A Volatility Smirk that Defaults: The Case of the S&P 500 Index Options

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A Volatility Smirk that Defaults: The Case of the S&P 500 Index Options"

Transcription

1 A Volatility Smirk that Defaults: The Case of the S&P 500 Index Options Andreou C. Panayiotis (Lecturer in Finance) Durham University Durham Business School, Mill Hill Lane, DH1 3LB, Durham, UK, First Version: June 19 th, 2009 Abstract Modern financial engineering has dedicated significant effort in developing sophisticated option pricing models to replicate the implied volatility smirk anomaly. Nonetheless, there is limited empirical evidence to examine the causes of this anomaly implied by market options data. The primary purpose of this study is to investigate the time-series economic determinants that affect the shape of the S&P 500 index Implied Volatility Function (IVF). The analysis is carried out on a daily basis and covers the period from January 1998 to December One of the most important contributions of this study is to investigate how the market default risk affects the shape of the risk-neutral density function implied by the S&P 500 index options. In order to create the proxy for the market default risk, I compute the daily probability-to-default measure for all individual, non-financial, firms included in the S&P 500 index. The daily probability-to-default is calculated with the distance-to-default measure, which is based on s (1974) option pricing model. Part of my analysis includes discussions of the different versions of the default risk that I compute and compare with some key results reported in Bharath and Shumway (2008). My analysis shows that the market default risk has a dual role to play, since it can potentially capture both, the market leverage effect, as well as, the market s perceptions about the future growth/state of the economy. As such, market default risk has been found to affect the shape of the S&P 500 index IVF in numerous ways. The results suggest that, besides options pricing models that admit stochastic volatility and random jumps, it is also worthwhile to exploit models that take into account market leverage such as the ones of Geske (1979) and Toft and Prucyk (1997). More importantly, in a regression analysis where I disentangle the role of market leverage by separating it from the asset return, I show that the contemporaneous index return is still important in explaining the shape of the S&P 500 index IVF. The results of this study illuminate a set of economic determinants that are found to affect the risk-neutral density function of the index. These factors are related to characteristics of the underlying asset and micro-structure variables characterizing the option market itself. Financial engineers can exploit the role and importance of these factors in the future, in order to improve the forecasting accuracy, as well as, the hedging and risk management performance of option pricing models. JEL classification: G12, G13, G14 Keywords: default risk, implied volatility smirk, deterministic volatility functions, determinants, trading volume. Electronic copy available at:

2 1. Introduction Fischer Black and Myron Scholes introduced in 1973 their milestone parametric option pricing model that nowadays is known as the Black-Scholes (BS) formula. This model was a breakthrough in the pricing of options and still has a tremendous influence on the way that practitioners price various derivative securities. Despite its long lasting endurance in time, the BS formula is built on a set of simplistic assumptions. As such, it assumes that the asset price follows a geometric Brownian motion with constant volatility, thus, all options on the same asset should provide the same implied volatility. Many researchers have documented systematic biases (i.e. Rubinstein, 1994, Bakshi et al., 1997, Bates, 1996 and 2000) whereas, the BS implied volatilities for the S&P 500 index options tend to vary across option moneyness and time-to-maturity. This repudiates the principle that, under the assumptions of the BS model of a lognormal density, the index s option Implied Volatility Function (IVF) should be flat and constant through time. The S&P 500 index IVF forms a smile pattern prior to the October 1987 market crash, where out-of-the-money and in-the-money implied volatilities are higher compared to at-the-money ones. According to Rubinstein (1994, see also Dumas et al., 1998), after the crash a smirk pattern is most prominent where implied volatilities decrease monotonically as the option strike price rises relative to the index level (this stylized fact is also apparent in the dataset that I use herein). Moreover, implied volatilities (especially those of at-the-money options) also present a term structure pattern that again cannot be rationalized by the BS model. The modern financial engineering research has invented more elaborated option pricing models to mitigate the market biases associated with the BS model. For example, recent developments in this area relate to option pricing models that admit stochastic volatility (SV) or stochastic volatility and jump (SVJ) risk factors (e.g. Heston, 1993, Bates, 1991, 1996 and 2000, Bakshi et al., 1997). SV models are not capable of generating high levels of skewness and kurtosis at short maturities under reasonable parameterizations. The addition of a jump component enhances the distributional flexibility of the model, since it can now internalize additional levels of negative skewness and excess kurtosis. This allows the SVJ model to explain better the heavy-tailedness of the asset return distribution and to generate more realistic implied volatility smirk patterns, especially, at short maturities. Nevertheless, 1 Electronic copy available at:

3 Bakshi et al. (1997) point out, that SV and SVJ models are still misspecified, since their implied parameters (after being transformed from the risk-neutral to the real measure) are statistically inconsistent with those implicit by the time-series of the S&P 500 returns. In addition, for a given time-to-maturity, the modern theoretic parametric models cannot always generate implied volatility smirks, as sharp, as those that are typically observed in practise (see Das and Sundaram, 1999, Dumas et a., 1998, Pan, 2002, Backus et al., 2004). Based on Das and Sundaram (1999), it is even less obvious whether the theoretical predictions of such option pricing models are or can be made consistent with the observed term structure of the IVF. Another way to mitigate the implied volatility smirk anomaly is to employ interpolative techniques to model the local structure of the IVF; this is equivalent as of backing out the implied risk neutral density function from market option prices. As such, the implied binomial tree method of Dupire (1994), Derman and Kani (1994) and Rubinstein (1994) is so flexible that, in-sample, is capable of achieving a perfect match when fitted to option market prices across moneyness and timeto-maturity. Dumas et al. (1998) estimate regression-based Deterministic Volatility Function (DVF) specifications of quadratic forms that provide unique per-contract volatility estimates (in contrast to the overall average volatility estimates of Whaley, 1982), and examine how well they predict option prices out-of-sample. They find that this regression-based approach 1 produces significantly more accurate option prices and hedging parameters compared to the implied volatility trees. Bollen and Whaley (2004) find that the slope of the daily S&P 500 index IVF is erratic across time, which is able to explain the poor performance of the implied volatility trees approach when used for pricing and hedging options out-of-sample. Andreou et al. (2008a) extend the regression-based DVF models of Dumas et al. (1998) by developing a semi-parametric option pricing model able to produce Generalized Parameter Functions for the S&P 500 index IVF. Their semi-parametric method provides an enhancement of parameters beyond volatility (like skewness and kurtosis) without specifying a-priori a deterministic parametric functional form like in the case of DVF. This method results in excellent option pricing performance, 1 Option pricing models that require asset return volatility to be a deterministic function of the underlying asset price and time are appealing because they offer a practical approach to option pricing under stochastic volatility (see for instance Rosenberg, 2000). 2 Electronic copy available at:

4 which outperforms the regression-based DVF parametric counterparts in pricing and hedging the S&P 500 index options out-of-sample. It is also competitive in performance to models that admit stochastic volatility and random jumps. The superiority of this method comes from the fact that it captures the salient features embedded in the options data, since it does not impose any restrictive shapes for the higher moments across time. Andreou et al. (2008a) report that their semi-parametric models predict a smirk effect for short and medium term options, and also, skewness that is increasing in moneyness and decreasing in maturity, and kurtosis that is hump shaped in moneyness. Such results hint to serious misspecification of the stochastic processes that govern the dynamics of the parametric option pricing models 2. The former indicates that the discrepancy we observe between risk-adjusted option implied parameters and the estimated parameters from the time-series (see Bakshi et al., 1997, Pan, 2000) can be also attributed to micro-structure characteristics of the option markets, which are not related to the distributional characteristics of the underlying asset returns. From the previous discussions, it is obvious that the shape of the IVF 3 is significantly affected by economic variables not included in the existing and widely used theoretical (parametric) options pricing models. For instance, Peña et al. (1999) report evidence that variables that are related to liquidity and trading costs can explain the pronounced shape of the Spanish IBEX-35 index IVF. Bollen and Whaley (2004) report that changes in the shape of the S&P 500 index IVF are directly related to net buying pressure (computed from options trading volume) coming from public order flow. 2 Moreover, Das and Sundaram (1999) examine whether option pricing models that admit stochastic volatility or jumps can fit the data well by capturing the level of skewness and kurtosis implied by the data for all maturities. They state that (compared with empirical observations) jump models allow too rapid decay in skewness and kurtosis, and stochastic volatility models exhibit a hump shape overly pronounced for intermediate maturities. 3 It is well established in the literature that the shape of the IVF is directly linked to the shape of the risk-neutral density implied by option market prices. Shimko (1993) was the first one to show how to recover the riskneutral probability density function by fitting a smooth curve to the implied volatility smirk and by exploiting the idea of Breeden and Litzenberger (1978), that the second partial derivative of the European option with respect to strike price is proportional to the risk-neutral density of the asset s returns. Moreover, Bakshi et al. (2003) and Backus et al. (2004) have shown that the IVF is directly linked to the risk-neutral skewness and kurtosis of the implied distribution. Zhang and Xiang (2008) derive analytical formulas that allow them to recover the risk-neutral probability distribution from a smirk implied volatility function. Dennis and Mayhew (2002) find that there is one-to-one mapping between the risk neutral density function and the implied volatility curve, whereas negatively sloped volatility curves correspond to negative skewness in the risk-neutral density. Bakshi et al. (2003) verify a high correlation between their measure of the risk-neutral skewness and the slope of the implied volatility curve. Thus, it is obvious that investigating the shape of the daily S&P 500 index IVF is tantamount to investigating the shape of its option implied risk-neutral probability density function. 3

5 I model the S&P 500 index IVF using the regression-based DVF approach of Dumas et al. (1998). This method allows me to simultaneously model the slope and convexity of the IVF across option moneyness and time-to-maturity. Such treatment of the IVF is more elaborated compared with studies that ignore the time dimension and investigate the slope and/or the convexity of the IVF across moneyness only (e.g. see Peña et al., 1999, Dennis and Maynew, 2002, Bollen and Whaley, 2004, Chang et al., 2009, etc). Moreover, many studies in this area model the IVF using OLS estimation (e.g. Ncube, 1996, Peña et al., 1999, Chang et al., 2009). Yet, Christoffersen and Jacobs (2004) demonstrate that OLS estimates yield biased option pricing results and that a Nonlinear Least Squares pricing loss function should be used instead. For this reason, I estimate the regression-based DVF model using Nonlinear Least Squares - where the loss function is the price difference between the BS and the option market-price. It is well established in the literature that leverage, or equivalently default risk, affects the market prices of options (for instance, see Geske, 1979). There are also other theoretical proposals to support that the presence of leverage can give birth to a monotonically downward IVF, whereas the steepness of the smile depends on the level of leverage (see Toft and Prucyk, 1997). Thus, part of the empirical anomaly related to the implied volatility smirk can be attributed to default risk as well. For example, Geske and Zhou (2007) show that the leverage effect causes the index volatility to be both stochastic and inversely related to the level of the index. As a result, the index s implied returns distribution will have a fatter left tail and a thinner right tail than the BS assumption of a normal return distribution. Effectively, the former translates to a downward sloping volatility smile like the one we empirically observe for the S&P 500 index options. Figlewski and Wang (2000) find that the size of the leverage effect is distinctly greater for the S&P 100 index than for single stock options. Despite, the extant empirical evidence looking into the intimate relationship of default risk and implied volatility smirk is extremely limited and concentrated mainly on equity options 4. Moreover, such type of research for the S&P 500 index options is rather unexploited and merits further analysis. This study addresses this gap by investigating the time-series economic determinants that affect the shape of the S&P 500 index IVF. The analysis is carried out on a daily basis and covers the period from January 4 For instance, Walter (2007) manages to locate only a handful of studies in this area, with most of them focusing on the relationship between equity default risk and the (stock option) slope at the at-the-money point. 4

6 1998 to December More importantly, it assesses how one of the economics determinants considered, namely the market default risk, affects the shape of the risk-neutral density function implied by the S&P 500 index options 5. In order to create the proxy for the market default risk, I compute the daily probability-todefault for all individual, non-financial, firms included in the S&P 500 index. I employ the distance-to-default (thereinafter DD) measure as employed by Bharath and Shumway (2008) 6 to forecast corporate default values. As Bharath and Shumway (2008) assert, this is an innovative default probability forecasting model, which has been widely applied in both academic research and practice. The DD model combines the framework of s (1974) bond pricing model and, in conjunction with the contingent claims methodology of Black and Scholes (1973), it treats the equity as a call option on the firm s total assets with a strike price equal to the face value of the firm s debt. Given the value of the volatility of the firm s equity (a known quantity, readily available from the market), a procedure is applied to solve a system of two nonlinear equations in order to retrieve the value of the firm s total assets and volatility (both are unknown quantities). The distance-todefault measure captures the difference between the market-value of the firm s assets and the face value of its debt, scaled by the volatility of the firm s assets value that is measured to reflect the time horizon of the required forecast. Subsequently, the DD probability-to-default (i.e. default risk) for a particular firm (namely, π ) is calculated by plugging the total value of the firm s assets and the firm s volatility along with other observables into a z-score functional form 7. All in all, the DD model allows me to measure the value of leverage in market terms, and by using it, I gain a significant advantage compared to previous studies that measure leverage using book-values of debt retrieved from Compustat (e.g. Toft and Prucyk, 1997, Figlewski and Wang, 2000, Dennis and Mayhey, 2002, etc). 5 The S&P 500 index options are European styled and allow me to examine the effect of market default risk without having to control for any early exercise premium. 6 In the later sections, for compatibility purposes, I follow most of the nomenclature used by these authors. 7 This particular application of the (1974) model was developed by the proprietors of the KMV Corporation which was acquired by the Moody s in The model as applied in Bharath and Shumway (2008) differs in several potentially important aspects than that of Moddy s KMV, albeit they have found high correlations between the default probabilities produced by the DD model and the ones produced by the Moody s KMV model. The differences between the two alternative models are discussed in section 2.2 of Bharath and Shumway (2008). 5

7 I estimate the individual firm s default risk ( π Specifically, I consider the case when the expected return on the firm s asset ( ) using three different expected returns. ) is equal to: i) the firm s stock returns over the previous year ( r ), ii) the prevailing risk free rate ( r ), and iii) a return r G E ( ) which is given implicitly by the hedge parameters (i.e. Greek letters) that can be calculated as part of the solution of the DD model. Bharath and Shumway (2008) have considered only the μ V first two cases ( r and E r ), while to the best of my knowledge there is lack of empirical evidence regarding the third case ( ). Moreover, for comparison purposes with the results of Bharath and Shumway (2008), I also estimate their naïve alternative default probability measure ( default risk measure, mimics the functional form of ( r G π π naive ) but is much simpler to calculate. ). This Overall, I find that the market default risk is a primary economic determinant of the S&P 500 index IVF. Figlewski and Wang (2000) by using monthly returns data and quarterly book-values of debt, find a strong leverage effect for the S&P 100 index options but only in down markets. In contrast to them, I find a strong leverage effect even when the S&P 500 index is rising. Moreover, I find that the market default risk affects the shape of the IVF in other ways as well. There can be two explanations for this to happen. First, market default risk obtained via the DD model is a much better and a forward looking proxy of the leverage effect compared with the face value of the debt that Figlewski and Wang (2000) use 8. Moreover, the use of market default risk allows me to capture the leverage effect on a daily basis, while Figlewski and Wang (2000) investigate the leverage effect by measuring the change in volatility that results from the quarterly change in book-values of leverage. Second, my results suggest the existence of another important role between the contemporaneous index return and the shape of IVF. Specifically, the contemporaneous index return is still highly 8 Figlewski and Wang (2000) recognise this drawback by saying that: one problem with this specification, shared with previous articles on this subject, is that leverage should be measured using market-values for firm securities, but only the book-value of debt is available from Compustat. As a partial remedy to this, they construct a monthly series of leverage by assigning changes in outstanding bonds to the final month of the quarter in which they occur. Other studies that investigate the leverage effect rely also on the crucial assumption that book-value of debt is an adequate proxy for market-values (e.g. Toft and Prucyk, 1997, Dennis and Mayhey, 2002). 6

8 significant in explaining the S&P 500 index IVF even after I remove from it the effect of leverage 9. Thus, some of the inconsistencies that Figlewski and Wang (2000) find for the role of leverage might be explained by the fact, that the contemporaneous index return might not be the best proxy for market leverage in all time instances. Consistent with Figlewski and Wang (2000) though, my regression results reveal that the leverage effect cannot be the sole explanation for the implied volatility skew anomaly. Specifically, variables that are related to uncertainty, trading activity and direction of the underlying asset s future return, seem to be key determinants of the shape of the implied volatility function as well. In the following, I briefly discuss previous literature that is related to this topic. Subsequently, I review the DD model, I explain how I compute the market default risk and I also compare and contrast the different versions I consider with some key results reported in Bharath and Shumway (2008). Then, I discuss the methodology used in order to model the daily S&P 500 index IVF. Following that, I review the different datasets and I discuss the results. Finally, I conclude. 2. Relation to previous studies There is only a limited number of studies to investigate the link between the equity volatility smile and the default risk, like the ones of Toft and Prucyk (1997) and Dennis and Meyhew (2002). For instance, Dennis and Meyhew (2002) test whether leverage, firm size beta, trading volume and/or the put/call volume ratio can explain the cross-section variation in the equity risk-neutral skew. To the best of my knowledge, this is the first study to investigate whether market default risk acts as an economic determinant of the S&P 500 index IVF (or equivalently of the shape of the riskneutral index return density). Geske and Zhou (2007) is the only other study to elaborate on pertinent issues 10. Specifically, Geske and Zhou (2007) examine whether existing market leverage has an effect 9 The index return net of the leverage effect, continues to be negatively related to the level of the at-the-money implied volatility regardless of the period, but its relationship with the slope of the IVF swaps sign conditional on the market momentum (i.e. bullish or bearish). Moreover, the relation between the sign and magnitude of the market default risk with the slope of the IVF is conditional on the market momentum as well. 10 Bollen and Whaley (2004) focus their attention on how changes in the implied volatilities of the S&P 500 index options are related to the net buying pressure (an option volume related variable) that arises from public order flow. In the regressions, they also include as control variables, the contemporaneous index return, the trading volume of the index and one-day lagged change in the implied volatility. I also control for such variables in the regression analysis I consider later. 7

9 on the pricing of S&P 500 index put options. They separate the extent of the existing leverage effect in S&P 500 index options by measuring and using market leverage of the index that is retrieved using the Geske s (1979) model. My paper differs significantly from theirs with distinct contributions to the literature. First, I compute daily, the market-value of assets and the market-value of the leverage using a firm-by-firm approach; thus, depending on the year, I estimate daily around 400 firm default risk measures, which I aggregate in order to proxy the market default risk level. On the contrary, Geske and Zhou (2007) estimate only one market value of their variables per day, by summing the observations for all of the firms included in the S&P 500 index. I believe that my approach is better since I exclude all financial firms from my calculations because the debt of such firms has a totally different meaning 11. As a result, my proxy for the market default risk should be measured with higher accuracy. In addition, my approach enables me to observe daily the probability-to-default distribution across all firms included in my sample. On the contrary, Geske and Zhou (2007) have only a single point estimate of market-value of leverage. Nonetheless, by investigating the characteristics of the market default risk distribution we might reveal other important dimensions on the way that agents price and trade options in the market. Second, Geske and Zhou (2007), in order to estimate the market-values of their variables, use concurrently data from the underlying and the option market. In such cases, the validity of the empirical results is based on the premise that the option market is fully integrated with the spot market, sharing the same price dynamics and the same market prices of risk (see Pan, 2002) 12. One example that invalidates this premise happens when the option s market is somehow segmented from the spot market, because of some option-specific factors, such as liquidity. Bollen and Whaley (2004) find that the volatility smirk can be attributed to the buying pressure (excess demand) of specific option series and the limited ability of arbitrageurs to bring prices back to alignment (see also discussions in Peña et al., 1999, and Chang et al., 2009). I also find that options trading activity is a 11 It is usual to exclude financial firms because high leverage that is normal for these firms probably does not have the same meaning as for non-financial firms, where high leverage more likely indicates financial distress (see Fama and French, 1992). 12 As noted by Das and Sundaram (1999), Chernov and Ghysels (2000) and Christoffersen et al. (2009) for the purpose of option valuation, parameters estimated from option prices are preferable to parameters estimated from the underlying returns. 8

10 significant economic determinant of the S&P 500 index IVF. Unlike Geske and Zhou (2007), my purpose in this study is to see whether the market default risk is an economic determinant of the S&P 500 index IVF. In my case though, I do not have to bear the restricting assumption that the option market is fully integrated with the spot market because the individual firm s probability-to-default measures are estimated using data of the underlying market only. Third, following Campbell et al. (2008), I align each firm s fiscal year appropriately with the calendar year, and then I lag accounting data by two months. This ensures that all quarterly accounting data needed for the DD model are publicly available before each estimation period, and limits significantly any look-ahead bias in the construction of the market default risk measure. On the contrary, Geske and Zhou (2007) do not allow for such lag period when they use quarterly balance sheet information collected from the S&P s Compustat database. Finally, the main purpose of Geske and Zhou (2007) is to investigate the out-of-sample pricing performance of the Geske s leverage-based option pricing model. In other words, they want to see how stochastic characteristics for volatility, jumps and interest rates are estimated better after accounting for leverage. In contrast, my primary purpose is to identify the set of economic determinants that affect the shape of the S&P 500 index IVF. At the end, the findings of my study offer an empirical justification for the results reported by Geske and Zhou (2007). Moreover, my results offer an empirical motivation that, besides options pricing models that admit stochastic volatility and random jumps, it is also worthwhile to exploit models that take into account market leverage such as the ones of Geske (1979) and Toft and Prucyk (1997). 3. The Default Risk Model and Methodology for Modeling the S&P 500 Index IVF Below, I first describe the DD model and the different default risk measures that I consider. Following that, I rationalize the use of DD model for meeting the needs of this study, and I describe the methodology used to model daily the S&P 500 index IVF. 9

11 3.1 The DD Model In corporate finance, equity holders are considered to be residual claimants on the firm s assets after all other obligations have been met. Therefore, equity can be considered to be a call option on the firm s total assets, whereas equity holders will exercise only when the underlying value of the firm s assets is greater than the book-value (i.e. face value) of the firm s liabilities. The market-value of the firm is the sum of the market-values of the firm s debt and equity. The market-value of equity can be easily computed by multiplying the firm s market-value of its stock times the number of outstanding shares, whilst only the book-value of the debt is readily available 13. As explained by Bharath and Shumway (2008), in such a case, the DD model estimates the market-value of the debt by applying the classic (1974) bond pricing model. This model posits that the dynamics of the equity value of the company can be described by a geometric Brownian motion where E is the value of the firm s equity, de = μ E Edt + σ EdW, (1) E μ E is the expected continuously compounded return on E (i.e. the instantaneous drift), σ is the instantaneous volatility of firm s equity values, and dw is a standard Gauss-Wiener process. (1974) shows that the dynamics of the total value of a firm can also be described by a geometric Brownian motion E dv = μ V Vdt + σ VdW, (2) V where V is the total value of the firm s assets, μ V is the expected continuously compounded return on V (i.e. the instantaneous drift), and σ is the instantaneous volatility of firm value. V The model assumes that the capital structure of the firm includes: i) the residual claim, equity, and ii) a single, homogeneous class of debt (i.e. discount bond) that pays of the total amount to the bondholders on a specified calendar date, T, in the future. Under the classic (1974) model, the market-value of equity, E, can be viewed as a call option on the total value of the assets, V (i.e. the underlying asset), with exercise price equal to the face value of the debt, F, and time-to-maturity 13 In addition, the firm s total value volatility is not observable and should be estimated somehow from other quantities. 10

12 T. Therefore, the market-value of the equity can be written at any point in time as a function of the value of the firm and time (i.e. E = f ( V, T ) ), thus, it can be described by the Black and Scholes (1973) formula for call options, as follows, where Fe rt E = VΝ(d) Ν( d σ T ), (3) ln( V / F) + ( r + 0.5σV ) T d = σ T V 2, (4) with r to be the instantaneous risk-free rate, σ to be the volatility of the firm value, and Ν (.) to be V the cumulative standard normal distribution. The volatility of the firm s total asset is not readily available from the market, but it can be retrieved by an explicit functional relationship that links it with other observables. To achieve this, the model explores the fact that E = f ( V, T ), and uses Ito s Lemma to derive another expression for the dynamics of the equity, given by: E E E E de = 0.5σVV + μ V dt V dw 2 V + + σv V V t. (5) V By comparing the diffusion terms of Eq. (1) and Eq. (5), it follows directly that the volatility of the equity returns,, equals: σ E V E σ E = σv. (6) E V By noticing also that E / V = Ν( d) is the delta hedge parameter that is computed by Eq. (3), the resulting relationship becomes: V σ E = Ν( d) σv, (7) E where d is given by Eq. (4). Eq. (7) reflects the fact that because of leverage, the volatility of an option (i.e. the equity in this case) is always greater than or equal to the volatility of the underlying asset (i.e. the market-value of the total assets). Moreover, Eq. (7) can offer an explanation to the stylized negative correlation between the index price and its volatility; that is, when the equity index level drops, the equity index volatility rises and vice versa. 11

13 It is obvious that E, σ E, and r can be observed from the financial markets, F and T can be observed from the financial statements of the firm, whilst V and σ V should be inferred using the DD model, since neither of them is directly observable. Nonetheless, it is easy to construct measures of these variables by solving Eqs. (3) and (7) simultaneously. Once this numerical solution is obtained for V and σ V, the distance-to-default value at each time instance is: DD t ln( V / F) + ( μ = σ V V 0.5σ T 2 V ) T. (8) The resulting probability-to-default value is computed using the normal cumulative distribution, which is the distribution implied by the (1974) model 14, and is given as follows: π = Ν DD ). (9) ( t Vassalou and Xing (2004) and Bharath and Shumway (2008) follow a complicated iterative procedure that uses historical returns data in order to find the implicit values 15 of V and σ V. In this paper, I solve Eqs. (3) and (7) simultaneously via a numerical nonlinear root finding algorithm. I do this for three reasons. First, this estimation scheme is straightforward and it is considered sufficient approach for the given problem; for example, it has been employed recently by Campbell et al. (2008), Agarwal and Taffler (2008), and Hillegeist et al. (2004) among others. Second, Vassalou and Xing (2004) and Bharath and Shumway (2008) apply their approach on a monthly basis, which is much less timeconsuming from applying it on a daily basis like in my case. Third, and more importantly, the empirical results of Bharath and Shumway (2008) support that the simultaneously solved π has actually better out-of-sample predicting performance than the one that is solved iteratively. 14 As Vassalou and Xing (2004, pg. 837) explain, strictly speaking, π is not a default probability because it does not correspond to the true probability-of-default in large samples. In contrast, the default probabilities calculated by Moody s KMV are indeed default probabilities because they are calculated using the empirical distribution of distance-to-default values. As pointed out by Bharath and Shumway (2008), albeit the empirical distribution of distances-to-default is an important input to default probabilities, it is not required for ranking firms by their relative probability. 15 First, they use daily data from the past 12 months to obtain an estimate of the equity volatility σ E, which is then used to initialize σ V and they use this value in Eq. (3) to infer the market-value of each firm s assets every day. They then calculate the implied log-return on assets each day and use that returns series to generate new estimates for σ and using a numerical nonlinear root finding algorithm. They iterate on in this manner V μ V σv until it converges, so the absolute difference in adjacent values is less than a small threshold. 12

14 3.2. The Naïve DD Model Bharath and Shumway (2008) have proposed a naïve estimator of the distance-to-default measure that requires the same basic inputs and resembles the functional form and structure of the original DD model. Its intriguing feature is that is simple enough to implement, since it does not require solving any equations or estimating any difficult quantities. Bharath and Shumway (2008) approximate the total volatility of the firm for their naïve estimator as follows: E F naive σv = σ E + naive σ D, (10) E + F E + F where naive σ D is their approximation for the volatility of each firm s debt, given by: naive σ = (11) D σ E They include the five percentage points to represent the term structure of volatility, and they include 25% times equity volatility to allow for volatility associated with default risk. Moreover, they set the expected return on the firm s assets equal to the firm s stock return over the previous year, naive μ =, (12) V r E which allows them to capture part of the same information captured by the DD model when estimated with the iterative procedure conditional on an entire year of equity return data. They define the naïve distance-to-default value as: naive DD t ln[( E + F) / F] + ( re 0.5 naiveσ = naiveσ T V 2 V ) T, (13) and the naïve probability-to-default as: π = Ν(-naive DD ). (14) naive Bharath and Shumway (2008) show empirically that the naïve estimator captures approximately the same quantity of information as the DD probability that is computed with the complicated iterative approach using historical equity returns (like the one used in Vassalou and Xing, 2004). t 3.3. Alternative market-based probability-to-default estimators Before moving into the main analysis, I would like to gauge the relation between the different versions of the probability-to-default estimators. It is very interesting to see whether the empirical 13

15 relationships of the estimators reported before in Bharath and Shumway (2008) hold in my data as well. I consider three alternative cases where Eqs. (3) and (7) are solved simultaneously 16, but every time a different expected return on the firm s total assets ( μ ) is used to compute the default risk value given by Eq. (9). The first two have been considered by Bharath and Shumway (2008). The first V predictor is r as μv = E π, where the expected return on the firm s sets is equal to the firm s stock return μ V = r over the previous year ( r ). The second estimator is π, where the prevailing risk-free rate ( r ) E μ = V is used as the expected return on the firm s assets. The third esti mator denoted by r G π, explores the fact that the expected return on the firm s assets can be expressed as a function of hedge parameters (i.e. Greek letters) computed via Eq. (3). Specifically, by comparing the drift terms of Eqs. (1) and (5), we have that and by rearranging terms, μ E E E E E = 0.5σVV + μvv + V 2, V t r G 2 2 E E E μv = ( μ E E 0.5σVV ) / V 2 V t V 2, (15) where the hedge parameters are given as follows (see Hull, 2008): delta : E V = Ν( d), (16) 2 E N' ( d) gamma : = 2 V V T σ V, (17) E theta : t V Ν' ( d) σ = 2 T V rfe rt Ν( d σ V T ), (18) with Ν '( d) to denote the density function for the standard normal distribution. This estimator has not been considered by prior studies such as the ones of Bharath and Shumway (2008), Campbell et al. (2008) and Vassalou and Xing (2004). 16 For the simultaneous estimation, the starting value for V is set to E + F, whilst for is set to σ E ( E / E + F). 14 σ V

16 After estimating daily the probability-to-default measures for each one of the firms in my sample, I create the alternative measures of market default risk by aggregating the individual firmspecific default risks. For example, the market default risk on trading day t is computed by aggregating the firm-specific default risks μv = re π as follows: Market default risk: n t 1 V re V re Π μ = ( t) = π μ = ( i, t), (19) n t i= 1 where V r n denotes the number of firms in trading day t, and π E ( i, t) t μ = represents the default risk computed for firm i on trading day t using the DD model. The market default risk measures using the rest probability-to-default estimators are estimated accordingly in a similar manner The DD model as a proxy for default risk Bharath and Shumway (2008) conclude that the DD model is useful method for modeling the firm s default risk, albeit not a totally sufficient statistic for accurately forecasting the (exact) probability-to-default value. In a similar view, Campbell et al. (2008) assess that an econometric approach that allows volatility and leverage to enter into the model with free coefficients is a better alternative compared to the DD model. Nevertheless, both studies attest that the DD model captures important aspects of the process that determines the corporate failure and that it can provide useful guidance for building default forecast models. My goal in this paper is not to predict corporate failures as in the studies of Campbell et al. (2008), Bharath and Shumway (2008) and Hillegeist et al. (2004). I rather seek to investigate whether the market default risk is an economic determinant of option related variables and more specifically, whether it can explain the daily shape of the S&P 500 index IVF. In this context, I presume that the values computed via the DD model is an adequate proxy for the market default risk, for several reasons. 15

17 First, the DD model is estimated using market variables, which by virtue are forwardlooking and reflect investor s expectations about future. This is most relevant for my analysis, since information embedded in option data is forwarding looking as well. Second, because the model employs market-based variables, it is able to capture timely information about default risk faster than traditional agency rating models 17 and econometric approaches that rely on accounting ratio-based data 18 (see Bharath and Shumway, 2008, and Agarwal and Taffler, 2008). Evidently, the DD model gives me a significant advantage over previous studies that measure leverage using book-values of debt retrieved from Compustat (e.g. Toft and Prucyk, 1997, Figlewski and Wang, 2000, Dennis and Mayhey, 2002, etc). Third, Agarwal and Taffler (2008) conclude that in terms of predicting accuracy, there is little difference between the market-based and accounting-based models. Despite this, the DD model preserves two significant features over traditional econometric models that are developed using accounting ratio-based variables (such the ones of Altman, 1968, and Ohlson, 1980), or more recent leading econometric alternatives that make use of market-based variables as well. One significant feature is that the DD model can produce the default risk values on a daily basis, for every firm in my sample and at any given point in time. Such capability coincides with the needs of my analysis. In contrast, recent leading alternative estimators, such as the dynamic logit model of Campbell et al. (2008) that makes use of both accounting and market data, is shown to outperform the DD when the models are estimated at a monthly frequency. The other significant feature is that the DD model is neither a time nor a sample specific estimator, since it can be estimated independently for any firm. In contrast, the default risk forecasting performance of econometric approaches is likely to be sample specific. As argued by Hillegeist et al. (2004) and Agarwal and Taffler (2008), econometric estimators are typically developed by searching through a large sample of 17 Most of the times, bond-ratings changes take place with a significant delay. Thus, the rating change can be a poor estimator of the probability-to-default measure (see Vassalou and Xing, 2004). 18 Vassalou and Xing (2004) conjecture that there are several concerns about the use of accounting models in estimating the default risk of equities, since they use information derived from financial statements. As they say, such information is inherently backward looking, since financial statements aim to report a firm s past performance, rather than its future prospects. Agarwal and Taffler (2008) criticize the validity of accountingbased models because accounting numbers are subject to manipulation by the management and in addition, conservatism and historical cost accounting imply that the true asset values may be very different from the bookvalues. Hillegeist et al. (2004) argue that because financial statements are formulated under the going-concern principle, their ability of assessing the individual s firm default risk will be limited by design. 16

18 accounting and/or market ratios with the ratio weightings estimated on a large sample of failed and non-failed firms (traded in many different stock exchanges like NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ). In this study, I focus my analysis on the companies included in the S&P 500 index only, making it a very specific group of companies. These are leading firms in leading industries of the U.S. economy, and by nature are very large in market capitalization, have high financial viability and high prices per share. Campbell et al. (2008) report that financially distressed firms tend to be relatively small, have severely low financial viability, and tend to trade at very low prices per share. Under this, it is high unlikely that the superiority of the econometric models over the DD model will hold in my sample too Option pricing approach: The Black and Scholes model The dividend adjusted Black and Scholes (1973) formula (see also, 1973) for the value of the European call option is: c BS = Se d T y o N( δ) Ke r T o o N( d δ T ), (20.1) o and for the value of the European put option is: with BS r T d T o o y o p = Ke N( δ + σ T ) Se N( δ), (20.2) o ln( S / K) + ( ro - d y ) To + ( σ δ = σ T o T o ) 2 / 2. (20.3) In the above expressions, S is the spot price of the underlying asset; K is the strike price of the r o option; is the continuousl y compounded risk free interest rate; d is the continuous dividend yield T o paid by the underlying asset; is the time left until the option expiration date; σ is the yearly variance of the rate of re turn for the underlying asset and N(.) stands for the standard normal cumulative distribution. y 2 19 In addition, since the majority of the bankrupt firms do not match the characteristics of the ones included in the S&P 500 index, it would be very difficult to develop an econometric model to provide an accurate default risk measure for such firms. 17

19 The abundant empirical evidence regarding the smirk behavior of the BS implied volatility is indicative of implied return distributions that are negatively skewed and heavier tailed than those im plied by the BS log-normal distribution (see Bakshi et al., 1997 and Bates, 2000). Thus, the regression-based DVF approach of Dumas et al. (1998) is a way to mitigate the volatility smirk anomaly, by allowing the implied volatilities to be deterministic functions of the option s strike price ( K ) and maturity ( T o ) 20. According to Dumas et al. (1998), the approach of smoothing the BS implied volatilities across strike prices and maturities exhibits superior in- and out-of-sample performance for pricing European options. Christoffersen and Jacobs (2004) have found that this approach outperforms the Heston (1993) SV model. The DVF parameters can be estimated using either OLS - where the loss function is the difference between the estimated and the actual contractspecific implied volatility - or Nonlinear Least Squares - where the loss function is the difference between the theoretical/model-based and the actual/market-based option prices. In fact, many studies in this area concentrate only on OLS estimation (e.g. Ncube, 1996, Peña et al., 1999, Chang et al., 2009). Yet, Christoffersen and Jacobs (2004) demonstrate that OLS estimates of such regression based models yield biased option pricing results and that a Nonlinear Least Squares pricing loss function should be used instead. Akin to Andreou et al. (2008b), I model the S&P 500 index IVF using Nonlinear Least Squares based on the following DVF specification: o 4 o 5 o σ = max(0.01, a + a LnX + a ( LnX ) + a T + a ( LnX ) T + a T ) (21) where X = S / K (i.e. the moneyness ratio). Following Dumas et al. (1998), a minimum value of 0.01 is imposed to prevent negative values of volatility. An intriguing advantage of this specification is that, for a given maturity, the at-the-money implied volatility value is explicitly defined by the intercept a 0. This happens because the natural logarithm of an option that is exactly at-the money (X =1) equals zero. The coefficient a 1 ( a 2 ) captures the slope (curvature) of the implied volatility smirk with respect to moneyness. For instance, Zhang and Xiang (2008) derive analytical formulas that relate the level ( a 0 ), the slope ( a1 ) and the convexity ( a 2 ) of the IVF, to standard deviation, 20 This is equivalent saying that the DVF approach is able to capture the salient features of negative skewness and excess kurtosis of the risk-neutral distribution that is implied by the market option data at different maturities. 18

20 skewness and excess kurtosis of the risk-neutral distribution of the underlying asset. The coefficient a 3 ( a 5 ) captures the slope (curvature) of the term structure/time-dimension. The use of a quadratic time-term is motivated by the empirical presence of curvature (even humps) in the term structure of implied volatility 21. The coefficient a 4 reflects the importance of the cross product ( LnX ) T that allows the DVF slope with respect to moneyness to be time dependent, and the slope with respect to time to depend on the moneyness level, thus capturing changes in the shape of the volatili ty smirk over different maturities. The regression based-dvf coefficients in Eq. (21) are obtained via Nonlinear Least Squares by using the Whaley s (1982) simultaneous equation procedure 22. According to this method, option mrk market prices ( o ) are assumed to be the corresponding BS-DVF estimates ( o ) plus a BS DVF BS DVF random additive disturbance term ( ε ): mrk o = o BS DVF + ε BS DVF (22) To find the implied DVF coefficient values daily, I estimate an optimization problem that has the following form: P t BS DVF j 2 SSE ( t) = min ( ε ) (23) ξ DVF j= 1 where P t refers to the number of different option transaction datapoints available in day t, and ξ DVF to the unknown DVF coefficients in Eq. (21). The SSE in Eq. (23) is minimized using the Levenberg- Marquardt method with a line search based on a mixed quadratic and cubic polynomial interpolation and extrapolation method offered by Matlab. Daily recalibration of the implied coefficients is also adopted by Christoffersen and Jacobs (2004) (see also discussions in Ncube, 1996, Peña et al., 1999, Rosenberg, 2000, Hull and Suo, 2002). 21 Empirical evidence of such curvature in the time structure of implied volatility can be found in Table II of Bakhsi et al. (1997), in Table 1 of Christoffersen et al. (2009). I have confirm that such curvature is present in my option data as well. 22 The methodology employed here for estimating daily the DVF coefficients via Nonlinear Least Squares is similar to that in previous studies that adopt the Whaley s (1982) simultaneous equation procedure to minimize a price deviation function with respect to the unobserved parameters (see for instance Bates, 1991, Bakshi et al., 1997, Dumas et al., 1998, Christoffersen and Jacobs, 2004, Christoffersen et al., 2009). See also Andreou et al. (2008b) for more details. 19

Hedging the Smirk. David S. Bates. University of Iowa and the National Bureau of Economic Research. October 31, 2005

Hedging the Smirk. David S. Bates. University of Iowa and the National Bureau of Economic Research. October 31, 2005 Hedging the Smirk David S. Bates University of Iowa and the National Bureau of Economic Research October 31, 2005 Associate Professor of Finance Department of Finance Henry B. Tippie College of Business

More information

1. What is Implied Volatility?

1. What is Implied Volatility? Numerical Methods FEQA MSc Lectures, Spring Term 2 Data Modelling Module Lecture 2 Implied Volatility Professor Carol Alexander Spring Term 2 1 1. What is Implied Volatility? Implied volatility is: the

More information

Lecture 4: Forecasting with option implied information

Lecture 4: Forecasting with option implied information Lecture 4: Forecasting with option implied information Prof. Massimo Guidolin Advanced Financial Econometrics III Winter/Spring 2016 Overview A two-step approach Black-Scholes single-factor model Heston

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model The Black-Scholes Model Liuren Wu Options Markets (Hull chapter: 12, 13, 14) Liuren Wu ( c ) The Black-Scholes Model colorhmoptions Markets 1 / 17 The Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) model Black and Scholes

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model The Black-Scholes Model Liuren Wu Options Markets Liuren Wu ( c ) The Black-Merton-Scholes Model colorhmoptions Markets 1 / 18 The Black-Merton-Scholes-Merton (BMS) model Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton

More information

Preference-Free Option Pricing with Path-Dependent Volatility: A Closed-Form Approach

Preference-Free Option Pricing with Path-Dependent Volatility: A Closed-Form Approach Preference-Free Option Pricing with Path-Dependent Volatility: A Closed-Form Approach Steven L. Heston and Saikat Nandi Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper 98-20 December 1998 Abstract: This

More information

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 The Greeks Introduction We have studied how to price an option using the Black-Scholes formula. Now we wish to consider how the option price changes, either

More information

Pricing of a European Call Option Under a Local Volatility Interbank Offered Rate Model

Pricing of a European Call Option Under a Local Volatility Interbank Offered Rate Model American Journal of Theoretical and Applied Statistics 2018; 7(2): 80-84 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/ajtas doi: 10.11648/j.ajtas.20180702.14 ISSN: 2326-8999 (Print); ISSN: 2326-9006 (Online)

More information

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Ilkka Rahikainen DIRECT METHODOLOGY FOR ESTIMATING THE RISK NEUTRAL PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTION

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Ilkka Rahikainen DIRECT METHODOLOGY FOR ESTIMATING THE RISK NEUTRAL PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTION OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL Ilkka Rahikainen DIRECT METHODOLOGY FOR ESTIMATING THE RISK NEUTRAL PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTION Master s Thesis Finance March 2014 UNIVERSITY OF OULU Oulu Business School ABSTRACT

More information

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Peter Carr NYU CBOE Conference on Derivatives and Volatility, Chicago, Nov. 10, 2017 Peter Carr (NYU) Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns 11/10/2017 1 / 33 Interest Rates

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh The Black-Scholes Model In these notes we will use Itô s Lemma and a replicating argument to derive the famous Black-Scholes formula

More information

Factors in Implied Volatility Skew in Corn Futures Options

Factors in Implied Volatility Skew in Corn Futures Options 1 Factors in Implied Volatility Skew in Corn Futures Options Weiyu Guo* University of Nebraska Omaha 6001 Dodge Street, Omaha, NE 68182 Phone 402-554-2655 Email: wguo@unomaha.edu and Tie Su University

More information

Portfolio Management Using Option Data

Portfolio Management Using Option Data Portfolio Management Using Option Data Peter Christoffersen Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto, Copenhagen Business School, and CREATES, University of Aarhus 2 nd Lecture on Friday 1 Overview

More information

No-Arbitrage Conditions for the Dynamics of Smiles

No-Arbitrage Conditions for the Dynamics of Smiles No-Arbitrage Conditions for the Dynamics of Smiles Presentation at King s College Riccardo Rebonato QUARC Royal Bank of Scotland Group Research in collaboration with Mark Joshi Thanks to David Samuel The

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Dynamic Relative Valuation Dynamic Relative Valuation Liuren Wu, Baruch College Joint work with Peter Carr from Morgan Stanley October 15, 2013 Liuren Wu (Baruch) Dynamic Relative Valuation 10/15/2013 1 / 20 The standard approach

More information

Edgeworth Binomial Trees

Edgeworth Binomial Trees Mark Rubinstein Paul Stephens Professor of Applied Investment Analysis University of California, Berkeley a version published in the Journal of Derivatives (Spring 1998) Abstract This paper develops a

More information

Credit Risk Modelling: A Primer. By: A V Vedpuriswar

Credit Risk Modelling: A Primer. By: A V Vedpuriswar Credit Risk Modelling: A Primer By: A V Vedpuriswar September 8, 2017 Market Risk vs Credit Risk Modelling Compared to market risk modeling, credit risk modeling is relatively new. Credit risk is more

More information

Chapter 18 Volatility Smiles

Chapter 18 Volatility Smiles Chapter 18 Volatility Smiles Problem 18.1 When both tails of the stock price distribution are less heavy than those of the lognormal distribution, Black-Scholes will tend to produce relatively high prices

More information

Simple Formulas to Option Pricing and Hedging in the Black-Scholes Model

Simple Formulas to Option Pricing and Hedging in the Black-Scholes Model Simple Formulas to Option Pricing and Hedging in the Black-Scholes Model Paolo PIANCA DEPARTMENT OF APPLIED MATHEMATICS University Ca Foscari of Venice pianca@unive.it http://caronte.dma.unive.it/ pianca/

More information

Pricing with a Smile. Bruno Dupire. Bloomberg

Pricing with a Smile. Bruno Dupire. Bloomberg CP-Bruno Dupire.qxd 10/08/04 6:38 PM Page 1 11 Pricing with a Smile Bruno Dupire Bloomberg The Black Scholes model (see Black and Scholes, 1973) gives options prices as a function of volatility. If an

More information

Smile in the low moments

Smile in the low moments Smile in the low moments L. De Leo, T.-L. Dao, V. Vargas, S. Ciliberti, J.-P. Bouchaud 10 jan 2014 Outline 1 The Option Smile: statics A trading style The cumulant expansion A low-moment formula: the moneyness

More information

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets Chapter 5: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets It is easy to argue that Brownian motion paths cannot model actual stock price movements properly in reality,

More information

Credit Risk and Underlying Asset Risk *

Credit Risk and Underlying Asset Risk * Seoul Journal of Business Volume 4, Number (December 018) Credit Risk and Underlying Asset Risk * JONG-RYONG LEE **1) Kangwon National University Gangwondo, Korea Abstract This paper develops the credit

More information

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Peter Carr NYU IFS, Chengdu, China, July 30, 2018 Peter Carr (NYU) Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns 7/30/2018 1 / 35 Interest Rates and Volatility Practitioners and

More information

The Impact of Volatility Estimates in Hedging Effectiveness

The Impact of Volatility Estimates in Hedging Effectiveness EU-Workshop Series on Mathematical Optimization Models for Financial Institutions The Impact of Volatility Estimates in Hedging Effectiveness George Dotsis Financial Engineering Research Center Department

More information

FX Smile Modelling. 9 September September 9, 2008

FX Smile Modelling. 9 September September 9, 2008 FX Smile Modelling 9 September 008 September 9, 008 Contents 1 FX Implied Volatility 1 Interpolation.1 Parametrisation............................. Pure Interpolation.......................... Abstract

More information

Valuation of Volatility Derivatives. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 2005 Paris May 24, 2005

Valuation of Volatility Derivatives. Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 2005 Paris May 24, 2005 Valuation of Volatility Derivatives Jim Gatheral Global Derivatives & Risk Management 005 Paris May 4, 005 he opinions expressed in this presentation are those of the author alone, and do not necessarily

More information

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying Sensitivity analysis Simulating the Greeks Meet the Greeks he value of a derivative on a single underlying asset depends upon the current asset price S and its volatility Σ, the risk-free interest rate

More information

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Tommi Huhta PERFORMANCE OF THE BLACK-SCHOLES OPTION PRICING MODEL EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON S&P 500 CALL OPTIONS IN 2014

OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL. Tommi Huhta PERFORMANCE OF THE BLACK-SCHOLES OPTION PRICING MODEL EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON S&P 500 CALL OPTIONS IN 2014 OULU BUSINESS SCHOOL Tommi Huhta PERFORMANCE OF THE BLACK-SCHOLES OPTION PRICING MODEL EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON S&P 500 CALL OPTIONS IN 2014 Master s Thesis Department of Finance December 2017 UNIVERSITY

More information

Trading Volatility Using Options: a French Case

Trading Volatility Using Options: a French Case Trading Volatility Using Options: a French Case Introduction Volatility is a key feature of financial markets. It is commonly used as a measure for risk and is a common an indicator of the investors fear

More information

A VALUATION MODEL FOR INDETERMINATE CONVERTIBLES by Jayanth Rama Varma

A VALUATION MODEL FOR INDETERMINATE CONVERTIBLES by Jayanth Rama Varma A VALUATION MODEL FOR INDETERMINATE CONVERTIBLES by Jayanth Rama Varma Abstract Many issues of convertible debentures in India in recent years provide for a mandatory conversion of the debentures into

More information

Pricing of Stock Options using Black-Scholes, Black s and Binomial Option Pricing Models. Felcy R Coelho 1 and Y V Reddy 2

Pricing of Stock Options using Black-Scholes, Black s and Binomial Option Pricing Models. Felcy R Coelho 1 and Y V Reddy 2 MANAGEMENT TODAY -for a better tomorrow An International Journal of Management Studies home page: www.mgmt2day.griet.ac.in Vol.8, No.1, January-March 2018 Pricing of Stock Options using Black-Scholes,

More information

HEDGING AND ARBITRAGE WARRANTS UNDER SMILE EFFECTS: ANALYSIS AND EVIDENCE

HEDGING AND ARBITRAGE WARRANTS UNDER SMILE EFFECTS: ANALYSIS AND EVIDENCE HEDGING AND ARBITRAGE WARRANTS UNDER SMILE EFFECTS: ANALYSIS AND EVIDENCE SON-NAN CHEN Department of Banking, National Cheng Chi University, Taiwan, ROC AN-PIN CHEN and CAMUS CHANG Institute of Information

More information

A New Methodology For Measuring and Using the Implied Market Value of Aggregate Corporate Debt in Asset Pricing:

A New Methodology For Measuring and Using the Implied Market Value of Aggregate Corporate Debt in Asset Pricing: A New Methodology For Measuring and Using the Implied Market Value of Aggregate Corporate Debt in Asset Pricing: Evidence from S&P 500 Index Put Option Prices By Robert Geske* and Yi Zhou The Anderson

More information

Pricing Implied Volatility

Pricing Implied Volatility Pricing Implied Volatility Expected future volatility plays a central role in finance theory. Consequently, accurate estimation of this parameter is crucial to meaningful financial decision-making. Researchers

More information

Dynamic Hedging in a Volatile Market

Dynamic Hedging in a Volatile Market Dynamic in a Volatile Market Thomas F. Coleman, Yohan Kim, Yuying Li, and Arun Verma May 27, 1999 1. Introduction In financial markets, errors in option hedging can arise from two sources. First, the option

More information

Walter S.A. Schwaiger. Finance. A{6020 Innsbruck, Universitatsstrae 15. phone: fax:

Walter S.A. Schwaiger. Finance. A{6020 Innsbruck, Universitatsstrae 15. phone: fax: Delta hedging with stochastic volatility in discrete time Alois L.J. Geyer Department of Operations Research Wirtschaftsuniversitat Wien A{1090 Wien, Augasse 2{6 Walter S.A. Schwaiger Department of Finance

More information

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 796 March 2017

Indian Institute of Management Calcutta. Working Paper Series. WPS No. 796 March 2017 Indian Institute of Management Calcutta Working Paper Series WPS No. 796 March 2017 Comparison of Black Scholes and Heston Models for Pricing Index Options Binay Bhushan Chakrabarti Retd. Professor, Indian

More information

Predicting probability of default of Indian companies: A market based approach

Predicting probability of default of Indian companies: A market based approach heoretical and Applied conomics F olume XXIII (016), No. 3(608), Autumn, pp. 197-04 Predicting probability of default of Indian companies: A market based approach Bhanu Pratap SINGH Mahatma Gandhi Central

More information

Smooth pasting as rate of return equalisation: A note

Smooth pasting as rate of return equalisation: A note mooth pasting as rate of return equalisation: A note Mark hackleton & igbjørn ødal May 2004 Abstract In this short paper we further elucidate the smooth pasting condition that is behind the optimal early

More information

Energy Price Processes

Energy Price Processes Energy Processes Used for Derivatives Pricing & Risk Management In this first of three articles, we will describe the most commonly used process, Geometric Brownian Motion, and in the second and third

More information

Fixed-Income Securities Lecture 5: Tools from Option Pricing

Fixed-Income Securities Lecture 5: Tools from Option Pricing Fixed-Income Securities Lecture 5: Tools from Option Pricing Philip H. Dybvig Washington University in Saint Louis Review of binomial option pricing Interest rates and option pricing Effective duration

More information

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 and Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 Prof. Dr. Erich Walter Farkas Lecture 06: March 26, 2015 1 / 47 Remember and Previous chapters: introduction to the theory of options put-call parity fundamentals

More information

Calculation of Volatility in a Jump-Diffusion Model

Calculation of Volatility in a Jump-Diffusion Model Calculation of Volatility in a Jump-Diffusion Model Javier F. Navas 1 This Draft: October 7, 003 Forthcoming: The Journal of Derivatives JEL Classification: G13 Keywords: jump-diffusion process, option

More information

Financial Engineering. Craig Pirrong Spring, 2006

Financial Engineering. Craig Pirrong Spring, 2006 Financial Engineering Craig Pirrong Spring, 2006 March 8, 2006 1 Levy Processes Geometric Brownian Motion is very tractible, and captures some salient features of speculative price dynamics, but it is

More information

CHAPTER IV THE VOLATILITY STRUCTURE IMPLIED BY NIFTY INDEX AND SELECTED STOCK OPTIONS

CHAPTER IV THE VOLATILITY STRUCTURE IMPLIED BY NIFTY INDEX AND SELECTED STOCK OPTIONS CHAPTER IV THE VOLATILITY STRUCTURE IMPLIED BY NIFTY INDEX AND SELECTED STOCK OPTIONS 4.1 INTRODUCTION The Smile Effect is a result of an empirical observation of the options implied volatility with same

More information

TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING

TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING Semih Yön 1, Cafer Erhan Bozdağ 2 1,2 Department of Industrial Engineering, Istanbul Technical University, Macka Besiktas, 34367 Turkey Abstract.

More information

Sensex Realized Volatility Index (REALVOL)

Sensex Realized Volatility Index (REALVOL) Sensex Realized Volatility Index (REALVOL) Introduction Volatility modelling has traditionally relied on complex econometric procedures in order to accommodate the inherent latent character of volatility.

More information

A METHODOLOGY FOR ASSESSING MODEL RISK AND ITS APPLICATION TO THE IMPLIED VOLATILITY FUNCTION MODEL

A METHODOLOGY FOR ASSESSING MODEL RISK AND ITS APPLICATION TO THE IMPLIED VOLATILITY FUNCTION MODEL A METHODOLOGY FOR ASSESSING MODEL RISK AND ITS APPLICATION TO THE IMPLIED VOLATILITY FUNCTION MODEL John Hull and Wulin Suo Joseph L. Rotman School of Management University of Toronto 105 St George Street

More information

Appendix A Financial Calculations

Appendix A Financial Calculations Derivatives Demystified: A Step-by-Step Guide to Forwards, Futures, Swaps and Options, Second Edition By Andrew M. Chisholm 010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Appendix A Financial Calculations TIME VALUE OF MONEY

More information

Richardson Extrapolation Techniques for the Pricing of American-style Options

Richardson Extrapolation Techniques for the Pricing of American-style Options Richardson Extrapolation Techniques for the Pricing of American-style Options June 1, 2005 Abstract Richardson Extrapolation Techniques for the Pricing of American-style Options In this paper we re-examine

More information

Multi-factor Stochastic Volatility Models A practical approach

Multi-factor Stochastic Volatility Models A practical approach Stockholm School of Economics Department of Finance - Master Thesis Spring 2009 Multi-factor Stochastic Volatility Models A practical approach Filip Andersson 20573@student.hhs.se Niklas Westermark 20653@student.hhs.se

More information

Market interest-rate models

Market interest-rate models Market interest-rate models Marco Marchioro www.marchioro.org November 24 th, 2012 Market interest-rate models 1 Lecture Summary No-arbitrage models Detailed example: Hull-White Monte Carlo simulations

More information

Option-based tests of interest rate diffusion functions

Option-based tests of interest rate diffusion functions Option-based tests of interest rate diffusion functions June 1999 Joshua V. Rosenberg Department of Finance NYU - Stern School of Business 44 West 4th Street, Suite 9-190 New York, New York 10012-1126

More information

THE GARCH STRUCTURAL CREDIT RISK MODEL: SIMULATION ANALYSIS AND APPLICATION TO THE BANK CDS MARKET DURING THE CRISIS

THE GARCH STRUCTURAL CREDIT RISK MODEL: SIMULATION ANALYSIS AND APPLICATION TO THE BANK CDS MARKET DURING THE CRISIS THE GARCH STRUCTURAL CREDIT RISK MODEL: SIMULATION ANALYSIS AND APPLICATION TO THE BANK CDS MARKET DURING THE 2007-2008 CRISIS ABSTRACT. We develop a structural credit risk model in which the asset volatility

More information

The Implied Volatility Index

The Implied Volatility Index The Implied Volatility Index Risk Management Institute National University of Singapore First version: October 6, 8, this version: October 8, 8 Introduction This document describes the formulation and

More information

1 The continuous time limit

1 The continuous time limit Derivative Securities, Courant Institute, Fall 2008 http://www.math.nyu.edu/faculty/goodman/teaching/derivsec08/index.html Jonathan Goodman and Keith Lewis Supplementary notes and comments, Section 3 1

More information

Lecture 9: Practicalities in Using Black-Scholes. Sunday, September 23, 12

Lecture 9: Practicalities in Using Black-Scholes. Sunday, September 23, 12 Lecture 9: Practicalities in Using Black-Scholes Major Complaints Most stocks and FX products don t have log-normal distribution Typically fat-tailed distributions are observed Constant volatility assumed,

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes 1/ 27 Introduction Using a mixture of jump and di usion processes can model asset prices that are subject to large, discontinuous changes,

More information

Variance Swaps in the Presence of Jumps

Variance Swaps in the Presence of Jumps Variance Swaps in the Presence of Jumps Max Schotsman July 1, 213 Abstract This paper analyses the proposed alternative of the variance swap, the simple variance swap. Its main advantage would be the insensitivity

More information

Market Risk Analysis Volume I

Market Risk Analysis Volume I Market Risk Analysis Volume I Quantitative Methods in Finance Carol Alexander John Wiley & Sons, Ltd List of Figures List of Tables List of Examples Foreword Preface to Volume I xiii xvi xvii xix xxiii

More information

Accelerated Option Pricing Multiple Scenarios

Accelerated Option Pricing Multiple Scenarios Accelerated Option Pricing in Multiple Scenarios 04.07.2008 Stefan Dirnstorfer (stefan@thetaris.com) Andreas J. Grau (grau@thetaris.com) 1 Abstract This paper covers a massive acceleration of Monte-Carlo

More information

Beyond Black-Scholes: The Stochastic Volatility Option Pricing Model and Empirical Evidence from Thailand. Woraphon Wattanatorn 1

Beyond Black-Scholes: The Stochastic Volatility Option Pricing Model and Empirical Evidence from Thailand. Woraphon Wattanatorn 1 1 Beyond Black-Scholes: The Stochastic Volatility Option Pricing Model and Empirical Evidence from Thailand Woraphon Wattanatorn 1 Abstract This study compares the performance of two option pricing models,

More information

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu 4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs Math6911 S08, HM Zhu References 1. Chapter 13, J. Hull. Section.6, P. Brandimarte Outline Derivation of Black-Scholes equation Black-Scholes models for options Implied

More information

Simple Robust Hedging with Nearby Contracts

Simple Robust Hedging with Nearby Contracts Simple Robust Hedging with Nearby Contracts Liuren Wu and Jingyi Zhu Baruch College and University of Utah October 22, 2 at Worcester Polytechnic Institute Wu & Zhu (Baruch & Utah) Robust Hedging with

More information

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon Ziemowit Bednarek, Pratish Patel and Cyrus Ramezani December 8, 2014 ABSTRACT Both building blocks of the Sharpe ratio the expected return and the expected volatility

More information

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives Department of Mathematics MA408 Mathematics of Financial Derivatives Thursday 15th January, 2009 2pm 4pm Duration: 2 hours Attempt THREE questions MA408 Page 1 of 5 1. (a) Suppose 0 < E 1 < E 3 and E 2

More information

Short-time-to-expiry expansion for a digital European put option under the CEV model. November 1, 2017

Short-time-to-expiry expansion for a digital European put option under the CEV model. November 1, 2017 Short-time-to-expiry expansion for a digital European put option under the CEV model November 1, 2017 Abstract In this paper I present a short-time-to-expiry asymptotic series expansion for a digital European

More information

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Local Volatility Dynamic Models René Carmona Bendheim Center for Finance Department of Operations Research & Financial Engineering Princeton University Columbia November 9, 27 Contents Joint work with Sergey Nadtochyi Motivation 1 Understanding

More information

Implied Volatility Surface

Implied Volatility Surface Implied Volatility Surface Liuren Wu Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College Options Markets (Hull chapter: 16) Liuren Wu Implied Volatility Surface Options Markets 1 / 1 Implied volatility Recall the

More information

Hedging under Model Mis-Specification: Which Risk Factors Should You Not Forget?

Hedging under Model Mis-Specification: Which Risk Factors Should You Not Forget? Hedging under Model Mis-Specification: Which Risk Factors Should You Not Forget? Nicole Branger Christian Schlag Eva Schneider Norman Seeger This version: May 31, 28 Finance Center Münster, University

More information

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL

AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL AN ANALYTICALLY TRACTABLE UNCERTAIN VOLATILITY MODEL FABIO MERCURIO BANCA IMI, MILAN http://www.fabiomercurio.it 1 Stylized facts Traders use the Black-Scholes formula to price plain-vanilla options. An

More information

EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON ARBITRAGE BY CHANGING THE STOCK EXCHANGE

EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON ARBITRAGE BY CHANGING THE STOCK EXCHANGE Advances and Applications in Statistics Volume, Number, This paper is available online at http://www.pphmj.com 9 Pushpa Publishing House EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON ARBITRAGE BY CHANGING THE STOCK EXCHANGE JOSÉ

More information

Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty

Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty March 2017 Recap: Heston model Recall the Heston stochastic volatility model ds t = rs t dt + Y t S t dw 1 t, dy t = κ(θ Y t ) dt + ξ Y t dw 2 t, where

More information

GN47: Stochastic Modelling of Economic Risks in Life Insurance

GN47: Stochastic Modelling of Economic Risks in Life Insurance GN47: Stochastic Modelling of Economic Risks in Life Insurance Classification Recommended Practice MEMBERS ARE REMINDED THAT THEY MUST ALWAYS COMPLY WITH THE PROFESSIONAL CONDUCT STANDARDS (PCS) AND THAT

More information

An Empirical Comparison of GARCH Option Pricing Models. April 11, 2006

An Empirical Comparison of GARCH Option Pricing Models. April 11, 2006 An Empirical Comparison of GARCH Option Pricing Models April 11, 26 Abstract Recent empirical studies have shown that GARCH models can be successfully used to describe option prices. Pricing such contracts

More information

************************

************************ Derivative Securities Options on interest-based instruments: pricing of bond options, caps, floors, and swaptions. The most widely-used approach to pricing options on caps, floors, swaptions, and similar

More information

In Search of Distress Risk

In Search of Distress Risk In Search of Distress Risk John Y. Campbell, Jens Hilscher, and Jan Szilagyi Presentation to Third Credit Risk Conference: Recent Advances in Credit Risk Research New York, 16 May 2006 What is financial

More information

Term Structure Lattice Models

Term Structure Lattice Models IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh Term Structure Lattice Models These lecture notes introduce fixed income derivative securities and the modeling philosophy used to

More information

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes Stochastics & Computational Finance 2015 Xuecan CUI Jang SCHILTZ University of Luxembourg July 9, 2015 Xuecan CUI, Jang SCHILTZ University

More information

Estimating the Current Value of Time-Varying Beta

Estimating the Current Value of Time-Varying Beta Estimating the Current Value of Time-Varying Beta Joseph Cheng Ithaca College Elia Kacapyr Ithaca College This paper proposes a special type of discounted least squares technique and applies it to the

More information

1) Understanding Equity Options 2) Setting up Brokerage Systems

1) Understanding Equity Options 2) Setting up Brokerage Systems 1) Understanding Equity Options 2) Setting up Brokerage Systems M. Aras Orhan, 12.10.2013 FE 500 Intro to Financial Engineering 12.10.2013, ARAS ORHAN, Intro to Fin Eng, Boğaziçi University 1 Today s agenda

More information

Proxy Function Fitting: Some Implementation Topics

Proxy Function Fitting: Some Implementation Topics OCTOBER 2013 ENTERPRISE RISK SOLUTIONS RESEARCH OCTOBER 2013 Proxy Function Fitting: Some Implementation Topics Gavin Conn FFA Moody's Analytics Research Contact Us Americas +1.212.553.1658 clientservices@moodys.com

More information

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key MFE/3F Questions Download free full solutions from www.actuarialbrew.com, or purchase a hard copy from www.actexmadriver.com, or www.actuarialbookstore.com. Chapter 1 Put-Call Parity and Replication 1.01

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing We shall go over this note quickly due to time constraints. Key concept: Ito s lemma Stock Options: A contract giving

More information

Working Paper October Book Review of

Working Paper October Book Review of Working Paper 04-06 October 2004 Book Review of Credit Risk: Pricing, Measurement, and Management by Darrell Duffie and Kenneth J. Singleton 2003, Princeton University Press, 396 pages Reviewer: Georges

More information

Return dynamics of index-linked bond portfolios

Return dynamics of index-linked bond portfolios Return dynamics of index-linked bond portfolios Matti Koivu Teemu Pennanen June 19, 2013 Abstract Bond returns are known to exhibit mean reversion, autocorrelation and other dynamic properties that differentiate

More information

Understanding Index Option Returns

Understanding Index Option Returns Understanding Index Option Returns Mark Broadie, Columbia GSB Mikhail Chernov, LBS Michael Johannes, Columbia GSB October 2008 Expected option returns What is the expected return from buying a one-month

More information

Credit Risk in Banking

Credit Risk in Banking Credit Risk in Banking CREDIT RISK MODELS Sebastiano Vitali, 2017/2018 Merton model It consider the financial structure of a company, therefore it belongs to the structural approach models Notation: E

More information

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income 3. Uncertainty and Risk Uncertainty and risk lie at the core of everything we do in finance. In order to make intelligent investment and hedging decisions, we need

More information

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics

Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics Amath 546/Econ 589 Univariate GARCH Models: Advanced Topics Eric Zivot April 29, 2013 Lecture Outline The Leverage Effect Asymmetric GARCH Models Forecasts from Asymmetric GARCH Models GARCH Models with

More information

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1 Volatility Definition and Estimation 1.1 WHAT IS VOLATILITY? It is useful to start with an explanation of what volatility is, at least for the purpose of clarifying the scope of this book. Volatility

More information

MANY FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS HOLD NONTRIVIAL AMOUNTS OF DERIVATIVE SECURITIES. Issues in Hedging Options Positions SAIKAT NANDI AND DANIEL F.

MANY FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS HOLD NONTRIVIAL AMOUNTS OF DERIVATIVE SECURITIES. Issues in Hedging Options Positions SAIKAT NANDI AND DANIEL F. Issues in Hedging Options Positions SAIKAT NANDI AND DANIEL F. WAGGONER Nandi is a senior economist and Waggoner is an economist in the financial section of the Atlanta Fed s research department. They

More information

NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS

NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS 1 NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS Options are contracts used to insure against or speculate/take a view on uncertainty about the future prices of a wide range

More information

The Effect of Net Buying Pressure on Implied Volatility: Empirical Study on Taiwan s Options Market

The Effect of Net Buying Pressure on Implied Volatility: Empirical Study on Taiwan s Options Market Vol 2, No. 2, Summer 2010 Page 50~83 The Effect of Net Buying Pressure on Implied Volatility: Empirical Study on Taiwan s Options Market Chang-Wen Duan a, Ken Hung b a. Department of Banking and Finance,

More information

Volatility Forecasting and Interpolation

Volatility Forecasting and Interpolation University of Wyoming Wyoming Scholars Repository Honors Theses AY 15/16 Undergraduate Honors Theses Spring 216 Volatility Forecasting and Interpolation Levi Turner University of Wyoming, lturner6@uwyo.edu

More information

Modeling the Implied Volatility Surface:

Modeling the Implied Volatility Surface: Modeling the Implied Volatility Surface: An Empirical Study for S&P 5 Index Option by Tiandong Zhong B.B.A, Shanghai University of Finance of Economics, 29 and Chenguang Zhong B.Econ, Nankai University,

More information