply by making households choose their hours of work, the addition of a second asset leads to a complete departure from the qualitative result generated by the one-asset model. Aggregate labor falls in the one-asset economy but 4

5 rises in the two-asset economy thanks to a much stronger consumption response in the two-asset setting. Since the capital stock is predetermined, the government expenditure multiplier on the impact date is negative in the one-asset economy but positive in the two-asset economy. The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 first lays out both the two-asset and the one-asset model with fixed labor supply. Next, it gives a detailed description of my parameterization. Then it compares the transitional dynamics generated by the two models in response to a rise in government spending. The assumption of fixed labor supply is relaxed in Section 3. This section first describes how the two models are augmented with endogenous labor supply. After briefly describing the parameterization, it then highlights the difference the addition of a second asset makes by analyzing the transitional dynamics generated by the two models in response to a rise in government spending. Second 4 concludes. 2 A life-cycle model with fixed labor supply 2.1 Model Demographics The economy has a continuum of households indexed by their age j = 1, 2,..., J. Households retire at age J ω and retirement lasts for J r periods. Hence, J ω + J r = J. Preference Households are forward-looking and each of them has a time-separable, expected utility: E j=1 J β j 1 log c j where c j is each household s consumption at age j. 5

6 Earnings For each working household, its labor supply is exogenously given and fixed at h. In every period, the household is also assigned an exogenous labor productivity ɛ, which follows a Markov process. Thus, the household s income can be represented as (1 τ)wɛh, where w is wage and τ is labor income tax rate. For each retired household, it receives a lump-sum tax-free government transfer ρ(j, ɛ J ω) in every period. Thus, transfers depend on the retiree s current age j and his last-workingperiod labor productivity ɛ J ω. Financial Assets There are two assets, denoted as a and m, in the economy. The illiquid asset a is restricted to be non-negative and earns a gross return of R a = 1/q a. An adjustment cost κ is associated with this asset. In particular, at the beginning of each period, every household has an i.i.d draw of κ from the same uniform distribution U(, κ), where the lower-bound is zero and the upper-bound is κ. After seeing its current idiosyncratic state ɛ, each household decides whether or not to adjust its illiquid asset holdings (i.e. deposit or withdraw). If the household decides to adjust the asset, it has to pay the fixed cost it has drawn. If the household decides not to adjust the asset, it pays no fixed cost and its current illiquid wealth earns a gross return of R a. The adjustment cost is set to zero for all the households who are at their last period of life. Thus, there will be no positive illiquid wealth left behind when a household exits the economy. The liquid asset m has a fixed zero borrowing limit, earns a gross return of R m = 1/q m, and is costless to adjust. Household Problem I formulate the household problem in a recursive fashion. The state variables for a single household at each period are its age j, its current asset holdings of a and m, and the current-period draw of both productivity ɛ and cost κ. The value function of a household is V (a, m, ɛ, j, κ), which depends on V (a, m, ɛ, j) and V 1 (a, m, ɛ, j, κ). V (a, m, ɛ, j) and V 1 (a, m, ɛ, j, κ) are the value functions conditional on not adjusting and adjusting the 6

7 illiquid asset, respectively. During each working period, the household will choose not to adjust the asset if V (a, m, ɛ, j) V 1 (a, m, ɛ, j, κ). In other words, it solves the following problem: V (a, m, ɛ, j) = max c,m subject to: N ɛ u(c) + β π(ɛ l ɛ) V (a, m, ɛ l, j + 1, κ )H(dκ ) (2.1) κ l=1 c + q m m (1 τ)wɛh + m a = a q a m. The household will choose to adjust the illiquid asset if V (a, m, ɛ, j) < V 1 (a, m, ɛ, j, κ). Then it solves: V 1 (a, m, ɛ, j, κ) = max c,a,m subject to: N ɛ u(c) + β π(ɛ l ɛ) V (a, m, ɛ l, j + 1, κ )H(dκ )(2.2) κ l=1 c + q a a + q m m (1 τ)wɛh + a + m κ a m. Here, H(κ ) is the cdf at κ of the uniform distribution U(, κ) and H(dκ ) is its pdf. Therefore, the ex-post value function of a household is V (a, m, ɛ, j, κ) = max{v (a, m, ɛ, j), V 1 (a, m, ɛ, j, κ)}. (2.3) To solve the retiree s problem, I substitute (1 τ)wɛh with ρ(j, ɛ J ω) and replace Nɛ l=1 π(ɛ l ɛ) V (a, m, ɛ κ l, j + 1, κ )H(dκ ) with V (a, m, ɛ, j + 1, κ )H(dκ ). κ Appendix B1 has a detailed description of the computational algorithm used to solve the household problem. 7

8 Government The government collects income taxes from workers, pays transfers to retirees, and borrows money from all households by issuing a one-period bond M at price q m. Government expenditures G are not valued by households. Let e j = (ɛ j, κ j ) be the vector of the productivity and adjustment cost drawn by a household aged j in the current period, and s j = (a j, m j ) be the vector of the household s illiquid and liquid wealth. The government budget constraint can be written as: J ω τ j=1 J whɛ j µ j ([ds j de j ]) + q m M = G + j=j ω +1 ρ(j, ɛ J ω)µ j ([ds j de j ]) + M (2.4) where µ j ([s j e j ]) is the distribution of households of age j over s j and e j. Firm The economy has a representative firm who hires labor and borrows capital from households. In return, it produces a homogeneous final good for households to consume. The production technology is standard Cobb-Douglas, F (K, N) = K α N 1 α. Capital depreciates at rate δ. The firm maximizes its profit by choosing K and N so that: w = (1 α)( K N )α, (2.5) 1 q a = α( K N )α δ. (2.6) General Equilibrium A recursive competitive equilibrium consists of a set of functions, (q a, q m, w, V, V 1, V, c, a, m, K, N, M, Γ), that satisfies the following conditions. 1. Individual Household Optimization: V, V 1 and V satisfy (2.1),(2.2) and (2.3), and c, a and m are the associated policy 8

9 functions. 2. Representative Firm Optimization: The representative firm chooses N and K as shown in (2.5) and (2.6). 3. Labor Market Clearing Condition: J ω N = j=1 hɛ j µ j ([ds j de j ]). 4. Capital Market Clearing Condition: J K = q a j=1 a j µ j ([ds j de j ]). 5. Bond Market Clearing Condition: M = J j=1 m j µ j ([ds j de j ]). 6. Goods Market Clearing Condition: J zk α N 1 α = c j µ j ([ds j de j ]) + K (1 δ)k + G + K j=1 where: J K = q a a j+1 µ j ([ds j de j ]), K = j=1 J j=1 G satisfies (2.4). κ j I adj=1 µ j ([ds j de j ]), Here, I is an indicator function which takes one if a household adjusts the illiquid asset and zero otherwise. 7. Law of Motion of the Distribution: 9

10 Γ is defined as follows. For all K K and M M, for j = 1,..., J 1, µ j+1 ( K q a, M, ɛ j+1, κ j+1 ) = { } I sj+1 =s dπ(ɛ j+1 j+1 ɛ j )H(dκ j+1 )µ j ([ds j de j ]) µ j ([ds j de j]) and µ 1 ( K q a, M, ɛ 1, κ 1 ) = { } I dπ(ɛ s1 =( K q a,m ) 1 ɛ J )H(dκ 1 )µ J ([ds J de J ]) µ J ([ds J de J]). Here, s j+1 = (a j+1, m j+1) solves (2.3), π(ɛ j+1 ɛ j ) denotes the transitional probability from ɛ j to ɛ j+1, and I is an indicator function which takes one if s j+1 ( K q a, M ) and zero otherwise. One-Asset Model The two assets in the model described above are differentiated by a stochastic adjustment cost. The adjustment cost is drawn from a uniform distribution U[, κ], where zero is the lower-bound and κ is the upper-bound. Therefore, if κ is set to zero, the two-asset model becomes equivalent to a one-asset model. In other words, the one-asset model is an economy where there is only the liquid asset. 2.2 Parameterization Steady State: Two-Asset The model has an annual frequency. I assume that each household enters the economy as a worker at age 22, retires at age 6, and dies without uncertainty when it reaches age 78 (i.e. the U.S. life expectancy in 211 is years). Therefore, I set the lifespan of a household to 55 years (i.e. J = 55). The household works for the first 37 years (i.e. J ω = 37) and becomes a retiree for the last 18 years. The discount factor β is.956, targeting a four-percent annual real interest rate (i.e. 1/q a ) at the steady state. 1

11 For working households, I approximate their idiosyncratic labor productivity process using the PSID family public data over the period. In particular, I closely follow the estimation procedure outlined in Heathcote et al. (21). Appendix A1 describes the procedure and my sample selection criteria in detail. I then use Tauchen (1986) method to generate an AR(1) 5-state Markov chain based on the estimates I obtain from the PSID data (i.e. autocorrelation ρ ɛ =.752, variance of innovation σɛ 2 =.6). Moreover, each household devotes one-third of its time to working (i.e. h = 1/3) and is subject to an income tax rate of 26% (i.e. τ =.26) as reported in Kiefer et al. (22, Table 5, prior-egtrra overall on wages). For retired households, I adopt ρ(j, ɛ J ω) = χ p j ɛ J ω as the functional form to approximate the amount of transfers a retiree receives at age j. 3 Here, χ is common across all retirees, representing a deterministic age factor that differentiates retirees from workers. The value of χ is set to 5. so that the ratio of mean wage income to mean transfers is equal to The second component, p j, captures a deterministic age-specific effect on retirees earnings. Based on SCF 21, I first compute the social security income received by each age group j as a percentage of the total social security income received by all households aged from 6 to 78. Then I set each p j to its corresponding percentage value. The last component, ɛ J ω, denotes the stochastic labor productivity drawn by the household at its last working period. Please see appendix A3 for more details. For the bond market, the total supply of liquid assets M is.36, targeting a 2-3% annual inflation rate. Hence, the debt-to-output ratio is not a target. Nevertheless, the debt-to-output ratio (i.e. q m M ) resulting from the model is 99.4%, a value very close Y to the U.S. public debt-to-gdp ratio of 1% observed in the data. The government expenditure G is set to balance the government budget constraint at the steady state. For the capital market, I choose the capital production share and the depreciation 3 My definition is similar to that in KV(211). KV(211) define a retiree s income as y j = exp(χ J ω + α + ψj + z J ω), where χ J ω is a deterministic age profile common across all retired households, α is a household-specific fixed effect, ψ is a household-specific age-earnings profile, and z J ω is a stochastic idiosyncratic component following a first-order Markov process. J ω denotes the last working period of a household. 4 Based on SCF 21, the ratio of mean wage income to mean social security income among households who are aged 6 to 78 is

12 rate (i.e. α =.25 and δ =.7) to target an annual capital-to-output ratio of 2.7 (1.8 quarterly) and an annual investment-to-capital ratio of.63 (.2 quarterly), respectively. Last but not least, the upper-bound of the adjustment cost is set to 1.5 (i.e. κ = 1.5). At this value, the total fraction of households who choose to adjust their illiquid assets is 19.8%, matching an adjustment rate of 15-2% as estimated from SCF 21 by KV(211). Steady State: One-Asset For the one-asset model, κ is set to zero and the model frequency remains to be annual. The discount factor β is changed to.965, targeting a four-percent annual real interest rate. Meanwhile, the capital production share α is set to.3 so that the annual capitalto-output ratio is The values of all other parameters are kept unchanged. Transition To study the transitional dynamics, I assume the economy initially (i.e. date ) was at its steady state, and then a relative three-percent rise in government spending takes effect (i.e. date 1). The length of the fiscal stimulus is set to one year. The government raises taxes to finance its spending and thus maintains a balanced budget. As a result, the return on liquid assets (i.e. R m = 1/q m ) stays unchanged. My transitional economy is solved using the perfect foresight algorithm described in Guerrieri and Lorenzoni (211, Appendix). Table 3 lists all the parameter values. 2.3 A fiscal stimulus experiment I subject both the one-asset and the two-asset economy to the same fiscal stimulus policy (i.e. a relative 3% increase in G). I then examine how differently the two economies respond to the policy. Figure 4 and 5 show the transitional dynamics of the major economic variables in both models. For the one-asset economy, aggregate capital is predetermined on the impact date, 12

13 and so are total output and wage since labor supply is fixed. Meanwhile, the rise in government expenditures crowds out investment and consumption. This is because the government maintains a balanced budget by increasing taxes. The rise in the income tax rate reduces working-age households disposable income and limits both their abilities to save and to consume. After the impact date, government spending reverts back to its steady state level, marking the end of the fiscal stimulus. During these subsequent periods, aggregate capital first decreases as a result of the drop in investment and then gradually rises back. The movements of total output and wage exhibit the same pattern given the fixed labor supply. Therefore, the government expenditure multiplier is negative in this economy. Moreover, the real interest rate moves in the opposite direction of capital thanks to the inverse relationship between capital and marginal product of capital. At the same time, the transitional path of consumption mimics that of wage due to the fixed labor supply. For the two-asset economy, the transitional dynamics is similar to the one-asset economy. Investment and consumption are crowded out by government spending. After the impact date, total output first decreases before eventually rising back to its steady state, indicating a negative government expenditure multiplier as well. To sum up, if the labor supply is assumed to be fixed, the addition of a second asset does not alter the qualitative result generated by a life-cycle one-asset model. Specifically, the rise in government spending crowds out investment, leading to a drop in capital which drives down the total output in both the one-asset and the two-asset economy. Therefore, in contrast to some recent New Keynesian models, 5 the experiment here shows that the government expenditure multiplier can be negative in general equilibrium models with capital, flexible prices and a fixed labor supply. 5 For example, the New Keynesian models in Woodford (211) and Christiano, Eichenbaum and Rebelo (211) can generate a government expenditure multiplier in excess of one when the nominal interest rate reaches zero. 13

14 3 A life-cycle model with endogenous labor supply In this section, I relax the assumption of fixed labor supply by making hours of work as a choice variable for working-age households. 3.1 Model Demographics The economy is still populated with a continuum of households indexed by their age j = 1, 2,..., J. Households work for the first J ω periods, and then become retirees for the next J r periods before exiting the economy. Hence, J ω + J r = J. Preference Households now value both consumption and leisure. Each of them has an expected lifetime utility: J ω E { β j 1 [log c j + ψ log(1 n j )] + J β j 1 log c j }, ψ > j=1 j=j ω +1 where c j and n j denote the household s consumption and hours of work at age j, respectively. Since households do not work after retirement (i.e. n j = for j = J ω + 1,..., J), the leisure utility term drops out for the retirees thanks to the log functional form. Financial Assets The setup for financial assets remains the same as in the model with fixed labor supply. The economy has one costless-to-adjust liquid asset m with a gross return of R m = 1/q m, and one costly-to-adjust illiquid asset a with a gross return of R a = 1/q a. A borrowing limit of zero is imposed on both assets. The adjustment cost κ is an i.i.d draw from a uniform distribution U(, κ), where the lower-bound is zero and the upper-bound is κ. The adjustment cost is set to zero for the oldest households, eliminating the possibility of positive leftover illiquid wealth. 14

15 Earnings For each working household, it draws an exogenous labor productivity ɛ at the beginning of every period. The productivity follows a Markov process. After seeing its ɛ and adjustment cost draw κ, the household chooses the number of hours it wants to work (i.e. n) while taking wage w as given. Thus, the household s income is (1 τ)wɛn, where τ is labor income tax rate. For each retired household, it still receives a lump-sum tax-free government transfer ρ(j, ɛ J ω) in every period. Household Problem The formulation of the household problem is similar to the model with fixed labor supply. Therefore, I briefly list the three key equations below. For each working household, it will choose not to adjust the illiquid asset if V (a, m, ɛ, j) V 1 (a, m, ɛ, j, κ). Then it solves: V (a, m, ɛ, j) = max c,m,n subject to: N ɛ u(c, n) + β π(ɛ l ɛ) V (a, m, ɛ l, j + 1, κ )H(dκ ) (3.1) κ l=1 c + q m m (1 τ)wɛn + m a = a q a m n 1. The household will choose to adjust the illiquid asset if V (a, m, ɛ, j) < V 1 (a, m, ɛ, j, κ). 15

16 Then it solves: V 1 (a, m, ɛ, j, κ) = max c,a,m,n subject to: N ɛ u(c, n) + β π(ɛ l ɛ) V (a, m, ɛ l, j + 1, κ )H(dκ(3.2) ) κ l=1 c + q a a + q m m (1 τ)wɛn + a + m κ a m n 1. The ex-post value function of a household is V (a, m, ɛ, j, κ) = max{v (a, m, ɛ, j), V 1 (a, m, ɛ, j, κ)}. (3.3) To solve the retiree s problem, I set n to zero, substitute (1 τ)wɛn with ρ(j, ɛ J ω), and remove the expectation over ɛ l. Appendix B2 has a detailed description of the computational algorithm used to solve the household problem. Government The role of the government remains the same in this economy as it is in the economy with fixed labor supply. Its budget constraint can be written as: J ω τ j=1 J wn j ɛ j µ j ([ds j de j ]) + q m M = G + j=j ω +1 ρ(j, ɛ J ω)µ j ([ds j de j ]) + M (3.4) where µ j ([s j e j ]) is the distribution of households of age j over s j = (a j, m j ) and e j = (ɛ j, κ j ). 16

17 Firm A representative firm produces a homogeneous final good for households to consume by using the Cobb-Douglas production technology, F (K, N) = K α N 1 α. Capital depreciates at rate δ. The firm maximizes its profit by choosing K and N so that: w = (1 α)( K N )α, (3.5) 1 q a = α( K N )α δ. (3.6) General Equilibrium A recursive competitive equilibrium consists of a set of functions, (q a, q m, w, V, V 1, V, c, n, a, m, K, N, M, Γ), that satisfies the following conditions. 1. Individual Household Optimization: V, V 1 and V satisfy (3.1),(3.2) and (3.3), and c, n, a and m are the associated policy functions. 2. Representative Firm Optimization: The representative firm chooses N and K as shown in (3.5) and (3.6). 3. Labor Market Clearing Condition: J ω N = j=1 n j ɛ j µ j ([ds j de j ]). 4. Capital Market Clearing Condition: J K = q a j=1 a j µ j ([ds j de j ]). 17

18 5. Bond Market Clearing Condition: M = J j=1 m j µ j ([ds j de j ]). 6. Goods Market Clearing Condition: J zk α N 1 α = c j µ j ([ds j de j ]) + K (1 δ)k + G + K j=1 where: J K = q a a j+1 µ j ([ds j de j ]), K = j=1 J j=1 G satisfies (3.4). κ j I adj=1 µ j ([ds j de j ]), 7. Law of Motion of the Distribution: Γ is defined as follows. For all K K and M M, for j = 1,..., J 1, µ j+1 ( K q a, M, ɛ j+1, κ j+1 ) = { } I sj+1 =s dπ(ɛ j+1 j+1 ɛ j )H(dκ j+1 )µ j ([ds j de j ]) µ j ([ds j de j]) and µ 1 ( K q a, M, ɛ 1, κ 1 ) = { } I dπ(ɛ s1 =( K q a,m ) 1 ɛ J )H(dκ 1 )µ J ([ds J de J ]) µ J ([ds J de J]). Here, s j+1 = (a j+1, m j+1) solves (3.3), π(ɛ j+1 ɛ j ) denotes the transitional probability from ɛ j to ɛ j+1, and I is an indicator function which takes one if s j+1 ( K q a, M ) and zero otherwise. 18

19 One-Asset Model For the one-asset model, the economy only has the liquid asset (i.e. κ = ). Working-age households not only choose their consumption and savings in liquid assets but the number of hours they want to work. Meanwhile, the choice variables for retired households are still consumption and liquid asset savings. 3.2 Parameterization Steady State: Two-Asset The model has an annual frequency. Except for the leisure preference parameter ψ, all other parameters here, together with their targets, are the same as they are in the fixed labor supply case. Therefore, in this section, I only briefly describe the parameters whose values have been changed. Please see Table 3 for details. First, the leisure preference parameter ψ is set to.6, targeting an aggregate labor of.3-.4 at the steady state. Second, the common age profile for transfers, χ J ω, is changed to 15 so that the ratio of mean wage income to mean transfers is about Last, to keep an annual inflation of 2-3%, the total supply of liquid assets M is set to.23. Steady State: One-Asset For the one-asset model, κ is set to zero and the model frequency is annual. The discount factor β is.965, targeting a four-percent annual real interest rate. The capital production share α is set to.29 so that the annual capital-to-output ratio is The values of all other parameters are kept same as in the two-asset case above. Transition To study the transitional dynamics, I again assume the economy initially (i.e. date ) was at its steady state, and then a relative three-percent rise in government spending takes effect (i.e. date 1). The length of the fiscal stimulus is one year. The government raises taxes to finance its spending and thus maintains a balanced budget. Hence, the 19

20 return on liquid assets (i.e. R m = 1/q m ) stays unchanged. 3.3 A fiscal stimulus experiment I subject both the one-asset and the two-asset model to the same fiscal stimulus policy (i.e. a relative 3% increase in G). I then examine how differently the two economies respond to the policy. Figure 6 and 8 show the transitional dynamics of the major economic variables in both models. One-Asset Economy Similar to the fixed labor supply case, aggregate capital is predetermined on the impact date. Since the government uses taxes to maintain a balanced budget, the rise in its spending crowds out consumption and investment. Unlike the fixed labor supply case, total output drops on the impact date because aggregate labor decreases. The intuition behind this decrease in labor can be explained using a representative household s problem. For example, a representative household solves the problem below: max c t,n t,k t+1 E{ subject to: T β t [log c t + ψ log(1 n t )]} t=1 c t + q t k t+1 (1 τ)w t n t + k t. After taking first-order conditions, we can obtain the following labor-leisure condition: ψ 1 n t = (1 τ) w t c t. Hence, there are two opposing effects on n. The first effect is the labor income tax effect. In particular, the government raises the labor income tax rate τ to fund its spending. As τ increases on the right hand side, n on the left hand side has to decrease. The second effect comes from w. Figure 6 shows that wage increases and consumption decreases on c 2

21 the impact date. Therefore, w goes up, putting an upward pressure on n. In the end, the c first effect overwhelms the second effect and aggregate labor decreases. To further corroborate the above-described intuition, I replace the proportional labor income tax in the one-asset model with a lump-sum tax. Figure 7 shows the transitional dynamics of the economy. On the impact date, total output rises because aggregate labor increases. The intuition behind this increase in labor can be explained using the same representative household s problem: max E{ c t,n t,k t+1 subject to: T β t [log c t + ψ log(1 n t )]} t=1 c t + q t k t+1 w t n t + k t τ τ : now a lump-sum tax. After taking first-order conditions, we can obtain the following labor-leisure condition: ψ 1 n t = w t c t. Hence, the labor income tax effect disappears in the lump-sum tax case. Figure 7 shows that wage stays close to its steady state level and consumption decreases on the impact date. Therefore, w c goes up and n increases. The analysis above reveals an important observation. For a one-asset model with endogenous labor supply, the government expenditure multiplier can be negative in the presence of a proportional labor income tax, but become positive under a lump-sum tax environment. Two-Asset Economy Similar to the one-asset model, aggregate capital is predetermined on the impact date. The rising government spending crowds out consumption, investment and aggregate savings in liquid assets (i.e. M ). 21

22 In contrast to the one-asset model, total output increases on the impact date because aggregate labor jumps up. The intuition behind this increase in labor can be again explained using a representative household s problem: max E{ c t,n t,k t+1,m t+1 subject to: T β t [log c t + ψ log(1 n t )]} t=1 c t + q k t k t+1 + q m t m t+1 (1 τ)w t n t + k t + m t. After taking first-order conditions, we obtain the same labor-leisure condition as in the one-asset model: ψ 1 n t = (1 τ) w t c t. However, the relative decrease in consumption in the two-asset economy is ten times that of the one-asset economy (i.e. 1% vs..1%). As a result, the effect of w c overwhelms the labor income tax effect, and aggregate labor jumps up on the impact date. The much stronger consumption response in the two-asset model merits an explanation. In both the one-asset and the two-asset model, only households who are wealth constrained have to cut down their consumption considerably. The non-constrained households can resort to their savings for consumption smoothing. In the one-asset economy, the empirical counterpart to the wealth in the model is net worth. Therefore, the magnitude of the aggregate consumption response to a fiscal stimulus depends on how many households who are net worth constrained. In the two-asset economy, the empirical counterparts to the two wealth are liquid and illiquid wealth. Appendix A2 details the definition of the two wealth. On one hand, the existence of adjustment cost prevents households from accessing their illiquid wealth. On the other hand, the illiquid asset enjoys a higher return, so the majority of a household s wealth will be stored in its illiquid account. Therefore, the number of households who are liquid wealth constrained determines how big an aggregate consumption response the two-asset model can generate. 22

23 In the data, there are many more households who are liquid wealth constrained. As a result, under parametrization that is in line with the data, aggregate consumption drops more in the two-asset model. I adopt the definition of wealth-constrained households as suggested in KV (211) and use the same dataset (i.e. SCF 21) to measure the fraction of wealth-constrained households in both the one-asset and the two-asset economy. Specifically, I assume that households are surveyed at the midpoint of a pay period, and their expenditures remain constant across two pay periods. Then households whose wealth (i.e. net worth in oneasset model and liquid wealth in two-asset model) is less than half of their earnings per pay period are considered as wealth constrained. The frequency of pay dates is assumed to be monthly. Table 4 reports my empirical estimates and their model counterparts. 6 As shown in Table 4, the number of liquid-wealth constrained households in the twoasset economy is much bigger than the number of net-worth constrained households in the one-asset economy. Even though my two-asset model underestimates the fraction of liquid-wealth constrained households, 7 it still generates an aggregate consumption response big enough to overcome the labor income tax effect, which the one-asset model fails to do. To sum up, under an endogenous labor supply and a proportional labor income tax, the addition of a second asset can lead to a complete departure from the qualitative result generated by a life-cycle one-asset model. Particularly, on the impact date, aggregate labor drops in the one-asset economy but increases in the two-asset economy. Since the capital stock is predetermined, the government expenditure multiplier on the impact date is negative in the one-asset model but positive in the two-asset model. 6 KV (211) find that 5.6%-7.1% of households are net-worth constrained and 3-42% of households are liquid-wealth constrained. My empirical estimates are higher than theirs, because my definition of earnings excludes benefits such as unemployment and disability insurances but theirs does. 7 The underestimation might be due to two factors. First, households are not allowed to borrow in the model, but people often borrow through credit cards in real life. Second, the only channel for households in the model to partially insure themselves against future adversities (i.e. low productivity draws) is to save in one or both assets. In reality, policies such as food stamps and unemployment benefits often reduce one s incentive to save. As a result, households hold more liquid wealth in my model when compared to the data. 23

24 4 Conclusion In this paper, I develop a general equilibrium model with four main features: (1) a built-in lifecycle; (2) an income process estimated using the U.S. earnings data; (3) two assets differentiated by an adjustment cost; (4) idiosyncratic risks with respect to labor productivity and adjustment cost. A one-asset version of the model can be obtained by setting the adjustment cost to zero. I subject both the two-asset and the one-asset version of the model to a rise in government spending. As a result, my main findings are as follows. First, for both versions of the model, under fixed labor supply, the rise in government spending crowds out investment, causing capital to drop and thus driving down the total output. Second, under endogenous labor supply, aggregate labor falls in the one-asset economy but a substantial decrease in consumption causes it to rise in the two-asset economy. The capital stock is predetermined, so total output decreases in the one-asset economy but increases in the two-asset economy. References [1] Aiyagari, S. Rao, Lawrence Christiano and Martin Eichenbaum (1992): The Output, Employment, and Interest Rate Effects of Government Consumption, Journal of Monetary Economics, 3(1), [2] Baxter, Marianne and Robert King (1993): Fiscal Policy in General Equilibrium, The American Economic Review, 83(3), [3] Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum and Jonas Fisher (24): Fiscal Shocks and Their Consequences, Journal of Economic Theory, 115, [4] Christiano, Lawrence, Martin Eichenbaum and Sergio Rebelo (211): When Is the Government Spending Multiplier Large? Journal of Political Economy, 119(1),

25 [5] Deaton, Angus (1991): Saving and Liquidity Constraints, Econometrica, 59(5), [6] Gali, Jordi, David López-Salido and Javier Vallés (27): Understanding the Effects of Government Spending on Consumption, Journal of the European Economics Association, 5(1), [7] Guerrieri, Veronica and Guido Lorenzoni (211): Credit Crisis, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap, NBER Working Paper No [8] Heathcote, Jonathan (25): Fiscal Policy with Heterogeneous Agents and Incomplete Markets, Review of Economic Studies, 72(1), [9] Heathcote, Jonathan, Kjetil Storesletten and Giovanni Violante (29): Quantitative Macroeconomics with Heterogeneous Households, NBER Working Paper No [1] Heathcote, Jonathan, Fabrizio Perri and Giovanni Violante (21): Unequal We Stand: An Empirical Analysis of Economic Inequality in the United States, , Review of Economic Dynamics, 13, [11] Huggett, Mark (1993): The Risk-free Rate in Heterogeneous-agent Incompleteinsurance Economies, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 17(5-6): [12] Johnson, David, Jonathan Parker and Nicholas Souleles (26): Household Expenditure and the Income Tax Rebates of 21, The American Economic Review, 96(5), [13] Kaplan, Greg and Giovanni Violante (211): A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments, NBER Working Paper No [14] Kiefer, Donald, Robert Carroll, Janet Holtzblatt, Allen Lerman, Janet McCubbin, David Richardson and Jerry Tempalski (22): The Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 21: Overview and Assessment of Effects on Taxpayers, National Tax Journal, 55(1),

26 [15] Lusardi, Annamaria, Daniel Schneider and Peter Tufano (211): Financially Fragile Households: Evidence and Implications, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring 211, [16] Misra, Kanishka and Paolo Surico (211): Heterogeneous Responses and Aggregate Impact of the 21 Income Tax Rebates, NBER Working Paper No [17] Monacelli, Tommaso and Roberto Perotti (28): Fiscal Policy, Wealth Effects and Markups, NBER Working Paper No [18] Parker, Jonathan, Nicholas Souleles, David Johnson and David Johnson (211): Consumer Spending and the Economic Stimulus Payments of 28, Tax Policy and the Economy, 17, [19] Tauchen, George (1986): Finite State Markov-Chain Approximations to Univariate and Vector Autoregressions, Economics Letters, 2, [2] Woodford, Michael (211): Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 3(1),

27 Table 1. Household Portfolio Composition, SCF 21* Median Mean ($21) ($21) Earnings plus benefits (age 22 59) 5, , 291 Net worth 89, , 1 Net liquid wealth 3, , 737 Cash,checking,saving,MM accounts 3, , 737 Directly held MF,stocks,bonds 24, 179 Credit card debt 2, 39 Net illiquid wealth 78, , 363 Housing net of mortgages 37, , 142 Vehicles net of installment loans 7, 475 1, 929 Retirement accounts 2, 451 7, 74 Life insurance 12, 21 Certificates of deposit 6, 43 Saving bonds 1, 334 *Please see Appendix A2 for details on the data. Table 2. Parameter Description Parameter Description Source/Target J ω retirement age 6 as retirement age J r retirement length 78.6 as U.S. life expectancy J total life span J = J ω + J r β household discount factor 4-6% annual real interest rate ψ household leisure preference 1/3 time spent working h working hours 1/3 time spent working τ labor income tax rate Kiefer et al.(211, Table 5) ρ ɛ labor productivity persistence PSID σ ɛ variance of innovation to labor productivity PSID χ common age effect on transfers SCF 21 p j age-specific effect on transfers SCF 21 M total supply of liquid assets 3-4% annual inflation α capital production share annual K/Y = 2.36, NIPA δ capital depreciation rate annual I/K =.8, NIPA κ adjustment cost upper-bound 15-2% adjustment, KV(211) 27

28 Table 3. Parameter Values One-Asset Model Parameter Fixed Endogenous Endogenous Lump-Sum J ω J r J β ψ.6 (N =.39) 2. (N =.35) h 1/3 τ ρ ɛ σ ɛ χ 5. ( (1 τ)w n ρ = 1.3) 15. ( (1 τ)w n ρ = 1.3) 15. ( (1 τ)w n ρ = 1.3) p j Appendix A3 Appendix A3 Appendix A3 M α.3 (K/Y = 2.44).29 (K/Y = 2.28).3 (K/Y = 2.37) δ.7 (I/K =.7).7 (I/K =.7).7 (I/K =.7) κ... Two-Asset Model Parameter Fixed Endogenous J ω J r J β ψ.6 (N =.4) h 1/3 τ ρ ɛ σ ɛ.6.6 χ 5. ( (1 τ)w n ρ = 1.2) 15. ( (1 τ)w n ρ = 1.3) p j Appendix A3 Appendix A3 M.36 (3% inflation).23 (3.8% inflation) α.25 (K/Y = 2.7).27 (K/Y = 2.) δ.7 (I/K =.6).7 (I/K =.8) κ 1.5 (19.76% adjust) 1.5 (2.89% adjust) Table 4. Wealth-Constrained Households as Percentage, SCF21 vs. Model* Two-asset Liquid-Wealth Constrained One-asset Net-Worth Constrained SCF % 12.6% Model 33.46% 13.13% *The pay frequency is assumed to be monthly, and both models have an endogenous labor supply. 28

29 Figure 1A. Real U.S. Government Spending (in 29 dollar), Figure 1B. U.S. Government Spending as Fraction of GDP,

30 Figure 2. U.S. Taxation, Figure 3. Median Liquid and Illiquid Wealth by Age Cohorts, SCF 21* *Please see Appendix A2 for details on the data. 3

31 Figure 4. Transitional Dynamics: One-Asset with Fixed Labor Supply % deviation % deviation % deviation % deviation G C I Y N 1 1 w.5.1 K x R Figure 5. Transitional Dynamics: Two-Asset with Fixed Labor Supply % deviation % deviation % deviation % deviation % deviation G Tax C I Y N 1 1 w.5.5 K x Ra M

32 Figure 6. Transitional Dynamics: One-Asset with Endogenous Labor Supply % deviation % deviation % deviation % deviation G C I Y N 2 2 w.5.5 K x R Figure 7. Transitional Dynamics: One-Asset with Endogenous Labor Supply and Lump-Sum Tax % deviation % deviation % deviation % deviation G C I Y N 1.5 w 1 2 K x R

33 Figure 8. Transitional Dynamics: Two-Asset with Endogenous Labor Supply 3 G.2 N % deviation Tax.5 w % deviation C.5 K % deviation I 1 2 x 1 3 Rk % deviation Y 2 M % deviation

34 Appendix A: Data A1: Labor Income Process I use the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) over the period to estimate the labor income process in my model. 8 The statistical model and estimation method are adopted from Heathcote et al.(21). A1.1: Sample Selection My sample selection criteria mainly follow Heathcote et al.(21) with the exception that I only include households whose heads have remained the same over the entire period. I use PSID family public data but restrict my focus on heads of households. 9 The following list details my sample selection criteria. - The head of household is considered unchanged if 1) no individual moves in or out of the family, 2) there is a change in members other than head or wife only, or 3) the head is the same but the spouse left, died or has changed. - The head is aged between 25 and The head s annual number of hours working for money is bigger than The head s annual labor income is positive. 11 A1.2: Estimation Method First, I retrieve log hourly wage residuals from the following Mincerian regression which is run separately year by year. 12 log E t = β + β 1 male + β 2 age + β 3 (age age) + β 4 college + β 5 white E t : male : college : white : hourly wage at year t 1 if male; otherwise 1 if went to college (regardless if a degree is received); otherwise 1 if white; otherwise 8 The frequency of the PSID data have changed from annual to biennial since My model has an annual frequency, so I exclude the biannual PSID data from my analysis. 9 Heathcote et al.(21) argue that endogenous labor participation choices can contaminate the estimation of income dynamics for secondary earners. 1 In the PSID, while age of the head refers to the survey year, questions about income and the number of hours worked refer to the previous year. Following Heathcote et al.(21), I do not adjust this timing discrepancy. 11 The labor income includes labor part of farm income and business income, bonuses, overtime, commissions, professional practice, labor part of income from roomers and boarders or business income. 12 I define the hourly wage as the head s annual labor income divided by the annual number of hours he worked. All wages are deflated using annual BEA price indexes for GDP (29=1). 34

35 Second, I assume the log hourly wage residual follows a permanent-transitory statistical process. More specifically, let w i,c,t be the log hourly wage residual for individual i of cohort c at year t. w i,c,t = z i,c,t + ɛ i,c,t, z i,c,t = z i,c,t 1 + η i,c,t, where ɛ i,c,t and η i,c,t are i.i.d across individuals and uncorrelated with each other or over time. Therefore, ɛ i,c,t can be interpreted as a transitory income shock and η i,c,t as a permanent income shock. I can then express the variances of the two shocks, σ ɛ,t and σ η,t, as follows. var c (w i,c,t ) cov c (w i,c,t+1, w i,c,t ) = σ ɛ,t, var c (w i,c,t ) cov c (w i,c,t, w i,c,t 1 ) = σ η,t + σ ɛ,t. Since neither σ ɛ,t nor σ η,t depends on cohort c under the true model, I can estimate variances at year t by averaging across all sample cohorts. A1.3: Results Table A1 lists the summary statistics of the shocks. 13 Following KV(211), I treat transitory shocks as measurement errors. Therefore, the variance of labor income shocks in my model is set to.6, the average value for the variances of permanent shocks from 1968 to I decide to select the average value from 1968 to 1993 for two reasons. First, the sample size drops below 5 after Second, the PSID data are released in two stages: early release and final release. The early release version is more preliminary. The 1994 onward data are still at the early-release stage. A2: Asset Holdings I use the Summary Extract Dataset of Survey of Consumer Finance 21 (SCF 21) to calculate the mean and median liquid and illiquid wealth held by households of each age group. The dataset is available on the Federal Reserve s website at http : // ederalreserve.gov/econresdata/ scf/scf 21survey.htm. When defining the liquid and illiquid wealth, I try to follow KV (211, Table 2) as closely as possible. The following list describes how I define the liquid wealth. - Variable LIQ is used as the estimate of cash, checking, saving and MM accounts. - I use variable NMMF, STOCKS, and BOND as the estimate of directly held MF, stocks, and bonds. - Credit card debt is set to the value of variable CCBAL. - Hence, the liquid wealth is defined as the sum of LIQ, NMMF, STOCKS and BOND, minus CCBAL. 13 Similar to Heathcote et al.(21), my estimates of σ η,t have negative values. Heathcote et al.(21) attribute the negative values to potential misspecification, an issue they call for future research to resolve. 14 Heathcote et al.(21) find the variance of permanent shocks to be.7, a value very close to mine. 35

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models?

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models? How Much Insurance in Bewley Models? Greg Kaplan New York University Gianluca Violante New York University, CEPR, IFS and NBER Boston University Macroeconomics Seminar Lunch Kaplan-Violante, Insurance

More information

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge By Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Elena Pastorino This paper is motivated by the strong correlation between changes in household debt and employment across regions

More information

A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments

A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments Greg Kaplan University of Pennsylvania Gianluca Violante New York University Federal Reserve Board May 31, 2012 1/47 Fiscal stimulus payments

More information

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices Phuong V. Ngo,a a Department of Economics, Cleveland State University, 22 Euclid Avenue, Cleveland,

More information

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy Johannes Wieland University of California, San Diego and NBER 1. Introduction Markets are incomplete. In recent

More information

Final Exam Solutions

Final Exam Solutions 14.06 Macroeconomics Spring 2003 Final Exam Solutions Part A (True, false or uncertain) 1. Because more capital allows more output to be produced, it is always better for a country to have more capital

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 Instructions: Read the questions carefully and make sure to show your work. You

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk Vasia Panousi Catarina Reis April 27 WP 27/64 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far.

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model Eric Sims University of otre Dame Spring 7 Introduction This set of notes studies fiscal policy in the RBC model. Fiscal policy refers to government

More information

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19

Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal 1 / of19 Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap (R&R Quarterly Journal of nomics) October 31, 2016 Credit Crises, Precautionary Savings and the Liquidity Trap October (R&R Quarterly 31, 2016Journal

More information

Fiscal Policy Puzzle and Intratemporal Substitution among Private Consumption, Government Spending, and Leisure.

Fiscal Policy Puzzle and Intratemporal Substitution among Private Consumption, Government Spending, and Leisure. Fiscal Policy Puzzle and Intratemporal Substitution among Private Consumption, Government Spending, and Leisure. Masataka Eguchi Faculty of Economics, Keio University and Yuhki Hosoya Graduate School of

More information

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) ....... Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) Rapid Aging and Chinese Pension Reform, June 3, 2014 SHUFE, Shanghai ..... The results in this

More information

A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT

A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT Discussion Paper No. 779 A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT Ryu-ichiro Murota Yoshiyasu Ono June 2010 The Institute of Social and Economic Research Osaka University

More information

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation Joachim Hubmer, Per Krusell, and Tony Smith Yale, IIES, and Yale March 2016 Evolution of top wealth inequality

More information

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 7b

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 7b 316-406 ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 7b Chris Edmond hcpedmond@unimelb.edu.aui Aiyagari s model Arguably the most popular example of a simple incomplete markets model is due to Rao Aiyagari (1994,

More information

A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments

A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments Greg Kaplan 1 Gianluca Violante 2 1 Princeton University 2 New York University Presented by Francisco Javier Rodríguez (Universidad Carlos

More information

Government spending and firms dynamics

Government spending and firms dynamics Government spending and firms dynamics Pedro Brinca Nova SBE Miguel Homem Ferreira Nova SBE December 2nd, 2016 Francesco Franco Nova SBE Abstract Using firm level data and government demand by firm we

More information

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis University of Western Ontario February 2013 Question Main Question: what is the welfare cost/gain of US social safety

More information

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania Vol. 3, No.3, July 2013, pp. 365 371 ISSN: 2225-8329 2013 HRMARS www.hrmars.com The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania Ana-Maria SANDICA

More information

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Department of Economics HKUST August 7, 2018 Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics 1 / 48 Reference Krueger, Dirk, Kurt Mitman, and Fabrizio Perri. Macroeconomics

More information

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho Beggar-thy-parents? A Lifecycle Model of Intergenerational Altruism Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho University of New South Wales March 2009 Motivation & Question Since Becker (1974), several studies analyzing

More information

Nonlinear Persistence and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID

Nonlinear Persistence and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID AEA Papers and Proceedings 28, 8: 7 https://doi.org/.257/pandp.2849 Nonlinear and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID By Manuel Arellano, Richard Blundell, and Stephane Bonhomme*

More information

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System Shinichi Nishiyama Department of Risk Management and Insurance Georgia State University November 17, 2008 Abstract We extend a standard overlapping-generations

More information

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation Matthias Doepke UCLA Martin Schneider NYU and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Abstract This paper shows that a zero-sum redistribution

More information

Welfare Evaluations of Policy Reforms with Heterogeneous Agents

Welfare Evaluations of Policy Reforms with Heterogeneous Agents Welfare Evaluations of Policy Reforms with Heterogeneous Agents Toshihiko Mukoyama University of Virginia December 2011 The goal of macroeconomic policy What is the goal of macroeconomic policies? Higher

More information

Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis

Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis Santanu Chatterjee University of Georgia Felix Rioja Georgia State University October 31, 2017 John Gibson Georgia State University Abstract

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Kenichi Ueda* *The University of Tokyo PRI-ADBI Joint Workshop January 13, 2017 The views are those of the author and should not be attributed

More information

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell National Institute of Economic and Social Research 1. Introduction

More information

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University March 2013 Idiosyncratic risk and the business cycle How much and what types

More information

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 2013 North American Summer Meeting Ralph Lütticke 13.06.2013 1 Joint-work with Christian Bayer, Lien Pham, and Volker Tjaden 1 / 30 Research

More information

Debt Burdens and the Interest Rate Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence.

Debt Burdens and the Interest Rate Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence. Debt Burdens and the Interest Rate Response to Fiscal Stimulus: Theory and Cross-Country Evidence. Jorge Miranda-Pinto 1, Daniel Murphy 2, Kieran Walsh 2, Eric Young 1 1 UVA, 2 UVA Darden School of Business

More information

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles RIETI Discussion Paper Series 07-E-062 Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles KOBAYASHI Keiichiro RIETI NUTAHARA Kengo the University of Tokyo / JSPS The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier Faculty of Social Sciences Jeppe Druedahl (Ph.d. Student) Department of Economics 16th of December 2013 Slide 1/29 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 16th of December 2013 Slide 2/29 The For Today 1 Some 2 A Benchmark

More information

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home midterm exam. 1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility The purpose of this question is to explore a labor market puzzle that has bedeviled business

More information

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity Ctirad Slavík, CERGE-EI, Prague (with Hakki Yazici, Sabanci University and Özlem Kina, EUI) January 4, 2019 ASSA in Atlanta 1 / 31 Motivation Optimal

More information

Optimal Income tax rates with non-democratic political constraints: case of Armenia

Optimal Income tax rates with non-democratic political constraints: case of Armenia Optimal Income tax rates with non-democratic political constraints: case of Armenia Vardan Baghdasaryan * Hayk Hambardzumyan Abstract Tax is the main source for a government to finance its expenditures

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model

The Basic New Keynesian Model Jordi Gali Monetary Policy, inflation, and the business cycle Lian Allub 15/12/2009 In The Classical Monetary economy we have perfect competition and fully flexible prices in all markets. Here there is

More information

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles Keiichiro Kobayashi Research Institute of Economy, Trade, and Industry Kengo Nutahara Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo, and the JSPS Research

More information

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports Alexandre Dmitriev University of New South Wales Ivan Roberts Reserve Bank of Australia and University of New South Wales February 2, 2011 Abstract Two-country,

More information

Problem Set 5. Graduate Macro II, Spring 2014 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims

Problem Set 5. Graduate Macro II, Spring 2014 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims Problem Set 5 Graduate Macro II, Spring 2014 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims Instructions: You may consult with other members of the class, but please make sure to turn in your own work. Where

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

The Zero Lower Bound

The Zero Lower Bound The Zero Lower Bound Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 4 Introduction In the standard New Keynesian model, monetary policy is often described by an interest rate rule (e.g. a Taylor rule) that

More information

From Wages to Welfare: Decomposing Gains and Losses From Rising Inequality

From Wages to Welfare: Decomposing Gains and Losses From Rising Inequality From Wages to Welfare: Decomposing Gains and Losses From Rising Inequality Jonathan Heathcote Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and CEPR Kjetil Storesletten Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and CEPR

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment Yi Wen Department of Economics Cornell University Ithaca, NY 14853 yw57@cornell.edu Abstract

More information

A Tale of Two Stimulus Payments: 2001 vs 2008

A Tale of Two Stimulus Payments: 2001 vs 2008 A Tale of Two Stimulus Payments: 2001 vs 2008 Greg Kaplan Princeton University & NBER Gianluca Violante New York University, CEPR & NBER American Economic Associa-on Annual Mee-ng January 5, 2013 Fiscal

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 26/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case

More information

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls Lucas (1990), Supply Side Economics: an Analytical Review, Oxford Economic Papers When I left graduate school, in 1963, I believed that the single most desirable change in the U.S. structure would be the

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007 Instructions: Read the questions carefully and make sure to show your work. You

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Vipin Arora Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Junsang Lee U.S. EIA Deakin Univ. SKKU December 16, 2013 GRIPS Junsang Lee (SKKU) Oil Price Dynamics in

More information

A simple wealth model

A simple wealth model Quantitative Macroeconomics Raül Santaeulàlia-Llopis, MOVE-UAB and Barcelona GSE Homework 5, due Thu Nov 1 I A simple wealth model Consider the sequential problem of a household that maximizes over streams

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Consumption and House Prices in the Great Recession: Model Meets Evidence

Consumption and House Prices in the Great Recession: Model Meets Evidence Consumption and House Prices in the Great Recession: Model Meets Evidence Greg Kaplan Kurt Mitman Gianluca Violante MFM 9-10 March, 2017 Outline 1. Overview 2. Model 3. Questions Q1: What shock(s) drove

More information

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 The Ramsey Model Lectures 11 to 14 Topics in Macroeconomics November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 Lecture 11, 12, 13 & 14 1/50 Topics in Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model: Introduction 2 Main Ingredients Neoclassical

More information

Behavioral Theories of the Business Cycle

Behavioral Theories of the Business Cycle Behavioral Theories of the Business Cycle Nir Jaimovich and Sergio Rebelo September 2006 Abstract We explore the business cycle implications of expectation shocks and of two well-known psychological biases,

More information

Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and U.S. growth

Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and U.S. growth Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and US growth Michele Cavallo Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Anthony Landry Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas October 2008

More information

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Sudden Stops and Output Drops Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 353 January 2005 Sudden Stops and Output Drops V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Patrick J.

More information

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Asset Prices and Finance Max Gillman Cardi Business School 0 December 200 Gillman (Cardi Business School) Chapter 7 0 December 200 / 38 Chapter 7: Asset Prices and Finance

More information

Inflation & Welfare 1

Inflation & Welfare 1 1 INFLATION & WELFARE ROBERT E. LUCAS 2 Introduction In a monetary economy, private interest is to hold not non-interest bearing cash. Individual efforts due to this incentive must cancel out, because

More information

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho Beggar-thy-parents? A Lifecycle Model of Intergenerational Altruism Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho University of New South Wales, Sydney July 2009, CEF Conference Motivation & Question Since Becker (1974), several

More information

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam MACROECONOMICS Prelim Exam Austin, June 1, 2012 Instructions This is a closed book exam. If you get stuck in one section move to the next one. Do not waste time on sections that you find hard to solve.

More information

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan Optimal Credit Market Policy Matteo Iacoviello 1 Ricardo Nunes 2 Andrea Prestipino 1 1 Federal Reserve Board 2 University of Surrey CEF 218, Milan June 2, 218 Disclaimer: The views expressed are solely

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2009

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2009 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2009 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Monetary Economics Final Exam 316-466 Monetary Economics Final Exam 1. Flexible-price monetary economics (90 marks). Consider a stochastic flexibleprice money in the utility function model. Time is discrete and denoted t =0, 1,...

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far. We first introduce and discuss the intertemporal budget

More information

Infrastructure and the Optimal Level of Public Debt

Infrastructure and the Optimal Level of Public Debt Infrastructure and the Optimal Level of Public Debt Santanu Chatterjee University of Georgia Felix Rioja Georgia State University February 29, 2016 John Gibson Georgia State University Abstract We examine

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Fiscal Policy

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Fiscal Policy Advanced Macroeconomics II Fiscal Policy Lorenza Rossi (Spring 2014) University of Pavia Part of these slides are based on Jordi Galì slides for Macroeconomia Avanzada II. Outline Fiscal Policy in the

More information

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases Vincent Sterk and Silvana Tenreyro UCL, LSE September 2015 Sterk and Tenreyro (UCL, LSE) OMO September 2015 1 / 28 The

More information

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 702 Extensions of Permanent Income

More information

On the new Keynesian model

On the new Keynesian model Department of Economics University of Bern April 7, 26 The new Keynesian model is [... ] the closest thing there is to a standard specification... (McCallum). But it has many important limitations. It

More information

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014 1. Do not write with pencil, please use a ball-pen instead. 2. Please answer in English. Solutions without traceable outlines, as well as those with unreadable

More information

Consumption and Labor Supply with Partial Insurance: An Analytical Framework

Consumption and Labor Supply with Partial Insurance: An Analytical Framework Consumption and Labor Supply with Partial Insurance: An Analytical Framework Jonathan Heathcote Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, CEPR Kjetil Storesletten Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, CEPR Gianluca

More information

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel Martin Eichenbaum, Sergio Rebelo, and Arlene Wong May 2018 Motivation In the US, bulk of household borrowing is in fixed rate mortgages with

More information

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier Michael Woodford Columbia University January 1, 2010 Abstract This paper explains the key factors that determine the effectiveness of government

More information

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Minchung Hsu Pei-Ju Liao GRIPS Academia Sinica October 15, 2010 Abstract This paper aims to discover the impacts

More information

International Debt Deleveraging

International Debt Deleveraging International Debt Deleveraging Luca Fornaro London School of Economics ECB-Bank of Canada joint workshop on Exchange Rates Frankfurt, June 213 1 Motivating facts: Household debt/gdp Household debt/gdp

More information

Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks

Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks Eunseong Ma September 27, 218 Department of Economics, Texas A&M University, College Station,

More information

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy Shutao Cao 1 Yahong Zhang 2 1 Bank of Canada 2 Western University October 21, 2014 Motivation The US experience suggests that the collapse

More information

The Budgetary and Welfare Effects of. Tax-Deferred Retirement Saving Accounts

The Budgetary and Welfare Effects of. Tax-Deferred Retirement Saving Accounts The Budgetary and Welfare Effects of Tax-Deferred Retirement Saving Accounts Shinichi Nishiyama Department of Risk Management and Insurance Georgia State University March 22, 2010 Abstract We extend a

More information

International recessions

International recessions International recessions Fabrizio Perri University of Minnesota Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California July 16, 2010 Abstract The 2008-2009 US crisis is characterized by un unprecedent degree

More information

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact Georgia State University From the SelectedWorks of Fatoumata Diarrassouba Spring March 29, 2013 Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact Fatoumata

More information

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Problem Set 2: Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Exercise 2.1: An infinite horizon problem with perfect foresight In this exercise we will study at a discrete-time version of Ramsey

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen June 15, 2012 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations June 15, 2012 1 / 59 Introduction We construct

More information

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism RIETI Discussion Paper Series 09-E-05 Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism INABA Masaru The Canon Institute for Global Studies KOBAYASHI Keiichiro RIETI The

More information

Microeconomic Heterogeneity and Macroeconomic Shocks

Microeconomic Heterogeneity and Macroeconomic Shocks Microeconomic Heterogeneity and Macroeconomic Shocks Greg Kaplan University of Chicago Gianluca Violante Princeton University BdF/ECB Conference on HFC In preparation for the Special Issue of JEP on The

More information

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy Index: 9. Real business cycles in a two period economy... 9. Introduction... 9. The Representative Agent Two Period Production Economy... 9.. The representative

More information

International recessions

International recessions International recessions Fabrizio Perri University of Minnesota Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California December 17, 2009 Abstract One key feature of the 2009 crisis has been its international

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007) Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007) Virginia Olivella and Jose Ignacio Lopez October 2008 Motivation Menu costs and repricing decisions Micro foundation of sticky

More information

Transitional Housing Market and the Macroeconomy

Transitional Housing Market and the Macroeconomy Transitional Housing Market and the Macroeconomy Lini Zhang October 5, 3 Abstract This paper studies the U.S. housing market in the Great Recession. To achieve this goal, I build a quantitative general

More information