The Retention Effects of Unvested Equity: Evidence from Accelerated Option Vesting

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Retention Effects of Unvested Equity: Evidence from Accelerated Option Vesting"

Transcription

1 The Retention Effects of Unvested Equity: Evidence from Accelerated Option Vesting Abstract We document that firms can effectively retain executives by granting deferred equity pay. We show this by analyzing a unique regulatory change (FAS 123-R) that prompted 720 firms to suddenly eliminate stock option vesting periods. This allowed CEOs to keep an additional $1.5 million in equity when departing the firm, and we find that voluntary CEO departure rates subsequently rose from 6% to 19%. Our identification strategy exploits FAS 123-R s almost-random timing, which was staggered by firms fiscal year ends. Firms that experienced departures suffered negative stock price reactions, and responded by increasing compensation for remaining and newly hired executives.

2 Demand for general human capital is rising across the economy (Zingales (2000); Custodia, Ferreira, and Matos (2013)), which makes it important to understand how firms can retain highly talented managers. One key retention mechanism that contract theory proposes is to defer parts of managers compensation into the future by granting equity that does not vest for several years (Edmans et al. (2012)). 1 Managers who voluntarily depart their firms typically forfeit unvested equity, which raises their cost of pursuing an outside option. Boards often grant managers large amounts of time-vesting equity based on this rationale (Ittner, Lambert, and Larcker (2003)). Nevertheless, whether unvested equity effectively conveys retention incentives is theoretically and empirically unclear. Models of managerial labor markets show that firms compensation policies can affect the type of managers that self-select to work for them (e.g., Lazear (2005)). This endogenous sorting makes it difficult to understand whether retention is driven by firms vesting policies or managers personal attributes. 2 Similarly, firms may grant unvested equity primarily to provide incentives against myopic behavior, rather than to retain talent (Gopalan et al. (2014); Edmans, Fang, and Lewellen (2016)). Furthermore, deferred pay s effectiveness for retaining highly sought managers may be limited because poaching firms can provide up-front payments to compensate managers for forfeited equity. As a result, causal identification is challenging, and this may explain why existing empirical work has been unable to link unvested equity to executive turnover (Fee and Hadlock (2003)). This paper presents novel, cleanly identified evidence on the retention incentives of deferred compensation. We study how executive turnover changes following the sudden elimination of equity vesting restrictions, and document three primary findings. First, voluntary CEO turnover triples, and voluntary top executive turnover doubles, when the amount of eq- 1 Edmans et al. (2012) show that gradual vesting of equity holdings ensures that managers will exert effort in future periods, instead of quitting to pursue outside options. 2 Managers who find it least costly to forfeit deferred compensation (such as those who expect to receive lucrative outside offers in the future) may sort to firms that grant the most unvested equity. Such managers may also be more likely to subsequently switch jobs. 1

3 uity forfeited upon leaving decreases. Second, these departures precipitate substantial drops in firm value. Third, firms respond to managerial turnover by raising remaining executives pay, implying that turnover allows firms to update their beliefs about executives outside options. Our findings provide new insights into the dynamics of managerial labor markets, and further complement a growing literature on the determinants of forced turnover (e.g., Huson, Parrino, and Starks (2001); Eisfeldt and Kuhnen (2013); Jenter and Kanaan (2015)). We establish these results by exploiting a unique feature of the landmark accounting regulation FAS 123-R, which required firms for the first time to expense stock options in their financial statements. FAS 123-R imposed retroactive accounting charges on unvested options that firms had granted years before the standard s adoption in December Corporate leaders vehemently opposed the new accounting expenses, which they feared would lead to a sudden drop in earnings and cause investors to sell off their firms stocks. Motivated by such concerns, 720 firms exploited a regulatory exemption: they accelerated executives previously granted, unvested options to vest immediately, thereby avoiding a 23% dropoff in net income (Choudhary, Rajgopal, and Venkatachalam (2009)). At the same time, however, acceleration allowed departing executives to keep options worth $1.5 million (twice the size of annual equity pay), which previously had been scheduled to remain unvested for several more years. Our hypothesis is that this sudden, large drop in departure costs led to an increase in executive turnover. An empirical challenge to testing this hypothesis is that firms decisions to accelerate option vesting are likely endogenous. First, some unobservable firm characteristics may have affected both option acceleration and executive turnover. For example, accelerating firms had worse stock performance over the previous year, and thus may have experienced more executive departures than non-accelerating firms. Second, estimates could be affected by reverse causality, if some firms accelerated options to provide a golden handshake to outgoing executives (Yermack (2006)). Such endogeneity can bias estimates obtained from 2

4 comparing accelerating and non-accelerating firms, leading to the false conclusion that a drop in unvested equity causes higher turnover. We overcome this identification challenge by using plausibly exogenous variation in option acceleration caused by FAS 123-R s staggered compliance dates. Specifically, the regulation took effect for each firm in its first fiscal year starting after June 15, Thus, firms with fiscal years ending June or later ( late fiscal-year-end firms ) had to comply immediately in calendar year 2005, while firms with fiscal years ending May or earlier ( early fiscal-year-end firms ) had to comply only in Our identification strategy therefore compares accelerating and non-accelerating firms across 2005 and 2006, using their fiscal year ends as an instrument for option acceleration. This 2SLS model tests whether turnover rose in 2005 for late fiscal-year-end firms that accelerated option vesting, relative to similar early fiscal-year-end firms that did not accelerate in that year due to a later compliance date. At the same time, it tests whether turnover rose in 2006 for early fiscal-year-end firms that accelerated option vesting, relative to late fiscal-year-end firms that had already complied with FAS 123-R. Because our model utilizes both cross-sectional and time-series variation, its estimates cannot be biased by unobserved time-invariant heterogeneity between firms with early and late fiscal year ends. In addition to affecting the timing of acceleration, our instrument also likely determined some firms decisions whether or not to accelerate option vesting. The reason is that the benefits of acceleration were lower for early fiscal-year-end firms that waited a year to comply, because more outstanding options vested under their normal schedules. 4 Our analysis starts by validating our fiscal-year-end instrument. We show that firms were 3 Executives likely did not anticipate the timing of option acceleration, because FAS 123-R s compliance schedule was unexpectedly delayed just two months before the regulation took effect (see Section I). Furthermore, executives had to wait until acceleration actually occurred to depart with the newly vested equity. 4 Our baseline sample includes both firms that did and did not accelerate option vesting. We obtain the same results after excluding firms that did not accelerate option vesting in any year. Furthermore, as we explain in Section II.C.3, including non-accelerating firms in our sample should not bias our 2SLS estimates, but excluding them could induce selection bias. 3

5 72% more likely to accelerate option vesting in their calendar year of compliance with FAS 123-R (1 st stage F -statistics of 25 or higher). This allowed executives to retain 63% of their previously unvested equity. Firms fiscal year ends also likely satisfy the exclusion restriction for an instrumental variable, as they were set many years in advance of FAS 123-R and thus should be uncorrelated with any contemporaneous changes that affect turnover. We confirm that early and late fiscal-year-end firms had identical turnover rates, firm characteristics, and executive compensation structure in the years before FAS 123-R took effect. We further exclude the few firms that changed their fiscal year. We proceed to examine how the acceleration-induced drop in unvested equity holdings affected executive turnover. A simple graphical examination shows that CEO turnover increased dramatically within a year after acceleration (see Figure 4). Prior to FAS 123-R, turnover rates did not vary across firms that accelerated in 2005 or Turnover then rose sharply, at first only for the firms that accelerated in 2005, and later only for firms that accelerated in Turnover rates for both sets of firms then quickly converged back to pre-fas 123-R levels. Acceleration thus led to a one-time spike in otherwise-stable turnover rates. Our 2SLS regressions confirm that these sequential jumps in turnover were due to the elimination of time-vesting restrictions, and not unobservable variables that may have affected firms acceleration decisions. We examine turnover both for CEOs and for top executives, and find that a one-standard-deviation increase in the fraction of accelerated options led to a rise in the CEO turnover rate from 6% to 19% (t-statistic of 3.6), and in the top executive turnover rate from 8% to 16% (t-statistic of 3). 5 We conduct several tests to confirm that these results are driven by voluntary turnover instead of firings following unobserved performance shocks. We next examine how this spike in turnover affected the value of firms that lost executives. Departures following option acceleration were relatively sudden, so they may have 5 These estimates likely represent the Local Average Treatment Effect (LATE), and thus are most informative for firms similar to those that considered accelerating option vesting before their FAS 123-R compliance date was determined (Angrist and Imbens (1994)). 4

6 disrupted firms business plans and led to costly searches for replacements. Indeed, we find that accelerating firms stocks dropped 1.4% in a [-3,+3] trading-day window around voluntary CEO departure announcements, erasing $31 million in these firms market values. In contrast, non-accelerating firms stocks were unaffected by voluntary departures. This value drop due to voluntary departures is similar to the ones documented in prior literature for CEO deaths (e.g., Johnson et al. (1985); Jenter, Matveyev, and Roth (2016)). We further find that firms responded to these departures by increasing the compensation of remaining executives and newly hired CEOs. Specifically, accelerating firms that experienced a departure subsequently raised non-departing executives pay by 14%, relative to accelerating firms that experienced no departures. Our estimates indicate that these executives were initially paid less than their peers, but then received higher pay after the raise. This adjustment was even larger for firms whose executives were poached by competitors. Newly hired CEOs received 36% higher compensation than the departing CEOs whom they replaced. This increase was persistent, and not due to a one-off signing bonus. Taken together, our results indicate that the vesting restrictions in place prior to option acceleration allowed firms to retain valuable executives. Acceleration-induced turnover was costly, but it also led boards to update their beliefs about remaining executives outside options and to adjust their compensation accordingly. One question these findings raise is why boards approved option acceleration. One possibility is that when FAS 123-R was adopted, the benefits of option acceleration outweighed the expected future costs. Specifically, our estimates imply that the expected value loss from acceleration-induced turnover was $5 million. At the same time, accelerating firms avoided an immediate plunge in net income. Ladika and Sautner (2016a) show that firms that reported lower income when complying with FAS 123-R were one-third more likely to miss analysts earnings forecasts and experienced stock price decreases of 3%. These estimates imply that the average accelerating firm would have faced a hypothetical value loss $66 mil- 5

7 lion had it not accelerated option vesting. 6 When accelerating firms later learned that an executive was planning to depart, they may have found it too costly to renegotiate pay ex post, and instead focused on retaining executives who had not yet threatened to leave. 7 Another possibility for why firms accelerated option vesting is that boards underestimated the turnover effects of option acceleration. We provide tentative evidence for this explanation by showing that boards did not replenish executives unvested equity holdings immediately after accelerating option vesting. We conclude our analysis with numerous robustness checks showing that our results cannot be explained by unobserved performance shocks or other variables that may differ across fiscal year ends. Placebo tests show that firms fiscal year ends did not affect executive turnover in years prior to FAS 123-R (i.e., before any firm accelerated option vesting). We also find that acceleration did not affect the turnover of outside directors, who were largely unaffected by FAS 123-R because they held little unvested equity (Yermack (2004)). 8 Thus, an omitted variable could confound our results only if it causes turnover of executives but not directors, and further affected late fiscal-year-end firms only in 2005 and early fiscalyear-end firms only in We further find that turnover rose among CEOs who were young or whose firms performed very well, confirming that scheduled retirements or firings do not drive our results. Acceleration also increased the departure rate of teams of top executives at high-performing firms. This further confirms that our results are due to voluntary turnover, as it is unlikely that multiple executives simultaneously planned to retire or were fired following strong firm performance. 6 Option acceleration also may have allowed firms to avoid violating bond covenants or other contracts with earnings-based provisions. 7 Replenishing an executive s unvested equity holdings would have required a large pay raise, as the value of accelerated options equaled two years worth of equity pay on average (see Section III.B). Shareholders may have considered such a pay grant shortly after option acceleration to be rent extraction. Additionally, increasing the pay of an executive who threatened to leave could have encouraged other executives to engage in disruptive searches for outside offers. 8 We further find no increase in the turnover of board compensation committee members or chairs following CEO departures from accelerating firms. 6

8 Our paper contributes to the understanding of managerial labor markets by quantifying the effect of unvested equity holdings on executive turnover. To the best of our knowledge, we are the first to show that changes to compensation policies have such a large impact on retention. We relate to a growing literature that studies the determinants of forced CEO turnover, such as corporate governance (e.g., Weisbach (1988); Denis, Denis, and Sarin (1997); Huson, Parrino, and Starks (2001)), industry shocks (Jenter and Kanaan (2015); Eisfeldt and Kuhnen (2013); Peters and Wagner (2014); Kaplan and Minton (2012)), failed takeover attempts (Denis and Serrano (1996)), and earnings management (Hazarika, Karpoff, and Nahata (2012)). We contribute to these papers by showing that the vesting of deferred compensation is a key determinant of voluntary executive turnover. This finding is most closely related to a contemporaneous working paper by Gopalan, Huang, and Maharjan (2014), who examine turnover after annual equity grants vest. Our setting differs as we examine a very large, one-time elimination of vesting periods, and study changes to pay policies and firm value following turnover. In a different setting, Chen (2004) shows that firms that restrict stock option repricing experience higher overall turnover. 9 Our paper also addresses a gap in the literature by documenting new evidence on the consequences of voluntary departures. Existing work finds that firm size determines executive pay in equilibrium, as the most productive managers sort to the largest firms (e.g., Gabaix and Landier (2008); Edmans, Gabaix, and Landier (2009)). However, little is known about the dynamics of pay that could lead to this equilibrium. Our result that firms increase compensation following voluntary turnover highlights one mechanism by which executive compensation can converge to its market value. Our findings also suggest that deferred compensation may be a (designed) friction to managerial sorting. More broadly, we contribute to the literature on how equity vesting restrictions affect executive incentives. Cai and Vijh (2007) find that executives pursue mergers to accelerate the 9 Several papers also examine how compensation structure affects general employee turnover (Oyer and Schaefer (2005); Balsam, Gifford, and Kim (2007); Aldatmaz, Ouimet, and Van Wesep (2014)). 7

9 vesting of their equity holdings. Other recent papers show that CEOs with short vesting periods act myopically (Edmans, Fang, and Lewellen (2016); Ladika and Sautner (2016b)), and that CEOs strategically release more news when their equity vests (Edmans et al. (2014)). The rest of this paper is structured as follows. Section I provides background information on FAS 123-R. Section II describes our sample and identification strategy. Section III presents 1 st -stage results for our instrument. Section IV presents our main 2SLS results. Section V contains placebo and robustness checks. Section VI concludes. I. Background on FAS 123-R Accounting regulations prior to FAS 123-R did not require firms to expense at-the-money option grants in their financial statements, and almost all firms avoided charges by granting executives such options. 10 FAS 123-R required firms to begin expensing the grant-date fair value of all new option awards. In the first year of compliance with the regulation, firms also had to expense the fair value of previously granted options that had not yet vested. FAS 123-R therefore generated substantial accounting charges for firms with many outstanding unvested options. However, FAS 123-R contained an exemption that allowed firms to avoid these charges by accelerating options to fully vest before the regulation took effect. Firms did not have to claim any expense when accelerating out-of-the-money options. For in-the-money options firms had to expense the difference between the strike price and the acceleration-date stock price, but for many firms this was a significantly smaller cost than the fair-value expense required by FAS 123-R (Balsam, Reitenga, and Yin (2008)). Importantly, both in- and out-of-the-money options are valuable to executives and can discourage departure before they vest. Executives may not want to forfeit options that are currently out- 10 Specifically, accounting standards required firms to expense the intrinsic value of stock option compensation (i.e., the stock price on the option grant date minus the option s strike price) while disclosing options grant-date fair values only in financial statement footnotes. See Choudhary, Rajgopal, and Venkatachalam (2009) and Balsam, Reitenga, and Yin (2008) for more information about the regulatory history of stock option expensing and FAS 123-R. 8

10 of-the-money options, because they can appreciate to provide substantial future payoffs. 11 FAS 123-R culminated a long debate about the accounting treatment of stock options. Previous attempts by the Financial Accounting Standard Board (FASB) to require fairvalue expensing drew substantial criticism from corporate managers, shareholder groups, and politicians. The corporate scandals of the early 2000s however generated substantial momentum for changing option expensing rules, and FASB responded with a new proposal in March CEOs of large companies such as Intel vehemently opposed the proposal, claiming that it would reduce financial statement informativeness and lead to costly missed earnings forecasts. 12 However, this time FASB faced relatively little political opposition, and FAS 123-R was officially adopted on December 15, Nevertheless, firms were unable to anticipate the precise costs and timing of FAS 123-R for two reasons. First, the regulation s final compliance schedule was unexpectedly changed just two months before the regulation took effect. 13 Second, firms did not know whether option acceleration would trigger accounting charges at all until October 6, 2004, when FASB decided in a narrow 4-3 vote to allow acceleration. Due to this uncertainty, almost no firms accelerated option vesting before late 2004 (Choudhary, Rajgopal, and Venkatachalam (2009)). A. Data II. Data, Empirical Measures, and Identification Strategy We collect turnover data for 4,988 firms that are in either the ExecuComp (mostly S&P 1500 firms) or BoardEx databases. 14 We exclude from this sample 405 firms that voluntarily 11 We find that at the start of the acceleration year, most executives unvested holdings consisted primarily of in-the-money options the average ratio of stock price to unvested option exercise price was See, for example, More Options for Trial Lawyers, The Wall Street Journal, March 31, FAS 123-R originally required all firms to begin expensing options on June 15, 2005, independent of their fiscal years. However, without prior notice, on April 14, 2005 the SEC changed the compliance date to the first quarterly earnings report of the first fiscal year starting after June 15, The change occurred because government regulators were burdened with a heavy workload, and because accountants worried about the difficulty of firms changing accounting standards in the middle of a fiscal year (McConnell et al. (2005)). 14 We use BoardEx to collect turnover data on non-s&p 1500 firms that accelerated option vesting. BoardEx contains detailed data on executives at a wide range of companies, and is frequently used in corporate 9

11 expensed stock options at fair value before FAS 123-R was proposed, because these firms could not benefit from option acceleration and also may have differed from other firms in ways that affect turnover (e.g., Aboody, Barth, and Kasznik (2004)). We further exclude 107 firms that changed their fiscal year between 2002 and 2006, perhaps to delay compliance with FAS 123-R. Our final sample contains 4,476 firms, of which 1,690 are in ExecuComp and 2,786 are only in BoardEx. It covers calendar years 2005 and We track the employment status of all of these firms top executives who are listed in ExecuComp or BoardEx. We exclude interim or acting CEOs because their eventual replacement is not a substantive turnover event. We also exclude executives who are not actively involved in the firm s management, such as former or emeritus CEOs. Our final sample contains 15,294 executives, of which 64% are presidents or C-Suite executives, 34% are vice presidents, and the remaining 2% have other senior executive functions. Next, we identify which sample firms accelerated option vesting using the R.G. Associates Option Accelerated Vester Database. The database contains information on acceleration events occurring between late 2004 and February 2006, which R.G. Associates, Inc. compiled from company disclosures about option acceleration that were mandated by FASB. We follow their procedure to extend the database through December The combined database contains 720 sample firms that accelerated option vesting in 2005 or 2006 (284 from ExecuComp and 436 from BoardEx). Our data includes the option acceleration dates and the total number of options accelerated, but does not contain individual option grant-level information as most firms disclosed only aggregate figures. B. Empirical Measures B.1. Turnover We measure annual turnover for both CEOs and a broader set of top executives. CEO Turnover is equal to 1 in a calendar year in which a firm experiences a CEO departure, and governance studies (e.g., Fracassi and Tate (2012); Cohen, Frazzini, and Malloy (2010); Duchin and Sosyura (2013)). 10

12 0 otherwise. Executive Turnover Rate measures turnover among all top executives, and is equal to the number of executives departing the firm in a calendar year divided by the total number of executives at the firm in the same year. For both variables, we follow Eisfeldt and Kuhnen (2013) by recording a departure event in calendar year t + 1 when the executive is at the firm at the end of year t but not at the end of year t + 1. Our hypothesis relates retention incentives to voluntary departures, but the above variables measure such turnover with noise because they include mandatory retirements and firings. This will not bias our 2SLS estimates unless our instrument is correlated with the measurement error. Nevertheless, we attempt to distinguish between voluntary and forced turnover using an approach based on Jenter and Kanaan (2015) and Peters and Wagner (2014). For ExecuComp firms, Voluntary CEO Turnover is equal to 1 when a firm experiences a departure that is not listed in a database of CEO firings constructed by these authors, and 0 when the firm experiences no departure. This database is based on extensive analysis of press reports of turnover events, but it covers only CEOs of ExecuComp firms. For BoardEx firms, we follow Peters and Wagner (2014) and set Voluntary CEO Turnover to 1 when the departing CEO is below 60 years of age. Similarly, Voluntary Executive Turnover Rate equals the number of executives below age 60 who depart the firm, divided by the firm s total number of executives. We use these admittedly imperfect measures because to the best of our knowledge, no existing database classifies departures of non-execucomp CEOs or non-ceo executives. 15 B.2. Option Acceleration We use two measures of option acceleration. Frac. Options Accelerated is the total number of options accelerated in the calendar year divided by the total number of (unvested and vested) options outstanding at the beginning of the year. It is equal to 0 for all firm-years 15 Classifying departures as forced or voluntary is not feasible for many non-ceo executives, as firms do not provide sufficient information to determine whether these executives leave voluntarily or are fired (e.g., Parrino (1997)). Section V performs further tests to rule out that our results are driven by forced turnover. 11

13 in which no options were accelerated. We use this proxy variable because data limitations at many sample firms prevent us from calculating the fraction of executives unvested options that are accelerated. Nonetheless, we find an almost one-to-one association between Frac. Options Accelerated and changes to executives unvested equity holdings among the subsample of firms for which both measures are available. 16 Furthermore, using a proxy will not bias our results in the likely case that measurement error does not vary across fiscal year ends. Our second measure, Accelerate, is equal to 1 if a firm accelerated options in a calendar year, and 0 otherwise. This variable does not differentiate between firms that accelerated many versus few options, but it is not a proxy variable and directly compares accelerating and non-accelerating firms. B.3. Firm and Executive Controls Our 2SLS model includes firm and executive characteristics that prior work has identified as determinants of option acceleration, and that may also affect executive turnover. We control for Log Assets and Market/Book Ratio because large or high-growth firms grant executives more equity pay, and hence may benefit more from acceleration. We control for stock market performance using Stock Return and Stock Volatility, and for operating performance using ROA and Sales Growth. We account for retirement-induced turnover using Executive Age, which is equal to 1 for CEOs who are 61 years or older. In regressions that explain top executive turnover, this variable equals the fraction of executives aged 61 or older. Our model also controls for calendar year and industry fixed effects. Some regressions control for measures of corporate governance, to account for the possibility that worse-governed firms were more likely to accelerate option vesting. Our measures are the fraction of independent board directors (Frac. Independent Directors), executives incentives from total equity holdings in the firm (Log Total Equity Incentives), and an indi- 16 For CEOs of accelerating firms in ExecuComp, a 1% increase in Frac. Options Accelerated leads to a 1.1% decrease in the dollar value of unvested option holdings (t-statistic of 2.4). Data on top executives unvested option holdings are not widely accessible for non-execucomp firms. 12

14 cator for whether the CEO is also board chairman (CEO Duality). We do not include these variables in all regressions because data are generally available only for ExecuComp firms. B.4. Summary Statistics Table 1, Panel A present summary statistics for our empirical measures in calendar years 2005 and The statistics show that a CEO departure occurs in 9% of these firm-years, and that 12% of top executives depart on average per year. Voluntary CEO and executive turnover are each 1% lower. [Insert Table 1 here] These turnover rates closely align with those documented in other studies. For example, Eisfeldt and Kuhnen (2013) and Jenter and Kanaan (2015) find CEO turnover rates of 10.5% and 10.8%, respectively. 17 Some studies document higher turnover rates (e.g., 12.8% in Kaplan and Minton (2012)), but these studies focus on large firms than generally have higher turnover rates. Panel B shows that overall 720 firms accelerated option vesting, comprising 16.1% of our sample of 4,476 firms (five firms accelerated options in multiple years). More firms accelerated options in 2005, but a similar proportion of firms that had to comply with FAS 123-R in each year accelerated option vesting. On average, firms accelerated 33.5% of total options outstanding, and 61.6% of outstanding unvested options (the latter statistic is unavailable before June 2005). Panel C shows that our sample contains sufficient cross-sectional variation in firms fiscal year ends for our identification strategy to work. The majority of firms (72%) have a December fiscal year end, but our sample contains more than 1,000 firms with fiscal years ending in other months, including 493 with fiscal year ending May or earlier. Additionally, 17 Our CEO turnover rate is slightly lower because our sample also includes some non-execucomp firms that experience lower executive turnover than the firms in the Eisfeldt and Kuhnen (2013) and Jenter and Kanaan (2015) samples. 13

15 we conduct a robustness check in Section V that omits firms with December fiscal year ends and confirms that our results still hold. C. Identification Strategy C.1. 2SLS Model Our goal is to test whether unvested equity conveys retention incentives to executives and reduces the frequency of voluntary departures. Option acceleration is a reasonable setting to test this hypothesis, because it led to a large, sudden drop in the amount of equity that executives forfeited upon leaving the firm. However, we cannot infer causality by examining whether firms that accelerated option vesting subsequently experienced higher executive turnover than firms that did not accelerate. Unobservable differences between these two sets of firms may have influenced both the option acceleration decision and turnover rates. For example, firms tend to rely more on equity compensation in the early stages of their life cycle, but such firms may also experience higher turnover rates. To overcome this challenge, we exploit the fact that FAS 123-R s compliance dates were staggered across time quasi-randomly by firms fiscal year ends. Our identification strategy uses the following 2SLS model for firm f in calendar year t: accel f,t = π 1 FAS 123-R Takes Effect f,t + π 2 x f,t + u f,t turnover f,t+1 = γ 1 âccel f,t + γ 2 x f,t + ν f,t+1 (1 st Stage) (2 nd Stage) The 1 st Stage regresses option acceleration in calendar year t on our instrument FAS 123-R Takes Effect f,t and a vector of firm characteristics x f,t including industry and year fixed effects. FAS 123-R Takes Effect f,t is an indicator variable for whether firm f had to comply with FAS 123-R in year t. It is equal to 1 in 2005 for late fiscal-year-end firms, 1 in 2006 for early fiscal-year-end firms, and 0 for all other firm-years. Therefore a positive value of π indicates that firms were more likely to accelerate option vesting in the year that FAS 14

16 123-R took effect than in the year before or afterward. We expect this because firms could only avoid expensing unvested options by eliminating the vesting provisions prior to their regulatory compliance date. Firms also benefited little by accelerating options a year early. 18 The 2 nd Stage regresses CEO or top executive turnover in year t + 1 on the fitted value of option acceleration from the 1 st Stage. The key coefficient in our model is γ 1. A positive value would indicate that firms that accelerated option vesting in year t due to upcoming FAS 123-R compliance also experienced higher executive turnover in year t + 1 precisely what we would expect if executives found it less costly to leave once they could keep their newly vested options. We examine turnover in the year after instead of the year of option acceleration, because executives likely required a few months to identify preferable outside opportunities. Some executives may have waited more than a year to depart, in which case turnover rates may have remained elevated in year t + 2. However, we expect turnover to be highest in year t + 1 and to decrease in subsequent years. Figure 1 illustrates our identification strategy, and shows our predictions for how staggered FAS 123-R compliance dates affected the timing of option acceleration and subsequent executive turnover. A key feature of the model is that the control group consists of two sets of firms: early fiscal-year-end firms in calendar year 2005, and late fiscal-year-end firms in As such, γ 1 > 0 would indicate that: (i) turnover rose in 2006 at late fiscal-year-end firms that complied with FAS 123-R in 2005, while remaining constant for early fiscal-year-end firms that did not comply; and (ii) turnover rose in 2007 among early fiscal-year-end firms that complied with FAS 123-R in 2006, relative to late fiscal-year-end that had previously complied. This research design ensures that results cannot be explained by time-invariant differences in turnover between early and late fiscal-year-end firms, nor by macroeconomic 18 Early fiscal-year-end firms were likely better off waiting until 2006 to accelerate than doing so in Waiting one year allowed some previously granted options to vest under their normal schedule, and may have allowed some firms to avoid accelerating altogether. 15

17 shocks that affected turnover at all firms in the same year. 19 [Insert Figure 1 here] C.2. Validity of 2SLS Assumptions Our instrument must satisfy two key assumptions to identify the causal effect of acceleration: 1. Relevance Condition: π 1 0. accel f,t must be correlated with FAS 123-R Takes Effect f,t after controlling for other firm characteristics X f,t. 2. Exclusion Restriction: Cov(FAS 123-R Takes Effect f,t, ν f,t+1 ) = 0. Differences in the FAS 123-R compliance dates across firms must only affect turnover through their effect on option acceleration. Section III shows that firms were far more likely to accelerate option vesting in the calendar year of compliance with FAS 123-R, thereby confirming the Relevance Condition. The Exclusion Restriction is satisfied if the determinants of executive turnover do not differ across early and late fiscal-year-end firms. We cannot test this condition for unobservable variables that could affect turnover (such variables would be elements of ν f,t+1 ). Table 2 however provides supporting evidence by examining differences in key observable variables across fiscal year ends. Panel A of the table compares executive turnover rates and firm fundamentals in the years before FAS 123-R took effect, and Panel B compares measures of executive equity holdings and annual compensation. The table presents these variables means and standard deviations, separately for early and late fiscal-year-end firms. It also shows the results of t-tests of the difference in means. [Insert Table 2 here] 19 As a robustness check, we estimate our 2SLS model with firm fixed effects in Appendix A-4. This model is an alternative way to test whether turnover increases in the year after option acceleration. 16

18 Panel A shows that differences in turnover rates were small and statistically insignificant prior to FAS 123-R. Stock and accounting performance did not differ across fiscal year ends, and all but one of the other firm characteristics are statistically indistinguishable. Additionally, executives of early and late-fiscal-year-end firms had similar amounts of unvested equity holdings prior to option acceleration, and their annual pay also did not differ. These results indicate that our instrument likely satisfies the Exclusion Restriction. Because turnover rates did not differ across early and late fiscal-year-end firms before FAS 123-R, any subsequent rise in turnover can only be due to option acceleration or an unobservable shock that precisely coincides with the regulation. Moreover, note that unobservable heterogeneity that is fixed over time cannot bias our results, because our identification strategy relies on different treatment and control groups in 2005 and C.3. Validity of Sampling Non-Accelerating Firms As in all 2SLS models, our identification comes from comparing accelerating firms in each year to other firms that are observationally similar and would have accelerated options, had they been required to comply with FAS 123-R in the same year ( compliers in the treatment effects terminology). Our sample also includes firms that did not accelerate option vesting in either 2005 or Some of these firms are never-takers that chose not to accelerate because their expected costs from executive turnover were particularly high. Importantly, including these firms in our sample does not bias our 2SLS estimates if the Exclusion Restriction is satisfied. This is because the sensitivity of firm value to executive turnover (or any other unobservable determinant of a firm s acceleration decision) is part of the regression residuals u f,t and ν f,t+1, which by assumption are uncorrelated with our instrument. If instead the unobservable determinants of option acceleration vary across fiscal years, then the percentage of firms affected by FAS 123-R that accelerated option vesting should differ between 2005 and For example, if turnover costs were higher among late fiscalyear-end firms, then a smaller percentage of these firms should have accelerated in

19 than early fiscal-year-end firms in However, we find that this is not the case: in 2005, 16.4% of late fiscal-year-end firms accelerated option vesting, compared to 14.4% of early fiscal-year-end firms in 2006 (this difference is statistically insignificant). Moreover, our baseline sample contains non-accelerating firms because excluding them could induce selection bias. For early fiscal-year-end firms, the benefits of option acceleration decreased from 2005 to 2006 waiting one year to comply with FAS 123-R allowed more options to vest under their normal schedule, potentially causing some of these firms to decide to not accelerate. By excluding these firms, we would be oversampling firms that received disproportionately high benefits from acceleration, and this can induce correlation between FAS 123-R Takes Effect and u f,t or ν f,t+1. In an accompanying online appendix, 20 we explicitly derive the 2SLS estimator for our model and show that it is unbiased when non-accelerating firms are included in the sample, but possibly biased downward when they are excluded. III. Empirical Results: 1 st Stage We start our analysis by presenting results for the 1 st stage of our 2SLS model, which show that firms were more likely to accelerate option vesting in the year in which they had to comply with FAS 123-R. We also show that option acceleration had a large effect on executives retention incentives. A. Effect of Fiscal Year Ends on Option Acceleration Figure 2 presents graphical evidence of the relationship between staggered FAS 123-R compliance dates and option acceleration. The figure shows, for each month between January 2005 and December 2006, the fraction of firms with fiscal year ending in that month that accelerated option vesting. The figure shows that option acceleration jumped sharply starting with firms whose fiscal year ended in June 2005; these were the first firms to comply with FAS 123-R. In calendar year 2006, option acceleration increased for firms with fiscal 20 The appendix is posted at 18

20 years ending January through May, and then dropped to almost zero for firms with later fiscal year ends that had already complied with FAS 123-R. Overall, 17.8% of firms with fiscal year ending June 2005 through May 2006 accelerated option vesting, compared to just 5.9% of firms with fiscal year ending January through May 2005, and 0.2% of firms with fiscal year ending June through December Thus, the rate of option acceleration was much higher in the calendar year in which firms had to comply with FAS 123-R. [Insert Figure 2 here] Table 3 confirms that fiscal year ends are a strong predictor of option acceleration after controlling for a variety of firm characteristics. Columns (1) through (3) present estimates from OLS regressions of Frac. Options Accelerated on FAS 123-R Takes Effect. Columns (4) through (6) present estimates of marginal effects from logistic regressions using Accelerate as the dependent variable. In all columns the sample is calendar years 2005 and [Insert Table 3 here] Each regression shows a strong positive relationship between option acceleration and our instrument. Column (5), for example, implies that the acceleration rate was 11.6% higher in the calendar year in which firms had to comply with FAS 123-R (a 72% increase over firms 16.1% unconditional likelihood of accelerating option vesting). Particularly striking is our instrument s high level of statistical significance across all tests; the t-statistic on FAS 123-R Takes Effect is 5 or higher in each regression. Additionally, all Kleibergen-Paap F -statistics by far exceed the commonly used threshold of 10 (Staiger and Stock (1997); Stock, Wright, and Yogo (2002)), confirming our instrument s strength. Overall, these results show that our instrument satisfies the Relevance Condition. 21 Regressions in columns (1) and (4) are estimated for the sample of firms for which we have data for control variables. 19

21 Consistent with prior research (Choudhary, Rajgopal, and Venkatachalam (2009); Balsam, Reitenga, and Yin (2008)), Table 3 shows that accelerating firms had worse stock performance in the previous year (performance in earlier years was identical). These firms were also more volatile, but interestingly their board structures were similar to those of non-accelerating firms. As executive departures may occur more frequently at risky firms with poor recent performance, this underscores the importance of our 2SLS identification strategy, and the fact that our instrument is uncorrelated with these variables (see Table 2). B. Effect of Option Acceleration on Unvested Equity Holdings Next, we examine the effect of option acceleration on executives unvested equity holdings. This is important because the results in Table 3 do not necessarily prove that top executives departure costs experienced a meaningful decrease. Firms may have accelerated only a small fraction of these executives options, or accelerated only deep out-of-the-money options with little economic value. In this case, option acceleration may not have materially affected executives incentives to leave or stay. However, Table 4 confirms that option acceleration led to a sharp drop in unvested equity holdings, implying a large decrease in departure costs. Columns (1) and (2) show results of OLS regressions with the change in (the logarithm of) the dollar amount of unvested equity holdings as the dependent variable. We show results separately for CEOs and all top executives. Columns (3) and (4) show results for incentives from unvested equity holdings, which we measure using pay-for-performance sensitivity (PPS) (Hall and Liebman (1998)). The sample in this analysis is restricted to ExecuComp firms, for which data on executives equity holdings are widely accessible. [Insert Table 4 here] The table shows that accelerating firms executives experienced a statistically significant decrease in unvested equity holdings in the year that options were accelerated, for both the 20

22 amount and PPS of unvested equity. This drop is not due to differences in performance between accelerating and non-accelerating firms, as the regressions control for stock returns. Our estimates indicate that the economic decrease in unvested equity holdings was substantial. Accelerating firms CEOs held total unvested equity worth $2.4 million at the start of the year in which options were accelerated. Our estimates in column (1) imply that these holdings then fell to $885,000. Thus, option acceleration caused equity worth $1.5 million to vest immediately, decreasing departure costs from forfeiting unvested equity by 63%. Similarly, unvested equity holdings fell by 62% for top executives, from $1 million to $376,000, based on estimates in column (2). This amount of newly vested equity was large relative to executives annual compensation and total holdings in the firm. It equaled two (1.7) times the value of equity (cash) pay that accelerating firms CEOs received in the year prior to option acceleration. These CEOs unvested options also comprised 18% of total stock and option holdings (29% for top executives) at the start of the acceleration year. Furthermore, option acceleration substantially reduced the amount of time executives had to wait before they could depart with their options. Figure 3 shows that the average duration of unvested options fell from 2 years just prior to acceleration to 0.5 years afterward, and 85% of options became exercisable within the year. 22 [Insert Figure 3 here] In summary, option acceleration reduced the vesting duration of executives holdings by 1.5 years, leading to a sharp rise in the amount of compensation that they could keep when leaving the firms. These holdings represented a large share of executives total wealth tied to 22 Our measure of unvested equity duration is defined similar to Gopalan et al. (2014), and represents the weighted average number of years until options vest. In Figure 3, vesting duration in the year of option acceleration equals (1-ˆλ) Unvested Option Duration t, where ˆλ is estimated from the regression Log Unvested Option Amount f,t = λ accel f,t + ψx f,t 1 + e f,t. This regression is identical to Table 4, Column (2), except that the dependent variable is the change in the natural logarithm of the amount of unvested options, instead of total unvested equity. Vesting duration is set to 0 for accelerated options. 21

23 the firm, and eliminating their vesting provisions likely affected executives trade-off between remaining at their current employer or pursuing an outside option. 23 IV. Empirical Results: 2 nd Stage This section contains our main 2SLS results showing the effect of option acceleration on executive turnover. We also show that the sudden rise in turnover led to a loss in value for accelerating firms, and that these firms responded by increasing the pay of remaining executives and newly hired CEOs. A. Option Acceleration and Executive Turnover: Graphical Evidence We start by analyzing graphically whether turnover is related to the timing of option acceleration. Recall, our hypothesis predicts that turnover should rise in the year after option acceleration, and therefore firms that accelerated option vesting in 2005 should experience an increase one year earlier than firms that accelerated in Figure 4 plots CEO turnover rates by calendar year, separately for firms that accelerated in 2005 versus 2006 (non-accelerating firms are excluded). Each bar in the figure is the percentage of accelerating firms that experienced a CEO departure within the following year. [Insert Figure 4 here] The figure shows that turnover rates for the two groups of firms were similar in the years before options were accelerated in each year from 2001 to 2004, turnover is statistically indistinguishable between the two groups. CEO departures then jumped suddenly, but only among firms that accelerated option vesting in In the following year, turnover rose 23 In addition to granting unvested equity, firms can defer executives compensation in two other ways: by promising large pension payments upon retirement, or by placing part of annual salary into a non-qualified deferred compensation account. Detailed data on these compensation grants is not available before 2006, but both are typically much smaller in size than equity holdings (Yermack and Sundaram (2007)). 22

24 sharply for only firms that accelerated in For both sets of firms, CEO turnover remained relatively high in the second year after option acceleration, consistent with some executives requiring more than a year to arrange an outside opportunity, before decreasing again. By 2008, turnover rates were once again the same for both groups. Overall, the figure indicates that a strong association exists between the precise timing of option acceleration and CEO departures. B. Option Acceleration and Executive Turnover: Regression Results One concern with Figure 4 is that the turnover patterns could be explained by performance shocks that simultaneously caused firms to accelerate options and executives to leave, and that affected some firms in 2005 and others in We therefore proceed to formally estimate the effect of option acceleration on executive turnover using our 2SLS identification strategy. Table 5 examines CEO turnover, and Table 6 examines turnover among top executives. Both tables first report results of OLS regressions comparing turnover at accelerating versus non-accelerating firms, and then 2SLS regressions that instrument option acceleration using FAS 123-R Takes Effect. We measure option acceleration using both Frac. Options Accelerated and Accelerate. The sample period is again calendar years 2005 and [Insert Table 5 here] In Table 5, the OLS regressions show a positive association between option acceleration and CEO turnover. This indicates that CEOs were more likely to depart accelerating than non-accelerating firms in the year after option acceleration. The estimate in column (1) indicates that a one-standard-deviation increase in Frac. Options Accelerated led to a ( =) 1.9% percentage-point increase in CEO Turnover, from 5.7% in the year before FAS 123-R took effect to 7.6%. Our 2SLS models in columns (3) and (4) continue to show positive and highly statistically significant coefficients on both measures of instrumented option acceleration. The regres- 23

25 sions in columns (5) and (6) document that this effect is robust to controlling for various corporate governance measures that are available for ExecuComp firms. These results also confirm that option acceleration affected turnover within the subsample of just ExecuComp firms. Next, columns (7) through (10) estimate the effect of option acceleration on Voluntary CEO Turnover. We continue to find a statistically significant effect with similar magnitudes for both acceleration variables as in previous regressions. This indicates that our results are not affected by firings. Table 6 shows that the effect of option acceleration on turnover was not confined to CEOs. Specifically, OLS regressions in columns (1) and (2) show that Executive Turnover Rate is higher for accelerating than non-accelerating firms. Additionally, in each 2SLS regression in columns (3) through (6), the effect of instrumented option acceleration is positive and highly statistically significant. As in Table 5, results are almost identical for Voluntary Executive Turnover Rate. The acceleration of option vesting therefore led to increased departures among a range of executives within firms leadership. [Insert Table 6 here] The economic magnitudes of our 2SLS results in both tables are large. Column (3) of Table 5 implies that the CEO turnover rate rose by ( =) 13.5% percentage points for a one-standard-deviation increase in Frac. Options Accelerated. This implies an increase for accelerating firms from the pre-fas 123-R unconditional mean of 5.7% to 19.2%. Similarly, column (3) of Table 6 indicates that top executive turnover rose by ( =) 7.5% percentage points for a one-standard-deviation increase in Frac. Options Accelerated, from 8.4% to 15.9%. These estimates provide important new evidence on the magnitude of the sensitivity of executive turnover to equity vesting duration, and show that properly structured compensation policies are crucial for retaining top managers. In order to properly interpret the estimates, it is important to note that our 2SLS specification likely identifies the LATE among the subset of marginal firms that were induced to 24

26 accelerate option vesting in 2005 (2006) because of a late (early) fiscal year end. 24 Hence, our estimates are directly applicable to firms that were considering to accelerate option vesting before FAS 123-R s compliance dates were set, but may be less informative for firms that would not have accelerated options under any circumstances. This also explains why our 2SLS estimates are substantially larger than the corresponding OLS estimates. Our results also indicate that option acceleration led to a one-time spike in executive turnover, instead of merely encouraging executives to depart slightly earlier than planned. Figure 4 shows that by 2008 turnover rates had returned to pre-fas123-r levels, as new grants of unvested equity restored executives retention incentives. We also find that the average age of executives who departed in the year after acceleration was 55. This confirms that our results are likely not driven by planned retirements and accelerators that provided golden retirement handshakes. The sample in Tables 5 and 6 includes non-accelerating firms, so our instrument identifies the timing of option acceleration and also, for early fiscal-year-end firms, the decision whether to accelerate options at all. Next, Table 7 contains regression results only for the subsample of firms that accelerated option vesting in at least one year, and examines the relationship between the timing of option acceleration and the turnover increase. Columns (1) and (2) present results for CEOs, and Columns (3) and (4) for all top executives. We find that the coefficients on the acceleration measures are all positive and significant, indicating that turnover rises in the year after each firm accelerated option vesting. These estimates are smaller than in Tables 5 and 6, perhaps because excluding firms that did not accelerate option vesting can induce downward selection bias (see Section II.C.3 and online appendix). [Insert Table 7 here] 24 2SLS identifies the LATE instead of the average treatment effect across the entire sample when the effect of acceleration on turnover (γ 1 ) is heterogeneous across sample firms. This is likely the case in our setting as FAS 123-R created accounting expenses for all firms with unvested options, but only some firms chose to accelerate option vesting. This indicates that the benefits of acceleration were relatively higher (γ 1 is larger) for these firms. 25

27 Appendix A-2 provides further validation for our instrument. We estimate reduced-form specifications that regress our turnover measures directly on the instrument FAS 123-R Takes Effect. Reduced-form regressions can help to gauge whether 2SLS results are consistent with the instrument s expected causal effect (see Angrist and Pischke (2009), pg. 213). A reduced-form coefficient of zero on FAS 123-R Takes Effect would indicate that 2SLS estimates are driven mostly by omitted variables or regression misspecification. Instead, we obtain coefficients that are positive and significant at the 1% level in all specifications. Overall, our results show that accelerating firms experienced a large increase in executive turnover, and this effect precisely corresponded to these firms staggered FAS 123-R compliance dates. These results support our hypothesis that unvested equity conveyed important retention incentives to top executives, and that the elimination of equity vesting periods reduced these incentives and increased departure rates. One implication is that prior to FAS 123-R, some executives passed up outside options because they did not want to lose their unvested equity holdings. C. Effects of Voluntary Departures on Firm Value We now turn to studying the consequences of executive departures. We start by examining whether the sharp rise in turnover after option acceleration affected the value of firms that lost executives. Our previous results show that option acceleration led to a sudden drop in retention incentives, so the executives who subsequently departed may not have announced their plans far in advance. This in turn may have left firms with little time to adjust business plans or find replacements. In contrast, executive departures at non-accelerating firms may have been less disruptive, as they likely were not motivated by sudden changes in retention incentives. For example, CEOs departing these firms may have indicated in advance that they did not plan to extend their contracts, allowing firms time to identify and train successors. Therefore, voluntary departures following option acceleration may have destroyed more value than contemporaneous departures at non-accelerating firms. 26

28 To analyze firm value effects, we examine stock price reactions following the announcement of voluntary CEO departures, separately for firms that did and did not accelerate option vesting. We collect data on CEO departure announcement dates from the Capital IQ database, which covers ExecuComp firms and also smaller firms. We collect departure announcements in the two years after FAS 123-R took effect (i.e., June 15, 2005 through June 15, 2007), to capture at least one full year after each firm accelerated option vesting. We exclude announcements made by firms that fired their CEOs (as identified by the Jenter and Kanaan (2015) and Peters and Wagner (2014) database). Our sample contains 90 CEO departure events at accelerating firms and 324 at non-accelerating firms. Table 8 reports raw returns and returns adjusted by the CAPM and 4-factor models. We document returns separately for the announcement date, a window of one day before to two days after the announcement, and a window of three days before to three days after the announcement. Panel A shows that CEO departures at accelerating firms were met with significant negative raw returns of -0.48% on the announcement day. Shareholder losses increased to -0.82% in the four-day window and to -1.07% in the seven-day window around the announcement. Losses are even bigger for adjusted returns. For example, CARs based on the 4-factor model are -0.57% on the announcement date and -1.06% and -1.44% in the wider windows. In contrast, CARs of non-accelerating firms are almost zero and statistically insignificant across all models. Panel B shows that median CARs are also negative and statistically significant only for accelerating firms. [Insert Table 8 here] These results indicate that sudden voluntary departures due to option acceleration led to substantial losses in firm value, and thus provide new evidence on the value effects of voluntary turnover. Our estimate is similar to the ones documented in prior literature for CEO deaths (see, e.g, Johnson et al. (1985); Jenter, Matveyev, and Roth (2016)). 27

29 Our estimates imply that the average accelerating firm, with market capitalization of $2.2 billion, experienced a drop in market value of ( =) $31 million (or $26 million relative to non-accelerating firms with CEO departures). This loss is substantially larger than the additional compensation that these firms paid to their newly hired CEOs (see Section IV.D), suggesting that markets expected voluntary departures to not only generate search and additional wage costs associated with CEO replacement, but also to possibly reduce firms future operating performance. The results also indicate that capital markets perceived departing CEOs to have provided valuable leadership to firms markets likely would not react negatively to the departure of value-destroying CEOs. D. Effects of Executive Departures on Firm Compensation Policies We next examine whether accelerating firms that experienced turnover responded by adjusting compensation for remaining and newly hired executives. Executives who are contemplating an outside option whether it is a managerial position at a rival firm or taking time off trade off its benefits against the costs of leaving their current employer. All else equal, executives will leave if the expected utility from future income earned at their current employers is less than the expected utility of the outside option. Firms can alter the outcome of this trade-off and reduce departure rates by increasing compensation. Firms that experienced turnover following option acceleration may have adjusted pay in this manner in order to stem further losses of talent. This response may have been optimal if departures provided a signal to firms that they had underestimated the value of executives outside options (such as the market wage for top executives). We test for such responses in Table 9 using the following difference-in-differences model: pay f,t = β 1 Post Acceleration t + β 2 Firm Experienced Departure f + β 3 Post Acceleration t Firm Experienced Departure f + β 4 X f,t 1 + u f,t 28

30 The model compares executive compensation in the years before and after option acceleration, separately for accelerating firms that did and did not experience an executive departure. We examine both total and equity compensation. Firm Experienced Departure f is equal to 1 in all years for firms that experienced a departure in the year after accelerating option vesting, and 0 otherwise. Post Acceleration t is equal to 1 in years after option acceleration, and 0 otherwise. We use a window of two years before to two years after acceleration. In this model, a positive value for the interaction coefficient β 3 would indicate that firms that experienced a departure after option acceleration subsequently increased executive pay, relative to firms that experienced no turnover after option acceleration. We use this model to analyze three different types of departure events. Panel A tests how compensation changes for remaining top executives following any executive departure, and also following an executive poaching. 25 Panel B examines pay changes following a CEO departure. We use different samples in the two panels to separately estimate pay changes for remaining and newly hired executives. The regressions in Panel A contains only executives who are present both before and after option acceleration, and examine whether firms grant these executives pay raises after a departure. The regressions in Panel B contain only CEOs, and examine whether firms pay newly hired CEOs more than the departing ones, relative to firms that continue to employ the same CEO. The samples in both panels contain only ExecuComp firms for which pay data is widely accessible. [Insert Table 9 here] In Panel A, the interaction term coefficients are positive in all columns, indicating that firms increased compensation following an executive departure. The coefficient in column (1) indicates that total compensation for executives remaining at departure firms increased by 25 Overall, the accelerating firms in the Table 9 sample experienced 291 executive departures in the year after option acceleration, of which 43 were CEOs. Also, 40 executives were poached. We label a departure as a poaching if the departing executive was hired into a top executive position by another sample firm within two years. 29

31 14% following option acceleration, relative to executives of non-departure firms. Column (2) shows that this increase came mainly from higher equity pay. In both columns the sum of the coefficients on Firm Experienced Departure and Post Acceleration Firm Experienced Departure is also positive, indicating that departure firms granted wage hikes to remaining executives so that their pay exceeded the amounts earned at non-departure firms. Next, columns (3) and (4) show even larger pay increases at firms that experienced an executive poaching. Executives who remained at these firms received a 20% increase in total compensation. 26 Panel B shows that firms that lost CEOs after option acceleration subsequently granted their new CEOs higher compensation. The coefficient on the interaction term in column (5) implies that newly hired CEOs received 36% higher pay than departing CEOs, $1.7 million in total. 27 Interestingly, the negative coefficient on Firm Experienced CEO Departure suggests that the CEOs who departed were paid less than their peers at other accelerating firms, who did not leave following option acceleration. Finally, note that the statistically insignificant coefficient on Post Acceleration indicates that firms, on average, did not adjust pay after accelerating option vesting; we explore this in more detail in the next section. Overall, results from both panels suggest that accelerating firms adjusted compensation policies as departures signaled that they were underpaying their executives. An important implication of these findings is that acceleration-induced turnover, while costly, allowed boards to update their beliefs about executives outside options. This may be one channel by which compensation converges to executives market values. E. Implications for Firms Acceleration Decisions Our results show that option acceleration led to the departure of executives who contributed substantial value to their firms. Given these results, it is important to consider why 26 We also find that poached executives total pay almost doubled at their new firms, increasing from $2.5 million to $4.6 million. 27 This pay increase is not limited to a signing bonus in the first year. We find that newly hired CEOs total compensation in their second through fourth years at the job was 23% higher than the pay of departing CEOs. 30

32 firms approved option acceleration, and why they raised compensation following departures instead of taking ex-ante actions to stem turnover. We offer two possible reasons. One explanation is that the immediate benefits from accelerating options and reporting higher accounting income exceeded the expected value loss from potential executive departures. The firm-value estimates in Table 8 imply that this expected loss was $5 million at the time that firms decided to accelerate option vesting. 28 While this is sizeable, the benefit from maintaining net income at pre-fas 123-R levels was potentially much larger. The reason is that option acceleration allowed firms to avoid reporting a sudden 23% reduction in net income (Choudhary, Rajgopal, and Venkatachalam (2009)). Ladika and Sautner (2016a) find that firms which reported lower net income in the first year of FAS 123-R compliance were one-third more likely to miss analysts earnings forecasts, and 6% more likely to receive a sell rating on their stocks. Stock prices fell 3% following a missed forecast, which when applied to our sample would have led to a loss of $66 million for the average accelerating firm (with $2.2 billion market value). Thus option acceleration may have maximized expected firm value if it led to just a small reduction in the probability of missing analysts expectations. Option acceleration also may have produced further benefits, such as allowing firms to avoid violating contracts with earnings-based provisions (e.g., Debt-to-EBITDA bond covenants). Once accelerating firms learned that an executive was contemplating departure, they may have found it too costly to grant new compensation that dominated the outside opportunity. First, replenishing the executive s unvested holdings would have required a large pay raise, because accelerated options were equal in value to two years worth of equity pay (see Section III.B). Shareholders may have viewed this as a disguised form of rent extraction, especially since firms would have to claim accounting expenses for the new equity grants. Second, 28 Our results imply that acceleration increased the probability of CEO turnover from 5.7% to 19.2%, and the departure realization (which increased turnover probability from 19.2% to 100%) then led to a $31 million value loss. If markets priced in the effect of option acceleration on expected CEO departure, then the total value loss is (31/( )=) $38 million. This leads to the expected marginal cost of option acceleration of ( =) $5 million. 31

33 rewarding executives who threatened to leave would have encouraged other top managers to search for outside offers, thereby distracting them from management duties and disrupting the executive suite s cohesion. Third, acceleration may have encouraged CEOs to take time off or to pursue non-managerial enterprises, which may have provided greater utility than even large pay increases. Boards therefore may have found it more effective to focus on retaining executives who had not yet threatened to leave. An alternative explanation is that corporate boards overestimated the importance of reporting higher earnings relative to the turnover effects of option acceleration. Indeed, 80% of firms cited accounting costs as the primary motivation for accelerating option vesting (Choudhary, Rajgopal, and Venkatachalam (2009)). Boards may not have adequately considered the long-term consequences of acceleration, especially if acceleration was recommended by management or by advisers to the firm such as accountants. Appendix A-3 provides tentative evidence consistent with this interpretation. It shows that, on average, firms that accelerated option vesting did not counter the reduction in retention incentives. We find no evidence that firms increased the value of new equity grants (columns (1) and (2)) or the length of vesting periods on new stock options (columns (3) and (4)) immediately after option acceleration. Instead, firms only adjusted compensation if they experienced an executive departure one year after acceleration (see previous section). V. Placebo and Robustness Tests We shore up our conclusions by further addressing two potential concerns with our analysis, namely (i) that our results may be affected by unobservables that vary across fiscal year ends; and (ii) that our results may be driven by forced turnover. We also provide several additional tests showing that our results are robust to changes in the baseline specification. 32

34 A. Placebo Tests A.1. Option Acceleration and Outside Director Turnover We first examine whether the documented increase in turnover could be explained by unobserved firm performance shocks that coincide with FAS 123-R s staggered compliance dates. We do so by testing whether option acceleration affected turnover among outside board directors. This is a natural setting for a placebo test, because option acceleration did not substantially reduce outside directors costs of pursuing outside options. One reason is that firms typically granted little equity to outside directors in the mid-2000s (e.g., Yermack (2004); Aon Hewitt (2010)), and hence directors of accelerating firms likely did not experience a meaningful decrease in retention incentives. Furthermore, unlike top executives, outside directors can accept additional board seats or employment opportunities without leaving their current firm. However, contemporaneous performance shocks should lead outside directors to depart in order to preserve their monitoring reputation (e.g., Harford (2003); Yermack (2004); Fahlenbrach, Low, and Stulz (2013)). Therefore, if executive turnover is driven by option acceleration instead of confounding performance shocks, then option acceleration should not cause outside director turnover to rise. This is precisely what we find in Table 10, Panel A. 29 To perform this test, we collect data on all outside directors sitting on the boards of 4,150 firms in our sample. Outside Director Turnover Rate is the number of outside directors departing a firm in year t+1 divided by the total number of outside directors on the firm s board in t + 1. We record director departures in the same way as executive departures. Column (1) reports OLS results regressing Outside Director Turnover Rate on Frac. Options Accelerated, and column (2) reports 2SLS results. [Insert Table 10 here] We find that the coefficients on Frac. Options Accelerated are statistically indistinguish- 29 In this section, we only present results for Frac. Options Accelerated in order to conserve space. We obtain almost identical results when using Accelerate instead. 33

35 able from zero in both regressions. This indicates that firms that accelerated option vesting did not subsequently experience a rise in outside director turnover. Yet, the negative coefficients on Stock Return in the regressions confirm that directors were more likely to leave following poor firm performance. Therefore, if an unobserved performance shock is correlated with both option acceleration and firms fiscal year ends, it can only bias our main results if it leads to a rise in executive but not outside director turnover. A.2. Executive Turnover Prior to Option Acceleration Another potential concern is that our 2SLS estimates could be biased by unobservable differences between early and late fiscal-year-end firms that also affect executive turnover. Table 2 shows that observable firm characteristics did not differ across fiscal year ends prior to FAS 123-R, but unobserved heterogeneity could violate our instrument s Exclusion Restriction. We complement the t-tests in that table by conducting a placebo analysis based on Rothstein (2010). The tests are in Table 10, Panel B. Columns (3) and (4) examine the relationship between executive turnover in 2001/2002 and option acceleration four years into the future, and columns (5) and (6) examine the relationship between turnover in 2003/2004 and acceleration two years into the future. In each column we instrument option acceleration using firms FAS 123-R compliance dates four or two years into the future. 30 If our main results are due to a decrease in retention incentives from option acceleration, then we should observe no effect on executive turnover years before any firm accelerated option vesting. Indeed, all four regressions show that no such relationship exists. These results support our hypothesis that turnover rose only when executives were able to depart with their newly vested stock options as a result of option acceleration. Thus, to explain our results, any con- 30 Specifically, column (3) contains observations for firms in calendar years 2001 and The column regresses CEO Turnover in 2001 on the value of Frac. Options Accelerated in 2005, and CEO Turnover in 2002 on the value of Frac. Options Accelerated in We instrument Frac. Options Accelerated with an indicator for whether firms had to comply with FAS 123-R in 2005 or We follow the same procedure in columns (4) through (6). 34

36 founding variable must affect both option acceleration and executive turnover, and correlate with firms fiscal year ends only when FAS 123-R took effect. B. Further Isolating Voluntary Turnover Table 5 provides evidence that option acceleration led to a rise in voluntary CEO turnover. We next conduct additional tests to confirm that our results are not due to firings or scheduled retirements. Table 11, Panel A presents results of turnover regressions using subsets of firms for which these types of departures are highly unlikely. Column (1) estimates our baseline 2SLS model only for firms with CEOs below the age of 55, to rule out retirement-induced turnover. The standard executive retirement age is 65, so it is highly unlikely that CEOs 10 or more years younger would be scheduled to retire. Column (2) restricts the sample to firms with CEOs that have tenure of three years or less, as firms likely did not hire these CEOs just a few years before their planned retirement. Column (3) examines CEO turnover only among firms in the top tercile of operating performance (measured using ROA), as such high-performing firms rarely fire their CEOs. The results confirm that option acceleration led to higher turnover in each of these subsets of firms. Therefore, our results cannot be explained by forced turnover or scheduled retirements, but rather by a rise in voluntary departures. [Insert Table 11 here] As an additional test, in Table 11, Panel B we investigate whether option acceleration affected executive team turnover at high-performing firms. We define executive team turnover as the simultaneous departure of two or more executives from a firm. This analysis is insightful as it is unlikely that multiple executives simultaneously planned to retire or were fired from successful firms. Such departures however would support prior findings that executives possess team-specific human capital which loses value after a CEO or other top executive 35

37 departs (e.g., Fee and Hadlock (2004)). Column (4) shows that acceleration did indeed lead to greater turnover of executive teams. C. Other Robustness Tests Appendix A-4 examines whether our results are robust to various changes in the baseline specification. The 2SLS regressions in columns (1) and (2) show that our results are robust to excluding firms with December fiscal year ends in 2005, which constitute the majority of our sample and of accelerating firms. Columns (3) and (4) use an alternate empirical specification motivated by recent literature on forced turnover (e.g., Jenter and Kanaan (2015)). This literature separately estimates the turnover effects of industry performance and industry-adjusted performance. Our results are virtually unchanged using this specification. Finally, columns (5) and (6) estimate 2SLS models with firm fixed effects to account for fixed differences in turnover rates across firms. These regressions require a wider window of calendar years 2003 through 2007 to estimate firm fixed effects precisely. We continue to find a positive and highly statistically significant relationship between option acceleration and executive turnover. Lastly, we verify that indicators of macroeconomic performance did not change suddenly when FAS 123-R took effect. During the June 2005 to June 2007 period when accelerating firms experienced elevated turnover, the U.S. unemployment rate gradually fell from 5% to 4.4% while GDP growth averaged 2.5%. We find no evidence from broader economic conditions that executives outside opportunities abruptly changed. VI. Conclusion We show that a sudden reduction in executives retention incentives from unvested equity led to a substantial increase in voluntary turnover. We document this effect by exploiting a unique event that prompted 720 firms to accelerate stock option vesting periods to avoid an accounting expense under FAS 123-R. Option acceleration plausibly reduced retention incentives, as options worth $1.5 million vested immediately instead of after several years 36

38 (decreasing equity forfeited upon departure by 63%), and executives could retain this newly vested equity when departing the firm. To identify causality, we exploit exogenous variation in the staggered timing of FAS 123- R firms with fiscal years ending June or later had to comply in 2005, while firms with fiscal years ending May or earlier could delay compliance until These two sets of firms were observationally identical before the regulation took effect, but they eliminated vesting restrictions in different years. Our tests use a 2SLS model that instruments for option acceleration using fiscal year ends, allowing us to estimate turnover effects that are unaffected by endogenous matching of executives to firms, and to firms endogenous acceleration decisions. Our main results show that firms that accelerated options experienced a sharp increase in executive turnover. Strikingly, the increase in turnover corresponded exactly to firms staggered FAS 123-R compliance dates. Our 2SLS estimates suggest that a one-standarddeviation increase in the percentage of accelerated options due to earlier FAS 123-R compliance increased the CEO turnover rate from 6% to 19%, and the top executive turnover rate from 8% to 16%. Additionally, we show that our results are driven by voluntary turnover. We find no effect on the turnover of non-executive outside directors (who receive very little stock option compensation) in the same firms and years. Furthermore, turnover did not vary across fiscal year ends prior to FAS 123-R. Hence, in order for an omitted variable to bias our results, it would have to affect executive but not outside director turnover, and vary across fiscal year ends precisely when FAS 123-R took effect. We also document that CEO departures at accelerating firms led to substantial shareholder losses. Departure announcements are met with a negative stock price reaction of -1.4%, reducing accelerating firms market values by $31 million. We find that after experiencing departures, accelerating firms responded by increasing the pay of their remaining executives. We further find that newly hired CEOs received higher pay than the departing CEOs whom they replaced. Both findings indicate that executive departures allow firms to learn 37

39 about the value of top executives outside options. Our paper thus provides new evidence of one channel by which executives compensation converges to the market value for their skills. Overall, our results provide well-identified evidence that equity vesting periods are an important tool for retaining key employees. This implication is important for firms that are designing recruitment and retention strategies, especially in high-tech industries where competition for top talent is fierce. Our findings on the effects of deferred pay are also relevant for policymakers who are debating new regulations on executive compensation, such as requirements that banks defer the payout of their executives bonuses.johnson, Magee, Nagarajan, and Newman (1985); Edmans, Gabaix, Sadzik, and Sannikov (2012); Edmans, Goncalves- Pinto, Wang, and Xu (2014); McConnell, Pegg, Senyek, and Mott (2005); Gopalan, Milbourn, Song, and Thakor (2014) 38

40 References Aboody, David, Mary E. Barth, and Ron Kasznik, 2004, Firms voluntary recognition of stock-based compensation expense, Journal of Accounting and Economics 42, Aldatmaz, Serdar, Paige Ouimet, and Edward D. Van Wesep, 2014, The option to quit: The effect of employee stock options, Working paper, University of North Carolina. Angrist, Joshua D., and Guido W. Imbens, 1994, Identification and estimation of local average treatment effects, Econometrica 62, Angrist, Joshua D., and Jörn-Steffen Pischke, 2009, Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist s Companion (Princeton University Press). Aon Hewitt, 2010, 2010 analysis of outside director compensation, Industry Study. Balsam, Steven, Richard H. Gifford, and Sungsoo Kim, 2007, The effect of stock option grants on voluntary employee turnover, Review of Accounting and Finance 6, Balsam, Steven, Austin Reitenga, and Jennifer Yin, 2008, Option acceleration in response to SFAS 123(R), Accounting Horizons 22, Cai, Jie, and Anand M. Vijh, 2007, Incentive effects of stock and option holdings of target and acquirer CEOs, Journal of Finance 62, Carhart, Mark M., 1997, On persistence in mutual fund performance, Journal of Finance 52, Chen, Mark A., 2004, Executive option repricing, incentives, and retention, Journal of Finance 59, Choudhary, Preeti, Shivaram Rajgopal, and Mohan Venkatachalam, 2009, Accelerated vesting of employee stock options in anticipation of FAS 123-R, Journal of Accounting Research 47,

41 Cohen, Lauren, Andrea Frazzini, and Christopher Malloy, 2010, Sell-side school ties, Journal of Finance 65, Core, John, and Wayne Guay, 2002, Estimating the value of employee stock option portfolios and their sensitivities to price and volatility, Journal of Accounting Research 40, Custodia, Claudia, Miguel A. Ferreira, and Pedro Matos, 2013, Generalists versus specialists: Lifetime work experience and CEO pay, Journal of Financial Economics 108, Denis, David J., Diane K. Denis, and Atulya Sarin, 1997, Ownership structure and top executive turnover, Journal of Financial Economics 45, Denis, David J., and Jan M. Serrano, 1996, Active investors and management turnover following unsuccessful control contests, Journal of Financial Economics 40, Duchin, Ran, and Denis Sosyura, 2013, Divisional managers and internal capital markets, Journal of Finance 68, Edmans, Alex, Vivian W. Fang, and Katharina A. Lewellen, 2016, Equity vesting and investment, Working paper, London Business School. Edmans, Alex, Xavier Gabaix, and Augustin Landier, 2009, A multiplicative model of optimal CEO incentives in market equilibrium, Review of Financial Studies 22, Edmans, Alex, Xavier Gabaix, Tomasz Sadzik, and Yuliy Sannikov, 2012, Dynamic CEO compensation, Journal of Finance 67, Edmans, Alex, Luis Goncalves-Pinto, Yanbo Wang, and Moqi Xu, 2014, Strategic news releases in equity vesting months, Working paper, London Business School. Eisfeldt, Andrea L., and Camelia M. Kuhnen, 2013, CEO turnover in a competitive assignment framework, Review of Financial Studies 109, Fahlenbrach, Rüdiger, Angie Low, and René M. Stulz, 2013, The dark side of outside directors: Do they quit ahead of trouble?, Working paper, Swiss Finance Institute. 40

42 Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1993, Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 33, Fee, Edward C., and Charles J. Hadlock, 2003, Raids, rewards and reputations in the market for managerial talent, Review of Financial Studies 16, , 2004, Management turnover across the corporate hierarchy, Journal of Accounting and Economics 37, Fracassi, Cesare, and Geoffrey Tate, 2012, External networking and internal firm governance, Journal of Finance 67, Gabaix, Xavier, and Augustin Landier, 2008, Why has CEO pay increased so much?, Quarterly Journal of Economics 123, Gopalan, Radhakrishnan, Sheng Huang, and Johan Maharjan, 2014, The role of deferred pay in retaining managerial talent, Working paper, Washington University in St. Louis. Gopalan, Radhakrishnan, Todd Milbourn, Fenghua Song, and Anjan V. Thakor, 2014, Duration of executive compensation, Journal of Finance 69, Hall, Brian J., and Jeffrey B. Liebman, 1998, Are CEOs really paid like bureaucrats?, Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, Harford, Jarrad, 2003, Takeover bids and target directors incentives: The impact of a bid on directors wealth and board seats, Journal of Financial Economics 69, Hazarika, Sonali, Jonathan M. Karpoff, and Rajarishi Nahata, 2012, Internal corporate governance, CEO turnover, and earnings management, Journal of Financial Economics 10, Huson, Mark R., Robert Parrino, and Laura T. Starks, 2001, Internal monitoring mechanisms and CEO turnover: A long term perspective, Journal of Finance 56,

43 Ittner, Christopher D., Richard A. Lambert, and David F. Larcker, 2003, The structure and performance consequences of equity grants to employees of new economy firms, Journal of Accounting and Economics 34, Jenter, Dirk, and Fadi Kanaan, 2015, CEO turnover and relative performance evaluation, Journal of Finance 70, Jenter, Dirk, Egor Matveyev, and Lukas Roth, 2016, Good and bad CEOs, Working paper, London School of Economics. Johnson, W. Bruce, Robert P. Magee, Nandu J. Nagarajan, and Harry A. Newman, 1985, An analysis of the stock price reaction to sudden executive deaths: Implications for the managerial labor market, Journal of Accounting and Economics 7, Kaplan, Steven N., and Bernadette A. Minton, 2012, How has CEO turnover changed?, International Review of Finance 12, Kleibergen, Frank, and Richard Paap, 2006, Generalized reduced rank tests using the singular value decomposition, Journal of Econometrics 133, Ladika, Tomislav, and Zacharias Sautner, 2016a, Limited attention to detail: Changes in financial analysts valuations following mandatory option expensing, Working paper, University of Amsterdam., 2016b, Managerial short-termism and investment: Evidence from accelerated option vesting, Working paper, University of Amsterdam. Lazear, Edward P., 2005, Output-based pay: Incentives, retention or sorting?, Research in Labor Economics 23, McConnell, Pat, Janet Pegg, Chris Senyek, and Dane Mott, 2005, SEC does it: Delays effective date for employee stock option expensing, Bear Stearns Equity Research Note. 42

44 Oyer, Paul, and Scott Schaefer, 2005, Why do some firms give stock options to all employees? An empirical examination of alternative theories, Journal of Financial Economics 76, Parrino, Robert, 1997, CEO turnover and outside succession: A cross-sectional analysis, Journal of Financial Economics 46, Peters, Florian, and Alexander Wagner, 2014, The executive turnover risk premium, Journal of Finance 69, Rothstein, Jesse, 2010, Teacher quality in educational production: Tracking, decay, and student achievement, Quarterly Journal of Economics 125, Staiger, Douglas, and James H. Stock, 1997, Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments, Econometrica 65, Stock, James H., Jonathan H. Wright, and Motohiro Yogo, 2002, A survey of weak instruments and weak identification in generalized methods of moments, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 20, Weisbach, Michael, 1988, Outside directors and CEO turnover, Journal of Financial Economics 20, Yermack, David, 2004, Remuneration, retention, and reputation incentives for outside directors, Journal of Finance 59, , 2006, Golden handshakes: Separation pay for retired and dismissed CEOs, Journal of Accounting and Economics 41, , and Rangarajan K. Sundaram, 2007, Pay me later: Inside debt and its role in managerial compensation, Journal of Finance 62, Zingales, Luigi, 2000, In search of new foundations, Journal of Finance 55,

45 Figure 1. Hypothesis Testing using Staggered FAS 123-R Compliance This figure shows how firms staggered FAS 123-R compliance dates, which are based on variation in fiscal year ends, should affect option acceleration and executive turnover. Panel A shows the predicted effect of FAS 123-R compliance on option acceleration (1 st Stage), and Panel B shows the predicted effect on executive turnover (2 nd Stage). Late Fiscal-Year-End firms have a fiscal year ending in June through December, and Early Fiscal-Year-End firms have a fiscal year ending in January through May. Panel A. 1 st Stage Predicted Effect on Option Acceleration Panel B. 2 nd Stage Predicted Effect on Executive Turnover

46 Figure 2. Effect of FAS 123-R Compliance on Option Acceleration This figure examines the relationship between firms staggered FAS 123-R compliance dates and the likelihood of accelerating option vesting. All sample firms are sorted based on the calendar month in which their fiscal year ends. The figure shows the percentage of firms with fiscal year ending in each month that accelerated option vesting, from January 2005 through December 2006.

47 Figure 3. Effect of Option Acceleration on Vesting Schedules This figure examines the effect of option acceleration on the time until executives option holdings vest. The sample is top executives of ExecuComp firms that accelerated option vesting. The figure shows the average percentage of total unvested options that become exercisable within a year, in one to three years, and in more than three years. It also shows average values of Unvested Option Duration, with accelerated options s duration set to 0. We report these statistics in the year of option acceleration (t=0), and also one to three years before option acceleration (t=-1, -2, or -3).

48 Figure 4. Effect of Option Acceleration on CEO Turnover This figure examines whether CEO turnover rose in the year after option acceleration. Accelerating firms are sorted based on the calendar year in which they accelerated option vesting. The figure shows the percentage of firms that experienced a CEO departure within the following year.

The role of deferred pay in retaining managerial talent

The role of deferred pay in retaining managerial talent The role of deferred pay in retaining managerial talent Radhakrishnan Gopalan Olin School of Business Washington University in St. Louis Phone: +1 (314) 9354899 Email: gopalan@wustl.edu Sheng Huang Lee

More information

The Effect of Managerial Short Termism on Corporate Investment*

The Effect of Managerial Short Termism on Corporate Investment* The Effect of Managerial Short Termism on Corporate Investment* September 2013 Abstract We provide evidence that executives with more short term incentives engage in myopic behavior by reducing real investment.

More information

Managerial Short- Termism and Investment: Evidence from Accelerated Option Vesting*

Managerial Short- Termism and Investment: Evidence from Accelerated Option Vesting* Managerial Short- Termism and Investment: Evidence from Accelerated Option Vesting* Tomislav Ladika University of Amsterdam t.ladika@uva.nl Zacharias Sautner Frankfurt School of Finance & Management z.sautner@fs.de

More information

Limited Attention to Detail in Financial Markets

Limited Attention to Detail in Financial Markets Limited Attention to Detail in Financial Markets Henrik Cronqvist Tomislav Ladika Zacharias Sautner University of Miami University of Amsterdam Frankfurt School of Finance & Management This Draft: May

More information

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Journal of Financial Economics 47 (1998) 219 239 Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover Anup Agrawal*, Charles R. Knoeber College of Management, North Carolina State University, Raleigh, NC

More information

THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND THE LINK BETWEEN EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND FIRM PERFORMANCE CHNG BEY FEN

THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND THE LINK BETWEEN EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND FIRM PERFORMANCE CHNG BEY FEN THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND THE LINK BETWEEN EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND FIRM PERFORMANCE CHNG BEY FEN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE 2001 THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE

More information

Limited Attention to Detail in Financial Markets

Limited Attention to Detail in Financial Markets Limited Attention to Detail in Financial Markets Henrik Cronqvist Tomislav Ladika Zacharias Sautner University of Miami University of Amsterdam Frankfurt School of Finance & Management This Draft: December

More information

Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior

Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior By Jackson Mills Abstract The retention of deep in-the-money exercisable stock options by CEOs has generally been attributed to managers

More information

The Determinants of CEO Inside Debt and Its Components *

The Determinants of CEO Inside Debt and Its Components * The Determinants of CEO Inside Debt and Its Components * Wei Cen** Peking University HSBC Business School [Preliminary version] 1 * This paper is a part of my PhD dissertation at Cornell University. I

More information

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination Arvind Magesan and Jordi Mondria January 31, 2011 Abstract In this paper we study the economic and strategic incentives for a country to financially liberalize

More information

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares Zhangkai Huang * and Xingzhong Xu Guanghua School of Management Peking University Abstract Unlike in other countries, negotiated block shares have

More information

Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes *

Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes * Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes * E. Han Kim and Paige Ouimet This appendix contains 10 tables reporting estimation results mentioned in the paper but not

More information

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix

The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix The Persistent Effect of Temporary Affirmative Action: Online Appendix Conrad Miller Contents A Extensions and Robustness Checks 2 A. Heterogeneity by Employer Size.............................. 2 A.2

More information

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality DORON NISSIM* Corporate disclosures are an important source of information for investors. Many studies have documented strong price

More information

Online Appendix for Liquidity Constraints and Consumer Bankruptcy: Evidence from Tax Rebates

Online Appendix for Liquidity Constraints and Consumer Bankruptcy: Evidence from Tax Rebates Online Appendix for Liquidity Constraints and Consumer Bankruptcy: Evidence from Tax Rebates Tal Gross Matthew J. Notowidigdo Jialan Wang January 2013 1 Alternative Standard Errors In this section we discuss

More information

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* Sónia Costa** Luísa Farinha** 133 Abstract The analysis of the Portuguese households

More information

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? October 19, 2009 Ulrike Malmendier, UC Berkeley (joint work with Stefan Nagel, Stanford) 1 The Tale of Depression Babies I don t know

More information

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Miguel Antón, Florian Ederer, Mireia Giné, and Martin Schmalz August 13, 2016 Abstract This internet appendix provides

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

New Evidence on the Demand for Advice within Retirement Plans

New Evidence on the Demand for Advice within Retirement Plans Research Dialogue Issue no. 139 December 2017 New Evidence on the Demand for Advice within Retirement Plans Abstract Jonathan Reuter, Boston College and NBER, TIAA Institute Fellow David P. Richardson

More information

The role of dynamic renegotiation and asymmetric information in financial contracting

The role of dynamic renegotiation and asymmetric information in financial contracting The role of dynamic renegotiation and asymmetric information in financial contracting Paper Presentation Tim Martens and Christian Schmidt 1 Theory Renegotiation Parties are unable to commit to the terms

More information

Trinity College and Darwin College. University of Cambridge. Taking the Art out of Smart Beta. Ed Fishwick, Cherry Muijsson and Steve Satchell

Trinity College and Darwin College. University of Cambridge. Taking the Art out of Smart Beta. Ed Fishwick, Cherry Muijsson and Steve Satchell Trinity College and Darwin College University of Cambridge 1 / 32 Problem Definition We revisit last year s smart beta work of Ed Fishwick. The CAPM predicts that higher risk portfolios earn a higher return

More information

How can we assess the policy effectiveness of randomized control trials when people don t comply?

How can we assess the policy effectiveness of randomized control trials when people don t comply? Zahra Siddique University of Reading, UK, and IZA, Germany Randomized control trials in an imperfect world How can we assess the policy effectiveness of randomized control trials when people don t comply?

More information

Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation

Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation University of Massachusetts Boston From the SelectedWorks of Atreya Chakraborty January 1, 2010 Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation

More information

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN The International Journal of Business and Finance Research Volume 5 Number 1 2011 DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN Ming-Hui Wang, Taiwan University of Science and Technology

More information

Executive Financial Incentives and Payout Policy: Firm Responses to the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut

Executive Financial Incentives and Payout Policy: Firm Responses to the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXII, NO. 4 AUGUST 2007 Executive Financial Incentives and Payout Policy: Firm Responses to the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut JEFFREY R. BROWN, NELLIE LIANG, and SCOTT WEISBENNER ABSTRACT

More information

Corporate Ownership Structure in Japan Recent Trends and Their Impact

Corporate Ownership Structure in Japan Recent Trends and Their Impact Corporate Ownership Structure in Japan Recent Trends and Their Impact by Keisuke Nitta Financial Research Group nitta@nli-research.co.jp The corporate ownership structure in Japan has changed significantly

More information

The Market for Comeback CEOs. Rüdiger Fahlenbrach, Bernadette A. Minton, and Carrie H. Pan* Abstract

The Market for Comeback CEOs. Rüdiger Fahlenbrach, Bernadette A. Minton, and Carrie H. Pan* Abstract The Market for Comeback CEOs Rüdiger Fahlenbrach, Bernadette A. Minton, and Carrie H. Pan* November 18, 2006 Abstract We study the determinants and valuation consequences of the decision to rehire a former

More information

Limiting executive compensation: the case of CEOs hired after the imposition of 162(m).

Limiting executive compensation: the case of CEOs hired after the imposition of 162(m). Limiting executive compensation: the case of CEOs hired after the imposition of 162(m). Steven Balsam Department of Accounting Fox School of Business and Management Temple University Philadelphia, PA 19122

More information

Are Consultants to Blame for High CEO Pay?

Are Consultants to Blame for High CEO Pay? Preliminary Draft Please Do Not Circulate Are Consultants to Blame for High CEO Pay? Kevin J. Murphy Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Los Angeles, CA 90089-0804 E-mail: kjmurphy@usc.edu

More information

Credit Market Consequences of Credit Flag Removals *

Credit Market Consequences of Credit Flag Removals * Credit Market Consequences of Credit Flag Removals * Will Dobbie Benjamin J. Keys Neale Mahoney July 7, 2017 Abstract This paper estimates the impact of a credit report with derogatory marks on financial

More information

Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction of the Riester Scheme in Germany

Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction of the Riester Scheme in Germany Modern Economy, 2016, 7, 1198-1222 http://www.scirp.org/journal/me ISSN Online: 2152-7261 ISSN Print: 2152-7245 Effects of Tax-Based Saving Incentives on Contribution Behavior: Lessons from the Introduction

More information

Why do larger firms pay executives more for performance?

Why do larger firms pay executives more for performance? Why do larger firms pay executives more for performance? Performance-based versus labor market incentives VU Finance Lunch Seminar Bo Hu October 26, 2018 Department of Economics, Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam

More information

Internet Appendix for Do General Managerial Skills Spur Innovation?

Internet Appendix for Do General Managerial Skills Spur Innovation? Internet Appendix for Do General Managerial Skills Spur Innovation? Cláudia Custódio Imperial College Business School Miguel A. Ferreira Nova School of Business and Economics, ECGI Pedro Matos University

More information

DO TARGET PRICES PREDICT RATING CHANGES? Ombretta Pettinato

DO TARGET PRICES PREDICT RATING CHANGES? Ombretta Pettinato DO TARGET PRICES PREDICT RATING CHANGES? Ombretta Pettinato Abstract Both rating agencies and stock analysts valuate publicly traded companies and communicate their opinions to investors. Empirical evidence

More information

LIQUIDITY EXTERNALITIES OF CONVERTIBLE BOND ISSUANCE IN CANADA

LIQUIDITY EXTERNALITIES OF CONVERTIBLE BOND ISSUANCE IN CANADA LIQUIDITY EXTERNALITIES OF CONVERTIBLE BOND ISSUANCE IN CANADA by Brandon Lam BBA, Simon Fraser University, 2009 and Ming Xin Li BA, University of Prince Edward Island, 2008 THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL

More information

Inequality and GDP per capita: The Role of Initial Income

Inequality and GDP per capita: The Role of Initial Income Inequality and GDP per capita: The Role of Initial Income by Markus Brueckner and Daniel Lederman* September 2017 Abstract: We estimate a panel model where the relationship between inequality and GDP per

More information

Does the Board of Directors Learn from Short Sellers? Evidence from CEO Turnovers 1 Anja Kunzmann 2, Kristina M. Meier 3 December 31, 2016

Does the Board of Directors Learn from Short Sellers? Evidence from CEO Turnovers 1 Anja Kunzmann 2, Kristina M. Meier 3 December 31, 2016 Does the Board of Directors Learn from Short Sellers? Evidence from CEO Turnovers 1 Anja Kunzmann 2, Kristina M. Meier 3 December 31, 2016 Abstract We provide evidence that the board of directors learns

More information

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV John E. Floyd University of Toronto May 10, 2013 Our major task here is to look at the evidence regarding the effects of unanticipated money shocks on real

More information

Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance

Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance Manohar Singh The Pennsylvania State University- Abington Reporting a positive relationship between institutional ownership on one hand and capital expenditures

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 3 Fall 1994 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: THE CASE OF BANK LOAN COMMITMENTS

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 3 Fall 1994 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: THE CASE OF BANK LOAN COMMITMENTS Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 3 Fall 1994 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: THE CASE OF BANK LOAN COMMITMENTS James E. McDonald * Abstract This study analyzes common stock return behavior

More information

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK Scott J. Wallsten * Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research 579 Serra Mall at Galvez St. Stanford, CA 94305 650-724-4371 wallsten@stanford.edu

More information

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers

Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXVI, NO. 1 MARCH 1991 Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers HENRI SERVAES* ABSTRACT This paper analyzes the relation between takeover gains and the q ratios of targets and

More information

Internet Appendix for Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation? 1. Additional robustness checks

Internet Appendix for Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation? 1. Additional robustness checks Internet Appendix for Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation? This internet appendix provides robustness tests and supplemental analyses to the main results presented in Does Banking Competition Affect

More information

Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the U.S., Gerald Auten Geoffrey Gee And Nicholas Turner

Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the U.S., Gerald Auten Geoffrey Gee And Nicholas Turner Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the U.S., 1987 2010 Gerald Auten Geoffrey Gee And Nicholas Turner Cross-sectional Census data, survey data or income tax returns (Saez 2003) generally

More information

Capital Gains Taxation and the Cost of Capital: Evidence from Unanticipated Cross-Border Transfers of Tax Bases

Capital Gains Taxation and the Cost of Capital: Evidence from Unanticipated Cross-Border Transfers of Tax Bases Capital Gains Taxation and the Cost of Capital: Evidence from Unanticipated Cross-Border Transfers of Tax Bases Harry Huizinga (Tilburg University and CEPR) Johannes Voget (University of Mannheim, Oxford

More information

US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies

US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies Nathan Foley-Fisher Bernardo Guimaraes August 2009 Abstract We empirically analyse the appropriateness of indexing emerging market sovereign

More information

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Linda Goldberg and Joseph Tracy Federal Reserve Bank of New York and NBER April 2001 Abstract Although the dollar has been shown to influence

More information

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 17 Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 Luísa Farinha Pedro Prego 2 Abstract The analysis of liquidity management decisions by firms has recently been used as a tool to investigate the

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 1 Spring 1994 INSTITUTIONAL INVESTMENT ACROSS MARKET ANOMALIES. Thomas M.

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 1 Spring 1994 INSTITUTIONAL INVESTMENT ACROSS MARKET ANOMALIES. Thomas M. Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 1 Spring 1994 INSTITUTIONAL INVESTMENT ACROSS MARKET ANOMALIES Thomas M. Krueger * Abstract If a small firm effect exists, one would expect

More information

Compensation Consultants and the Level, Composition and Complexity of CEO Pay

Compensation Consultants and the Level, Composition and Complexity of CEO Pay Compensation Consultants and the Level, Composition and Complexity of CEO Pay Kevin J. Murphy Tatiana Sandino Working Paper 18-027 Compensation Consultants and the Level, Composition and Complexity of

More information

Empirical Methods for Corporate Finance. Regression Discontinuity Design

Empirical Methods for Corporate Finance. Regression Discontinuity Design Empirical Methods for Corporate Finance Regression Discontinuity Design Basic Idea of RDD Observations (e.g. firms, individuals, ) are treated based on cutoff rules that are known ex ante For instance,

More information

Public Employees as Politicians: Evidence from Close Elections

Public Employees as Politicians: Evidence from Close Elections Public Employees as Politicians: Evidence from Close Elections Supporting information (For Online Publication Only) Ari Hyytinen University of Jyväskylä, School of Business and Economics (JSBE) Jaakko

More information

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong Petra Gerlach-Kristen Hong Kong Institute of Economics and Business Strategy May, Abstract This paper uses unobserved components analysis to estimate

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance.

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. RESEARCH STATEMENT Heather Tookes, May 2013 OVERVIEW My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. Much of my work focuses on understanding the ways in which capital market

More information

The impact of introducing an interest barrier - Evidence from the German corporation tax reform 2008

The impact of introducing an interest barrier - Evidence from the German corporation tax reform 2008 The impact of introducing an interest barrier - Evidence from the German corporation tax reform 2008 Hermann Buslei DIW Berlin Martin Simmler 1 DIW Berlin February 15, 2012 Abstract: In this study we investigate

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

At the height of the financial crisis in December 2008, the Federal Open Market

At the height of the financial crisis in December 2008, the Federal Open Market WEB chapter W E B C H A P T E R 2 The Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand Curves 1 2 The Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand Curves Preview At the height of the financial crisis in December 2008, the

More information

Box 1.3. How Does Uncertainty Affect Economic Performance?

Box 1.3. How Does Uncertainty Affect Economic Performance? Box 1.3. How Does Affect Economic Performance? Bouts of elevated uncertainty have been one of the defining features of the sluggish recovery from the global financial crisis. In recent quarters, high uncertainty

More information

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade The Time Cost of Documents to Trade Mohammad Amin* May, 2011 The paper shows that the number of documents required to export and import tend to increase the time cost of shipments. However, this relationship

More information

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr.

The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving. James P. Dow, Jr. The Importance (or Non-Importance) of Distributional Assumptions in Monte Carlo Models of Saving James P. Dow, Jr. Department of Finance, Real Estate and Insurance California State University, Northridge

More information

Review of Recent Evaluations of R&D Tax Credits in the UK. Mike King (Seconded from NPL to BEIS)

Review of Recent Evaluations of R&D Tax Credits in the UK. Mike King (Seconded from NPL to BEIS) Review of Recent Evaluations of R&D Tax Credits in the UK Mike King (Seconded from NPL to BEIS) Introduction This presentation reviews three recent UK-based studies estimating the effect of R&D tax credits

More information

How exogenous is exogenous income? A longitudinal study of lottery winners in the UK

How exogenous is exogenous income? A longitudinal study of lottery winners in the UK How exogenous is exogenous income? A longitudinal study of lottery winners in the UK Dita Eckardt London School of Economics Nattavudh Powdthavee CEP, London School of Economics and MIASER, University

More information

FINANCIAL INTEGRATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CASE OF PORTFOLIO EQUITY FLOWS TO SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

FINANCIAL INTEGRATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CASE OF PORTFOLIO EQUITY FLOWS TO SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA FINANCIAL INTEGRATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CASE OF PORTFOLIO EQUITY FLOWS TO SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA A Paper Presented by Eric Osei-Assibey (PhD) University of Ghana @ The African Economic Conference, Johannesburg

More information

Compensation of Executive Board Members in European Health Care Companies. HCM Health Care

Compensation of Executive Board Members in European Health Care Companies. HCM Health Care Compensation of Executive Board Members in European Health Care Companies HCM Health Care CONTENTS 4 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 5 DATA SAMPLE 6 MARKET DATA OVERVIEW 6 Compensation level 10 Compensation structure

More information

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Yongsik Kim * Abstract This paper provides empirical evidence that analysts generate firm-specific

More information

THE WILLIAM DAVIDSON INSTITUTE AT THE UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN BUSINESS SCHOOL

THE WILLIAM DAVIDSON INSTITUTE AT THE UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN BUSINESS SCHOOL THE WILLIAM DAVIDSON INSTITUTE AT THE UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN BUSINESS SCHOOL Financial Dependence, Stock Market Liberalizations, and Growth By: Nandini Gupta and Kathy Yuan William Davidson Working Paper

More information

Incentive Compensation vs SOX: Evidence from Corporate Acquisition Decisions

Incentive Compensation vs SOX: Evidence from Corporate Acquisition Decisions Incentive Compensation vs SOX: Evidence from Corporate Acquisition Decisions DAVID HILLIER, PATRICK McCOLGAN, and ATHANASIOS TSEKERIS * ABSTRACT We empirically examine the impact of incentive compensation

More information

Political Connections, Incentives and Innovation: Evidence from Contract-Level Data *

Political Connections, Incentives and Innovation: Evidence from Contract-Level Data * Political Connections, Incentives and Innovation: Evidence from Contract-Level Data * Jonathan Brogaard, Matthew Denes and Ran Duchin April 2015 Abstract This paper studies the relation between corporate

More information

Ownership, Concentration and Investment

Ownership, Concentration and Investment Ownership, Concentration and Investment Germán Gutiérrez and Thomas Philippon January 2018 Abstract The US business sector has under-invested relative to profits, funding costs, and Tobin s Q since the

More information

Investment Insight. Are Risk Parity Managers Risk Parity (Continued) Summary Results of the Style Analysis

Investment Insight. Are Risk Parity Managers Risk Parity (Continued) Summary Results of the Style Analysis Investment Insight Are Risk Parity Managers Risk Parity (Continued) Edward Qian, PhD, CFA PanAgora Asset Management October 2013 In the November 2012 Investment Insight 1, I presented a style analysis

More information

How Much Does Size Erode Mutual Fund Performance? A Regression Discontinuity Approach *

How Much Does Size Erode Mutual Fund Performance? A Regression Discontinuity Approach * How Much Does Size Erode Mutual Fund Performance? A Regression Discontinuity Approach * Jonathan Reuter Boston College and NBER Eric Zitzewitz Dartmouth College and NBER First draft: August 2010 Current

More information

Does Manufacturing Matter for Economic Growth in the Era of Globalization? Online Supplement

Does Manufacturing Matter for Economic Growth in the Era of Globalization? Online Supplement Does Manufacturing Matter for Economic Growth in the Era of Globalization? Results from Growth Curve Models of Manufacturing Share of Employment (MSE) To formally test trends in manufacturing share of

More information

Financial liberalization and the relationship-specificity of exports *

Financial liberalization and the relationship-specificity of exports * Financial and the relationship-specificity of exports * Fabrice Defever Jens Suedekum a) University of Nottingham Center of Economic Performance (LSE) GEP and CESifo Mercator School of Management University

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Work-Life Balance and Labor Force Attachment at Older Ages. Marco Angrisani University of Southern California

Work-Life Balance and Labor Force Attachment at Older Ages. Marco Angrisani University of Southern California Work-Life Balance and Labor Force Attachment at Older Ages Marco Angrisani University of Southern California Maria Casanova California State University, Fullerton Erik Meijer University of Southern California

More information

Investment Decisions and Negative Interest Rates

Investment Decisions and Negative Interest Rates Investment Decisions and Negative Interest Rates No. 16-23 Anat Bracha Abstract: While the current European Central Bank deposit rate and 2-year German government bond yields are negative, the U.S. 2-year

More information

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD European Economic Review 42 (1998) 887 895 The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD Philip R. Lane *, Roberto Perotti Economics Department, Trinity College Dublin, Dublin 2, Ireland Columbia University,

More information

Top Executive Turnover in Japanese Non-listed Firms: Causes and Consequences 1

Top Executive Turnover in Japanese Non-listed Firms: Causes and Consequences 1 Top Executive Turnover in Japanese Non-listed Firms: Causes and Consequences 1 Iichiro Uesugi 2 Yukiko Saito 3 3/14/2009 Abstract We examine the pattern of top executive turnover among small non-listed

More information

Mandatory Compensation Disclosure, CFO Pay, and Corporate. Financial Reporting Practices *

Mandatory Compensation Disclosure, CFO Pay, and Corporate. Financial Reporting Practices * Mandatory Compensation Disclosure, CFO Pay, and Corporate Financial Reporting Practices * Hongyan Li Virginia Tech hongyan@vt.edu Jin Xu Virginia Tech xujin@vt.edu September 9, 2016 *Both authors are at

More information

Equity Vesting and Managerial Myopia * Alex Edmans a London Business School; Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania; NBER; and ECGI

Equity Vesting and Managerial Myopia * Alex Edmans a London Business School; Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania; NBER; and ECGI Equity Vesting and Managerial Myopia * Alex Edmans a London Business School; Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania; NBER; and ECGI Vivian W. Fang b Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota

More information

Does portfolio manager ownership affect fund performance? Finnish evidence

Does portfolio manager ownership affect fund performance? Finnish evidence Does portfolio manager ownership affect fund performance? Finnish evidence April 21, 2009 Lia Kumlin a Vesa Puttonen b Abstract By using a unique dataset of Finnish mutual funds and fund managers, we investigate

More information

Do Value-added Real Estate Investments Add Value? * September 1, Abstract

Do Value-added Real Estate Investments Add Value? * September 1, Abstract Do Value-added Real Estate Investments Add Value? * Liang Peng and Thomas G. Thibodeau September 1, 2013 Abstract Not really. This paper compares the unlevered returns on value added and core investments

More information

Equity Vesting and Managerial Myopia *

Equity Vesting and Managerial Myopia * Equity Vesting and Managerial Myopia * Alex Edmans a London Business School; Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania; NBER; CEPR; and ECGI Vivian W. Fang b Carlson School of Management, University of

More information

Research Methods in Accounting

Research Methods in Accounting 01130591 Research Methods in Accounting Capital Markets Research in Accounting Dr Polwat Lerskullawat: fbuspwl@ku.ac.th Dr Suthawan Prukumpai: fbusswp@ku.ac.th Assoc Prof Tipparat Laohavichien: fbustrl@ku.ac.th

More information

You Can't Take It With You: Sunset Provisions for Equity Compensation When Managers Retire, Resign, or Die

You Can't Take It With You: Sunset Provisions for Equity Compensation When Managers Retire, Resign, or Die You Can't Take It With You: Sunset Provisions for Equity Compensation When Managers Retire, Resign, or Die Sandeep Dahiya a and David Yermack b December 27 Abstract Company stock option plans have diverse

More information

Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion. Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b

Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion. Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b a Department of Finance, Spears School of Business, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, OK

More information

Learning from Coworkers: Peer Effects on Individual Investment Decisions

Learning from Coworkers: Peer Effects on Individual Investment Decisions Learning from Coworkers: Peer Effects on Individual Investment Decisions Paige Ouimet a Geoffrey Tate b Current Version: October 2017 Abstract We use unique data on employee decisions in the employee stock

More information

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Abdulrahman Alharbi 1 Abdullah Noman 2 Abstract: Bansal et al (2009) paper focus on measuring risk in consumption especially

More information

Distracted Shareholders and Corporate Actions

Distracted Shareholders and Corporate Actions Distracted Shareholders and Corporate Actions Corporate Finance - PhD Course 2017 Stefan Greppmair Motivation 1. Measuring Distraction A Thought Experiment Car 1 Medicals Car 2 Companies Shareholders Managers

More information

We follow Agarwal, Driscoll, and Laibson (2012; henceforth, ADL) to estimate the optimal, (X2)

We follow Agarwal, Driscoll, and Laibson (2012; henceforth, ADL) to estimate the optimal, (X2) Online appendix: Optimal refinancing rate We follow Agarwal, Driscoll, and Laibson (2012; henceforth, ADL) to estimate the optimal refinance rate or, equivalently, the optimal refi rate differential. In

More information

Pension fund investment: Impact of the liability structure on equity allocation

Pension fund investment: Impact of the liability structure on equity allocation Pension fund investment: Impact of the liability structure on equity allocation Author: Tim Bücker University of Twente P.O. Box 217, 7500AE Enschede The Netherlands t.bucker@student.utwente.nl In this

More information

Monitoring, Contractual Incentive Pay, and the Structure of CEO Equity-Based Compensation. Fan Yu. A dissertation

Monitoring, Contractual Incentive Pay, and the Structure of CEO Equity-Based Compensation. Fan Yu. A dissertation Monitoring, Contractual Incentive Pay, and the Structure of CEO Equity-Based Compensation Fan Yu A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

More information

PUBLIC HEALTH CARE CONSUMPTION: TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS OR

PUBLIC HEALTH CARE CONSUMPTION: TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS OR PUBLIC HEALTH CARE CONSUMPTION: TRAGEDY OF THE COMMONS OR A COMMON GOOD? Department of Demography University of California, Berkeley March 1, 2007 TABLE OF CONTENTS I. Introduction... 1 II. Background...

More information

Average Earnings and Long-Term Mortality: Evidence from Administrative Data

Average Earnings and Long-Term Mortality: Evidence from Administrative Data American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2009, 99:2, 133 138 http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/aer.99.2.133 Average Earnings and Long-Term Mortality: Evidence from Administrative Data

More information

Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz

Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz Mortality of Beneficiaries of Charitable Gift Annuities 1 Donald F. Behan and Bryan K. Clontz Abstract: This paper is an analysis of the mortality rates of beneficiaries of charitable gift annuities. Observed

More information