Inferring the Shadow Rate from Real Activity

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Inferring the Shadow Rate from Real Activity"

Transcription

1 Inferring the Shadow Rate from Real Activity Benjamín García Arsenios Skaperdas June 8, 2017 PRELIMINARY Abstract We estimate a shadow rate for the effective lower bound, measured from real economic activity, that is directly comparable to the effective federal funds rate. Estimates indicate that unconventional monetary policy had significant real effects, reaching a maximum effect equivalent to a -4 percent policy rate. Each successive large-scale asset program was decreasing in effectiveness in stimulating growth. Our approach is validated by tests for parameter stability, accuracy of out-of-sample forecasts of all variables, and crossvalidation of the method when the federal funds rate is above its effective lower bound. JEL Classification: E43, E47, E52 We thank Dario Caldara, Benjamin K. Johanssen, Zeynep Senyuz, and seminar participants at the Central Bank of Ireland and Georgetown Center for Economic Research Conference. All errors are our own. We are responsible for the views expressed in this paper, and they should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Central Bank of Chile, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, or of anyone else associated with the Federal Reserve System. García: Central Bank of Chile, bgarcia@bcentral.cl. Skaperdas: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, arsenios.skaperdas@frb.gov. 1

2 1 Introduction A natural benchmark for evaluating the effects of unconventional monetary policy is to measure how unconventional policy affects the macroeconomy in the ways that conventional monetary policy is thought to. This paper presents a relatively simple, atheoretic approach to estimate a shadow interest rate at the effective lower bound (ELB) which takes into account the effects of unconventional policy. We find that unconventional policy created a negative interest rate environment, in that it increased macroeconomic aggregates in the way that further federal funds rate decreases below zero would have. Our approach departs from current literature by inferring a shadow rate directly from observed variables capturing real economic activity. We show that a simple VAR can be used backwards. Typically, a monetary VAR is estimated using the federal funds rate, and the resulting impulse response functions are used to measure the effects of a monetary shock. Our exercise instead asks a different question: given previously measured observed effects of federal funds rate changes, what interest rate is most consistent with macroeconomic dynamics since reaching the ELB? As our benchmark specification features a VAR estimated from before the ELB, we perform a host of checks testing for structural change, parameter instability, and forecast accuracy. We find that our VAR accurately captures dynamics following the ELB. This finding mirrors other results in the time series literature (Stock and Watson, 2012) suggesting that the Great Recession was the result of large shocks rather than underlying changes in the structure of the economy. Nonetheless, we do provide upper bounds on our estimated shadow rate through a biased VAR estimation process incorporating data from the ELB. Relative to the literature, our approach departs from common estimation techniques, such as dynamic term-structure models (Krippner, 2013; Wu and Xia, 2016; Christensen et al., 2013), in that our method features no financial variables or no-arbitrage restrictions. 2

3 In a paper outside of the no-arbitrage framework, Lombardi and Zhu (2014) estimate a shadow rate with a dynamic factor model derived from interest rate series, monetary aggregates, and balance sheet data. In contrast, our underlying data includes standard series such as GDP and investment, while our approach decomposes these time series to find the interest rate most consistent with their evolution since Interestingly, our shadow rate compares closely to that of Lombardi and Zhu (2014), despite the significant differences in our data and methodology. This indicates that the stance of monetary policy instruments during the ELB, as measured by Lombardi and Zhu (2014), is mirrored by policy effects, which we measure. Another approach similar to ours in the literature is Johannsen and Mertens (2016). These authors also use time series models to better understand the effective short-term interest rate. A difference in our approach is that while Johannsen and Mertens (2016) measure the nominal interest rate that would prevail in the absence of the ELB, our results are interpreted as the likeliest effective monetary policy stance, measured in terms of the equivalent interest rate during normal times. Finally, our paper relates to state of the art non-linear DSGE models created to characterize the effective lower bound (Gust et al., 2016). While our approach is a linear approximation to macroeconomic dynamics, we find evidence that a simple VAR model forecasts accurately at the effective lower bound, as has been found in previous literature (Aastveit et al., 2016). 1 Of note, other shadow rate papers in the literature also assume a linear structure. 2 In practice, evidence of non-linearities using quarterly aggregate data has been hard to find (Ng and Wright, 2013), in part because non-linearities present at the household and firm-level may not survive aggregation. 3 1 These authors also find that constant parameter VARs are difficult to beat in out-of-sample forecasting following the crisis. 2 Wu and Xia (2016), for example, assume that their shadow rate is an affine function of factors following a linear VAR(1) process. 3 Financial market responses to monetary policy at the ELB, for example, do not show signs of nonlinearities. Swanson (2017) finds that responses to unconventional monetary policy are largely similar to those of conventional monetary policy, and that factors capturing those responses are essentially 3

4 Our paper continues as follows: we explain the data and methodology in Sections 2 and 3. Section 4 is the bulk of our paper; it presents our benchmark results, and provides a great deal of evidence that the results are valid. Section 5 explores the implications of the results for policy effectiveness. Section 6 concludes. 2 Data In order to adequately capture the relationship between interest rates and the rest of the economy, we utilize a broad set of macroeconomic variables. As in Smets and Wouters (2007) we consider output, private consumption, private investment, real wages, hours, inflation (GDP deflator), and the federal funds rate. The first four variables are per capita and used in log levels so as to contain the history of their evolution. Real wages and hours are from the non-farm business sector (Bureau of Labor Statistics). As a robustness check, we also include log per capita government consumption and investment from the National Accounts in our estimations. 3 Methodology As in Skaperdas (2016), our methodology follows from the observation that VARs can be used to measure the federal funds rate as an unobserved variable. We ask the following question: given the measured effects of a monetary shock, what is the likeliest interest rate? We estimate a VAR and extract the likeliest interest rate at the effective bound, given the VAR parameters and observed data. More explicitly, consider a bivariate VAR(1) system in structural form unchanged when estimating over the ELB separately. B 0 Y t = B 1 Y t 1 + u t (1) 4

5 Rewrite as explicit equations for the two variables with a recursive ordering, letting (i, j) denote the ith row and jth column of the preceding matrix x t = B 1 (1, 1)x t 1 + B 1 (1, 2)z t 1 + u 1,t (2) z t = B 0 (2, 1)x t + B 1 (2, 2)x t 1 + B 1 (2, 1)z t 1 + u 2,t (3) The error terms are independent, zero mean, and normally distributed. Assume that the VAR parameters have been solved for using a sample of observed values. Then in state-space form, the measurement equation is as follows, While the state equation is x t = ˆB 1 (1, 1)x t 1 + ˆB 1 (1, 2)z t 1 + u 1,t (4) }{{} deterministic z t = ˆB 0 (2, 1)x t + ˆB 1 (2, 2)x t 1 + ˆB 1 (2, 1)z t 1 + u 2,t (5) }{{} deterministic Using an observed series of values, x t, we can solve for the optimal z t using the Kalman filter for the unobserved state, both in- or out-of-sample, using VAR parameter ˆB s. Since the shocks are orthogonalized, the Kalman filter provides an optimal linear estimate of the state. In brief, the filter minimizes one step ahead forecast errors. We treat deterministic terms as exogenous forcing variables. In practice, our measurement equations and the state are set up as functions as follows: Output Consumption Investment X t = RealW age Hours Inf lation [ ] Z t = F ederalf undsrate 5

6 As shown in the two variable example, we identify the VAR using the Cholesky decomposition. Since our data consists of non-financial variables, we consider consider the Cholesky identification acceptable. 4 In support of our identification, which imposes null responses upon impact of a monetary shock to the other VAR variables, Caldara and Herbst (2016) find insignificant contemporaneous effects of monetary shocks on real variables when identifying monetary shocks through high frequency identification. In order for our methodology to capture the overall effects of unconventional monetary policy, it must be the case that unconventional policy transmits to macro variables similarly to the way a change in the federal funds rate would have. Our estimates provide a benchmark estimate of unconventional policy through this lens. 5 Other researchers have made the case that large-scale asset purchases affect the macroeconomy in a similar way to conventional interest rate changes (Gagnon et al., 2016), while forward guidance was used both during and before the ELB period (Swanson, 2017). An alternative estimation approach to that examined in this paper would be to estimate all parameters in the state-space model at once, and treat the federal funds rate as an unobserved variable at the effective lower bound. However, this would also necessitate the estimation of the Federal Reserve s reaction function during the effective bound, confounding the estimation process. The identification of the unobserved variable would come not only from the reaction of the rest of the economy, but also from the likeliest reaction of the interest rate to the economic environment. This could also bias measures of monetary shocks from before the crisis. Nonetheless, to be explained, we do address a similar type of estimation process to bound the measures of our shadow rate by a biased estimation process. 4 While incorporating financial variables, a VAR with Cholesky identification is misspecified since financial markets are known to quickly react to policy changes. 5 Note that to the extent that unconventional policy affects macroeconomic aggregates in additional channels not occurring through conventional federal funds rate changes, we would understate its beneficial effects. 6

7 4 Results 4.1 Benchmark Estimation Figure 1 presents the benchmark estimation results from this paper. We use one lag, as suggested by both the Hannan-Quinn and Schwarz Information Criteria, since our data are quarterly and less than 120 observations before the ELB (Ivanov and Kilian, 2005). In-sample, the state estimates closely follows the federal funds rate. The out-of-sample estimates directly infer the equivalent federal funds rate following the incidence of the effective lower bound. These results provide a summary statistic of the net effect of Federal Reserve policies at each quarter, to the extent that they affect other variables in the model in the way traditional monetary policy would have. Of note, the estimates are negative soon following the financial crisis. Thus, unconventional policy was able to affect macroeconomic aggregates in the way a strong and persistent reduction of the federal funds rate would have. Figure 1: Implied Monetary Stance, Benchmark Estimate q1 1990q1 1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1 2015q1 Quarter Federal Funds Rate Filtered State Estimate (+/- 1 RMSE) The fact that the shadow rate initially increases following 2008:Q3 may at first appear 7

8 unintuitive. However, the shadow rate estimated in this paper is the most likely interest rate given observed variables. Although the Federal Reserve decreased the policy rate close to its effective lower bound in 2008:Q4, it is reasonable to believe that the tightening of financial markets following the crisis caused macroeconomic aggregates to grow as if a contractionary monetary policy had been in place. Thus, the increase in the shadow rate reflects the severity of the financial shock on the real economy. As evidence of this financial shock, we present Figure 2. In it, one can see that though the federal funds rate was set to near zero, interbank rates spiked heavily, which would influence broader financing conditions, and thus the shadow rate we estimate. Figure 2: Interbank Spreads /1/2002 7/1/2004 1/1/2007 7/1/2009 1/1/2012 7/1/2014 Date 6 mth Libor- 6 mth OIS 3 mth Libor- 3 mth OIS 1 mth Libor- 1 mth OIS The confidence bands on the estimates are calculated so as to correct for the generated regressors in the first state estimation of the VAR parameters. In all figures, standard error bands are calculated using a circular bootstrap. Steps are as follows: an artificial time series is created, equal in length to the sample, using random samples of residuals drawn with replacement from a circle of the VAR residuals, initiated with 1984:Q1 values. The VAR model is estimated over the artificial time series, yielding a distribution of the 8

9 VAR parameters. This process is repeated 200 times. We then estimate the shadow rate over the original 1984:Q1-2016:Q2 data with each iteration of the VAR parameters, and report the 16th and 84th percentile intervals of the resulting distribution of state estimate root mean squared errors. 4.2 Robustness Figure 3: Implied Monetary Stance, Smoothed Estimates q1 1990q1 1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1 2015q1 Quarter Federal funds rate Smoothed State Estimate (+/- 1 RMSE) VAR coefficients estimated using 1984Q1-2008:Q3 data, 1 lag. Figure 3 present the estimation results from the (two-sided) Kalman smoother. In each quarter, this estimation process uses the entire sample of observations, rather than observations for each time t through quarter t. The smoother results in state estimates that are fairly similar to the filter. This provides evidence that the model is accurately capturing dynamics at the effective lower bound, as the state estimates, and thus the variances of the measurement equations, are not significantly changed by the addition of ELB data. Nonetheless, the filter (one-sided) estimates are our preferred specification, as they do allow some real-time fluctuation in variance estimation. 9

10 The state estimates are robust to multiple other variations on the VARs. Figure 4 charts several variations of the shadow rate. The state estimates are exactly equal with an alternative VAR ordering, where inflation is ordered before all other variables. 6 Likewise, selecting a lag length of two results in very similar estimates and dynamics. 7 Within the context of our estimations, it does not seem to be the case that government spending is an important omitted variable, in spite of the fact that the effective bound period was also characterized by unprecedented fiscal contraction. In a variety of specifications, we do not find that including government spending increases the forecast accuracy of our methodology either in- or out-of-sample. Figure 4 presents one such specification, where we add government consumption and investment, ordered first to the VAR, and omit hours. Government spending shocks seem to be associated with shocks other than monetary in the model, as the resulting state estimate is similar. Whereas a monetary shock would typically increase private investment and consumption, a government spending shock would typically do the opposite due to crowding out (Coenen et al., 2013; Coenen and Straub, 2005). The finding that forecast errors of government spending are not associated with reductions in output in the US recovery is corroborated by House et al. (2017), though those authors do find strong effects in other countries. A possible concern of the use of the state-space model is that the estimates are driven by the state equation, rather than the measurement equations. If the measurement equations do not provide a good model during the effective bound period, it could be the case that the state estimate of the federal funds rate is simply tracing out the pre-effective lower bound reaction function of the Federal Reserve. In order to address this concern, we reformulate the state equation to be a random walk as follows: 6 Any ordering of the variables before the interest rate yields equal estimates by construction, as ordering of the non-policy block does not matter. 7 Since we have a short sample our VAR does not have many lags. One could think this is problematic, as monetary policy is typically thought to have lagged effects. Note, however, that the interest rate is measured off of its level at each period, not just shocks occurring in each quarter, as would be the case for a VAR estimated in differences. 10

11 Figure 4: Implied Monetary Stance, Various Alternative VARs q1 1990q1 1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1 2015q1 Quarter Federal Funds Rate State Estimate, With Govt. Spending State Estimate, Inflation Ordered First in VAR Filtered State Estimate (+/- 1 RMSE) State Estimate, 2 Lags VAR coefficients estimated using 1984Q1-2008:Q3 data, 1 lag. z t = z t 1 + u z,t (6) The state equation now contains no estimated parameters, and agnostically treats an increase or decrease in the federal funds rate as equally likely in each quarter. The measurement equations remain the same as in the benchmark estimation. Figure 5 reveals that the state estimate dynamics are largely unchanged, meaning that the precise structure of the state equation is not crucial for estimation of the shadow rate. However, the random walk formulation does imply somewhat less accommodation overall, and especially less in level terms in 2009 and Model Cross-Validation If the VAR models are accurately capturing the dynamics of the system, one should be able to estimate them with a shorter time series, and show that the federal funds 11

12 Figure 5: Implied Monetary Stance, Other Checks q1 1990q1 1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1 2015q1 Quarter Federal Funds Rate Baseline Filtered State Estimate (+/- 1 RMSE) State Estimate with Random Walk rate is correctly predicted out-of-sample. 8 Figure 6 presents the shadow rate estimation process using a VAR estimated from 1984Q1-2002:Q1. In-sample, the estimation once again closely recovers the federal funds rate, and lies within the bounds of the benchmark estimation standard error bands. More importantly, the out-of-sample results also recover the federal funds rate during which it is observed, and in addition, the ELB period estimate is characterized by similar dynamics. While Figure 6 uses VAR parameters estimated through 2002:Q1, we can repeat this process for many endpoints. Figure 7 presents the out-of-sample states estimated with VARs from 1984:Q1 to 2001:Q2, sequentially adding one quarter to the end date at a time, until the benchmark VAR estimated through 2008:Q3. Figure 8 repeats this process, but presents the smoothed estimates. In all cases, the methodology recovers the federal funds rate closely both in- and out-of-sample. Likewise, the state estimates during the effective bound period indicate the unconventional policy gave the economy under zero 8 Note that we use out-of-sample testing to verify our approach, not for model selection, which could be problematic Hirano and Wright (2013). 12

13 Figure 6: Implied Monetary Stance, Out-of-Sample Results, VAR coefficients 1984Q1-2002:Q q1 1990q1 1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1 2015q1 Quarter Federal Funds Rate Filtered State Estimate (+/- 1 RMSE from Benchmark Estimation) Out-of-sample beginning at first red line, second red line denotes start of effective lower bound. properties. 9 9 In the Appendix, we present similar exercises where the VARs are estimated using post-1990 data, and estimated out-of-sample in the 1980s. 13

14 Figure 7: Implied Monetary Stance, Filtered Out-of-Sample Forecasts Iterated Forward q1 1990q1 1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1 2015q1 Quarter Blue line: federal funds rate. Red lines: out-of-sample state estimates. Dashed black lines: 1984Q1-2008:Q3 state estimate 1 standard error band. Figure 8: Implied Monetary Stance, Smoothed Out-of-Sample Forecasts Iterated Forward q1 1990q1 1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1 2015q1 Quarter Blue line: federal funds rate. Red lines: out-of-sample state estimates. Dashed black lines: 1984Q1-2008:Q3 state estimate 1 standard error band. 14

15 4.4 Tests of Parameter Stability A concern regarding our methodology is that structural change occurred following 2008:Q3. We have assumed that a parsimonious VAR model from before the effective lower bound period can accurately describe dynamics during the effective bound. This could be problematic if, for example, the persistence of GDP decreased following the crisis. We would then find a sequence of contractionary shocks to GDP, as GDP realizations would be lower than the VAR predictions. The filter would then erroneously attribute these contractionary GDP shocks to contractionary monetary policy, and then estimate a more positive shadow rate Explicit Tests Aastveit et al. (2016) find in a 4-variable VAR that the GDP and inflation equations do not suffer from much instability through the crisis, while the unemployment rate and interest rate parameters do seem to have shifted. The interest rate equation would be expected to have time variation at the ELB due to the ELB constraint. As an explanation for the unemployment parameters shifting, it is known that the unemployment rate has overstated the strength of the labor market during the recovery, as the labor force participation rate has been low by historical standards (Kroft et al., 2016). Since we have used data from Smets and Wouters (2007), we fortunately do not use the unemployment rate in our estimation. We test explicitly for parameter instability in our sample through the following thought experiment: if one were to randomly test if a thirty one quarter period was structurally different during the Great Moderation, what are the chances that one would get a distribution of parameters as extreme as the ones from during the effective lower bound? 10 To this end, we estimate sequential VARs over thirty one quarters from 1984:Q1 through 10 We choose thirty one quarters, as this is the length of the observed sample during the ELB. 15

16 2001:Q1. The last start date for the thirty one quarter VAR sample, 2001:Q1, is chosen such that the sample ends before the ELB. Figure 9 plots the kernel density distributions of the estimated parameters with red lines for the ELB parameter estimates. The parameters during the ELB are very similar to pre-elb parameters, and lie plausibly within the pre-elb VAR parameter distributions. The parameters that are visibly different are the estimates of lagged interest rate coefficients. In Figure 10, we present rolling estimates of the lagged interest rate parameters. The VAR coefficients using data from the ELB are very extreme in comparison to the pre-elb sample. This is intuitive: if unconventional policy had significant effects, a federal funds rate of zero does not adequately describe the stance of policy. A VAR estimated with just the federal funds rate would then find very biased effects of the federal funds rate during the zero bound, as it would be measuring a policy instrument with a much tighter stance than that realized. We thus present blue dashed lines indicating VAR parameters estimated over the ELB data using the estimated shadow rate in the kernel density estimates of Figure 9. Validating our hypothesis regarding the bias of the federal funds rate as a stance of policy, the lagged interest rate parameters using the estimated benchmark shadow rate are much more consistent with the pre-elb distribution. It is important to remember that this is not a result of the state-space model maximizing these parameters. The Kalman filter maximizes the forecasts of the measurement series. In order to get a last sense of how the distribution of parameters during the ELB compares to the in-sample thirty one quarter estimated VARs, we present Figure 11. Each line connects the standardized parameters, ordered from smallest to largest, from each VAR estimated over thirty one quarters beginning 1984:Q1 to 2001:Q1. 11 We exclude 11 The parameters are standardized with respect to equivalent parameters estimated in each VAR. For example, every estimate of the constant for output is standardized with respect to all VAR estimates of that parameter. 16

17 Figure 9: Kernel Density Estimates of VAR Parameters, from Thirty One Quarters Sampled 1984:Q1-2008:Q3, Compared to ELB Parameters output_l_output output_l_consumption output_l_investment output_l_realwage output_l_hours output_l_inflation output_l_interestrate output_constant consumption_l_output consumption_l_consumption consumption_l_investment consumption_l_realwage consumption_l_hours consumption_l_inflation consumption_l_interestrate consumption_constant investment_l_output investment_l_consumption investment_l_investment investment_l_realwage investment_l_hours investment_l_inflation investment_l_interestrate investment_constant realwage_l_output realwage_l_consumption realwage_l_investment realwage_l_realwage realwage_l_hours realwage_l_inflation realwage_l_interestrate realwage_constant hours_l_output hours_l_consumption hours_l_investment hours_l_realwage hours_l_hours hours_l_inflation hours_l_interestrate hours_constant inflation_l_output inflation_l_consumption inflation_l_investment inflation_l_realwage inflation_l_hours inflation_l_inflation inflation_l_interestrate inflation_constant interestrate_l_output interestrate_l_consumption interestrate_l_investment interestrate_l_realwage interestrate_l_hours interestrate_l_inflation interestrate_l_interestrate interestrate_constant The x-axes denote parameter estimates from sequential VARs estimated over thirty one quarters from 1984:Q1-2008:Q3. The y-axes denote density. The red lines indicate parameters from a VAR estimated over 2008:Q4-2016:Q2, while the blue dashed lines indicate the same VAR estimated with the benchmark shadow rate in place of the federal funds rate. 17

18 Figure 10: Parameter Stability of Lagged Interest Rate Coefficient: Parameter Estimates from Thirty One Quarter Rolling VARs q1 1990q1 1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1 Quarter Federal Funds Rate Hours Investment Output Inflation Real Wage Consumption This figure presents the lagged interest rate coefficient on each variable over rolling thirty one quarter VAR samples from 1984:Q1-2016:Q2. Each point indicates the parameter over a VAR beginning at that date. 18

19 lagged interest rate predictors, as these were shown to be biased. Figure 11: Distribution of Standardized Parameters: Rolling Thirty One Quarter VAR Samples Standardized Coefficient Ordinal Rank The x-axes denotes the ranking of each standardized parameter from most negative to most positive, excluding lagged interest rate parameters. Each blue line is a separate VAR estimated over a thirty one quarter period between 1984:Q1 and 2008:Q3. The dashed red line is the distribution of standardized coefficients from a VAR estimated from 2008:Q4 to 2016:Q2. Visually, the ELB parameters fall for the most part in the middle of the distribution. Closer to the tails, there do seem to be some parameters that are more extreme at the ELB, however, there are still other VAR samples that have as extreme or more extreme parameters at every point. We present parameters ranked greater than 1.65 standard deviations from the mean in the ELB sample in Table As shown, the most extreme parameters are those governing the investment, real wage, and inflation predictions. If these parameters changed significantly following the crisis, the forecasts of these 12 Note that the parameters from the thirty one quarter VARs have heavier tales than would be expected from a normal distribution. 19

20 Table 1: ELB Parameters Greater than 1.65 Standard Deviations from Respective Means Parameter Z-Score Investment, Lagged Consumption 2.36 Investment, Lagged Hours Investment, Lagged Real Wage Investment Constant 2.17 Real Wage, Lagged Consumption 2.95 Real Wage, Lagged Hours Real Wage, Lagged Inflation Inflation, Lagged Inflation 2.16 Inflation, Lagged Hours time series, and hence the measurement equations, will result in less accurate estimates of the federal funds rate as an unobserved variable when the pre-elb VAR is used for the ELB. In order to gauge the influence of these series on the shadow rate estimation, we present Figure 12. This chart plots the estimated shadow rates when we exclude these series one at a time from the measurement equations. This prevents any potentially structurally changed parameters from influencing the estimation process. The estimated shadow rate is fairly similar to the benchmark shadow rate regardless of which series is excluded. Since the shadow rate is measured from each of the six time series, the few parameters that show evidence of structural change are not important enough to change the estimated shadow rate. The one exception is that while excluding investment, the shadow rate is slightly more negative before However, the estimate is still well within the confidence bounds of the benchmark shadow rate. In conclusion, a thorough evaluation of the VAR shows that parameter stability is not an issue in the implementation of our shadow rate Forecast Evaluation One further way to test for parameter instability is to evaluate the forecast performance of a model during the time in which it is thought that the parameters have changed. If 20

21 Figure 12: Implied Monetary Stance, Excluding Series From Measurement Equations q1 1990q1 1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1 2015q1 Quarter Federal Funds Rate Excluding Inflation Benchmark State Estimate (+/- 1 RMSE) Excluding Investment Excluding Real Wages Shadow rate estimates when excluding selected series from the measurement equations one at a time. The series excluded each have at least one parameter at a tail of the distribution in Figure 11 greater than 2 standard deviations from the mean. 21

22 the model is not a good characterization of the data during that time, the out-of-sample forecast errors will be larger than in-sample forecast residuals. Even if some parameters change, it could be the case that these parameters are not influential for model dynamics, and thus that the forecast accuracy of the model could be relatively unaffected. As shown in Table 2, the in-sample one-step ahead forecast errors (Column a) are largely comparable to the one-step ahead forecast residuals from after the crisis (Columns c and d). 13 The mean absolute forecast error is within one standard deviation of forecast residuals for every variable in the VAR. 14 This means that following the crisis, the VAR predictions still forecast relatively well, meaning that the model is likely to provide similarly accurate estimates of the effective federal funds rate as before the crisis. In addition, it is notable that the mean errors of many of the series are relatively small in an economic sense. For example, the forecasts of output and consumption are on average less than 0.5 percentage points from actual values. Note that we use the estimated shadow rate in lieu of the federal funds rate following 2008:Q3, in order not to bias our forecast errors by assuming unconventional policy had no effect. We also also present a placebo test, in Column (b), where we compare out-of-sample forecast errors from before the crisis with out-of-sample forecast errors during the effective bound. This exercise is based on the following logic: using out-of-sample testing, it is clear that our methodology captures the federal funds rate well during periods when it is observed. In particular, Figure 6 showed that the federal funds rate is adequately captured out-of-sample following 2002:Q1 using VARs estimated from 1984:Q1-2002:Q1. If out-of-sample forecast errors during that time are no larger than forecast errors during the effective bound, this provides evidence that our VAR parameters are also adequately 13 We present Column (d) for reference, which omits the 2008:Q4 residual, because that quarter is characterized by unprecedented shocks due to the financial crisis that are difficult to capture with a statistical model. A regime-shifting VAR would be best for this quarter, but there exists no comparable post-war data to estimate such a model on. 14 We use mean absolute forecast errors since larger shocks during the crisis, as found by Stock and Watson (2012), would necessarily imply greater mean squared errors during the ELB sample regardless of model stability. 22

23 Table 2: VAR Mean Absolute Forecast Accuracy (a) (b) (c) (d) Forecast Residuals Forecast Errors Forecast Errors Forecast Errors Pre-2008:Q4 2002:Q2-2008:Q3 Post-2008:Q3 Post-2008:Q4 Output (0.297) (0.240) (0.437) (0.238) Consumption (0.251) (0.224) (0.376) (0.329) Investment (0.758) (0.871) (1.35) (1.033) Real Wage (0.427) (0.440) (0.824) Hours (0.260) (0.260) (0.404) (0.362) Inflation (0.114) (0.254) (0.167) (0.128) Observations Mean one-step ahead forecast errors/residuals, standard deviations in parentheses. Column (a) denotes in-sample forecast residuals from a VAR estimated from 1984:Q1-2008:Q3. Column (b) denotes out-of-sample forecast errors from a VAR estimated from 1984:Q1-2002:Q1. Column (c) denotes out-of-sample forecast errors from a VAR estimated from 1984:Q1-2008:Q3. For comparison, Column (d) repeats Column (c), but does not include the error from 2008:Q4. capturing dynamics when the effective stance of monetary policy is unobserved. Column (b) presents forecast errors from 2002:Q2-2008:Q3 using VAR predictions from 1984:Q1-2002:Q1 and using the estimated out-of-sample shadow rate from the 1984:Q1-2002:Q1 VAR predictions. Comparing Column (b) with Columns (c) and (d) shows that the effective bound forecast errors compare well to the out-of-sample forecast errors during a time which we know that the methodology adequately recovers estimates of the federal funds rate. While the output, consumption and investment equations have slightly larger forecast errors, the real wage, hours, and inflation equations have smaller forecast errors Full-Sample Estimation As a final check, a bound on our benchmark results is presented in Figure 13 where we estimate the VAR over the whole sample (1984:Q1-2016:Q2), including the effective bound 23

24 period. 15 The resulting state estimate is now a result of parameters partly estimated during the effective bound, which assuages concern about structural change. On the other hand, this also introduces a very large bias in the results: the parameters are fit in order to minimize deviations from predictions where the stance of monetary policy is set to a federal funds rate of essentially zero during the effective bound period. The VAR parameters are thus heavily biased against finding an effect of unconventional policy, and also cause extreme bias in the measures of monetary shocks from before the effective bound. Nonetheless, the full sample VAR parameters still result in a state estimate that lies within the benchmark estimate confidence interval, and still result in monetary accommodation in excess of an effective federal funds rate of zero, though less accommodation than in the benchmark estimation. The full sample state estimate also depicts similar dynamics. Figure 13 also presents a second variation of the full sample VAR state estimate using a random walk reformulation of the state equation, as in Section 4.2. By imposing a random walk rather than using estimated parameters, we do not bias the state estimates with a reaction function predicting a federal funds rate of zero at the ELB. The state equation is especially problematic at the ELB as the persistence of the federal funds rate will be biased by a period of an unchanging interest rate that is unlikely without the ELB constraint. The random walk reformulation results in a state estimate that is more accommodative than the state estimate with estimated parameters in the state equation. The shadow rate troughs just 1 percent less negative than the baseline estimate. Overall, the full sample estimation procedures provide important evidence that a federal funds rate of zero did not capture the effects of policy during the ELB, meaning that unconventional policy had significant effects. Biased estimation procedures still result in shadow rate troughing 15 It is not possible to estimate a shadow rate over only the ELB, as there are too few observations. Even if it were possible to use only ELB VAR parameters, the bias of using well-measured parameters from before the ELB could be preferable to the increase in variance from such a a small sample (see Clark and McCracken (2009)). 24

25 below a -1 percent stance of policy. Figure 13: Implied Monetary Stance, Full Sample Results q1 1990q1 1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1 2015q1 Quarter Federal Funds Rate Filtered State Estimate (+/- 1 RMSE) State Estimate with Full Sample Estimation State Estimate with Full Sample Estimation and Random Walk 5 Implications 5.1 The Large-Scale Asset Purchase Programs As the validity of the estimation has been established, the estimates can be used to answer questions about policy effectiveness. Figure 14 presents the benchmark results from Figure 1, shown following 2006, and plots vertical lines for the announcements and implementations of the three large-scale asset purchase programs (henceforth, Quantitative Easings). As evidence for the effectiveness of the QE policies, we observe that the estimated shadow rate decreases immediately during the quarter that each of those programs were implemented While we loosely attribute decreases in our shadow rate to the QE programs, the Federal Reserve also implemented many other programs during this time period, such as the Term Auction Facility during QE 1. 25

26 In our estimation, QE1 and QE2 seem to have had a large effect, while QE3 less so. QE1 seems to have immediately decreased the effective interest rate environment, which is plausible given that it helped to unfreeze credit markets. While our baseline shadow rate decreases the quarter before the announcement of QE2, that program was widely anticipated by market participants. 17 This points to important signaling effects of policy. Figure 1 presents the shadow rate of Lombardi and Zhu (2014) for comparison. Our shadow rate exhibits strong comovoment with that of Lombardi-Zhu. This is interesting given the very different methodologies and underlying data of our measures. The Lombardi-Zhu shadow rate is derived from yields, monetary aggregates, and Federal Reserve balance sheet items. The fact that the two shadow rates are characterized by such similar dynamics is comforting in that it indicates that changes in the policy instruments of the Federal Reserve, as measured by Lombardi-Zhu, are mirrored by changes in policy effects, as measured by our shadow rate. Both our shadow rate and that of Lombardi and Zhu (2014) indicate quite different effects of unconventional policy than that of Wu and Xia (2016). It would seem that Wu- Xia s use of no-arbitrage restrictions, and focus on yields, imply very different shadow rate dynamics. In contrast, our results are determined by the levels of real activity in the six VAR measurement equations. In principle, these two shadow rate methodologies could result in very different values. For example, if the transmission from financial conditions to real activity was impaired, the size of the Federal Reserve s balance sheet and the size of unconventional monetary policy s real effects would not have to be correlated. While the Wu-Xia shadow rate is correlated with the size of the Federal Reserve s balance sheet, our shadow rate depicts immediate and visible effects of the large-scale asset purchase programs, pointing to strong flow or signaling rather than stock effects. One caveat to these comparisons, however, is that our standard error bands encompass the Wu-Xia 17 See an Op-ed by Ben Bernanke in the Washington Post at that time ( 26

27 shadow rate. Figure 14: Effects of Quantitative Easing q1 2008q1 2010q1 2012q1 2014q1 2016q1 Quarter Federal Funds Rate Filtered State Estimate (+/- 1 RMSE) Wu-Xia Lombardi-Zhu The red lines denote the starts of QE1, QE2, and QE How Reasonable are the Estimates? Our shadow rate methodology indicates that the QE programs had a maximum effect equivalent to approximately a -3 to -4 percent federal funds rate during the peak effects of QEs 1 and 2. Though these estimates are fairly uncertain, are they reasonable? Previous research (Chung et al., 2012) has found that a 100 basis point change in the federal funds rate tends to be associated with about a 25 basis point change in 10-year Treasury yields. Likewise, it has been widely estimated that the QE programs lowered 10-year yields by about 60 to 100 basis points during QE 1, and a further 20 basis points during QE 2 (Chung et al., 2012; Li and Wei, 2013). Thus, our estimates of the implied stance of policy are consistent with the previous estimates of the effects of QE on long- 27

28 term yields. The basis point change in long-term yields following QE 1 would typically be associated with the magnitude of the large decrease in the monetary stance that we observe, on the order of 4 percent below zero. Likewise, our 1-2 percent change in the shadow rate following QE 2 would be within the spectrum of estimates associated with a 20 bp change in 10-year Treasuries from that program. Finally, our shadow rate also takes into account the effects of forward guidance, meaning that it is sensible that our estimates would be more accommodative than that suggested by the QE programs alone. 6 Conclusion This paper provides new estimates of unconventional monetary policy s real effects by creating a shadow rate inferred directly from real economic activity. We show that a simple VAR model indicates that monetary policy was more accommodative than a federal funds rate of zero would imply. Our relatively simple framework provides direct visual evidence of beneficial effects from the three major quantitative easing programs. We are confident that our results accurately capture the dynamics and broad magnitudes of unconventional monetary policy s real effects. Our methodology forecasts the federal funds rate correctly out-of-sample before the ELB. After the ELB, we show that our VAR accurately forecasts variables other than the federal funds rate. Finally, explicit evaluation of the ELB VAR parameters shows that they are drawn from a similar distribution as parameters from the Great Moderation. The one exception we find is that the parameters governing interest rate effects on other variables are highly biased when not incorporating the shadow rate as the stance of policy. On the technical front, our approach to estimating the effect of unconventional policy as an unobserved variable could be extended. Estimation could incorporate time-varying volatility and Bayesian estimation of parameters, which would allow for longer lag lengths 28

29 and possibly more sophisticated estimation of parameters at the effective bound. Another possibility would be to incorporate a larger number of real variables affected by the federal funds rate subject to optimal information criteria. We leave these extensions to future work. 29

30 References Aastveit, K. A., Carriero, A., Clark, T. E., and Marcellino, M. (2016). Have standard vars remained stable since the crisis? Journal of Applied Econometrics. Caldara, D. and Herbst, E. (2016). Monetary policy, real activity, and credit spreads: Evidence from bayesian proxy svars. Christensen, J. H., Rudebusch, G. D., et al. (2013). Modeling yields at the zero lower bound: Are shadow rates the solution? Citeseer. Chung, H., Laforte, J.-p., Reifschneider, D., and Williams, J. C. (2012). Have we underestimated the likelihood and severity of zero lower bound events? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 44(s1): Clark, T. E. and McCracken, M. W. (2009). Improving forecast accuracy by combining recursive and rolling forecasts. International Economic Review, 50(2): Coenen, G. and Straub, R. (2005). Does government spending crowd in private consumption? theory and empirical evidence for the euro area. International Finance, 8(3): Coenen, G., Straub, R., and Trabandt, M. (2013). Gauging the effects of fiscal stimulus packages in the euro area. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 37(2): Gagnon, J. E. et al. (2016). Quantitative easing: An underappreciated success. Technical report. Gust, C. J., Lopez-Salido, J. D., Smith, M. E., Herbst, E., et al. (2016). The empirical implications of the interest-rate lower bound. Technical report, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (US). Hirano, K. and Wright, J. H. (2013). Forecasting with model uncertainty: Representations and risk reduction. House, C. L., Proebsting, C., and Tesar, L. L. (2017). Austerity in the aftermath of the great recession. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research. Ivanov, V. and Kilian, L. (2005). A practitioner s guide to lag order selection for var impulse response analysis. Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, 9(1):1 34. Johannsen, B. K. and Mertens, E. (2016). A time series model of interest rates with the effective lower bound. Krippner, L. (2013). Measuring the stance of monetary policy in zero lower bound environments. Economics Letters, 118(1):

31 Kroft, K., Lange, F., Notowidigdo, M. J., and Katz, L. F. (2016). Long-term unemployment and the great recession: the role of composition, duration dependence, and nonparticipation. Journal of Labor Economics, 34(S1):S7 S54. Li, C. and Wei, M. (2013). Term structure modeling with supply factors and the federal reserve s large-scale asset purchase progarms. International Journal of Central Banking, 9(1):3 39. Lombardi, M. J. and Zhu, F. (2014). A shadow policy rate to calibrate us monetary policy at the zero lower bound. Ng, S. and Wright, J. H. (2013). Facts and challenges from the recession for forecasting and macroeconomic modeling. Journal of Economic Literature, 51(4): Skaperdas, A. (2016). How effective is monetary policy at the zero lower bound? identification through industry heterogeneity. SSRN working paper. Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2007). Shocks and frictions in us business cycles: A bayesian dsge approach. The American Economic Review, 97(3): Stock, J. H. and Watson, M. W. (2012). Disentangling the channels of the recession. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Spring Swanson, E. T. (2017). Measuring the effects of federal reserve forward guidance and asset purchases on financial markets. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research. Wu, J. C. and Xia, F. D. (2016). Measuring the macroeconomic impact of monetary policy at the zero lower bound. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 48(2-3):

32 Appendix Figure 1: Implied Monetary Stance, Filtered Out-of-Sample Forecasts Iterated Backwards q1 1990q1 1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1 2015q1 Quarter Blue line: federal funds rate. Red lines: out-of-sample state estimates. Dashed black lines: 1984Q1-2008:Q3 state estimate 1 standard error band. 32

33 Figure 2: Implied Monetary Stance, Smoothed Out-of-Sample Forecasts Iterated Backwards q1 1990q1 1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1 2015q1 Quarter Blue line: federal funds rate. Red lines: out-of-sample state estimates. Dashed black lines: 1984Q1-2008:Q3 state estimate 1 standard error band. 33

Inferring the Shadow Rate from Real Activity

Inferring the Shadow Rate from Real Activity Inferring the Shadow Rate from Real Activity Benjamín García Arsenios Skaperdas June 26, 2018 Abstract We estimate a shadow rate consistent with the paths of time series capturing real activity. This allows

More information

Have We Underestimated the Likelihood and Severity of Zero Lower Bound Events?

Have We Underestimated the Likelihood and Severity of Zero Lower Bound Events? Have We Underestimated the Likelihood and Severity of Zero Lower Bound Events? Hess Chung, Jean Philippe Laforte, David Reifschneider, and John C. Williams 19th Annual Symposium of the Society for Nonlinear

More information

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle: Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia May 31, 214 Midwest Macro Conference Raju Huidrom Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle Background

More information

THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH

THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH South-Eastern Europe Journal of Economics 1 (2015) 75-84 THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH IOANA BOICIUC * Bucharest University of Economics, Romania Abstract This

More information

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies James Morley University of New South Wales 1. Introduction Garnier, Mertens, and Nelson (this issue, GMN hereafter) conduct model-based trend/cycle decomposition

More information

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes Syed M. Hussain Samreen Malik May 9,. Online Appendix.. Anticipated versus Unanticipated Tax changes Comparing our estimates with the estimates

More information

Online Appendixes to Missing Disinflation and Missing Inflation: A VAR Perspective

Online Appendixes to Missing Disinflation and Missing Inflation: A VAR Perspective Online Appendixes to Missing Disinflation and Missing Inflation: A VAR Perspective Elena Bobeica and Marek Jarociński European Central Bank Author e-mails: elena.bobeica@ecb.int and marek.jarocinski@ecb.int.

More information

WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM

WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM RAY C. FAIR This paper uses a structural multi-country macroeconometric model to estimate the size of the decrease in transfer payments (or tax

More information

Bank Lending Shocks and the Euro Area Business Cycle

Bank Lending Shocks and the Euro Area Business Cycle Bank Lending Shocks and the Euro Area Business Cycle Gert Peersman Ghent University Motivation SVAR framework to examine macro consequences of disturbances specific to bank lending market in euro area

More information

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s As part of its monetary policy strategy, the ECB regularly monitors the development of a wide range of indicators and assesses their implications

More information

Discussion of Beetsma et al. s The Confidence Channel of Fiscal Consolidation. Lutz Kilian University of Michigan CEPR

Discussion of Beetsma et al. s The Confidence Channel of Fiscal Consolidation. Lutz Kilian University of Michigan CEPR Discussion of Beetsma et al. s The Confidence Channel of Fiscal Consolidation Lutz Kilian University of Michigan CEPR Fiscal consolidation involves a retrenchment of government expenditures and/or the

More information

3. Measuring the Effect of Monetary Policy

3. Measuring the Effect of Monetary Policy 3. Measuring the Effect of Monetary Policy Here we analyse the effect of monetary policy in Japan using the structural VARs estimated in Section 2. We take the block-recursive model with domestic WPI for

More information

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis Jan Kuckuck and Frank Westermann Working Paper 96 June 213 INSTITUTE OF EMPIRICAL ECONOMIC RESEARCH Osnabrück University Rolandstraße 8 4969

More information

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves issn 1936-5330 Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves Brent Bundick Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City First Version: October 2007 This Version: June 2008 RWP 07-08 Abstract Piazzesi and Swanson

More information

Journal of Economics and Financial Analysis, Vol:1, No:1 (2017) 1-13

Journal of Economics and Financial Analysis, Vol:1, No:1 (2017) 1-13 Journal of Economics and Financial Analysis, Vol:1, No:1 (2017) 1-13 Journal of Economics and Financial Analysis Type: Double Blind Peer Reviewed Scientific Journal Printed ISSN: 2521-6627 Online ISSN:

More information

Márcio G. P. Garcia PUC-Rio Brazil Visiting Scholar, Sloan School, MIT and NBER. This paper aims at quantitatively evaluating two questions:

Márcio G. P. Garcia PUC-Rio Brazil Visiting Scholar, Sloan School, MIT and NBER. This paper aims at quantitatively evaluating two questions: Discussion of Unconventional Monetary Policy and the Great Recession: Estimating the Macroeconomic Effects of a Spread Compression at the Zero Lower Bound Márcio G. P. Garcia PUC-Rio Brazil Visiting Scholar,

More information

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom Gaétan Stephan 1 University of Rennes 1, CREM April 2012 (Preliminary draft) Abstract We model the relation between output

More information

The Response of Asset Prices to Unconventional Monetary Policy

The Response of Asset Prices to Unconventional Monetary Policy The Response of Asset Prices to Unconventional Monetary Policy Alexander Kurov and Raluca Stan * Abstract This paper investigates the impact of US unconventional monetary policy on asset prices at the

More information

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment International Journal of Business and Economics, 2002, Vol. 1, No. 1, 59-67 Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment Rosemary Rossiter * Department of Economics, Ohio University,

More information

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle Antonio Conti January 21, 2010 Abstract While New Keynesian models label money redundant in shaping business cycle, monetary aggregates

More information

Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan

Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan The US recession that began in late 2007 had significant spillover effects to the rest

More information

Web Appendix. Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? Olivier Coibion

Web Appendix. Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? Olivier Coibion Web Appendix Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? Olivier Coibion Appendix 1: Description of the Model-Averaging Procedure This section describes the model-averaging procedure used in

More information

Discussion of DSGE Models for Monetary Policy. Discussion of

Discussion of DSGE Models for Monetary Policy. Discussion of ECB Conference Key developments in monetary economics Frankfurt, October 29-30, 2009 Discussion of DSGE Models for Monetary Policy by L. L. Christiano, M. Trabandt & K. Walentin Volker Wieland Goethe University

More information

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description Carlos de Resende, Ali Dib, and Nikita Perevalov International Economic Analysis Department

More information

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY Alan J. Auerbach and Yuriy Gorodnichenko University of California, Berkeley January 2013 In this paper, we estimate the cross-country spillover effects of government

More information

Effects of US Monetary Policy Shocks During Financial Crises - A Threshold Vector Autoregression Approach

Effects of US Monetary Policy Shocks During Financial Crises - A Threshold Vector Autoregression Approach Crawford School of Public Policy CAMA Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis Effects of US Monetary Policy Shocks During Financial Crises - A Threshold Vector Autoregression Approach CAMA Working Paper

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve Jordi Galí, Mark Gertler and J. David López-Salido Preliminary draft, June 2001 Abstract Galí and Gertler (1999) developed a hybrid

More information

Working Paper Series. How Has Empirical Monetary Policy Analysis Changed After the Financial Crisis?

Working Paper Series. How Has Empirical Monetary Policy Analysis Changed After the Financial Crisis? RESEARCH DIVISION Working Paper Series How Has Empirical Monetary Policy Analysis Changed After the Financial Crisis? Neville R. Francis Laura E. Jackson and Michael T. Owyang Working Paper 2014-019C https://doi.org/10.20955/wp.2014.019

More information

Demographics and the behavior of interest rates

Demographics and the behavior of interest rates Demographics and the behavior of interest rates (C. Favero, A. Gozluklu and H. Yang) Discussion by Michele Lenza European Central Bank and ECARES-ULB Firenze 18-19 June 2015 Rubric Persistence in interest

More information

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios Amit Goyal Goizueta Business School Emory University Ivo Welch Yale School of Management Yale Economics Department NBER December 16, 2003 Abstract This

More information

Quantity versus Price Rationing of Credit: An Empirical Test

Quantity versus Price Rationing of Credit: An Empirical Test Int. J. Financ. Stud. 213, 1, 45 53; doi:1.339/ijfs1345 Article OPEN ACCESS International Journal of Financial Studies ISSN 2227-772 www.mdpi.com/journal/ijfs Quantity versus Price Rationing of Credit:

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

LECTURE 11 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. November 2, 2016

LECTURE 11 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. November 2, 2016 Economics 210c/236a Fall 2016 Christina Romer David Romer LECTURE 11 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing November 2, 2016 I. OVERVIEW Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Expectations

More information

Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University

Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University Business School Seminars at University of Cape Town

More information

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2016 Karl Whelan (UCD) VAR Studies Spring 2016 1 / 23 Examples of VAR Studies We will look at four different

More information

Transmission in India:

Transmission in India: Asymmetry in Monetary Policy Transmission in India: Aggregate and Sectoral Analysis Brajamohan Misra Officer in Charge Department of Economic and Policy Research Reserve Bank of India VI Meeting of Open

More information

Identifying of the fiscal policy shocks

Identifying of the fiscal policy shocks The Academy of Economic Studies Bucharest Doctoral School of Finance and Banking Identifying of the fiscal policy shocks Coordinator LEC. UNIV. DR. BOGDAN COZMÂNCĂ MSC Student Andreea Alina Matache Dissertation

More information

Unconventional Monetary Policy and the Great Recession:

Unconventional Monetary Policy and the Great Recession: Unconventional Monetary Policy and the Great Recession: Estimating the Macroeconomic Effects of a Spread Compression at the Zero Lower Bound Christiane Baumeister Luca Benati Bank of Canada University

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

The bank lending channel in monetary transmission in the euro area:

The bank lending channel in monetary transmission in the euro area: The bank lending channel in monetary transmission in the euro area: evidence from Bayesian VAR analysis Matteo Bondesan Graduate student University of Turin (M.Sc. in Economics) Collegio Carlo Alberto

More information

How do Macroeconomic Shocks affect Expectations? Lessons from Survey Data

How do Macroeconomic Shocks affect Expectations? Lessons from Survey Data How do Macroeconomic Shocks affect Expectations? Lessons from Survey Data Martin Geiger Johann Scharler Preliminary Version March 6 Abstract We study the revision of macroeconomic expectations due to aggregate

More information

A Markov switching regime model of the South African business cycle

A Markov switching regime model of the South African business cycle A Markov switching regime model of the South African business cycle Elna Moolman Abstract Linear models are incapable of capturing business cycle asymmetries. This has recently spurred interest in non-linear

More information

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance

Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy. Pairwise Tests of Equality of Forecasting Performance Online Appendix to Bond Return Predictability: Economic Value and Links to the Macroeconomy This online appendix is divided into four sections. In section A we perform pairwise tests aiming at disentangling

More information

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk Frank Schorfheide University of Pennsylvania, CEPR, NBER, PIER March 2018 Pushing the Frontier of Central Bank s Macro Modeling Preliminaries This paper

More information

EC910 Econometrics B. Exchange Rate Pass-Through and Inflation Dynamics in. the United Kingdom: VAR analysis of Exchange Rate.

EC910 Econometrics B. Exchange Rate Pass-Through and Inflation Dynamics in. the United Kingdom: VAR analysis of Exchange Rate. EC910 Econometrics B Exchange Rate Pass-Through and Inflation Dynamics in the United Kingdom: VAR analysis of Exchange Rate Pass-Through 0910249 Department of Economics The University of Warwick Abstract

More information

News and Monetary Shocks at a High Frequency: A Simple Approach

News and Monetary Shocks at a High Frequency: A Simple Approach WP/14/167 News and Monetary Shocks at a High Frequency: A Simple Approach Troy Matheson and Emil Stavrev 2014 International Monetary Fund WP/14/167 IMF Working Paper Research Department News and Monetary

More information

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU Tatjana Dahlhaus Danilo Leiva-Leon November 7, VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper assesses the effect of monetary policy during

More information

Macroeconometric Modeling: 2018

Macroeconometric Modeling: 2018 Macroeconometric Modeling: 2018 Contents Ray C. Fair 2018 1 Macroeconomic Methodology 4 1.1 The Cowles Commission Approach................. 4 1.2 Macroeconomic Methodology.................... 5 1.3 The

More information

The Effects of Fiscal Policy: Evidence from Italy

The Effects of Fiscal Policy: Evidence from Italy The Effects of Fiscal Policy: Evidence from Italy T. Ferraresi Irpet INFORUM 2016 Onasbrück August 29th - September 2nd Tommaso Ferraresi (Irpet) Fiscal policy in Italy INFORUM 2016 1 / 17 Motivations

More information

BANK OF CANADA RENEWAL OF BACKGROUND INFORMATION THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET. May 2001

BANK OF CANADA RENEWAL OF BACKGROUND INFORMATION THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET. May 2001 BANK OF CANADA May RENEWAL OF THE INFLATION-CONTROL TARGET BACKGROUND INFORMATION Bank of Canada Wellington Street Ottawa, Ontario KA G9 78 ISBN: --89- Printed in Canada on recycled paper B A N K O F C

More information

Uncertainty and the Transmission of Fiscal Policy

Uncertainty and the Transmission of Fiscal Policy Available online at www.sciencedirect.com ScienceDirect Procedia Economics and Finance 32 ( 2015 ) 769 776 Emerging Markets Queries in Finance and Business EMQFB2014 Uncertainty and the Transmission of

More information

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation" Valerie A. Ramey University of California, San Diego and NBER June 30, 2011 Abstract This brief note challenges

More information

UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES

UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES UCD CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES 2006 Measuring the NAIRU A Structural VAR Approach Vincent Hogan and Hongmei Zhao, University College Dublin WP06/17 November 2006 UCD SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS

More information

An EM-Algorithm for Maximum-Likelihood Estimation of Mixed Frequency VARs

An EM-Algorithm for Maximum-Likelihood Estimation of Mixed Frequency VARs An EM-Algorithm for Maximum-Likelihood Estimation of Mixed Frequency VARs Jürgen Antony, Pforzheim Business School and Torben Klarl, Augsburg University EEA 2016, Geneva Introduction frequent problem in

More information

The link between labor costs and price inflation in the euro area

The link between labor costs and price inflation in the euro area The link between labor costs and price inflation in the euro area E. Bobeica M. Ciccarelli I. Vansteenkiste European Central Bank* Paper prepared for the XXII Annual Conference, Central Bank of Chile Santiago,

More information

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions By DAVID BERGER AND JOSEPH VAVRA How big are government spending multipliers? A recent litererature has argued that while

More information

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation?

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation? 2011 年 2 月第十四卷一期 Vol. 14, No. 1, February 2011 Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation? Tao Chen http://cmr.ba.ouhk.edu.hk Web Journal of Chinese Management Review Vol. 14 No 1 1 Does Commodity

More information

Modeling Yields at the Zero Lower Bound: Are Shadow Rates the Solution?

Modeling Yields at the Zero Lower Bound: Are Shadow Rates the Solution? Modeling Yields at the Zero Lower Bound: Are Shadow Rates the Solution? Jens H. E. Christensen & Glenn D. Rudebusch Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Term Structure Modeling and the Lower Bound Problem

More information

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates Introduction 3 The unemployment rate in the Baltic States is volatile. During the last recession the trough-to-peak increase in the unemployment

More information

For Online Publication. The macroeconomic effects of monetary policy: A new measure for the United Kingdom: Online Appendix

For Online Publication. The macroeconomic effects of monetary policy: A new measure for the United Kingdom: Online Appendix VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY For Online Publication The macroeconomic effects of monetary policy: A new measure for the United Kingdom: Online Appendix James Cloyne and

More information

The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge

The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge Stefano Eusepi y Marc Giannoni z Bruce Preston x February 15, 2014 JEL Classi cations: E32, D83, D84 Keywords: Optimal Monetary Policy, Expectations

More information

Transmission of Quantitative Easing: The Role of Central Bank Reserves

Transmission of Quantitative Easing: The Role of Central Bank Reserves 1 / 1 Transmission of Quantitative Easing: The Role of Central Bank Reserves Jens H. E. Christensen & Signe Krogstrup 5th Conference on Fixed Income Markets Bank of Canada and Federal Reserve Bank of San

More information

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data Edith Cowan University Research Online ECU Publications 2013 2013 Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data A. Tsui C.Y. Xu Zhaoyong Zhang Edith Cowan University, zhaoyong.zhang@ecu.edu.au

More information

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus) Volume 35, Issue 1 Exchange rate determination in Vietnam Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus) Abstract This study investigates the determinants of the exchange rate in Vietnam and suggests policy

More information

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017 Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality June 19, 2017 1 Table of contents 1 Robustness checks on baseline regression... 1 2 Robustness checks on composition

More information

The Kalman Filter Approach for Estimating the Natural Unemployment Rate in Romania

The Kalman Filter Approach for Estimating the Natural Unemployment Rate in Romania ACTA UNIVERSITATIS DANUBIUS Vol 10, no 1, 2014 The Kalman Filter Approach for Estimating the Natural Unemployment Rate in Romania Mihaela Simionescu 1 Abstract: The aim of this research is to determine

More information

Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in Ireland

Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in Ireland Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Policy Research Working Paper 6525 Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in

More information

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for? Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for? Syed M. Hussain Lin Liu August 5, 26 Abstract In this paper, we estimate the

More information

Impact of Fed s Credit Easing on the Value of U.S. Dollar

Impact of Fed s Credit Easing on the Value of U.S. Dollar Impact of Fed s Credit Easing on the Value of U.S. Dollar Deergha Raj Adhikari Abstract Our study tests the monetary theory of exchange rate determination between the U.S. dollar and the Canadian dollar

More information

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1.1 WHAT IS VOLATILITY? It is useful to start with an explanation of what volatility is, at least for the purpose of clarifying the scope of this book. Volatility

More information

Rue de la Banque No. 52 November 2017

Rue de la Banque No. 52 November 2017 Staying at zero with affine processes: an application to term structure modelling Alain Monfort Banque de France and CREST Fulvio Pegoraro Banque de France, ECB and CREST Jean-Paul Renne HEC Lausanne Guillaume

More information

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Europe and the Euro Volume Author/Editor: Alberto Alesina and Francesco Giavazzi, editors Volume

More information

Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? *

Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? * Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? * Olivier Coibion College of William and Mary College of William and Mary Department of Economics Working Paper Number 9 Current Version: April 211

More information

ON THE LONG-TERM MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SPENDING IN THE UNITED STATES (*) Alfredo Marvão Pereira The College of William and Mary

ON THE LONG-TERM MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SPENDING IN THE UNITED STATES (*) Alfredo Marvão Pereira The College of William and Mary ON THE LONG-TERM MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SPENDING IN THE UNITED STATES (*) Alfredo Marvão Pereira The College of William and Mary Jorge M. Andraz Faculdade de Economia, Universidade do Algarve,

More information

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES Mahir Binici Central Bank of Turkey Istiklal Cad. No:10 Ulus, Ankara/Turkey E-mail: mahir.binici@tcmb.gov.tr

More information

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow, Co-movements of Shanghai and New York stock prices by time-varying regressions Gregory C Chow a, Changjiang Liu b, Linlin Niu b,c a Department of Economics, Fisher Hall Princeton University, Princeton,

More information

A1. Relating Level and Slope to Expected Inflation and Output Dynamics

A1. Relating Level and Slope to Expected Inflation and Output Dynamics Appendix 1 A1. Relating Level and Slope to Expected Inflation and Output Dynamics This section provides a simple illustrative example to show how the level and slope factors incorporate expectations regarding

More information

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Liuren Wu Baruch College, City University of New York Joint work with Jian Hua 6th Annual Conference of the Society for Financial Econometrics June 12-14,

More information

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking Michael Dotsey Executive Vice President and Director of Research Keith Sill Senior Vice President and Director, Real Time Data Research Center Federal

More information

Model Construction & Forecast Based Portfolio Allocation:

Model Construction & Forecast Based Portfolio Allocation: QBUS6830 Financial Time Series and Forecasting Model Construction & Forecast Based Portfolio Allocation: Is Quantitative Method Worth It? Members: Bowei Li (303083) Wenjian Xu (308077237) Xiaoyun Lu (3295347)

More information

Modeling and Forecasting the Yield Curve

Modeling and Forecasting the Yield Curve Modeling and Forecasting the Yield Curve III. (Unspanned) Macro Risks Michael Bauer Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco April 29, 2014 CES Lectures CESifo Munich The views expressed here are those of

More information

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning

Monetary Policy and Medium-Term Fiscal Planning Doug Hostland Department of Finance Working Paper * 2001-20 * The views expressed in this paper are those of the author and do not reflect those of the Department of Finance. A previous version of this

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities

Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities Topic 4: Introduction to Exchange Rates Part 1: Definitions and empirical regularities - The models we studied earlier include only real variables and relative prices. We now extend these models to have

More information

LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. October 10, 2018

LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. October 10, 2018 Economics 210c/236a Fall 2018 Christina Romer David Romer LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing October 10, 2018 Announcements Paper proposals due on Friday (October 12).

More information

Monetary policy and the yield curve

Monetary policy and the yield curve Monetary policy and the yield curve By Andrew Haldane of the Bank s International Finance Division and Vicky Read of the Bank s Foreign Exchange Division. This article examines and interprets movements

More information

The Zero Lower Bound

The Zero Lower Bound The Zero Lower Bound Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 4 Introduction In the standard New Keynesian model, monetary policy is often described by an interest rate rule (e.g. a Taylor rule) that

More information

CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS

CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS This chapter presents the results of the study and its analysis in order to meet the objectives. These results confirm the presence and impact of the biases taken into consideration,

More information

DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION

DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION APPENDIX DATA SUMMARIZATION AND VISUALIZATION PART 1 SUMMARIZATION 1: BUILDING BLOCKS OF DATA ANALYSIS 294 PART 2 PART 3 PART 4 VISUALIZATION: GRAPHS AND TABLES FOR SUMMARIZING AND ORGANIZING DATA 296

More information

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Properties of the estimated five-factor model Informationin(andnotin)thetermstructure Appendix. Additional results Greg Duffee Johns Hopkins This draft: October 8, Properties of the estimated five-factor model No stationary term structure model is

More information

Structural credit risk models and systemic capital

Structural credit risk models and systemic capital Structural credit risk models and systemic capital Somnath Chatterjee CCBS, Bank of England November 7, 2013 Structural credit risk model Structural credit risk models are based on the notion that both

More information

Macroeconomic Announcements and Investor Beliefs at The Zero Lower Bound

Macroeconomic Announcements and Investor Beliefs at The Zero Lower Bound Macroeconomic Announcements and Investor Beliefs at The Zero Lower Bound Ben Carlston Marcelo Ochoa [Preliminary and Incomplete] Abstract This paper examines empirically the effect of the zero lower bound

More information

IMES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

IMES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IMES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES A Survey-based Shadow Rate and Unconventional Monetary Policy Effects Hibiki Ichiue and Yoichi Ueno Discussion Paper No. 2018-E-5 INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES

More information

Estimated, Calibrated, and Optimal Interest Rate Rules

Estimated, Calibrated, and Optimal Interest Rate Rules Estimated, Calibrated, and Optimal Interest Rate Rules Ray C. Fair May 2000 Abstract Estimated, calibrated, and optimal interest rate rules are examined for their ability to dampen economic fluctuations

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh Volume 29, Issue 3 Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh Yu Hsing Southeastern Louisiana University A. M. M. Jamal Southeastern Louisiana University Wen-jen Hsieh

More information

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 11. The Smets-Wouters Model

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 11. The Smets-Wouters Model MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 11. The Smets-Wouters Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2016 Karl Whelan (UCD) The Smets-Wouters Model Spring 2016 1 / 23 A Popular DSGE Model Now we will discuss

More information

Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model

Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using SV Model In this chapter, the empirical performance of GARCH(1,1), GARCH-KF and SV models from

More information

Volume 38, Issue 1. The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy

Volume 38, Issue 1. The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy Volume 38, Issue 1 The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy Ivan Mendieta-Muñoz Department of Economics, University of Utah Abstract This paper studies if the supply

More information