Framing Effects and Expected Social Security Claiming Behavior

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Framing Effects and Expected Social Security Claiming Behavior"

Transcription

1 Framing Effects and Expected Social Security Claiming Behavior Jeffrey R. Brown, Arie Kapteyn, and Olivia S. Mitchell April 28, 2011 Abstract Eligible participants in the U.S. Social Security system may claim benefits anytime from age 62-70, with benefit levels actuarially adjusted based on the claiming age. This paper shows that individual intentions with regard to Social Security claiming ages are sensitive to how the early versus late claiming decision is framed. Using an experimental design, we find that the use of a break-even analysis has the very strong effect of encouraging individuals to claim early. We also show that individuals are more likely to report they will delay claiming when later claiming is framed as a gain, and when the information provides an anchoring point at older, rather than younger, ages. Moreover, females, individuals with credit card debt, and workers with lower expected benefits are more strongly influenced by framing. We conclude that some individuals may not make fully rational optimizing choices when it comes to choosing a claiming date. Acknowledgements: The research reported herein was performed pursuant to a grant from the U.S. Social Security Administration (SSA) funded as part of the Financial Literacy Consortium. The authors also acknowledge support provided by the Pension Research Council and Boettner Center at the Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania, and the RAND Corporation. The authors thank Mary Fu for her expert research assistance, and Matthew Greenwald, Tania Gutsche, Lisa Marinelli, Lisa Schneider, and Bas Weerman for their invaluable comments and assistance on the project. We also thank Steve Goss and Steve McKay of SSA for their guidance. The opinions and conclusions expressed herein are solely those of the authors and do not represent the opinions or policy of SSA, any agency of the Federal Government, or any other institution with which the authors are affiliated Brown, Kapteyn, and Mitchell. All rights reserved.

2 Framing Effects and Expected Social Security Claiming Behavior Abstract Eligible participants in the U.S. Social Security system may claim benefits anytime from age 62-70, with benefit levels actuarially adjusted based on the claiming age. This paper shows that individual intentions with regard to Social Security claiming ages are sensitive to how the early versus late claiming decision is framed. Using an experimental design, we find that the use of a break-even analysis has the very strong effect of encouraging individuals to claim early. We also show that individuals are more likely to report they will delay claiming when later claiming is framed as a gain, and when the information provides an anchoring point at older, rather than younger, ages. Moreover, females, individuals with credit card debt, and workers with lower expected benefits are more strongly influenced by framing. We conclude that some individuals may not make fully rational optimizing choices when it comes to choosing a claiming date. Jeffrey R. Brown Department of Finance, University of Illinois 515 East Gregory Drive Champaign, IL brownjr@illinois.edu Arie Kapteyn Labor and Population, RAND 1776 Main Street, P.O. Box 2138 Santa Monica, CA kapteyn@rand.org Olivia S. Mitchell Dept. of Insurance and Risk Management, Wharton School University of Pennsylvania, 3620 Locust Walk, 3000 SH-DH Philadelphia, PA mitchelo@wharton.upenn.edu

3 1 Framing Effects and Expected Social Security Claiming Behavior Jeffrey R. Brown, Arie Kapteyn, and Olivia S. Mitchell I. Introduction In the years since prospect theory first emerged onto the scene, economists have come to understand that important economic decisions can be substantially altered by the way in which information is framed. Perhaps the best-known example was offered by Tversky and Kahneman (1981), who showed that presenting a public policy choice in terms of lives saved versus lives lost dramatically shifted the proportion of the respondents who supported a given policy. More generally, numerous experimental and real-world settings indicate that individuals make decisions based not only on their consequences or outcomes as would be predicted by traditional economic theory but also based on how the choices are framed. Whereas a large literature has applied other insights from behavioral economics to retirement and savings behavior (e.g., the influential work on automatic enrollment in retirement plans by Madrian and Shea, 2001), researchers have only recently begun to explore the role of framing in influencing important decisions related to retirement. Brown et al. (2008) show that when financial products are presented in a frame that emphasizes consumption features, life annuities are perceived to be more attractive than non-annuitized assets. In contrast, when such products are presented in an investment-oriented frame, the majority of respondents prefer the non-annuitized alternative. Agnew et al. (2008) also find that framing which highlights the illiquidity aspect of annuitization makes individuals less likely to elect annuities. 1 1 There is, of course, a rich literature on how framing influences a wide range of economic decisions including Andreoni (1995), Bateman et al. (1997), and Shafir et al. (1997), among many others.

4 2 In this paper, we test whether framing can influence an important financial decision that approximately 93% of all Americans will make as they enter into retirement: 2 when to claim Social Security benefits. In the U.S. Social Security system, eligible individuals are entitled to claim benefits as early as age 62, but they can also defer the age at which they claim to as late as age 70. Monthly benefit levels are adjusted for one s claiming age, and these adjustments can be substantial: for example, an individual who stops working at age 62 but waits to claim benefits at age 70 will receive 76% more (real) dollars per month for the rest of her life, than if she claimed benefits at age 62. This adjustment is said to be actuarially fair, in that the expected presented value of the two streams of benefits will be equal for individuals with average population mortality. 3 Though the two benefit streams are designed to be equal in expected present value for the average individual, they generally are not equivalent when viewed through an expected utility framework. Heterogeneity of economic circumstances and/or preferences can lead to different optimal claiming ages for different individuals (e.g., Coile et al. 2002; Hurd et al. 2004). For example, liquidity-constrained individuals with a high disutility of labor and above-average expected mortality rates may find it optimal to claim early. In contrast, risk-averse consumers with non-annuitized financial wealth may find it optimal to delay claiming because delayed claiming is effectively akin to purchasing additional amounts of inflation-indexed annuitized income that will last for life, which the literature on annuities suggest would be welfare- 2 According to the Social Security Administration, 93% of all U.S. workers in 2010 were covered under the U.S. Social Security system. ( 3 This paper abstracts from the question of whether additional years of work would change future benefits, as well as the question of how delayed claiming might influence spousal and survivor benefits. This is because we are focused here only on how individual claiming might vary with different frames. In a recent survey, 75% of respondents indicated that they understand that benefits need not be claimed at the time they stop work (Greenwald et al. 2010b).

5 3 enhancing for many. 4 Indeed, the large literature on the annuity puzzle suggests that at least some part of the population is under-annuitized, and the limited extent to which people delay benefits claiming is one part of that puzzle. Rather than assuming that the choice of one s claiming date is a purely rational outcomes-based decision, we posit that individuals may be sensitive to the manner in which claiming information is framed. To study this, we have devised an experiment which presents individuals with alternative information formats about how benefits would be adjusted if they were to claim benefits early versus later. These alternative frames are shown to participants in the RAND American Life Panel (ALP), an internet-based survey. 5 Panel participants were randomized into one of 10 groups, and members of each group were presented the same underlying claiming information but in different frames. It is important to emphasize that the underlying financial information provided to participants namely, the monthly benefit they would receive at alternative ages was unaffected by the frame: only how this information was presented was altered. We then asked the participants at what age they would claim benefits given each frame, and we compare results to determine if the frame seems to alter anticipated claiming ages. The first of the ten frames we designed serves as a baseline by depicting the information as neutrally as possible. This frame is similar to the approach currently (since 2008) used by the Social Security Administration in its public information on claiming. The second frame emphasizes a breakeven concept, i.e., it emphasizes the minimum number of years one would need to live, in order for the nominal sum of the incremental monthly payments that arise from 4 The annuity literature is lengthy and rich, beginning with Yaari (1965), including important work by Friedman and Warshawsky (1990) and Eckstein et al (1985) and recently including Davidoff et al. (2005) and Horneff et al. (2007, 2009). 5

6 4 delay to offset the income forgone during the period of delay. This approach essentially frames the decision as a risky gamble while downplaying insurance aspects of the choice. This breakeven approach is consistent with how Social Security field representatives presented this choice to potential claimants for many decades (at least until 2008 when they switched to a more neutral frame). This approach is also widely used in the private sector financial advice and planning industry (c.f., Charles Schwab, 2010; GG&G 2011). The remaining eight frames show respondents combinations of differences along three dimensions: (i) consumption versus investment; (ii) gains versus losses; and (iii) older versus younger reference ages. The first of these is motivated by the work of Brown et al. (2008) where they found important differences in the reported attractiveness of life annuities, depending on whether these were described using consumption language or investment language. The second dimension uses gain versus loss terminology to portray the actuarial adjustment for later versus earlier claiming. The third dimension varies the initial age used to anchor individuals in the presentation. In all frames, respondents are provided with a sliding scale showing monthly benefit amounts at all ages between 62 and 70 (in monthly increments). The individual can use a computer mouse to slide along the scale and watch the benefits change with each claiming age. The initial starting point for the claim age indicator matches the reference age provided in each frame. After viewing a frame, individuals are asked to use the sliding scale to pinpoint the age at which they think they are most likely to claim benefits. (Screen shots of the frames and the slider are presented in Appendix A). We find several important differences across frames. The single largest effect is that using the breakeven analysis leads to substantially earlier expected claiming dates than any of

7 5 the other nine frames. For example, exposure to the breakeven frame leads people to report an expected claiming age that is months earlier (depending on specification) than under the baseline frame. The magnitude of this result is quite large compared to prior estimates of how changes in economic variables influence retirement dates. 6 Smaller, but still significant, differences obtain across other frames. Overall, joint tests indicate that presentation of gains leads to later claiming than losses. We also find evidence of an anchoring effect with regard to age. For example, we find that showing respondents a later age from which they can then evaluate benefit changes tends to have the effect of getting them to claim later. We find that presenting respondents with a consumption gain frame anchored at age 66 yields the highest claiming age, though several others also generate significantly later claiming ages than the neutral frame (e.g. the investment gain frame with anchoring at 66, and both the consumption loss and investment loss frame at 70.) These findings are important for our understanding of economic behavior and also for practical policy purposes. At an academic level, we provide further evidence that even highvisibility, high-stakes financial decisions in this case, when to claim Social Security benefits are sensitive to how the information is presented. One interpretation of our results is that they cast doubt on a simple economic model of fully rational decision-making by showing that individual decisions are influenced by factors other than ultimate consumption outcomes. At a practical policy level, our study indicates that the Social Security Administration (SSA), as well 6 For example, Coronado and Perozek (2003) find that each additional $100,000 of unexpected gains from stocks is associated with retiring only two weeks earlier than expected. Lumsdaine and Mitchell (1999) review the literature on the economic determinants of retirement behavior and conclude that changes in pension and Social Security benefits have small economic impacts on the choice of retirement age, as do Gustman and Steinmeier (2004; 2008). The present analysis focuses on Social Security benefit claiming decisions, as distinct from retirement decisions, and one might expect the claiming elasticity to be larger than the retirement elasticity. A few analysts (Benitez-Silva and Frank, 2008; Honig and Reimers 1996) examine interactions between claiming and work patterns, but they are interested in rewards to continued employment, whereas here we explore determinants of the claiming decision independent of the return-to-work decision.

8 6 as other public or private sector actors, can present information to participants in ways that can strongly influence behavior -- even when the actual information content is unchanged. This is particularly relevant for an agency such as the SSA that prides itself on providing relevant information without providing advice. Our findings suggest that individuals are very likely to adjust their claiming behavior, depending on how the information is presented. In what follows, Section II provides a very brief primer on how Social Security benefit claiming works, including a discussion of the actuarial adjustment process. In Section III, we discuss our research methodology including details about the RAND American Life Panel. In Section IV, we explain the motivation underlying our choice of the 10 frames that we tested. Results are discussed in Section V, and we provide a short conclusion in Section VI. II. Social Security Benefits and Claiming How Social Security benefits are adjusted based on the claiming date A covered worker who has contributed to the Social Security system for sufficiently long (roughly 10 years to be fully insured) 7 confronts a range of choices regarding when he can file for, or claim, his Social Security benefits. Age 62 is the earliest that one can claim as a retired worker, and this is also known as the Early Retirement Age (ERA). The rules also specify a Normal Retirement Age (NRA) 8 at which full or unreduced benefits can be paid. The NRA is currently age 66 (for those born , rising to 67 for people born 1960 and later). 7 Technically, an individual is considered fully insured once he has earned 40 quarters of coverage. In 2010, an individual earns a quarter of coverage up to a maximum of 4 per calendar year for each $1,120 of covered earnings. See for more information. 8 This is also sometimes referred to as the Full Retirement Age (FRA)

9 7 The SSA computes benefits by selecting a worker s highest 35 years of earnings and wage-indexing them so that nominal earnings are adjusted to near-current wage levels. 9 Next, the agency computes the worker s Average Indexed Monthly Earnings (AIME) over the 35-year period by averaging all indexed annual values (including zeros, if any) and dividing by 12. Then the basic benefit or Primary Insurance Amount (PIA) is computed as a nonlinear function of the worker s AIME; this is the base amount from which benefits are calculated. If the worker claims benefits at the NRA, his benefit equals 100% of his PIA. However, if he claims at some younger age, his benefit amount is reduced by 5/9 percent per month for the first 36 months of early benefit receipt and 5/12 percent per month for additional months of early claiming, and the reduction continues for the rest of his life (Frolik and Kaplan, 2010). For instance, at age 62 he would receive a PIA reduced by 25%. 10 Conversely, if he were to leave work but delay claiming beyond the NRA, his benefits are increased by 8% per year of age beyond the NRA for the remainder of his life; this is the Delayed Retirement Credit (DRC). 11 In other words, the age one stops working need not equal the age at which one claims benefits. 12 The intent of the early retirement reduction and delayed retirement credit adjustments is to recognize, on average, early claimants will receive benefits for a longer period than those who delay claiming. These adjustments therefore seek to be roughly actuarially neutral, so that, on average, people who take a lower benefit early would expect to receive about the same total amount in benefits over their lifetimes, compared to those who wait for the higher monthly benefit but start receiving it later. In other words, the choice of claiming age affects the monthly 9 This is computed as the year in which a worker turns age 60; for more information, see 10 Taken from Benefits payable to spouses and survivors are also adjusted based on the covered worker s claiming age, but we abstract from this in the present study (for more discussion see Coile et al and Mahaney and Carlson 2008). 11 In addition, Social Security benefits are annually adjusted for cost-of-living. 12 This difference is widely appreciated; see Greenwald et al. (2010). In practice, the majority of workers (over 90%) claim when first eligible at age 62; see Hurd and Rohwedder (2004) and Coile et al. (2002).

10 8 annuity stream, but for the population on average, it does not alter the expected total lifetime sum of benefits received. Other Factors Influencing the Claiming Decision The prior discussion of the effect of claiming age on benefits, while accurate, is a simplification of the broader claiming decision. In reality, there are a number of complex factors that go into the consideration of an optimal claiming date. In particular, this paper is focused specifically on the claiming decision, rather than the broader impact of benefit amounts on labor force participation. Technically, the claiming decision is fully independent of one s labor force participation status: people need not claim upon leaving the labor force, and they need not leave employment to claim. In practice, of course, there are obvious connections between retirement and Social Security claiming decisions. For example, if individuals continue to work while delaying claiming, their monthly benefit may rise both because of the actuarial adjustment and because of the additional years of earnings potentially increasing their PIAs. Additionally, lowwealth, liquidity-constrained individuals may not have the resources to provide for their consumption after retirement if they do not claim Social Security, and thus the claiming decision may be tightly linked with broader labor force participation considerations. Another reason that labor force participation and claiming are intertwined in practice is the Social Security earnings test. As described by the Social Security Administration, if one continues to work after claiming benefits, and if one is younger than the Normal Retirement Age, $1 in benefits will be deducted for each $2 you earn above the annual limit. 13 Importantly, the reduction in benefits that results from the application of the earnings test is returned to the 13 For 2010, the annual limit is $14,160. In the year one reaches the normal retirement age, the reduction is $1 for every $3 above a higher limit, up until the month one reaches the NRA..

11 9 beneficiary in the form of higher future benefits, although it is unclear how widely this feature is understood by those affected. 14 While each of these factors and others is quite important to consider when evaluating an optimal retirement age, we abstract from these additional considerations in our experimental design. Doing so has a distinct advantage of keeping the experimental frames as clean and simple as possible. Equally importantly, this simplification does not present a problem for our analysis, for reasons that we will describe in more detail in the next section. III. Study Design Focus Groups Prior to launching our quantitative survey, we conducted a large number of focus groups in the Chicago, Los Angeles, Philadelphia, and Washington, D.C. areas. These focus groups served two distinct purposes. The first, and the one most relevant to this paper, is that we used these groups to ensure that the language used in the frames ultimately tested in the online survey (discussed in Section IV below) was clear and salient to the participants. Indeed, the focus groups were quite useful in this regard, and they helped us to develop frames that respondents considered distinct along the margins that we wished to test, while maintaining their symmetry along other dimensions. The second purpose of the focus groups was to gain an understanding of a broader set of issues related to how individuals view the role of Social Security in retirement. 15 The American Life Panel 14 We also abstract from the possibility that an insured individual s claiming decision may affect the after-tax maximum family benefit received by the entire household. 15 While those findings are not discussed in the present paper, interested readers may find a summary of the qualitative findings in Greenwald & Associates (2010a).

12 10 After testing our frames (discussed in more detail in Section IV, below), we fielded a survey through the RAND American Life Panel (ALP). The ALP is a sample of approximately 3,000 households who are regularly interviewed over the Internet. An advantage relative to most other Internet panels is that the ALP is mostly based on a probability sample of the US population. 16 Currently, the panel comprises over 3000 active panel members of whom approximately 5% respond to the questionnaires using a WebTV. 17 Experimental Design The experimental design consists of several separate waves of data collection. We initiated the survey with a pre-wave in June of 2010, in which respondents were asked a single question about when they expected to claim Social Security: 16 ALP respondents have been recruited in one of three ways. Most were recruited from individuals age 18+ who were respondents to the Monthly Survey (MS) of the University of Michigan's Survey Research Center (SRC). The MS is the leading consumer sentiment survey that incorporates the long-standing Survey of Consumer Attitudes and produces, among others, the widely used Index of Consumer Expectations. Each month, the MS interviews approximately 500 households, of which 300 households are a random-digit-dial (RDD) sample and 200 are reinterviewed from the RDD sample surveyed six months previously. Until August 2008, SRC screened MS respondents by asking them if they would be willing to participate in a long term research project (with approximate response categories no, certainly not, probably not, maybe, probably, yes, definitely ). If the response category is not no, certainly not, respondents were told that the University of Michigan is undertaking a joint project with RAND. They were asked if they would object to SRC sharing their information about them with RAND so that they could be contacted later and asked if they would be willing to actually participate in an Internet survey. Respondents who do not have Internet were told that RAND will provide them with free Internet. Many MSrespondents are interviewed twice. At the end of the second interview, an attempt was made to convert respondents who refused in the first round. This attempt includes the mention of the fact that participation in follow-up research carries a reward of $20 for each half-hour interview. A subset of respondents (approximately 500) was recruited through a snowball sample; here respondents were given the opportunity to suggest friends or acquaintances who might also want to participate. Those friends were then contacted and asked if they wanted to participate. A new group of respondents (approximately 500) has recently been recruited after participating in the National Survey Project, created at Stanford University with SRBI. This sample was recruited in person, and at the end of their oneyear participation, they were asked whether they were interested in joining the RAND American Life Panel. Most of these respondents were given a laptop and broadband Internet access. Recently, the American Life Panel has begun recruiting based on a random mail and telephone sample using the Dillman method (see e.g. Dillman et al, 2008) with the goal to achieve 5000 active panel members, including a 1000 Spanish language subsample. If these new participants do not have Internet access yet, they will also be provided with a laptop and broadband Internet access. These panel members are not part of the sample used in this paper. 17 Respondents from the Michigan monthly survey without Internet were provided with so-called WebTVs ( which allows them to access the Internet using their television and a telephone line. The technology allows respondents who lacked Internet access to participate in the panel and furthermore use the WebTVs for browsing the Internet or .

13 11 We would next like to ask you a question about a different topic. As you know, in the United States people can start claiming Social Security benefits between the ages of 62 and 70. At what age would you expect to start collecting these Social Security benefits? This question was asked to provide a baseline which we could then compare against responses to future frames, and also to help us evaluate whether our frame randomization which occurred thereafter was not biased with regard to the outcome of interest. 18 As is described in detail in Section IV below, we test 10 different question frames. In three waves spaced at least two weeks apart, respondents are shown six different frames (two distinct frames per wave). These frames are randomly assigned in the following way: for each respondent we drew six numbers randomly without replacement from the set {1,2, 10}. These numbers determined which frames were shown to each respondent and in which order. For example, if we drew the vector (5, 7, 3, 9, 10, 6) for a given respondent, then that respondent is shown frames 5 and 7 in the first wave, frames 3 and 9 in the second wave, and frames 10 and 6 in the third wave. The frames are only shown to respondents who had not already claimed a benefit and who have worked at least 10 years (so that we can compute a projected Social Security benefit). Our outcome of interest is the respondent s intended claiming age. This raises a natural question of whether expectations about claiming are correlated with subsequent claiming behavior. Evidence from the Health and Retirement Survey (HRS) suggests that this is, indeed, the case: for many years the HRS has asked respondents about each person s expected claiming age every wave, making it possible to correlate these responses with ultimate claiming behavior. For HRS respondents age 62-70, we calculate the simple correlation between an indicator of 18 While most respondents (95%) provided an answer in the age range, some did not. When respondents did not answer in this age range, a follow-up question asked why not. Responses outside the interval were often given by younger respondents who believe that, by the time they will be eligible, the Social Security claiming age will have moved to higher ages, or they believe they will not receive any Social Security benefit at all and express this by responding outside the range.

14 12 whether the individual is receiving benefits in a given wave, and an indicator for whether the individual predicted that that he or she would be claiming benefits by this wave, based on interview responses in prior waves. These two variables are strongly and positively correlated, with coefficients ranging from 0.46 in wave 1 to over 0.6 in waves 6-7. Linear probability models of benefit receipt in wave 8 on predictions of prior waves have an R-squared of about IV. The Frames In what follows, we explain the rationale for the choice of our experimental frames, as well as our expectations about how alternative framing would affect the claiming decision. (The actual text of frames tested appears in Appendix A.) Our baseline case is intended to be an approximation of Social Security s current neutral stance on claiming ages. This is differentiated from what we call here the breakeven approach, which was used by SSA for many decades and which continues to be used by many financial advisors in the private sector. Next we discuss the three dimensions along which we vary our experimental frames, including: (i) the use of consumption language versus investment language, (ii) framing actuarial adjustments for earlier and later claiming as gains versus losses, and (iii) the use of alternative anchoring ages (including ages 62, 66 and 70). a. Baseline Case: Symmetric Treatment of Gains and Losses (Anchored at Age 66) Our baseline case is modeled on the Social Security Administration s current approach (in use since 2008) to discussing claiming ages (although we have simplified and shortened the presentation considerably for survey purposes). In essence, this approach seeks to simply and clearly lay out the facts in a neutral manner, with a symmetric treatment of earlier and later 19 Further results available on request to the authors.

15 13 claiming. This approach is consistent with the SSA s emphasis on providing information but not advice to participants, in that it seeks to avoid biasing individuals in any particular direction. Rather, it simply states the impact on benefits of claiming at various ages. Because this frame is intended to be neutral, and because it reflects the current public perspective of SSA on claiming ages, we use this frame as the baseline against which other frames are compared. b. Breakeven Analysis (Anchored at Age 62) Previous to 2008, one of the tools used by the SSA when providing information on the impact of claiming at various ages was to use a so-called breakeven analysis. Under this approach, individuals were told what their benefits would be if they claimed at an early age such as 62, versus at some later age, such as 63. They were then informed that, by delaying claiming from 62 to 63, they would forfeit a year of benefits. 20 In return for the deferral, they would receive a higher monthly benefit from age 63 on. But the breakeven presentation emphasized that people would not come out ahead unless they lived until at least to age X, where X was defined as the age at which the cumulative benefit payment amounts were equal. This approach combines some elements of both the negative annuity framing explored by Agnew et al. (2008) and the investment frame explored by Brown et al. (2008), both of which have been shown to reduce the perceived desirability of annuitization. While this breakeven analysis may have been instructive to many, it is also true that the framing of this approach implicitly places zero value on the insurance aspect of delaying 20 SSA field offices have long been equipped with a software program that claims representatives can use to compute breakeven dates for individuals who inquired about how benefits changed with the claiming date (known by SSA as month of election, or MOEL). Numerous conversations we have held with SSA field office representatives suggest that this breakeven analysis was widely used prior to Indeed, the use of the breakeven analysis was codified in the training manuals for employees: as recently as 2007, the training manual for Title II Claims Representatives (i.e., SSA employees who help citizens claim benefits, among other responsibilities) included a discussion of documentation required for Month of Election cases. It states if the claimant chooses the later of the two possible MOELs, he will forfeit the benefits he could have received with the earlier MOEL (emphasis added).

16 14 claiming. In essence, it provides a simplistic financial calculation which emphasizes that later claimers would be behind, until they reach a far distant breakeven date. As a result, this approach places little emphasis on the additional value that individuals who defer could receive for the rest of their lives beyond the breakeven date. This practice is akin to considering only the actuarial aspect of the decision, without taking into account the broader utility rewards of an annuity, which arise from risk aversion and protection against longevity risk. Indeed, in direct contrast to highlighting the insurance aspects of Social Security, this approach frames the decision to delay claiming more as a gamble, the outcome of which depends upon when one dies. It is worth noting that this breakeven approach is not unique to the Social Security Administration; in fact a widely referenced article by the Schwab Center for Financial Research (2010) 21 also discusses the claiming decision using a breakeven analysis. Our hypothesis is that this breakeven approach is likely to bias individuals toward claiming benefits earlier, than would a more neutrally worded frame. c. Consumption versus Investment As noted earlier, a prior study by Brown et al. (2008) showed that how individuals view the value of life annuities relative to other financial products depends on whether annuities are presented in a consumption frame or an investment frame. That is, when consumers are conditioned to think in terms of investments (e.g., when the presentation uses investment terminology such as invest and return ), the life annuities are made to appear unattractive. This is because life annuities are then perceived as paying low returns, being illiquid, and possibly even seeming risky (because the amount an annuitant gets back depends on how long 21 For further information see uld_you_take_social_security.html

17 15 he lives). By contrast, in a consumption frame (e.g., a frame that emphasizes one s ability to consume throughout life), a life annuity tends to be viewed as a very attractive form of protection against running out of money. While Brown et al. (2008) found powerful effects of framing on the attractiveness of life annuities relative to non-annuitized products, that analysis did not provide evidence on whether these alternative frames also have an effect on the desirability of earlier versus later annuitization. But given the magnitude of the effects they found (roughly 70% of respondents preferring a life annuity to a savings account in a consumption frame, versus about 20% in an investment frame), this distinction is potentially quite important to the Social Security claiming context. It is worth noting that the breakeven frame is itself a quite negative form of an investment frame, one that emphasizes the risk of not living long enough to recoup the foregone benefits. The investment language used in these additional frames focuses on returns, without explicitly pointing out the risk of not breaking even. This will allow us to determine whether it is the breakeven analysis per se, or the investment-oriented language more generally, that influences claiming behavior. d. Gains versus Losses The asymmetry in how individuals treat gains versus losses is one of the best-known results (at least among economists) from the psychology literature on choice. Most prominently, Kahneman and Tversky (1981) found that individuals exhibited an asymmetry between gains and losses. Specifically, they found in a situation of choice under uncertainty that people sometimes exhibit a preference for a certain gain of $ p* X to an uncertain gain of $X with probability p, while at the same time preferring an uncertain loss of $X with probability p, to a certain loss of $ p* X.

18 16 Relating this to the context of benefit claiming, it is possible to express actuarial adjustments in terms of a gain (e.g., delaying claiming by one year will increase your benefit by $X per month) or a loss (e.g., claiming one year earlier will reduce your benefit by $X per month). Accordingly, we expect that this gain/loss distinction may have important interactions with the consumption/investment distinction. As noted by Brown et al. (2008), additional annuitization may look very attractive in a consumption frame, while it may look less attractive in an investment frame. It is also, therefore, possible that gains and losses will be interpreted differently in each of these contexts. e. Age Anchors As discussed at length by Mussweiler et al. (2004), anchoring effects pervade a variety of judgments, from the trivial (i.e., estimates of the mean temperature in Antarctica) to the apocalyptic (i.e., estimates of the likelihood of nuclear war) In particular, they have been observed in a broad array of different judgmental domains, such as general-knowledge questions, price estimates, estimates of self-efficacy, probability assessments, evaluations of lotteries and gambles, legal judgment, and negotiation. 22 In our context, a very natural and salient anchoring point is the age that is first presented in each frame. Given that we are exploring both gains and losses, some variation in anchoring ages is useful. For example, while one can easily discuss gains in a frame anchored at age 62, it is not possible to anchor a loss frame at 62 because 62 is the earliest claiming age, and thus there is no way to characterize a loss from claiming earlier than this. Similarly, it is easy to anchor losses at age 70 (the maximum claiming age), but not gains. For this reason, in the experimental treatments that we describe next, the gain frames are 22 We have excluded the references included in the original quote. For these, as well as a full description of findings, see:

19 17 anchored at 62, and the loss frames at 70. In order to distinguish the gain/loss hypothesis from age anchoring, we also include both gain and loss frames that are anchored at age 66. f. The Ten Different Frames Putting these various permutations together results in 10 distinct frames, described more completely in the Appendix. Below we refer to these frames as follows: (i) Baseline (neutral) (ii) Breakeven (iii) Consumption Gain from Age 62 (iv) Consumption Gain from Age 66 (v) Consumption Loss from Age 66 (vi) Consumption Loss from Age 70 (vii) Investment Gain from Age 62 (viii) Investment Gain from Age 66 (ix) Investment Loss from Age 66 (x) Investment Loss from Age 70 g. How our Experimental Design Handles Complexity and Heterogeneity As discussed above, there will be heterogeneity in the optimal claiming date based on differences in economic situations as well as preferences. Heterogeneity also results from the numerous real-life complicating factors that would rationally influence the choice of an optimal claiming date, including labor force participation issues, the earnings test, and spousal or child benefits. Fortunately, our experimental design does not require that we know the optimal claiming date for any individual. Furthermore, our design allows us to dramatically simplify the scenarios that individuals face, including focusing on a single individual and avoiding a discussion of the earnings test. There are three reasons that our design does not require that we specific all relevant information. First, our experimental design is premised on the idea that if an individual is making a rational optimizing decision, that optimal decision will be based on how (possibly

20 18 unobservable) factors important to that individual map into utility outcomes. Because our framing experiment holds the relevant outcomes fixed in all cases, and only changes the way the claiming process is framed, optimizing individuals would be insensitive to frame changes. While the omission of a discussion of the earnings test, for example, might lead to answers that differ from those that the respondent would give if such information was provided, it is important to emphasize that the same information is provided or omitted in all frames, and we are examining differences across frames in how the same information is presented. Second, we randomize individuals into the ten treatment groups. Thus, there are no concerns about self-selection based on differences in the salience of the complicating factors that we have simplified away. Third, because we expose individuals to multiple frames, we are able to conduct some analyses including individual fixed effects, meaning that we are implicitly controlling for all unobservable differences across individuals. In essence, our identifying assumption is that any biases introduced into the expected claiming age by our omission of some factors are independent of how the information that we are providing is framed. V. Results Table 1 presents descriptive statistics for the ALP sample used in the experiment; we also provide average expected claiming ages reported by respondents about six weeks before the start of the experiment (the June 2010 question discussed in Section III). Here and in the remainder of the paper, claiming ages are expressed in terms of the number of months after the date when

21 19 the respondent turns 62. Thus for example a claiming age of 36 means age 65 and zero months (which is 36 months after one s 62 nd birthday.) Table 1 here A few points are worth noting from the third column of Table 1. First, women indicate that they plan to claim Social Security benefits about four months later than men. Planned claiming ages also rise with education and income: in both cases, those in the highest category say they intend to claim benefits about months later than the lowest category. Planned claiming ages are also slightly later for younger respondents. Thus those younger than age 50 say they plan to claim about two to four months later than respondents over age 55. This is likely an underestimate of the population difference, since our sample is restricted to individuals not yet retired (so anyone over 55 who self-described himself as retired is not included). These summary statistics are offered for general interest, though it is worth noting that, because we randomize exposure to the frames, we would not anticipate that these baseline differences will have any impact on results across frames. Further, in specifications that include individual fixed effects, these differences will be directly controlled. Figure 1 shows average expected claiming ages arrayed by frame across the six presentations. One can see quite clearly that the breakeven frame yields by far the earliest intended claiming age. There is also a suggestion of a difference between gain and loss frames, where the gain frames yield a somewhat later claiming age than the loss frames. Below we verify these results using multivariate regression models. Figure 1 here Table 2 presents average claiming ages for the various frames administered to the ALP broken down by treatment, and Figure 2 shows the same information in the form of a bar chart.

22 20 Once again, the breakeven frame generates by far the lowest claiming age. For example, in wave 1.1 (the first treatment in the first wave), the breakeven frame generates a claiming age that is between 22 and 26 months earlier than the claiming age generated by the frames that take 66 as an anchoring age. Table 2 and Figure 2 here We are aware that there could be some spillover from the first to the second treatment within a wave. That is, when reading the second frame presented in a wave, the respondent might remember what he answered when shown the first frame, and possibly even offer the exact same age. Our data do indeed reveal many instances where respondents first and second answers within a wave are identical. Below we analyze this pattern more formally. Spillovers help explain for instance why the claiming age associated with the breakeven frame is higher in 1.2 (wave 1, exposure 2), 2.2 and 3.2 than in 1.1, 2.1 and 3.1, respectively. Table 3 and Figures 3-6 report intended claiming ages (now averaged across all waves) by frame and demographics and show that there are some differences (below we test for significance more formally). Women tend to be somewhat more responsive to the difference between gain frames and loss frames than men, deferring intended claiming ages more when benefit enhancements are emphasized. Younger people and less educated individuals appear to be more responsive to framing than older people and respondents with a college degree. The last column in Table 3 shows the variance of the average claiming ages across the ten frames, which we interpret as a measure of how sensitive respondents are to the different frames. The variance proves to be considerably larger for less-educated respondents than for respondents with a college degree, suggesting that respondents with less education are more susceptible to framing effects. The age pattern is not quite monotonic, but it does suggest more susceptibility to framing among the young versus the older respondents.

23 21 Table 3 and Figures 3-6 here It is useful to summarize these differences using multivariate regression analyses, with results appearing in Table 4. In all five columns, the dependent variable is the number of months after age 62 that the respondent indicates he intends to claim his Social Security benefits. The first three columns of Table 4 present results from regression analyses pertaining to the first wave. In the first two columns, we regress the number of months a respondent indicates he will claim post-62 on nine treatment dummies, one for each frame, with the omitted category being the baseline frame (which uses an anchoring age of 66 and describes the effects of changing claiming ages in symmetric terms). In the first column, the dependent variable is the answer to the first frame in the first wave (i.e. wave 1.1), while in the second column, the dependent variable is the response to the second frame in the wave (wave 1.2). As noted before, it is possible that responses to the second frame in a given wave could be influenced by responses to the first frame, so in the third column of Table 4, we use as the dependent variable the answer to the second frame exposure and also control for which frame the respondent saw in the first frame. These lagged dummy variables are statistically significant (p=.02) though a comparison of the second and third columns suggests that the estimates of the treatment effects are not much affected. Table 4 here When combining results across waves, it is important to account for correlations across observations that refer to the same respondents. A natural solution is to include individual fixed effects, and results are given in columns 4 and 5 of Table 4. Accordingly, column 4 combines the results of all six waves, while column 5 once again includes dummies for preceding treatments for waves 1.2, 2.2, and 3.2. That is, when the dependent variable refers to wave 1.2,

24 22 the treatment in wave 1.1 is included as an extra explanatory variable; similarly for wave 2.2, the treatment in 2.1 is included as an explanatory variable, and similarly for waves 3.2 and The finding of most interest in Table 4 is that several of the treatment frame coefficients differ significantly from that of the neutral frame where the anchoring age is 66. The models confirm that the breakeven SSA frame leads to substantially earlier claiming: compared to the neutral frame, the breakeven frame appears to induce claiming around 15 months earlier. This is an enormous impact, one that should be of substantial interest to policymakers who seek to offer the best unbiased advice possible to the working public. It appears that the gain frame with anchoring at 66 yields the highest claiming age, though several others also generate significantly later claiming ages than the neutral frame specifically the loss frames with anchoring at 70. We also note that the gain frames appear to lead to later claiming than do loss frames. The difference between the gain frames at 66 and the loss frames at 66 is statistically significant (p=.01). An alternative way to disentangle the effects of anchoring ages, gain vs. loss, and consumption vs. investment, is provided in Table 5. Here we present the results of a fixed-effect analysis with the control variables now redefined to represent framing dimensions (e.g., gain versus loss, or anchoring ages) rather than individual frames. As before, the second column regression includes dummies for the preceding treatments when the dependent variable refers to waves 1.2 and The joint tests reported in Table 5 show that the gain and loss frames have different effects, depending on when an individual first says he is intending to claim. That is, gain frames lead to later claiming ages than loss frames. The null hypothesis that consumption 23 The coefficients on these lagged treatments are not reported, but they operate in the expected direction and are highly significant (p=.00). 24 These lagged treatment effects are highly significant (p=.00), although the estimates in which we are most interested are very similar with or without them.

25 23 and investment frames have equal effects cannot be rejected. Anchoring ages 66 and 70 are both associated with significantly later claiming ages, compared to anchoring at age 62. The difference between 66 and 70 is not significantly different from zero, however. Table 5 here Two additional tables permit us to test whether sub-groups of people respond differently to the manner in which benefits claiming is framed. Table 6 provides one approach, wherein we adopt the same fixed-effects model as in Table 5 but also add four additional variables, namely interaction terms between the breakeven frame and sex, the individual s predicted benefit level if he claimed at age 62, a third variable indicating whether a respondent reports having credit card debt, and a fourth variable which is a measure of financial literacy. Since the neutral frame is the reference category, one may interpret the coefficient on the interaction variables as the effect of the factor on the difference between the neutral frame and the breakeven frame. Table 6 here In the first column, we see that compared to men, women are prompted to claim six months earlier when they see the breakeven frame versus the neutral frame, and the effect is statistically significant. (It will be recalled that these are fixed-effects estimates, so individualspecific factors are differenced out.) The second column shows the impact of interacting respondents anticipated monthly Social Security benefits at age 62 (the mean of that variable is $1,275). The statistically significant estimate implies that if the monthly benefit level were to rise from $1,275 to $2,275, this would narrow the gap between the neutral and the breakeven frame by 8 months. The third column shows that individuals with credit card debt are significantly more sensitive to the difference in framing between neutral and breakeven (the difference widens by about 4.5 months). One possible interpretation of this is that individuals with credit card debt

26 24 find financial management more challenging, and are thus more affected by framing. Finally, in the fourth column we show the interaction between the financial literacy measure and the breakeven frame. The financial literacy variable simply counts the number of correct answers to a sequence of 17 financial literacy questions. 25 The interaction is not statistically significant, although potentially of quantitative significance. For instance if a respondent moves from 50% correct to 100% correct, the gap between the neutral frame and breakeven narrows by 7.25 months. (The mean percent correct is 68 in the sample). Finally, Table 7 offers a more complex set of additional interaction terms, again using a fixed-effects framework obviating the need for non-time-varying controls. Multicollinearity results from including such a large set of interactions, though the joint test of the interaction terms reported at the bottom of the table indicates that the significant differences persist by age and sex (at least at the 10% level), even in this more complex case. And the anchoring age interactions are also quite significant. Table 7 here VI. Conclusions We draw two primary conclusions, one of them of interest to academics, and the other of practical interest to policymakers and financial advisers. The academic conclusion is that individuals appear to be behaving in a manner that is inconsistent with purely rational economic optimizing behavior. Were individuals focusing solely on consumption outcomes as standard life-cycle models posit, then such decisions would be unaffected by how information is framed. 25 The 17 questions measure knowledge in five domains: compound interest (4 questions), inflation (2 questions), risk diversification (3 questions), tax treatment of DC savings (4 questions), and employer matches of DC contributions (4 questions).

27 25 Instead, our evidence strongly suggests that how the claiming information is framed has a substantial influence on expected claiming behavior. The practical lesson to draw from these findings is that the manner in which information is provided to plan participants can shape behavior. Indeed this research suggests that Social Security s historical emphasis on breakeven analysis may have inadvertently encouraged several generations of American workers to claim benefits earlier than they would have otherwise, had the information been presented in a different frame. It is especially important to understand these effects because unlike the benefit rules themselves the framing of information is under the control of the SSA staff and administration, rather than something requiring Congressional legislation to alter. While we have provided evidence from the HRS that expected claiming ages are correlated with actual claiming ages in later waves, we nonetheless recognize that one would ideally study the effects of framing on actual claiming behavior. In principle, it is possible to experimentally test the impact of framing on actual claiming decisions, especially now that many retirement benefit claims are processed using internet-based on-line claiming. Such real world experiments might be a promising avenue for future analysis.

28 26 References Agnew, Julie, Lisa Anderson, Jeff Gerlach, and Lisa Szykman. (2008). Who Chooses Annuities? An Experimental Investigation of Gender, Framing and Defaults. The American Economic Review, 98 (2): Andreoni, James. (1995). Warm-Glow Versus Cold-Prickle: The Effects of Positive and Negative Framing on Cooperation in Experiments. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(1): Au, Andrew, Olivia S. Mitchell, and John W.R. Phillips. (2005). Saving Shortfalls and Delayed Retirement. MRRC Working Paper Bateman, Ian, Alistair Munro, Bruce Rhodes, Chris Starmer, Robert Sugden. (1997). A Test of the Theory of Reference-Dependent Preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2): Benitez-Silva, Hugo, and Frank Heiland "Early Claiming of Social Security Benefits and Labour Supply Behaviour of Older Americans." Applied Economics. 40:23. Brown, J., J. Kling, S. Mullainathan, and M. Wrobel. (2008). Why Don't People Insure Late Life Consumption? A Framing Explanation of the Under-Annuitization Puzzle. The American Economic Review, 98: Brown, Jeffrey, Olivia S. Mitchell, and James Poterba. (2002). The Role of Real Annuities and Indexed Bonds in an Individual Accounts Retirement Program. In Innovations in Financing Retirement., eds. Z. Bodie, B. Hammond, and O. S. Mitchell. Philadelphia, PA: Univ. of Pennsylvania Press: Coile, Courtney C., Peter Diamond, Jonathan Gruber, and Alain Jousten. (2002) Delays in Claiming Social Security Benefits. Journal of Public Economics 84(3): Coronado, Julia L. and Maria G. Perozek. (2003). Wealth Effects and the Consumption of Leisure: Retirement Decisions During the Stock Market Boom of the 1990s. FEDS Working Paper No , May. Available at SSRN: or doi: /ssrn Davidoff, Tom, Jeffrey Brown, and Peter Diamond. (2005). Annuities and Individual Welfare. American Economic Review, 95: Dillman, D.A., J.D Smyth, and L.M. Christian. (2008). Internet, Mail, and Mixed-Mode Surveys: The Tailored Design Method, 3 rd edition. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley. Eckstein, Zvi, Martin S. Eichenbaum, Dan Peled. (1985). The Distribution of Wealth and Welfare in the Presence of Incomplete Annuity Markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics 100(3):

29 27 Friedman, Benjamin, and Mark Warshawsky (1990). The Cost of Annuities: Implications for Saving Behavior and Bequests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(1): Frolik, Lawrence A. and Richard L. Kaplan. (2010) Elder Law in a Nutshell. 5 th edition. St Paul, MN: West Publishing. p Gray, Gray & Gray (GG&G) (2011). The Effect of When you Start Collecting Social Security. Greenwald, Mathew & Associates. (2010a). Claiming Social Security Benefits and Understanding Peer Effects: A Summary Report of Ten Focus Groups. RAND Report to the SSA for the Financial Literacy Center, September. Greenwald, Mathew, Arie Kapteyn, Olivia S. Mitchell, and Lisa Schneider. (2010b). What Do People Know about Social Security? RAND Report to the FLC/SSA, September. Gustman, Alan and Thomas L Steinmeier. (2004). The Social Security Retirement Earnings Test, Retirement, and Benefit Claiming. NBER Working Paper 10905, November. Gustman, Alan and Thomas L. Steinmeier. (2008). How Changes in Social Security Affect Retirement Trends. NBER Working Paper Horneff, Wolfram, Raimond Maurer, Olivia S. Mitchell, and Ivica Dus. (2007). Following the Rules: Integrating Asset Allocation and Annuitization in Retirement Portfolios. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics. 42: Horneff, Wolfram, Raimond Maurer, Olivia S. Mitchell, and Michael Stamos. (2009). Asset Allocation and Location over the Life Cycle with Survival-Contingent Payouts. Journal of Banking and Finance, (33)9, September: Hurd, Michael, James P. Smith, Julie M. Zissimopoulos. (2004). The Effects of Subjective Survival on Retirement and Social Security Claiming. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 19(6): Kahneman, Daniel, and Amos Tversky. (1981). The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice. Science, 211(4481), January 30: Lumsdaine, Robin and Olivia S. Mitchell. (1999). New Developments in the Economics of Retirement. In Handbook of Labor Economics, eds. Orley Ashenfelter & David Card. Amsterdam: North Holland: Madrian, Brigitte and Dennis F. Shea (2001). The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) Participation and Savings Behavior. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(4):

30 28 Mahaney, James I. and Peter C. Carlson. (2008). Rethinking Social Security Claiming in a 401(k) World. In Recalibrating Retirement Spending and Saving, eds. J. Ameriks & O.S. Mitchell. Oxford: Oxford University Press: Mitchell, Olivia S., James Poterba, Mark Warshawsky, and Jeffrey Brown. (1999). New Evidence on the Money s Worth of Individual Annuities. American Economic Review, December: Mussweiler, Thomas, Birte Englich, and Fritz Strack. (2004) Anchoring Effect. In Cognitive Illusions - A Handbook on Fallacies and Biases in Thinking, Judgment, and Memory, ed. R. Pohl. London: Psychology Press: Reimers, Cordelia, and Marjorie Honig Responses to Social Security by Men and Women: Myopic and Far-Sighted Behavior. Journal of Human Resources, 31-2: Shafir, Eldar, Peter Diamond and Amos Tversky. (1997). Money Illusion. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 112(2): Yaari, Menachim. (1965). Uncertain Lifetime, Life Insurance, and the Theory of the Consumer. Review of Economic Studies, 32:

31 29 Table 1. Descriptive Statistics on the ALP Sample Frequency Percentage Mean Claiming Age GENDER (months>62) 1 Male Female AGE > EDUCATION HS or less Some college/ associate degree College degree HH INCOME < > Note: Table contains demographics for respondents to Wave 1. Mean claiming ages are based on slightly fewer observations, due to missing claiming ages. Means are weighted Table 2. Expected Claiming Ages by Frame and Wave Frame Wave 1.1 Wave 1.2 Wave 2.1Wave 2.2 Wave 3.1 Wave 3.2 Breakeven neutral, c , gain, c , gain, c , loss, c , loss, c , gain, i , gain, i , loss, i , loss, i Notes: Ages are expressed in months past age 62. frames; gain or loss indicate if loss or gain frames were used; c indicates a consumption frame, while i indicates an investment fram

32 30 Table 3. Expected Claiming Ages by Frame and Respondent Characteristics Note: Expressed as number of months after age 62, unweighted data. See Table 2 for additional definitions. 66 neutral, cons 62, gain, cons FRAME 66, gain, cons 70, loss, cons 66, loss, cons 62, gain, inv 66, gain, inv Breakeven Variance GENDER Male Female AGE GROUP > EDUCATION HS or less Some college/ associate degree College degree HH INCOME < > OVERALL Average Standard Deviation Frequency , loss, inv 66, loss, inv

33 31 Table 4. Framing Regressions: Dependent Variable is Expected Claiming Age Note: Dependent variable is expressed as number of months after age 62, unweighted data. Reference frame is Age 66, neutral (see text). Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses; * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%. See Table 2 and text for additional definitions. FRAME Wave 1.1 Wave 1.2 Wave 1.2, lagged dummies included All waves, fixed effects All waves, fixed effects, lagged dummies included Breakeven (4.29)** (2.62)** (2.79)** (16.03)** (16.21)** 62_gain_c (1.19) (2.26)* (2.43)* (1.12) (1.09) 66_gain_c (2.44)* (1.60) (1.82) (3.88)** (4.13)** 70_loss_c (0.78) (0.02) (0.16) (2.81)** (2.98)** 66_loss_c (3.03)** (1.09) (1.37) (1.35) (1.70) 62_gain_i (1.11) (1.63) (1.73) (0.38) (0.48) 66_gain_i (2.47)* (1.26) (1.41) (3.50)** (3.80)** 70-loss-i (0.79) (0.09) (0.45) (1.98)* (2.35)* 66-loss-i (2.12)* (1.04) (1.20) (1.10) (1.33) Constant (22.22)** (22.34)** (14.18)** (85.40)** (81.98)** Observations R-squared p gain at cons=inv p gain at cons=inv p loss at cons=inv p loss at cons=inv p cons at gain=loss p inv at gain=loss p joint cons=inv p joint gain=loss Number of id p previous dummies zero

34 32 Table 5. Framing contrasts (Fixed Effect Models, All Waves: Dependent Variable is Expected Claiming Age) Note: Dependent variable measured in number of months after age 62, unweighted data. Reference frame is Age 66, neutral (see text). Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses; * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%. See Table 2 for additional definitions. Table 5: Framing contrasts, fixed effects, all waves All waves All waves, lagged dummies included Breakeven (10.94)** (10.90)** cons_loss (1.59) (1.87) cons_gain (4.23)** (4.47)** inv_loss (1.03) (1.35) inv_gain (3.64)** (3.98)** anchor_ (4.30)** (4.65)** anchor_ (1.70) (1.67) Constant (85.41)** (82.04)** Observations Number of id R-squared p cons_loss=gain p inv_loss=gain p gain_cons=inv p loss_cons=inv p anchor62= p joint gain=loss p joint cons=inv p previous dummies zero 0.00

35 Table 6. Fixed Effect Models With Interactions, All Waves: Dependent Variable is Expected Claiming Age Note: Dependent variable measured in number of months after age 62, unweighted data. Reference frame is Age 66, neutral (see text). Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses; * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%. See Table 2 for additional definitions. FRAME (1) (2) (3) (4) Breakeven (6.79)** (7.60)** (7.78)** (5.70)** Loss_c (1.59) (1.57) (1.58) (1.19) Gain_c (4.23)** (4.21)** (4.23)** (3.91)** Loss_i (1.03) (1.02) (1.01) (0.97) Gain_i (3.65)** (3.62)** (3.65)** (3.33)** anchor_ (4.28)** (4.28)** (4.32)** (4.13)** anchor_ (1.71) (1.72) (1.71) (1.62) Female* breakeven (4.08)** Benefit62* Breakeven (3.70)** Cred. card debt* Breakeven (3.10)** Fin. literacy* Breakeven (1.50) Constant (85.52)** (85.52)** (85.48)** (81.57)** Observations Number of id R-squared

36 Table 7. Fixed Effect Models With Interactions, All Waves: Dependent Variable is Expected Claiming Age Note: Dependent variable measured in number of months after age 62, unweighted data. Reference frame is Age 66, neutral (see text).absolute value of t statistics in parentheses; * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%. See Table 2 for additional definitions. (1) (2) Breakeven (10.94)** (3.28)** Loss_c (1.59) (1.36) Gain_c (4.23)** (0.04) Loss_i (1.03) (1.60) Gain_i (3.64)** (0.52) anchor_ (4.30)** (2.42)* anchor_ (1.70) (0.30) Female*Breakeven (2.41)* Female*Loss_c (0.26) female*gain_c (0.29) female*loss_i (1.43) female*gain_i (0.55) Female*anchor_ (0.58) Female*anchor_ (0.47) agecat2*breakeven (1.04) agecat2*loss_c (0.13) agecat2*gain_c (0.02) agecat2*loss_i (0.09) agecat2*gain_i (0.06) agecat2*anchor_ (1.70) agecat2*anchor_ (0.23) agecat3*breakeven (0.70) agecat3*loss_c (0.20) agecat3*gain_c

37 (0.07) agecat3*loss_i (0.47) agecat3*gain_i (0.53) agecat3*anchor_ (0.83) agecat3*anchor_ (0.60) agecat4*breakeven (1.81) agecat4*loss_c (0.66) agecat4*gain_c (0.38) agecat4*loss_i (0.44) agecat4*gain_i (0.30) agecat4*anchor_ (1.23) agecat4*anchor_ (0.65) Constant (85.41)** (25.55)** Observations Number of id R-squared p Loss_c=gain 0.00 p Loss_i=gain p Gain_c=inv p Loss_c=inv p anchor62= p joint gain=loss p joint cons=inv p income interactions p education interactions p age interactions p sex interactions p anchor66= Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1% 35

38 Months After Age 62 Months after Age 62 Figure 1. Average Expected Claiming Ages by Frame Note: Expressed as number of months after age 62, unweighted Average Figure 2. Average Expected Claiming Ages by Frame and Wave Note: Expressed as number of months after age 62, unweighted Wave 1.1 Wave 1.2 Wave 2.1 Wave 2.2 Wave 3.1 Wave 3.2.

39 Months After Age 62 Months After Age Figure 3. Expected Claiming Ages by Frame and Respondent Sex Note: Expressed as number of months after age 62, unweighted Male Female Figure 4. Expected Claiming Ages by Frame and Respondent Age Note: Expressed as number of months after age 62, unweighted >55

40 Months After Age 62 Months After Age Figure 5. Expected Claiming Ages by Frame and Education (unweighted) Note: Expressed as number of months after age 62, unweighted HS or less Some college/ associate degree College degree Figure 6. Expected Claiming Ages by Frame and Respondent Income ($) Note: Expressed as number of months after age 62, unweighted < >75000

41 39 Appendix A: The Ten Frames Frame 1: Baseline (Neutral)

42 Frame 2: Breakeven 40

43 Frame 3: 62, gain, consumption 41

44 Frame 4: 66, gain, consumption 42

45 Frame 5: 70, loss, consumption 43

46 Frame 6: 66, loss, consumption 44

47 Frame 7: 62, gain, investment 45

48 Frame 8: 66, gain, investment 46

49 Frame 9: 70, loss, investment 47

50 Frame 10: 66, loss, investment 48

Framing Effects and Expected Social Security Claiming Behavior

Framing Effects and Expected Social Security Claiming Behavior Framing Effects and Expected Social Security Claiming Behavior Jeffrey R. Brown, Arie Kapteyn, and Olivia S. Mitchell November 2010 PRC WP2010-42 Pension Research Council Working Paper Pension Research

More information

Are the American Future Elderly Prepared?

Are the American Future Elderly Prepared? Are the American Future Elderly Prepared? Arie Kapteyn Center for Economic and Social Research, University of Southern California Based on joint work with Jeff Brown, Leandro Carvalho, Erzo Luttmer, Olivia

More information

Americans Willingness to Voluntarily Delay Retirement

Americans Willingness to Voluntarily Delay Retirement Americans Willingness to Voluntarily Delay Retirement Raimond H. Maurer Olivia S. Mitchell The Wharton School MRRC Tatjana Schimetschek Ralph Rogalla Prepared for the 16 th Annual Joint Meeting of the

More information

Cognitive Constraints on Valuing Annuities. Jeffrey R. Brown Arie Kapteyn Erzo F.P. Luttmer Olivia S. Mitchell

Cognitive Constraints on Valuing Annuities. Jeffrey R. Brown Arie Kapteyn Erzo F.P. Luttmer Olivia S. Mitchell Cognitive Constraints on Valuing Annuities Jeffrey R. Brown Arie Kapteyn Erzo F.P. Luttmer Olivia S. Mitchell Under a wide range of assumptions people should annuitize to guard against length-of-life uncertainty

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DECISION TO DELAY SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS: THEORY AND EVIDENCE. John B. Shoven Sita Nataraj Slavov

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DECISION TO DELAY SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS: THEORY AND EVIDENCE. John B. Shoven Sita Nataraj Slavov NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DECISION TO DELAY SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS: THEORY AND EVIDENCE John B. Shoven Sita Nataraj Slavov Working Paper 17866 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17866 NATIONAL BUREAU OF

More information

Future Beneficiary Expectations of the Returns to Delayed Social Security Benefit Claiming and Choice Behavior

Future Beneficiary Expectations of the Returns to Delayed Social Security Benefit Claiming and Choice Behavior Future Beneficiary Expectations of the Returns to Delayed Social Security Benefit Claiming and Choice Behavior Jeff Dominitz Angela Hung Arthur van Soest RAND Preliminary and Incomplete Draft Updated for

More information

IMPACT OF THE SOCIAL SECURITY RETIREMENT EARNINGS TEST ON YEAR-OLDS

IMPACT OF THE SOCIAL SECURITY RETIREMENT EARNINGS TEST ON YEAR-OLDS #2003-15 December 2003 IMPACT OF THE SOCIAL SECURITY RETIREMENT EARNINGS TEST ON 62-64-YEAR-OLDS Caroline Ratcliffe Jillian Berk Kevin Perese Eric Toder Alison M. Shelton Project Manager The Public Policy

More information

Evaluating Lump Sum Incentives for Delayed Social Security Claiming*

Evaluating Lump Sum Incentives for Delayed Social Security Claiming* Evaluating Lump Sum Incentives for Delayed Social Security Claiming* Olivia S. Mitchell and Raimond Maurer October 2017 PRC WP2017 Pension Research Council Working Paper Pension Research Council The Wharton

More information

Opting out of Retirement Plan Default Settings

Opting out of Retirement Plan Default Settings WORKING PAPER Opting out of Retirement Plan Default Settings Jeremy Burke, Angela A. Hung, and Jill E. Luoto RAND Labor & Population WR-1162 January 2017 This paper series made possible by the NIA funded

More information

Online Appendices for: Cognitive Constraints on Valuing Annuities

Online Appendices for: Cognitive Constraints on Valuing Annuities Online Appendices for: Cognitive Constraints on Valuing Annuities Jeffrey R. Brown, Arie Kapteyn, Erzo F.P. Luttmer, and Olivia S. Mitchell Online Appendix Tables and Figures... page A-2 Online Appendix

More information

When and How to Delegate? A Life Cycle Analysis of Financial Advice

When and How to Delegate? A Life Cycle Analysis of Financial Advice When and How to Delegate? A Life Cycle Analysis of Financial Advice Hugh Hoikwang Kim, Raimond Maurer, and Olivia S. Mitchell Prepared for presentation at the Pension Research Council Symposium, May 5-6,

More information

What You Don t Know Can t Help You: Knowledge and Retirement Decision Making

What You Don t Know Can t Help You: Knowledge and Retirement Decision Making VERY PRELIMINARY PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE COMMENTS WELCOME What You Don t Know Can t Help You: Knowledge and Retirement Decision Making February 2003 Sewin Chan Wagner Graduate School of Public Service New

More information

Selection of High-Deductible Health Plans

Selection of High-Deductible Health Plans Selection of High-Deductible Health Plans Attributes Influencing Likelihood and Implications for Consumer- Driven Approaches Wendy Lynch, PhD Harold H. Gardner, MD Nathan Kleinman, PhD 415 W. 17th St.,

More information

Selection of High-Deductible Health Plans: Attributes Influencing Likelihood and Implications for Consumer-Driven Approaches

Selection of High-Deductible Health Plans: Attributes Influencing Likelihood and Implications for Consumer-Driven Approaches Selection of High-Deductible Health Plans: Attributes Influencing Likelihood and Implications for Consumer-Driven Approaches Wendy D. Lynch, Ph.D. Harold H. Gardner, M.D. Nathan L. Kleinman, Ph.D. Health

More information

Retirement funding is at a crossroads. For many years, Why Income Should Be the Outcome of a Defined Contribution Plan. Retirement

Retirement funding is at a crossroads. For many years, Why Income Should Be the Outcome of a Defined Contribution Plan. Retirement Retirement Why Income Should Be the Outcome of a Defined Contribution Plan Defined contribution (DC) plan participants need to understand how their savings will translate to income during retirement. For

More information

Investment Decisions and Negative Interest Rates

Investment Decisions and Negative Interest Rates Investment Decisions and Negative Interest Rates No. 16-23 Anat Bracha Abstract: While the current European Central Bank deposit rate and 2-year German government bond yields are negative, the U.S. 2-year

More information

Framing, Reference Points, and Preferences for Life Annuities

Framing, Reference Points, and Preferences for Life Annuities - The Retirement Security Project Research Brief Framing, Reference Points, and Preferences for Life Annuities Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey R. Kling, Sendhil Mullainathan, Garth R. Wiens and Marian V. Wrobel

More information

Does It Pay to Delay Social Security? * John B. Shoven Stanford University and NBER. and. Sita Nataraj Slavov American Enterprise Institute.

Does It Pay to Delay Social Security? * John B. Shoven Stanford University and NBER. and. Sita Nataraj Slavov American Enterprise Institute. Does It Pay to Delay Social Security? * John B. Shoven Stanford University and NBER and Sita Nataraj Slavov American Enterprise Institute July 2013 Abstract Social Security benefits may be commenced at

More information

Work-Life Balance and Labor Force Attachment at Older Ages. Marco Angrisani University of Southern California

Work-Life Balance and Labor Force Attachment at Older Ages. Marco Angrisani University of Southern California Work-Life Balance and Labor Force Attachment at Older Ages Marco Angrisani University of Southern California Maria Casanova California State University, Fullerton Erik Meijer University of Southern California

More information

Social Security Reform: How Benefits Compare March 2, 2005 National Press Club

Social Security Reform: How Benefits Compare March 2, 2005 National Press Club Social Security Reform: How Benefits Compare March 2, 2005 National Press Club Employee Benefit Research Institute Dallas Salisbury, CEO Craig Copeland, senior research associate Jack VanDerhei, Temple

More information

Complexity as a Barrier to Annuitization: Do Consumers Know How to Value Annuities?

Complexity as a Barrier to Annuitization: Do Consumers Know How to Value Annuities? Complexity as a Barrier to Annuitization: Do Consumers Know How to Value Annuities? Jeffrey R. Brown, Arie Kapteyn, Erzo F. P. Luttmer, and Olivia S. Mitchell March 2013 PRC WP2013-01 Pension Research

More information

This work is distributed as a Discussion Paper by the STANFORD INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC POLICY RESEARCH. SIEPR Discussion Paper No.

This work is distributed as a Discussion Paper by the STANFORD INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC POLICY RESEARCH. SIEPR Discussion Paper No. This work is distributed as a Discussion Paper by the STANFORD INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC POLICY RESEARCH SIEPR Discussion Paper No. 13-019 RECENT CHANGES IN THE GAINS FROM DELAYING SOCIAL SECURITY By John

More information

Using Consequence Messaging to Improve Understanding of Social Security

Using Consequence Messaging to Improve Understanding of Social Security Using Consequence Messaging to Improve Understanding of Social Security Anya Samek and Arie Kapteyn Center for Economic and Social Research University of Southern California 20 th Annual Joint Meeting

More information

Changes over Time in Subjective Retirement Probabilities

Changes over Time in Subjective Retirement Probabilities Marjorie Honig Changes over Time in Subjective Retirement Probabilities No. 96-036 HRS/AHEAD Working Paper Series July 1996 The Health and Retirement Study (HRS) and the Study of Asset and Health Dynamics

More information

Research. Michigan. Center. Retirement

Research. Michigan. Center. Retirement Michigan University of Retirement Research Center Working Paper WP 2007-164 Future Beneficiary Expectations of the Returns to Delayed Social Security Benefit Claiming and Choice Behavior Jeff Dominitz,

More information

The Value of Social Security Disability Insurance

The Value of Social Security Disability Insurance #2001-09 June 2001 The Value of Social Security Disability Insurance by Martin R. Holmer Policy Simulation Group John R. Gist and Alison M. Shelton Project Managers The Public Policy Institute, formed

More information

Issue Number 60 August A publication of the TIAA-CREF Institute

Issue Number 60 August A publication of the TIAA-CREF Institute 18429AA 3/9/00 7:01 AM Page 1 Research Dialogues Issue Number August 1999 A publication of the TIAA-CREF Institute The Retirement Patterns and Annuitization Decisions of a Cohort of TIAA-CREF Participants

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 3 Fall 1997 CORPORATE MANAGERS RISKY BEHAVIOR: RISK TAKING OR AVOIDING?

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 3 Fall 1997 CORPORATE MANAGERS RISKY BEHAVIOR: RISK TAKING OR AVOIDING? Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 3 Fall 1997 CORPORATE MANAGERS RISKY BEHAVIOR: RISK TAKING OR AVOIDING? Kathryn Sullivan* Abstract This study reports on five experiments that

More information

THE CODING OF OUTCOMES IN TAXPAYERS REPORTING DECISIONS. A. Schepanski The University of Iowa

THE CODING OF OUTCOMES IN TAXPAYERS REPORTING DECISIONS. A. Schepanski The University of Iowa THE CODING OF OUTCOMES IN TAXPAYERS REPORTING DECISIONS A. Schepanski The University of Iowa May 2001 The author thanks Teri Shearer and the participants of The University of Iowa Judgment and Decision-Making

More information

The Perception Of Social Security Incentives For Labor Supply And Retirement: The Median Voter Knows More Than You d Think *

The Perception Of Social Security Incentives For Labor Supply And Retirement: The Median Voter Knows More Than You d Think * The Perception Of Social Security Incentives For Labor Supply And Retirement: The Median Voter Knows More Than You d Think * Jeffrey B. Liebman Erzo F.P. Luttmer September 24, 2008 Abstract: The degree

More information

Is Retiree Demand for Life Annuities Rational? Evidence from Public Employees *

Is Retiree Demand for Life Annuities Rational? Evidence from Public Employees * Is Retiree Demand for Life Annuities Rational? Evidence from Public Employees * John Chalmers and Jonathan Reuter Current Draft: December 2009 Abstract Oregon Public Employees Retirement System (PERS)

More information

Restructuring Social Security: How Will Retirement Ages Respond?

Restructuring Social Security: How Will Retirement Ages Respond? Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR Articles and Chapters ILR Collection 1987 Restructuring Social Security: How Will Retirement Ages Respond? Gary S. Fields Cornell University, gsf2@cornell.edu

More information

How Much Should Americans Be Saving for Retirement?

How Much Should Americans Be Saving for Retirement? How Much Should Americans Be Saving for Retirement? by B. Douglas Bernheim Stanford University The National Bureau of Economic Research Lorenzo Forni The Bank of Italy Jagadeesh Gokhale The Federal Reserve

More information

To What Extent is Household Spending Reduced as a Result of Unemployment?

To What Extent is Household Spending Reduced as a Result of Unemployment? To What Extent is Household Spending Reduced as a Result of Unemployment? Final Report Employment Insurance Evaluation Evaluation and Data Development Human Resources Development Canada April 2003 SP-ML-017-04-03E

More information

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits Day Manoli UCLA Andrea Weber University of Mannheim February 29, 2012 Abstract This paper presents empirical evidence

More information

Do Older SSDI Applicants Denied Benefits on the Basis of their Work Capacity Return to Work After Denial?

Do Older SSDI Applicants Denied Benefits on the Basis of their Work Capacity Return to Work After Denial? DRC Brief Number: 2018-01 Do Older SSDI Applicants Denied Benefits on the Basis of their Work Capacity Return to Work After Denial? Jody Schimmel Hyde and April Yanyuan Wu In this issue brief, we document

More information

Risk Tolerance and Risk Exposure: Evidence from Panel Study. of Income Dynamics

Risk Tolerance and Risk Exposure: Evidence from Panel Study. of Income Dynamics Risk Tolerance and Risk Exposure: Evidence from Panel Study of Income Dynamics Economics 495 Project 3 (Revised) Professor Frank Stafford Yang Su 2012/3/9 For Honors Thesis Abstract In this paper, I examined

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity

Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity Investor Competence, Information and Investment Activity Anders Karlsson and Lars Nordén 1 Department of Corporate Finance, School of Business, Stockholm University, S-106 91 Stockholm, Sweden Abstract

More information

Nonrandom Selection in the HRS Social Security Earnings Sample

Nonrandom Selection in the HRS Social Security Earnings Sample RAND Nonrandom Selection in the HRS Social Security Earnings Sample Steven Haider Gary Solon DRU-2254-NIA February 2000 DISTRIBUTION STATEMENT A Approved for Public Release Distribution Unlimited Prepared

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

The Decision to Delay Social Security Benefits: Theory and Evidence

The Decision to Delay Social Security Benefits: Theory and Evidence The Decision to Delay Social Security Benefits: Theory and Evidence John B. Shoven Stanford University and NBER and Sita Nataraj Slavov American Enterprise Institute and NBER 14 th Annual Joint Conference

More information

WHY DO MARRIED MEN CLAIM SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS SO EARLY? IGNORANCE OR CADDISHNESS? Steven A. Sass, Wei Sun, and Anthony Webb*

WHY DO MARRIED MEN CLAIM SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS SO EARLY? IGNORANCE OR CADDISHNESS? Steven A. Sass, Wei Sun, and Anthony Webb* WHY DO MARRIED MEN CLAIM SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS SO EARLY? IGNORANCE OR CADDISHNESS? Steven A. Sass, Wei Sun, and Anthony Webb* CRR WP 2007-17 Released: October 2007 Draft Submitted: October 2007 Center

More information

THE EFFECT OF THE REPEAL OF THE RETIREMENT EARNINGS TEST ON THE LABOR SUPPLY OF OLDER WORKERS

THE EFFECT OF THE REPEAL OF THE RETIREMENT EARNINGS TEST ON THE LABOR SUPPLY OF OLDER WORKERS THE EFFECT OF THE REPEAL OF THE RETIREMENT EARNINGS TEST ON THE LABOR SUPPLY OF OLDER WORKERS Bac V. Tran University of Maryland at College Park November 21, 2002 Abstract This paper studies the impact

More information

The text reports the results of two experiments examining the influence of two war tax

The text reports the results of two experiments examining the influence of two war tax Supporting Information for Kriner et al. CMPS 2015 Page 1 The text reports the results of two experiments examining the influence of two war tax instruments on public support for war. The complete wording

More information

Retirement Savings: How Much Will Workers Have When They Retire?

Retirement Savings: How Much Will Workers Have When They Retire? Order Code RL33845 Retirement Savings: How Much Will Workers Have When They Retire? January 29, 2007 Patrick Purcell Specialist in Social Legislation Domestic Social Policy Division Debra B. Whitman Specialist

More information

Volume Title: Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment. Volume Author/Editor: Jeffrey Brown, Jeffrey Liebman and David A.

Volume Title: Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment. Volume Author/Editor: Jeffrey Brown, Jeffrey Liebman and David A. This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment Volume Author/Editor: Jeffrey Brown, Jeffrey

More information

5 Steps To Planning Success :

5 Steps To Planning Success : 5 Steps To Planning Success : Developing and Testing New Strategies for Reaching Young Adults Aileen Heinberg Angela Hung Arie Kapteyn Annamaria Lusardi Joanne K. Yoong With DC Plans, Starting Early Can

More information

Family Status Transitions, Latent Health, and the Post- Retirement Evolution of Assets

Family Status Transitions, Latent Health, and the Post- Retirement Evolution of Assets Family Status Transitions, Latent Health, and the Post- Retirement Evolution of Assets by James Poterba MIT and NBER Steven Venti Dartmouth College and NBER David A. Wise Harvard University and NBER May

More information

NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX: HOW MUCH LONGER DO WE NEED TO WORK?

NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX: HOW MUCH LONGER DO WE NEED TO WORK? June 2012, Number 12-12 RETIREMENT RESEARCH NATIONAL RETIREMENT RISK INDEX: HOW MUCH LONGER DO WE NEED TO WORK? By Alicia H. Munnell, Anthony Webb, Luke Delorme, and Francesca Golub-Sass* Introduction

More information

Jamie Wagner Ph.D. Student University of Nebraska Lincoln

Jamie Wagner Ph.D. Student University of Nebraska Lincoln An Empirical Analysis Linking a Person s Financial Risk Tolerance and Financial Literacy to Financial Behaviors Jamie Wagner Ph.D. Student University of Nebraska Lincoln Abstract Financial risk aversion

More information

Do Tax Incentives Increase 401(k) Retirement Saving? Evidence from the Adoption of Catch-Up Contributions

Do Tax Incentives Increase 401(k) Retirement Saving? Evidence from the Adoption of Catch-Up Contributions Do Tax Incentives Increase 401(k) Retirement Saving? Evidence from the Adoption of Catch-Up Contributions Matthew S. Rutledge Center for Retirement Research at Boston College April Yanyuan Wu Mathematica

More information

Framing, Reference Points, and Preferences for Life Annuities

Framing, Reference Points, and Preferences for Life Annuities Framing, Reference Points, and Preferences for Life Annuities Jeffrey R. Brown University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign and NBER Jeffrey R. Kling Congressional Budget Office Sendhil Mullainathan Harvard

More information

Family Status Transitions, Latent Health, and the Post-Retirement Evolution of Assets

Family Status Transitions, Latent Health, and the Post-Retirement Evolution of Assets Family Status Transitions, Latent Health, and the Post-Retirement Evolution of Assets James Poterba MIT and NBER Steven Venti Dartmouth College and NBER David A. Wise Harvard University and NBER 11 th

More information

N.B. PIPE TRADES SHARED RISK PLAN. Employee Summary Booklet. June 2014

N.B. PIPE TRADES SHARED RISK PLAN. Employee Summary Booklet. June 2014 N.B. PIPE TRADES SHARED RISK PLAN Employee Summary Booklet June 2014 INDEX Section Page INTRODUCTION 1 EXPLANATION OF TERMS 3 Accumulated interest 3 Active member 3 Actuarial valuation 3 Beneficiary 4

More information

A Canonical Correlation Analysis of Financial Risk-Taking by Australian Households

A Canonical Correlation Analysis of Financial Risk-Taking by Australian Households A Correlation Analysis of Financial Risk-Taking by Australian Households Author West, Tracey, Worthington, Andrew Charles Published 2013 Journal Title Consumer Interests Annual Copyright Statement 2013

More information

The Power of Working Longer 1. Gila Bronshtein Cornerstone Research Jason Scott

The Power of Working Longer 1. Gila Bronshtein Cornerstone Research Jason Scott The Power of Working Longer 1 Gila Bronshtein Cornerstone Research GBronshtein@cornerstone.com Jason Scott Jscott457@yahoo.com John B. Shoven Stanford University and NBER shoven@stanford.edu Sita N. Slavov

More information

Life Expectancy as a Constructed Belief: Evidence of a Live-to or Die-by Framing Effect i

Life Expectancy as a Constructed Belief: Evidence of a Live-to or Die-by Framing Effect i Life Expectancy as a Constructed Belief: Evidence of a Live-to or Die-by Framing Effect i John W. Payne Namika Sagara Suzanne B. Shu Kirstin C. Appelt Eric J. Johnson John W. Payne and Namika Sagara are

More information

In Meyer and Reichenstein (2010) and

In Meyer and Reichenstein (2010) and M EYER R EICHENSTEIN Contributions How the Social Security Claiming Decision Affects Portfolio Longevity by William Meyer and William Reichenstein, Ph.D., CFA William Meyer is founder and CEO of Retiree

More information

Longevity Risk Pooling Opportunities to Increase Retirement Security

Longevity Risk Pooling Opportunities to Increase Retirement Security Longevity Risk Pooling Opportunities to Increase Retirement Security March 2017 2 Longevity Risk Pooling Opportunities to Increase Retirement Security AUTHOR Daniel Bauer Georgia State University SPONSOR

More information

Demographic and Economic Characteristics of Children in Families Receiving Social Security

Demographic and Economic Characteristics of Children in Families Receiving Social Security Each month, over 3 million children receive benefits from Social Security, accounting for one of every seven Social Security beneficiaries. This article examines the demographic characteristics and economic

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MISMEASUREMENT OF PENSIONS BEFORE AND AFTER RETIREMENT: THE MYSTERY OF THE DISAPPEARING PENSIONS WITH IMPLICATIONS FOR THE IMPORTANCE OF SOCIAL SECURITY AS A SOURCE OF RETIREMENT

More information

Comments on File Number S (Investment Company Advertising: Target Date Retirement Fund Names and Marketing)

Comments on File Number S (Investment Company Advertising: Target Date Retirement Fund Names and Marketing) January 24, 2011 Elizabeth M. Murphy Secretary Securities and Exchange Commission 100 F Street, NE Washington, D.C. 20549-1090 RE: Comments on File Number S7-12-10 (Investment Company Advertising: Target

More information

a partial solution to the annuity puzzle

a partial solution to the annuity puzzle 59 Disengagement: a partial solution to the annuity puzzle Hazel Bateman Director, Risk and Actuarial Studies, University of New South Wales, Sydney Christine Eckhert Marketing and CenSoC, University of

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GROWTH IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AMONG THE RETIREMENT AGE POPULATION FROM INCREASES IN THE CAP ON COVERED EARNINGS

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GROWTH IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AMONG THE RETIREMENT AGE POPULATION FROM INCREASES IN THE CAP ON COVERED EARNINGS NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GROWTH IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AMONG THE RETIREMENT AGE POPULATION FROM INCREASES IN THE CAP ON COVERED EARNINGS Alan L. Gustman Thomas Steinmeier Nahid Tabatabai Working

More information

Introduction to Social Security. Learn about your Social Security benefits

Introduction to Social Security. Learn about your Social Security benefits Introduction to Social Security Learn about your Social Security benefits Taking the mystery out of Social Security 1 Overview 2 When can I start taking benefits? 4 How should I decide when to start taking

More information

HOW MUCH DO HOUSEHOLDS REALLY LOSE BY CLAIMING SOCIAL SECURITY AT AGE 62? Wei Sun and Anthony Webb*

HOW MUCH DO HOUSEHOLDS REALLY LOSE BY CLAIMING SOCIAL SECURITY AT AGE 62? Wei Sun and Anthony Webb* HOW MUCH DO HOUSEHOLDS REALLY LOSE BY CLAIMING SOCIAL SECURITY AT AGE 62? Wei Sun and Anthony Webb* CRR WP 2009-11 Released: March 2009 Draft Submitted: March 2009 Center for Retirement Research at Boston

More information

Questions and Answers about OLDER WORKERS: A Sloan Work and Family Research Network Fact Sheet

Questions and Answers about OLDER WORKERS: A Sloan Work and Family Research Network Fact Sheet Questions and Answers about OLDER WORKERS: A Sloan Work and Family Research Network Fact Sheet Introduction The Sloan Work and Family Research Network has prepared Fact Sheets that provide statistical

More information

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* Sónia Costa** Luísa Farinha** 133 Abstract The analysis of the Portuguese households

More information

HOW HAS THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AFFECTED THE CONSUMPTION OF RETIREES?

HOW HAS THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AFFECTED THE CONSUMPTION OF RETIREES? August 2013, Number 13-12 RETIREMENT RESEARCH HOW HAS THE FINANCIAL CRISIS AFFECTED THE CONSUMPTION OF RETIREES? By Richard W. Kopcke and Anthony Webb* Introduction Despite the recovery of the stock market

More information

Portfolio Choice in Retirement: Health Risk and the Demand for Annuities, Housing, and Risky Assets

Portfolio Choice in Retirement: Health Risk and the Demand for Annuities, Housing, and Risky Assets Portfolio Choice in Retirement: Health Risk and the Demand for Annuities, Housing, and Risky Assets Motohiro Yogo University of Pennsylvania and NBER Prepared for the 11th Annual Joint Conference of the

More information

Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz

Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz Abstract: This paper is an analysis of the mortality rates of beneficiaries of charitable gift annuities. Observed

More information

For More Information

For More Information THE ARTS CHILD POLICY CIVIL JUSTICE EDUCATION ENERGY AND ENVIRONMENT This PDF document was made available from www.rand.org as a public service of the RAND Corporation. Jump down to document6 HEALTH AND

More information

The Economic Consequences of a Husband s Death: Evidence from the HRS and AHEAD

The Economic Consequences of a Husband s Death: Evidence from the HRS and AHEAD The Economic Consequences of a Husband s Death: Evidence from the HRS and AHEAD David Weir Robert Willis Purvi Sevak University of Michigan Prepared for presentation at the Second Annual Joint Conference

More information

What Explains Changes in Retirement Plans during the Great Recession?

What Explains Changes in Retirement Plans during the Great Recession? What Explains Changes in Retirement Plans during the Great Recession? By Gopi Shah Goda and John B. Shoven and Sita Nataraj Slavov The economic recession which began in December 2007 resulted in a sharp

More information

Retirement Behavior and the Global Financial Crisis

Retirement Behavior and the Global Financial Crisis Retirement Behavior and the Global Financial Crisis Jason J. Fichtner, John W.R. Phillips, and Barbara A. Smith September 2011 PRC WP2011-10 Pension Research Council Working Paper Pension Research Council

More information

WHY DO WOMEN CLAIM SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS SO EARLY?

WHY DO WOMEN CLAIM SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS SO EARLY? OCTOBER 2005, NUMBER 35 WHY DO WOMEN CLAIM SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS SO EARLY? BY ALICIA H. MUNNELL AND MAURICIO SOTO* Introduction If individuals continue to withdraw completely from the labor force in

More information

The Role of Exponential-Growth Bias and Present Bias in Retirment Saving Decisions

The Role of Exponential-Growth Bias and Present Bias in Retirment Saving Decisions The Role of Exponential-Growth Bias and Present Bias in Retirment Saving Decisions Gopi Shah Goda Stanford University & NBER Matthew Levy London School of Economics Colleen Flaherty Manchester University

More information

Load and Billing Impact Findings from California Residential Opt-in TOU Pilots

Load and Billing Impact Findings from California Residential Opt-in TOU Pilots Load and Billing Impact Findings from California Residential Opt-in TOU Pilots Stephen George, Eric Bell, Aimee Savage, Nexant, San Francisco, CA ABSTRACT Three large investor owned utilities (IOUs) launched

More information

What is the status of Social Security? When should you draw benefits? How a Job Impacts Benefits... 8

What is the status of Social Security? When should you draw benefits? How a Job Impacts Benefits... 8 TABLE OF CONTENTS Executive Summary... 2 What is the status of Social Security?... 3 When should you draw benefits?... 4 How do spousal benefits work? Plan for Surviving Spouse... 5 File and Suspend...

More information

COMMUNITY ADVANTAGE PANEL SURVEY: DATA COLLECTION UPDATE AND ANALYSIS OF PANEL ATTRITION

COMMUNITY ADVANTAGE PANEL SURVEY: DATA COLLECTION UPDATE AND ANALYSIS OF PANEL ATTRITION COMMUNITY ADVANTAGE PANEL SURVEY: DATA COLLECTION UPDATE AND ANALYSIS OF PANEL ATTRITION Technical Report: March 2011 By Sarah Riley HongYu Ru Mark Lindblad Roberto Quercia Center for Community Capital

More information

Your guide to filing for Social Security

Your guide to filing for Social Security RETIREMENT INSTITUTE SM Social Security Your guide to filing for Social Security It s a choice of a lifetime. Make it count. 2 Social Security It s more than a monthly check As you approach retirement,

More information

Risks of Retirement Key Findings and Issues. February 2004

Risks of Retirement Key Findings and Issues. February 2004 Risks of Retirement Key Findings and Issues February 2004 Introduction and Background An understanding of post-retirement risks is particularly important today in light of the aging society, the volatility

More information

SUMMARY PLAN DESCRIPTION

SUMMARY PLAN DESCRIPTION SUMMARY PLAN DESCRIPTION A Summary of Benefits for Employees who Retire, Become Disabled or Otherwise Terminate Participation After December 31, 2013 CONTENTS PAGE INTRODUCTION... 1 DEFINITIONS... 2 IMPORTANT

More information

Research. Michigan. Center. Retirement. Individuals Responses to Social Security Reform Adeline Delavande and Susann Rohwedder. Working Paper MR RC

Research. Michigan. Center. Retirement. Individuals Responses to Social Security Reform Adeline Delavande and Susann Rohwedder. Working Paper MR RC Michigan University of Retirement Research Center Working Paper WP 2008-182 Individuals Responses to Social Security Reform Adeline Delavande and Susann Rohwedder MR RC Project #: UM08-08 Individuals Responses

More information

Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages. Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder

Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages. Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder Health and the Future Course of Labor Force Participation at Older Ages Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder Introduction For most of the past quarter century, the labor force participation rates of the older

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HEALTH SHOCKS AND COUPLES LABOR SUPPLY DECISIONS. Courtney C. Coile. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HEALTH SHOCKS AND COUPLES LABOR SUPPLY DECISIONS. Courtney C. Coile. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HEALTH SHOCKS AND COUPLES LABOR SUPPLY DECISIONS Courtney C. Coile Working Paper 10810 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10810 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

Personality Traits and Economic Preparation for Retirement

Personality Traits and Economic Preparation for Retirement Personality Traits and Economic Preparation for Retirement Michael D. Hurd Susann Rohwedder RAND Angela Lee Duckworth University of Pennsylvania and David R. Weir University of Michigan 14 th Annual Joint

More information

RetirementWorks. The input can be made extremely simple and approximate, or it can be more detailed and accurate:

RetirementWorks. The input can be made extremely simple and approximate, or it can be more detailed and accurate: Retirement Income Annuitization The RetirementWorks Retirement Income Annuitization calculator analyzes how much of a retiree s savings should be converted to a monthly annuity stream. It uses a needs-based

More information

Danish expectations. for the housing market. A survey of expectations and their causes. September 2010 September 2012

Danish expectations. for the housing market. A survey of expectations and their causes. September 2010 September 2012 Danish expectations for the housing market A survey of expectations and their causes September 2010 September 2012 The Knowledge Center for Housing Econimics Table of Contents Table of Contents... 2 Table

More information

Financial Literacy and Subjective Expectations Questions: A Validation Exercise

Financial Literacy and Subjective Expectations Questions: A Validation Exercise Financial Literacy and Subjective Expectations Questions: A Validation Exercise Monica Paiella University of Naples Parthenope Dept. of Business and Economic Studies (Room 314) Via General Parisi 13, 80133

More information

CHAPTER 5 PROJECTING RETIREMENT INCOME FROM PENSIONS

CHAPTER 5 PROJECTING RETIREMENT INCOME FROM PENSIONS CHAPTER 5 PROJECTING RETIREMENT INCOME FROM PENSIONS I. OVERVIEW The MINT 3. pension projection module estimates pension benefits and wealth from defined benefit (DB) plans, defined contribution (DC) plans,

More information

The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital

The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital The Long Term Evolution of Female Human Capital Audra Bowlus and Chris Robinson University of Western Ontario Presentation at Craig Riddell s Festschrift UBC, September 2016 Introduction and Motivation

More information

The Voya Retire Ready Index TM

The Voya Retire Ready Index TM The Voya Retire Ready Index TM Measuring the retirement readiness of Americans Table of contents Introduction...2 Methodology and framework... 3 Index factors... 4 Index results...6 Key findings... 7 Role

More information

MassMutual RetireEase Choice SM

MassMutual RetireEase Choice SM MassMutual RetireEase Choice SM A Flexible Premium Deferred Income Annuity TABLE OF CONTENTS 1 Predictable future income 3 Section 1: The contract 8 Section 2: Purchase payments 10 Section 3: Annuity Date

More information

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Introduction to "Pensions in the U.S. Economy"

Volume URL:  Chapter Title: Introduction to Pensions in the U.S. Economy This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Pensions in the U.S. Economy Volume Author/Editor: Zvi Bodie, John B. Shoven, and David A.

More information

Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth

Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth Shelly J. Lundberg University of Washington and Jennifer Ward-Batts University of Michigan Prepared for presentation at the Second Annual

More information

Older Workers: Employment and Retirement Trends

Older Workers: Employment and Retirement Trends Cornell University ILR School DigitalCommons@ILR Federal Publications Key Workplace Documents 9-15-2008 Older Workers: Employment and Retirement Trends Patrick Purcell Congressional Research Service; Domestic

More information

The Potential Effect of Offering Lump Sums in the Social Security Program1

The Potential Effect of Offering Lump Sums in the Social Security Program1 publicpolicy.wharton.upenn.edu The Potential Effect of Offering Lump Sums in the Social Security Program1 ISSUE BRIEF VOLUME 3 NUMBER 9 NOVEMBER 2015 Raimond Maurer, PhD; Olivia S. Mitchell, PhD; Ralph

More information

Insights: Financial Capability. Gender, Generation and Financial Knowledge: A Six-Year Perspective. Women, Men and Financial Literacy

Insights: Financial Capability. Gender, Generation and Financial Knowledge: A Six-Year Perspective. Women, Men and Financial Literacy Insights: Financial Capability March 2018 Author: Gary Mottola, Ph.D. FINRA Investor Education Foundation What s Inside: Women, Men and Financial Literacy 1 Gender Differences in Investor Literacy 4 Self-Assessed

More information