Macro-hedging and sovereign default for commodity exporters

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Macro-hedging and sovereign default for commodity exporters"

Transcription

1 Macro-hedging and sovereign default for commodity exporters Chang Ma Johns Hopkins University Fabián Valencia International Monetary Fund This draft: January 31, 2017 Abstract Motivated by Mexico s oil hedging program, this paper studies the benefits of macrohedging in a model with sovereign default. We show that hedging against commodity price risk enhances domestic welfare through two channels: first, by reducing income volatility; and second, by reducing countries incentive to default and thus relaxing the endogenous borrowing limit. The majority of welfare gains come from the second channel since the default spreads on sovereign bond are reduced. Quantitative results suggest that the size of welfare gains is at the magnitude of 0.5% of annual consumption increase if the country pays an actuarially fair price on the hedging instruments. However, the benefit vanishes if the country has to pay a higher enough premium. Furthermore, considerable welfare gains can be also found using different macro-hedging instruments such as forwards and GDP-indexed bonds. Keywords: Hedging, Commodity exporters, Sovereign debt, Default JEL Classification: F3; F4; G1 The authors thank Ali Alichi, Michal Andrle, Ravi Balakrishnan, Paolo Cavallino, Stephan Danninger, Olivier Jeanne, Laura Kodres, Anton Korinek, Leonardo Martinez, Dora Iakova, Andrea Pescatori, Francisco Roch, Damiano Sandri, Alejandro Werner, Jinfan Zhang and and seminar participants at IMF brown bag seminar for helpful comments. All errors are our own. Address: Wyman Park Building 544E, 3400 N. Charles St, Baltimore, MD cma18@jhu.edu. Address: th St NW, Washington, DC FValencia@imf.org.

2 1 Introduction Commodity exporters can insure against fluctuations in commodity prices by accumulating assets in commodity stablization funds, issuing defaultable debt or hedging with financial instruments. The first strategy is dominated by the latter two from a theoretical perspective since more insurances are provided to the country from either defaultable debt or macro-hedging 1 (See Borensztein et al. (2013) and Borensztein et al. (2017) for quantitative calculations of welfare gains from using defaultable debt or hedging as opposed to stabilization funds). The relationship between defaultable debt and macro-hedging, however, is less clear, even from the theoretical perspective. Clearly, both methods provide some insurances to the country at certain costs: default might lead to an output loss or an exclusion from financial market for certain periods while buying hedging instruments might be too costly and risky especially if the country has no corresponding expertise in managing financial risk. In reality, many countries, especially less developed countries, default frequently in their external liability but few of them actually conduct macro-hedging programs to smooth their income. Interestingly, Mexico is the only country, to our knowledge, who is involved in a macro-hedging program since Meanwhile, Mexico has experienced 8 episodes of default in its sovereign debt since 1800 and the last default episode happens in Motivated by Mexico s experiences, we want to explore the following questions: what is the relationship between defaultable debt and macro-hedging? How much are the welfare gains from applying macro-hedging strategies in the presence of defaultable debt? Will the cost of hedging affect the welfare gains? In this paper, we address these questions using a willingness-to-pay framework á la Eaton- Gersovitz model. In this framework, the country is exposed to a risk in the price of its commodity exports. The country can insure against this risk by issuing defaultable debt or using hedging instruments. Defautable debt allows the country to default whenever it is optimal to do so. Meanwhile, hedging instrument helps the country to smooth income fluctuations in its export 1 Daniel (2001) argues that stabilization funds are inherently flawed since the international oil spot price does not have a well-defined time-invariant equilirbium value. 2 Other countries or regions have participated in macro-hedging programs as well but only Mexico has a largescale annual program over a long period. For example, Ecuador terminated its oil hedging program in 1993 after a loss of 20 million dollars to Goldman Sachs followed by a political storm. 3 The data on Mexico s default is from Carmen M. Reinhart s website: data/browse-by-topic/topics/7/. 1

3 income. In our baseline framework, we assume that the commodity is oil and the hedging instrument is put options since Mexico is an oil exporter and it has adopted put options as macrohedging instruments for nearly 20 years. We firstly calibrate the model with both defaultable debt and put options to Mexico s data from since it is the relevant period when Mexico participates in oil hedging program. We then compare the benchmark model with an otherwise equal defaultable debt model without put options. The difference between these two economies is considered to be the welfare gains from using put options and the we find the gains are at the order of 0.5% permanent increase in annual consumption. The welfare gains come from two channels. The first channel is the income smoothing channel as in Lucas (1987): lower income fluctuations transfer into a smoother consumption path and thus a higher welfare gains since representative agents are risk averse to fluctuations in consumption. In his calculation, Lucas (2003) argues that the welfare gains from smoothing business calculation are very small for the United States. We conduct the same calculation using data from Mexico and find that the welfare gains are at the same magnitude as that in U.S., around 0.05% of permanent annual consumption increase. In our model, we provide a way to isolate the welfare gains from the income smoothing and the relaxation of endogenous borrowing limit which will be explained further later. We find that the welfare gains from the income smoothing are around 0.08% of permanent annual consumption increase, the same magnitude as that in the data. Apparently, the majority of welfare gains in macro-hedging is not from the income smoothing channel but the other source. The second channel is from the relaxation of endogenous borrowing limit. In our framework, countries might choose to default whenever it is in their best interests to do so. Investors understand the countries incentive and thus demand a higher default spread when the probability of future default is higher. The default spread imposes an endogenous borrowing limit on the countries borrowing capacity in each period since the default spreads above a certain threshold are too high and it is not optimal for the country to borrow at that price. In the presence of hedging, future income is higher and the default incentive is thus reduced, which lowers the default spread and thus relaxes the endogenous borrowing limit. This channel is the majority of total welfare gains since the country is allowed to borrow more and gets a better risk sharing from the defaultable debt contract. From this perspective, we shall view hedging as complementary to defaultable debt. Indeed, we quantify the welfare gains from this channel by providing 2

4 the country in a no-hedging world with the same default spreads as that in a hedging world and find that the gains are at the magnitude of 0.40% permanent increase in annual consumption, which is 83% of the total welfare gains. We also find considerable welfare gains using other types of hedging instruments, such as selling forwards and GDP-indexed bonds. In our quantitative results, selling forwards can generate a higher welfare gains: at the order of 1.43 %, which is at the same order of gains as in Borensztein et al. (2013). The gains are larger than our benchmark model since selling forwards does not require any cost ex-ante while purchasing put options requires sacrificing current consumption. Depending on the degree of indexation, the gains from selling GDPindexed bonds differ. Intuitively, when the country can sell fully indexed bonds to investors, the country is effectively access to Arrow-Debreu securities and thus has perfect risk-sharing with foreign investors. As a result, the gains should be very large and we find the gains are at the order of 8 % of permanent consumption increase, much larger than the gains from put options and forwards. Also, this number is larger than the quantitative results of GDP-indexed bonds in Hatchondo and Martinez (2012) since we use a much lower discount rate than theirs in order to match the data. The gains become smaller when the discount rate increases and we find the similar size of welfare gains when using the same discount rate as in Hatchondo and Martinez (2012). Furthermore, we find that when the degree of indexation decreases, the gains decrease since the degree of hedging becomes smaller. Literature review: This paper is at the intersection of several lines of literature. First, our paper belongs to the literature on quantitative models of sovereign default. Essentially, this literature focuses on a willingness-to-pay problem where a country decides to honor its external debt or not. In a seminal paper, Eaton and Gersovitz (1981) argues that international borrowing can be rationalized in a model with reputation concern even if there is no explicit mechanism deterring a government from repudiating its external debt and the punishment of no repayment includes exclusion from future borrowing. 4 Aguiar and Gopinath (2006) and Arellano (2008) generalize Eaton-Gersovitz framework in quantitative models and find this framework can closely match the data in terms of business cycle feature. Mendoza and Yue (2012), on the other hand, provide a general equilibrium framework in order to endogenize the cost of default and shows 4 Indeed, this punishment could be very persistent. Reinhart et al. (2003) find that the history of default matters for the sovereign borrowing, which they called debt intolerance. 3

5 that the model can match both sovereign default episodes and business fluctuation dynamics. Moreover, Hatchondo and Martinez (2009) and Chatterjee and Eyigungor (2012) extend the framework into a longer duration of debt and find that models with longer maturity debt can better match the data. The Eaton-Gersovitz model has been proved to be successful in providing a useful benchmark to investigate various of interesting questions. 5 For example, Cuadra and Sapriza (2008) introduce political uncertainty into a sovereign default model and show that politically unstable and more polarized economies are associated with higher default rates and interest spreads. Na et al. (2014) characterize the jointly optimal default and exchange-rate policy in a sovereign default model and nominal wage rigidity. Unlike the previous literature, we use the sovereign default framework to investigate the benefits of macro-hedging. In particular, we focus on the channel through which hedging increases social welfare. Second, our paper belongs to the branch of literature that calculates the welfare gains of macro-hedging. For example, Caballero and Panageas (2008) show that optimal hedging strategies can reduce the precautionary savings for a country facing against sudden stop risks in capital flows. Borensztein et al. (2013) find that the welfare gains from macro-hedging against commodity price fluctuations are at the magnitude of several points of permanent consumption increase. In their framework, the insurance that country would adopt other than financial innovations is the risk-free bond. The channel is through either the reduction of precautionary savings as in Caballero and Panageas (2008) or the relaxation of external borrowing limit as in Borensztein et al. (2013). In our paper, however, the country cannot issue risk-free bond. Instead, it chooses to strategically default whenever it is optimal to do so. Therefore, the borrowing limit is endogenous rather than exogenous. Our paper is closely related to Hatchondo and Martinez (2012), Borensztein et al. (2017) and Lopez-Martin et al. (2016), where Hatchondo and Martinez (2012) investigates the role of GDP-indexed bond in an otherwise equal sovereign defaultable bond model and Borensztein et al. (2017) studies the role of catastrophic (CAT) bond in a framework with either risk-free or defaultable bond. There are two main differences between our work and these two papers. First, both GDP-index bonds and CAT bonds provide a complete insurance to the country and thus complete the market. In our framework, however, hedging instrument such as put options only provides partial insurance to the country. As a result, one should 5 To see more works in sovereign default models, we suggest the readers to read the survey papers such as Eaton and Fernandez (1995) and Aguiar et al. (2014). 4

6 expect relatively lower welfare gains from our calculation. Secondly, our exercise motivates from Mexico s oil hedging program and we can calibrate our model to Mexico s data. Hatchondo and Martinez (2012) investigate the GDP-indexed bond mainly through a theoretical exercise even if the author motivates the paper from many other countries experience in issuance of GDPindexed bond. In reality, however, the data on GDP-indexed bond is sparse, which does not allow for a rigorous calibration. 6 Borensztein et al. (2017), however, focus mainly on the welfare gains from CAT bond with respect to default-free bond. In the end of their paper, the author provides a generalization for the welfare gains with respect to defaultable debt but their cost of default is very artificial in the sense that they assume a welfare loss under default. 7 Moreover, they do not calibrate their model with defaultable debt to the data since their main focus is the welfare gains with respect to default-free debt. Lopez-Martin et al. (2016) also calibrate their sovereign default model using Mexican data. However, there are several differences. Firstly, they investigate the effectiveness of financial instruments in reducing the volatility of macroeconomic variables where we focus on the welfare gains from adopting financial instruments. Secondly, they assume that government pays zero cost in access to financial instrument and ask the question that how much government would like to pay for financial instrument where we assume that government needs to pay an actuarially fair price for the financial instrument and calculate the benefit of macro-hedging. Moreover, we focus more on the channel through which financial instruments enhance social welfare. In particular, we find that the main channel is through the relaxation of endogenous borrowing limit. The organization of this paper is as follows: section 2 provides institutional details about Mexico s oil hedging program; section 3 presents a benchmark model; section 4 presents the calibration procedure; section 5 presents the quantitative results and section 7 concludes. 6 Furthermore, some countries issue GDP-indexed bond in default episodes, such as Argentina in 2002 and Greece in It is hard to make the case that the country uses GDP-indexed bond for hedging purpose. It is more likely that country uses GDP-index bond for debt-restructuring purpose. 7 Unlike most literature in sovereign default literature, the cost of default comes from either output loss or exclusion of international market. 5

7 2 Mexico s oil hedging program We focus on the experience of Mexico since it is involved in the macro-hedging program for nearly 16 years. To be specific, Mexico government purchases put options in each fiscal year from Wall Street banks to hedge against its oil export price risk in the next fiscal year. The put options entitle the Mexican government to sell its oil at a predetermined price (strike price), which provides a floor to its downside risk. The underlying asset of the put options is the crude oil which Mexico government sells to the foreigners and the strike price is determined using a complicated formula that tries to estimate the long run equilibrium level of oil prices. The maturity of the put options is one year since the government wants to hedge against its annual fiscal budget. On the maturity day, the payoff from the put options is the difference between the strike price and the average oil price in the past year. If the former is larger than the latter, the government chooses to exercise the put options and its downside risk from oil price is hedged. Otherwise, the put options are out of money. Figure 1 plots the oil price (in black line) and the strike price (in red line) from the Mexico s oil hedging program. One can see that Mexico has exercised its put options twice in history: 2009 and Given the current oil price and the strike price set in 2015, it is expected that Mexico will exercise again in The payoffs from exercising put options are large compared with the cost of purchasing. Historically, the cost is around 0.1% of its GDP but the benefit is around 0.6%. The net benefits up until now are positive, which makes the hedging program attractive to other countries facing the similar shocks. However, all this calculation is from an ex-post perspective. A more relevant question is the benefit of hedging ex-ante. To formally answer that question, we need to establish an analytical framework. Figure 2 plots the oil price and the sovereign spreads in Mexican sovereign bonds. These two series are negatively correlated and the correlation is -0.59, which implies that oil price is associated with sovereign spreads. Interestingly, the standard deviation of sovereign spreads has declined from 300 basis point before 2000 to 82 basis point after The average spreads has dropped from 603 basis point to 222 basis point. Yet the standard deviation of oil price does not change so much: 1.03 before 2000 and 1.06 after Indeed, it is hard to attribute the change of spreads entirely to the oil hedging program. However, hedging could potentially reduce the sovereign spreads since it facilitates a better risk management. 6

8 3 The Model Economy We start from a standard sovereign default model as in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006) and Arellano (2008) to investigate the benefit of hedging. To quantify the benefit of hedging, we setup a counterfactual economy where no macro-hedging tools are allowed. The difference between these two economies is considered as the benefit/cost of hedging. In our benchmark model, we allow the economy to sell put options since Mexico has been following this strategy over a decade. For robustness, we also investigate the benefit of other potential macro-hedging tools. 3.1 Benchmark Model Consider a small open economy populated with representative infinitely-lived consumers. The consumer derives utility from consuming consumption good which we use as numeraire. The representative agent has CRRA preference over consumption stream {C t } t=0 as follows: E 0 t=0 β t C1 γ t 1 γ (1) where β is the discount factor and γ is the coefficient of risk aversion. The total income Y t has two components: the non-oil income (f t ) and oil-component income (x t ) as follows: where p t and Q t are the price and quantity of oil respectively. Y t = f t + x t f t + p t Q t (2) Source of risk: We assume that the shock to this country is from the price of oil: p t, where its process follows an AR(1): [ log p t = (1 ρ) log(p) 1 2 σ 2 1 ρ 2 ] + ρ log p t 1 + ε t (3) where p is the unconditional mean for commodity price, ρ < 1 is the persistent parameter and ε t N(0, σ 2 ). In order to better focus on the consequence of uncertain oil income, we assume that nonoil income f t is deterministic, and grows at the rate of G in every period. We normalize all the variables in the economy by f t and present the normalized economy from now on. The 7

9 normalized income and utility function can be written as y t = Y t Q t = 1 + p t = 1 + p t Q f t f t (4) E 0 (βg 1 γ ) t c1 γ t 1 γ (5) t=0 where we assume that the normalized quantity Q = Qt f t is constant since our primary interest lies in the risk from price of oil, and c t = Ct f t is the normalized consumption at period t. The government is benevolent and its objective is to maximize the utility of all the households. 8 The government can buy one-period discount bond b t+1 at price q t in each period, where q t is determined in equilibrium and thus depends on the state of economy. In each period t, government can choose whether to default or not. When the government chooses to default, the economy is excluded from international bond market for current period. It stays in the state of default for several periods and might re-enter the market with probability of λ (0, 1). Moreover, there will be a one-period output loss h (y t ) in the state of default. Macro-hedging: We allow the government to purchase put options as macro-hedging for a fraction α of its oil income. Put options provide a mechanism for the government to hedge against the downside risk of export income. Specifically, government can purchase put option that allows the country to sell the commodity at the price of p t at t + 1 and the unit cost of options is ξ( p t ). Here the strike price p t is time-variant and set at the period t. This is to mimic the practice of Mexican government in its hedging strategy: in the data the strike price is time-variant and supposed to hedge the downside risk in one-year ahead. In the state of default, we assume that the country has no access to the put options. It is convenient to denote the beginning-of-period wealth by w t = y t + b t. The state of this economy can be summarized by two state variables: (w t, p t ). Let V (w t, p t ), V c (w t, p t ) and V d t (p t ) denote the value function at the beginning of period t, the value function of not default and the value function of default respectively. default if and only if V d (w t, p t ) > V c (p t ). Therefore, ( ) V (w t, p t ) = max V c (w t, p t ), V d (p t ) At each period t, the government chooses to 8 It is standard in sovereign default literature that government makes decision on behalf of domestic agents. The rationale is that government can always decentralize its allocation through taxes and transfers. 8

10 If the economy does not default, we have: V c c 1 γ t (w t, p t ) = max c t,b t+1 1 γ + βg1 γ E t V (w t+1, p t+1 ) (6) s.t. c t + q t Gb t+1 + α QGξ( p t ) = w t w t+1 = y t+1 + α Q max{ p t p t+1, 0} + b t+1 Here the bond holding b t+1 and cost of options ξ( p t ) are multiplied by a growth factor G since the economy grows at the rate of G. In period t + 1, the wealth w t+1 is hedged by the amount α Q max{ p t p t+1, 0} whenever the country exercises put options, i.e. p t > p t+1. If the economy defaults, in next period there is a probability λ that the economy will be redeemed and re-enter the international market. If redeemed, all the past debt is forgiven and the economy starts with zero net assets. Furthermore, a country in default status cannot purchase put options. In a recursive form, we have; V d (p t ) = c 1 γ [ ] t 1 γ + βg1 γ λe t V (w t+1, p t+1 ) + (1 λ)e t V d (p t+1 ) s.t. c t = y t h (y t ) (7) w t+1 = y t+1 Risk-Neutral Investors: We assume that both the sovereign bonds and put options are purchased/sold by a continuum of risk-neutral investors. Denote the world risk-free rate by r, and the default function D(w t, p t ) = 1 if government defaults and zero otherwise. Then no-arbitrage condition requires that q t (b t+1, p t ) = E t [1 D(y t+1 + b t+1, p t+1 )] 1 + r ξ( p t ) = E t[max{ p t p t+1, 0}] 1 + r Note In our benchmark model, we do not allow countries to choose whether to purchase put options or not and how much share of export to hedge for the sake of simplicity. That said, the welfare gains should be considered as a lower bound of hedging. 3.2 Benefit of Macro-Hedging To quantify the gains from hedging, we setup a counterfactual economy where no hedging is allowed. In order to differentiate these two scenarios, we use variables with tilde to denote value 9

11 functions in the no macro-hedging economy. The state variables (w t, p t ) are defined the same as before. So, in each period, the value function is defined as follows. ) c Ṽ t (w t, p t ) = max (Ṽt (w t, p t ), Ṽ t d (p t ) If the economy does not default, we have: Ṽt c c 1 γ t (w t, p t ) = max c t,b t+1 1 γ + βg1 γ E t Ṽ t (w t+1, p t+1 ) s.t. c t + q t Gb t+1 = w t, w t+1 = y t+1 + b t+1. If the economy defaults, Ṽ d t (p t ) = [y t h(y t )] 1 γ 1 γ [ ] + βg 1 γ λe t Ṽ t (w t+1, p t+1 ) + (1 λ)e t Ṽt d (p t+1 ) The bond price is pined down by q(b t+1, p t ) = E t [1 D(y ] t+1 + b t+1, p t+1 ) 1 + r 4 Calibration The model can be solved using value function iteration and the procedure is described in Appendix C. Benchmark model is calibrated to match Mexico s data from where it includes the periods when Mexico s government starts to use put options for hedging. Each period in our model refers to a year and the parameter values are reported in Table 1. Output cost function As is known to the literature, the output cost function is very crucial for quantitative results in the type of models following Eaton and Gersovitz (1981). As Arellano (2008) points out in her paper, the asymmetric feature of output cost function is the key to generate reasonable default rate and thus default spreads in the model. Since our purpose is to investigate the role of macro-hedging in this framework, we just follow her assumption for output loss function. h(y t ) = y t y, if y t y 0, if y t < y 10

12 In the model, there are 13 parameters that we need to assign values and we proceed by grouping them into three categories. The first category of parameter values can be directly obtained from the data, such as {r, γ, λ, p, ρ, σ, Q, α, G}. The second category of parameters is chosen to match relevant moments in the data, such as {β, y }. The last category is approximated under reasonable assumptions, such as {ξ(p t ), p t }. The real risk free interest rate r is calibrated to be 0.71 % using data of U.S. 1-year treasury bill. Risk aversion parameter γ is set to be 2, which is a standard value in the literature. The probability of redemption parameter λ is calibrated to be 0.11, which implies that the country is expected to stay in financial autarky for 9.38 years. The number matches the historical experience for Mexico. For oil income process, we have data for Mexico s oil price and its relevant parameters such as unconditional mean p, persistence ρ and volatility σ can be easily estimated using MLE method described in Appendix D. We also have data for GDP and oil revenue, and the difference between these two series is used as f t in the model for normalization. The growth rate G in the data is 3.75%, which is reasonable in small open economies. For macro-hedging programs, we have a relative short sample series. The information on hedging volumes helps pin down the share of hedging parameter α. We have time-variant strike prices and cost of hedging for some years, from which we need to get an approximation for p t and ξ(p t ). We proceed by assuming that p t = µe t [p t+1 p t ] since Mexico government applies a complicated formula to estimate the long run equilibrium value of oil prices. We choose µ such that the long run probability of exercising options is 18.75% since Mexican government exercises its put options three times out of 16 years. For the option price function, we use an actuarial fair price implied by no-arbitrage condition in the market. The calculation method is reported in Appendix E. The oil price process can be approximated using Tauchen (1986) s method to discretize an AR(1) process. We use 21 points to approximate the income process and 500 points to approximate the bond space. The model is finally calibrated by choosing {β, y } to match two important empirical moments: (1) debt to non-oil fiscal revenue ratio: 9.03%; (2) average default spreads: 3.68%. 11

13 5 Welfare gains from hedging 5.1 Benchmark results We measure welfare gains from macro-hedging by comparing the utility of the economy who uses put options with the utility of the economy who does not have access to put options. As common in the literature, we express the welfare gains as the permanent percentage increase in annual consumption that yields the same level of utility. Formally, the welfare gains is expressed in equation (8). We calculate this number by running a Monte Carlo simulation for the economy with and without hedging. Given the same initial condition, we can calculate the welfare as the discounted sum of utilities. The unconditional welfare gains are calculated by plugging into the utilities into equation (8). (b t, p t ) = 100 [ (V (bt, p t ) Ṽ (b t, p t ) ) 1 1 γ 1 ] (8) From the simulation, the unconditional welfare gain is around %. This numbers are comparable to the previous study in a similar environment. For example, Borensztein et al. (2017) finds that the welfare gains from using catastrophe(cat) bonds in the presence of defaultable debt are typically small: less than 0.12 % in their calculation. They rationalize this results by claiming that the CAT bonds do not change the default threshold. However, even if the instrument does change the default threshold, the welfare gains are also small. Hatchondo and Martinez (2012) did an exercise for the GDP-indexed bond in a model with defaultable debt. They find that GDP-indexed bond could change the default threshold but the welfare gains are also small: around 0.46% in terms of permanent consumption increase. Source of welfare gains: the welfare gains from hedging mainly come from the relaxation of endogenous borrowing limit. Intuitively speaking, if the country ever borrows to the point where the investors know that it will default for sure in the future, investors will never be willing to lend. As a result, there is a borrowing limit imposed on this country. Under the hedging program, the income becomes more smoothed and the incentive to default is attenuated, which corresponds to a more favorable default spreads charged by the investors. To confirm this intuition, we compare the simulation results for economy with hedging and without hedging and report them in Table 2. We find that from hedging to non-hedging world the debt ratio is reduced from 9.77% to 8.96% but the default spreads increased from 3.21 % to 4.72%. 12

14 This intuition can be further strengthened by looking at the price schedule under these two economy. Figure 3 shows the bond price and sovereign spreads for the economy with and without hedging. One can see that the bond is priced higher in the world with hedging, which implies a lower default spreads. To see the contribution of the reduction in default spreads, we firstly solve the model without hedging again but under the same price schedule as that in the model with hedging and then calculate the welfare gains by comparing its utility with that in the model without hedging. Presumably, the welfare gains here purely capture the benefit from relaxation of borrowing limit and reduction in default spreads. In our simulation, we find that this number is around %. 5.2 Cost of Hedging Current calculation is based on the premise that Mexico government pays zero premium for put options to hedge. Clearly, the cost of buying put options affects the effectiveness of hedging. One should expect that the higher the cost premium, the lower the welfare gains from hedging. In order to better understand the cost of hedging, we augment the fair price of options with a premium µ. By setting µ to the different cost premiums paid by Mexico government, we want to understand how the unconditional welfare gains change with respect to µ. From Figure 4, we find that the welfare gains vanish when the cost premium is around 1.14 $ per barrel. 5.3 Feature of hedging program Before entering into a contract of put options, the government might be concerned about several questions about the feature of hedging. These questions include the strike price of the contract, the share of productions that the government is going to hedge and the productions that are exposed to commodity price risk. To better understand the sensitivity of our benchmark results with respect to the feature of hedging program, we conduct the following experiments. Strike prices: Mexico government has its own formula to calculate the strike price of put options. To simplify life, in our baseline calculation we assume that strike price is a fraction of conditional price mean. In the historical data that we have, the mean is In the data, this number varies from year to year as in Table 3. We find from Figure 5 that the higher the strike price, the more welfare gains there are since more risk is covered by the put options. However, the cost of put options increases as the strike price increases. As a result, the welfare gains from 13

15 hedging cease to increase at certain point. Hedging shares: Mexico government only hedges a fraction of their oil revenue. The share of hedging α ranges from 44% to 72% as in Table 4. In the calibration, we use the average number of hedging, which is 55%. Figure 6 plots the unconditional welfare gains for different hedging share α. Clearly, one find that our results are robust to different hedging shares. Again, the higher the hedging share is, the more risk the country is covered, and thus the higher the welfare gain is. When α exceeds 100%, the country actually speculates using put options. 5.4 Robustness Check Oil price process: We also calculate welfare gains using different values for parameters in oil price process such as unconditional mean ρ, persistence ρ and volatility σ. The results are reported in Table 5. We find that the welfare gains are robust to different parameters. Other parameters: We also conduct robustness check with respect to different parameters in our model such as risk free rate (r ), risk aversion parameter (γ), probability of redemption (λ), growth rate G, output loss function y, discount rate β,and redemption parameter λ. The results are presented in Table 6. The welfare gains are robust to various of parameters. Finer grid spaces: We also apply a finer grid space for the calculation of welfare gains since Hatchondo et al. (2010) points out that a coarse grid space is subject to approximation errors. Our results are robust if we increase the number of grid points for endowment space from 21 points to Extensions 6.1 Selling forwards as hedging Suppose that we allow the economy to sell forward contract one year in advance. Specifically, the budget constraint changes into the following form. w t = c t + q t Gb t+1 w t+1 = 1 + Q {(1 α)p t+1 + αe t [p t+1 ]} + b t+1 14

16 We use the same parameters as in the benchmark model and find the welfare gains are at the order of % in terms of permanent consumption increase. The debt has increased from 8.96% to 13.97% and the default spread has decreased from 4.72% to 1.42%. Clearly, the gains are larger than the benchmark model since the economy does not pay any cost when selling forwards. Put options require the economy to sacrifice current consumption to hedge. 6.2 Selling GDP-indexed bonds as hedging We assume that the economy issue bonds that promise to pay in the next period a coupon s and (1 s)y t+1. Parameter s [0, 1] determines the extent to which debt is indexed to GDP. As a result, the wealth and price of GDP-indexed bonds change into the following forms: w t = c t + q t Gb t+1 w t+1 = y t+1 + b t+1 [s + (1 s)y t+1 ] q t (b t+1, p t ) = E t [1 D(y t+1 + b t+1, p t+1 )[s + (1 s)y t+1 ]] 1 + r The welfare gains are plot in Figure 7. As the degree of indexation increase, i.e. decrease in s, the welfare gains increase. The maximum gains are at the order of 8% in terms of permanent consumption increase, which is much larger than the number in Hatchondo and Martinez (2012) since they use a higher discount rate factor. Using the same discount factor, we also find the gains are at the order of 0.16%, which is at the same magnitude as in Hatchondo and Martinez (2012). 6.3 Risk averse investors We assume that international investors are risk averse. In particular, they have a time-variant pricing kernel m t, i.e. intertemporal marginal rate of substitution. Following Arellano (2008), we assume that m is an i.i.d. random variable with a constant mean equal to the inverse of the risk-free rate and with an innovation correlated with the economy s income. Here we assume that log m t+1 takes the following form to make sure that m t+1 is non-negative. log m t+1 = r νε t+1 Here ε t is the same shock to the price of oil and E[log m t+1 ] = r and var(log m t+1 ) = ν 2 σ 2. 15

17 The pricing of sovereign bond and options are given by the following formula. q t (b t+1, p t ) = E t [m t+1 (1 D(y t+1 + b t+1, p t+1 ))] (9) ξ t (p t ) = E t [m t+1 max( p p t+1, 0)] (10) We increase ν so as to increase the risk aversion of investors. Not surprisingly, we find that in Table 7 the welfare gains are becoming smaller as ν increases since the price of options becomes more and more expensive. We do not calibrate ν to any empirical objects but instead choose several points to calculate welfare gains. Clearly, as ν increases, the investors become more and more risk-averse and starts to charge a higher price for both put options and sovereign bonds. At certain point (ν = 0.5 in our exercise), the default spreads become negative. However, negative default spreads are inconsistent with the data so we interpret a reasonable ν should lie in the range of [0, 0.5). Given that welfare gains decrease with ν, the gains for risk-averse investors are at the range of 0.36% and 0.49%, which is roughly the same as our benchmark result. 7 Conclusion Countries can hedge against their income shocks through either issuance of defaultable debt or involvement in hedging programs. Both methods provide partial insurance to the country. In this paper, we show that these two methods are complementary in providing a better risk sharing mechanism. Macro-hedging instruments can enhance social welfare through its effect on countries incentive to default. Using Mexico s oil hedging program experience, we quantify the welfare gains are at the order of 0.5% of annual permanent consumption increase, the majority of which comes from the relaxation of endogenous borrowing limit rather than smoothing business fluctuations as in Lucas (1987). The welfare gains, however, depend on the cost of hedging instruments. If the country has to pay a higher price for the acturially fair price of the hedging instruments, the welfare gains might vanish. There are some aspects in reality that our paper does not touch and we leave them for future research agenda. Firstly, the interactions between private hedging and sovereign default. In reality, some countries are exposed to income shocks but the hedging program is involved by private firms. How should one think about the interactions between private hedging and sovereign default in a unified framework is an interesting question. Secondly, there is political pressure from using macro-hedging program. If government losses money from hedging, there 16

18 might be some political chaos afterward. If, however, government makes money from the hedging, there will be criticism based on the argument that public sector should not make money from financial business. All in all, the main cost of hedging is not just economical but also political. Last but not least, hedging requires expertise: Mexico has been involved in macro-hedging for nearly 10 years. It is fair to say that Mexico government has gained affluent experience in financial risk management. Other countries might not have this expertise. Before they decide to join the macro-hedging program, they should be able to evaluate their ability to manage such hedging program and corresponding risk aversion of such business on top of other economical and political concerns. 17

19 References Aguiar, Mark and Gita Gopinath, Defaultable debt, interest rates and the current account, Journal of international Economics, 2006, 69 (1), , Manuel Amador et al., Sovereign Debt, Handbook of International Economics, 2014, 4, Arellano, Cristina, Default risk and income fluctuations in emerging economies, The American Economic Review, 2008, pp Borensztein, Eduardo, Eduardo Cavallo, and Olivier Jeanne, The welfare gains from macro-insurance against natural disasters, Journal of Development Economics, 2017, 124, , Olivier Jeanne, and Damiano Sandri, Macro-hedging for commodity exporters, Journal of Development Economics, 2013, 101, Caballero, Ricardo J and Stavros Panageas, Hedging sudden stops and precautionary contractions, Journal of Development Economics, 2008, 85 (1), Chatterjee, Satyajit and Burcu Eyigungor, Maturity, indebtedness, and default risk, The American Economic Review, 2012, 102 (6), Cuadra, Gabriel and Horacio Sapriza, Sovereign default, interest rates and political uncertainty in emerging markets, Journal of international Economics, 2008, 76 (1), Daniel, James, Hedging Government Oil Price Risk, IMF working papers, Eaton, Jonathan and Mark Gersovitz, Debt with potential repudiation: Theoretical and empirical analysis, The Review of Economic Studies, 1981, 48 (2), and Raquel Fernandez, Sovereign debt, Handbook of international economics, 1995, 3, Hatchondo, Juan Carlos and Leonardo Martinez, Long-duration bonds and sovereign defaults, Journal of international Economics, 2009, 79 (1),

20 and, On the benefits of GDP-indexed government debt: lessons from a model of sovereign defaults, Economic Quarterly, 2012, 98 (2), ,, and Horacio Sapriza, Quantitative properties of sovereign default models: solution methods matter, Review of Economic dynamics, 2010, 13 (4), Lopez-Martin, Bernabe, Julio Leal, and Andre Martinez Fritscher, Commodity Price Risk Management and Fiscal Policy in a Sovereign Default Model, Lucas, Robert E, Models of business cycles, Vol. 26, Basil Blackwell Oxford, 1987., Macroeconomic priorities, The American Economic Review, 2003, 93 (1), 1. Mendoza, Enrique G and Vivian Z Yue, A General Equilibrium Model of Sovereign Default and Business Cycles, The Quarterly journal of economics, 2012, 127 (2), Na, Seunghoon, Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé, Martin Uribe, and Vivian Z Yue, A model of the twin ds: Optimal default and devaluation, Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research Reinhart, Carmen M, Kenneth S Rogoff, and Miguel A Savastano, Debt Intolerance, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2003, 2003 (1), Tauchen, George, Finite state markov-chain approximations to univariate and vector autoregressions, Economics letters, 1986, 20 (2),

21 A Tables Table 1: Parameters Parameters Value Source Standard Value in literature Risk-free interest rate r = 0.71% U.S. Real Interest Rate (1-Year Treasury Bill): Risk Aversion γ = 2 Standard Value in literature Probability of redemption λ = 0.11 Average years in default for Mexico: Calibrated From Mexico s Income Data Growth rate of non-oil fiscal revenue G Unconditional commodity price mean p Log commodity price persistence ρ Log commodity price volatility σ Oil to non-oil GDP ratio p Q 6.46% Strike Price p t µe t[p t+1 p t], where µ = 0.74 Share of Hedging α 0.55 Cost of Hedging ξ( p t) Fair price implied by risk-neutral investors Parameter to match moments Discount rate β Output loss function y Target Moments Data Model Simulation Debt to non-oil GDP ratio 9.03% 9.77% Sovereign spread 3.68% 3.21% Table 2: Simulation results: hedging and no-hedging world Economy debt ratio default spreads default probability Hedging 9.97% 3.21% 2.38% No-Hedging 8.96% 4.72 % 3.17 % 20

22 Table 3: Strike Prices Time Strike price (real $) Ratio to conditional price mean Table 4: Hedging Shares Time Share 70% 72% 65% 52% 45% 44% 48% 50% 55% 50% Table 5: Oil Price Parameters Parameters Welfare gains ρ = % ρ = % ρ = % ρ = % ρ = % σ = % σ = % σ = % σ = % σ = % p = % p = % p = % p = % p = % 21

23 Table 6: Robustness check for different parameters Parameter r = 1% r = 2% r = 3% r = 4% r = 5% r = 6% Welfare gains % % % % % % Parameter γ = 3 γ = 4 γ = 5 λ = 0.1 λ = λ = 0.2 Welfare gains % % % % % % Parameter G = 1 G = 1.01 G = 1.02 G = 1.03 G = 1.04 Welfare gains % % % % % Parameter β = 0.8 β = 0.85 β = 0.9 β = 0.95 β = 0.96 β = 0.99 Welfare gains % % % % % % Parameter y = y = y = y = y = 1.3 Welfare gains % % % % % Table 7: Risk Averse Investors: hedging and no-hedging world Economy welfare gains debt ratio default spreads default probability ν = 0 Hedging % 9.97% 3.21% 2.38% No-Hedging 8.96% 4.72 % 3.17 % ν = Hedging % 9.39% 2.42% 1.84% No-Hedging 8.71% 4.32 % 2.83 % ν = Hedging % 9.31% 2.22% 1.76% No-Hedging 8.35% 3.79 % 2.54 % ν = 0.5 Hedging % % -1.04% 0.02% No-Hedging % % 0.05 % 22

24 B Figures Figure 1: Mexico s oil hedging program 140 Mexico's Oil Price (US $ per barrel) 0.7 Flows from hedging (% of GDP) Oil Price Cost Paid Payoff 23

25 Figure 2: Mexico s sovereign spreads and oil price 2500 Mexico Sovereign Bond Spread (bp) and oil price Spread Oil Price

26 Figure 3: Bond price and sovereign spreads 1 Bond Price Sovereign spreads (in percentage) 14 #108 Hedging Hedging No-Hedging 12 No-Hedging b b Figure 4: Welfare gains for different cost premiums Welfare Gains(%) cost premium (Unit $) 25

27 Figure 5: Welfare gains for different strike prices Welfare Gains(%) Strike Price (Ratio of unconditional price mean) Figure 6: Hedging share α 2.5 Welfare Gains(%) , 26

28 Figure 7: Welfare gains of GDP-indexed bonds 8 Welfare Gains(%) Coefficient of Index 27

29 C Algorithm To solve the model, we need to apply value function iteration. We create grid spaces for both b t and p t and denote them by B and P respectively. Starting from an initial guess of bond price q i (b, p) for each b B and p P for iteration i = 0. Conduct the following process. 1. Staring from an initial guess of {V i (b, p), Vi d(p), V c (b, p)} for each b B and p P for iteration i = Update Vi+1 d (p) using equation (7), 3. Update Vi+1 c (b, p) according to equation (6). 4. Update V i+1 (b, p) using V i+1 (w, p) = max { Vi+1 c (b, p), V d i+1 (p)}. 5. Calculate the implied bond price as follows q i+1 (b, p) = E [ p p V c i+1 (b, p ) Vi+1 d (p ) ] 1 + r 6. Iterate until the endogenous objectives q j (b, p), V j (b, p), Vj c(b, p ) and Vj d (p) are close enough for j = i and j = i + 1. i D Estimation of Income Process Suppose that we find a series for price {p t } T t=1 and transform it into {log p t} T t=1. We can find an estimator for unconditional mean p = 1 T T t=1 p t. To get an estimator for the AR(1) coefficient, we assumed that For the conditional density, we have [ log p t = (1 ρ) log(ˆp) 1 σ 2 ] 2 1 ρ 2 + ρ log p t 1 +ε t }{{} µ t 1 f ( log p t p t 1, p, ρ, σ 2) = 1 (log p t µ t 1 ) 2πσ 2 e 2σ 2 2 The likelihood can be written as: L = Π T t=2 1 (log p t µ t 1 )2 2πσ 2 e 2σ 2 log L = T 1 2 log(2πσ 2 ) 1 2σ 2 T t=2 (log p t µ t 1 ) 2 28

30 The first order conditions require: log L ρ = 1 2σ 2 T t=2 2(log p t µ t 1 )( log p t 1 ) = 0 log L σ 2 = T 1 2σ (σ 2 ) 2 T t=2 (log p t µ t 1 ) 2 = 0 E Option Pricing The payoff of the put options is given by max{ p p t+1, 0} for strike price p and current price p t at time t. For a risk neutral investor, the put option is priced according to the following formula: ξ(p t ) = E t [max{ p p t+1, 0}] 1 + r Since we assume that log p t follows an AR(1) process, i.e. Hence, we have [ log p t+1 N (1 ρ) log(p) 1 σ 2 ] 2 1 ρ 2 + ρ log p t, σ 2 }{{} µ t ξ(p t ) = E t [max{ p p t+1, 0}] 1 + r log p = t+1 log p ( p p t+1) 1 + r = = = r log p ( p log p 1 + r Φ µt σ ( p log p 1 + r Φ µt σ 1 ( p p t+1 ) (log p t+1 µ t ) 2 2πσ 2 e 2σ 2 d log p t+1 ) r ) 1 log p 1 + r eµt+ σ 2 1 p t+1 (log p t+1 µ t ) 2 2πσ 2 e 2σ 2 d log p t+1 ( log p µt σ 2 ) 2 Φ σ 29

Welfare Gains from Market Insurance: The Case of Mexican Oil Price Risk

Welfare Gains from Market Insurance: The Case of Mexican Oil Price Risk WP/18/35 Welfare Gains from Market Insurance: The Case of Mexican Oil Price Risk by Chang Ma and Fabian Valencia IMF Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to elicit

More information

Sudden stops, time inconsistency, and the duration of sovereign debt

Sudden stops, time inconsistency, and the duration of sovereign debt WP/13/174 Sudden stops, time inconsistency, and the duration of sovereign debt Juan Carlos Hatchondo and Leonardo Martinez 2013 International Monetary Fund WP/13/ IMF Working Paper IMF Institute for Capacity

More information

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults. June 3, 2009

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults. June 3, 2009 Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Juan C. Hatchondo Richmond Fed Leonardo Martinez Richmond Fed June 3, 2009 1 Business cycles in emerging economies Emerging Economies Developed Economies σ(gdp)

More information

Quantitative Models of Sovereign Default on External Debt

Quantitative Models of Sovereign Default on External Debt Quantitative Models of Sovereign Default on External Debt Argentina: Default risk and Business Cycles External default in the literature Topic was heavily studied in the 1980s in the aftermath of defaults

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

Managing Capital Flows in the Presence of External Risks

Managing Capital Flows in the Presence of External Risks Managing Capital Flows in the Presence of External Risks Ricardo Reyes-Heroles Federal Reserve Board Gabriel Tenorio The Boston Consulting Group IEA World Congress 2017 Mexico City, Mexico June 20, 2017

More information

The sovereign default puzzle: A new approach to debt sustainability analysis

The sovereign default puzzle: A new approach to debt sustainability analysis The sovereign default puzzle: A new approach to debt sustainability analysis Frankfurt joint lunch seminar Daniel Cohen 1 Sébastien Villemot 2 1 Paris School of Economics and CEPR 2 Dynare Team, CEPREMAP

More information

Sovereign default and debt renegotiation

Sovereign default and debt renegotiation Sovereign default and debt renegotiation Authors Vivian Z. Yue Presenter José Manuel Carbó Martínez Universidad Carlos III February 10, 2014 Motivation Sovereign debt crisis 84 sovereign default from 1975

More information

Debt dilution and sovereign default risk

Debt dilution and sovereign default risk Debt dilution and sovereign default risk Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez César Sosa Padilla December 13, 2010 Abstract We propose a sovereign default framework that allows us to quantify the importance

More information

Sovereign Default and the Choice of Maturity

Sovereign Default and the Choice of Maturity Sovereign Default and the Choice of Maturity Juan M. Sanchez Horacio Sapriza Emircan Yurdagul FRB of St. Louis Federal Reserve Board Washington U. St. Louis February 4, 204 Abstract This paper studies

More information

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico Thomas F. Cooley New York University Vincenzo Quadrini Duke University and CEPR May 2, 2000 Abstract This paper develops a two-country monetary

More information

Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis

Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis Quantitative Sovereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis Luigi Bocola Gideon Bornstein Alessandro Dovis ISOM Conference June 2018 This Paper Use Eaton-Gersovitz model to study European debt crisis

More information

Heterogeneous borrowers in quantitative models of sovereign default

Heterogeneous borrowers in quantitative models of sovereign default Heterogeneous borrowers in quantitative models of sovereign default J.C. Hatchondo, L. Martinez and H. Sapriza October, 2012 1 / 25 Elections and Sovereign Bond in Brasil 2 / 25 Stylized facts Declaration

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Commodity Price Risk Management and Fiscal Policy in a Sovereign Default Model

Commodity Price Risk Management and Fiscal Policy in a Sovereign Default Model Commodity Price Risk Management and Fiscal Policy in a Sovereign Default Model Bernabe Lopez-Martin Banco de México Julio Leal Banco de México July 15, 2016 Andre Martinez Fritscher Banco de México Abstract

More information

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default Private Leverage and Sovereign Default Cristina Arellano Yan Bai Luigi Bocola FRB Minneapolis University of Rochester Northwestern University Economic Policy and Financial Frictions November 2015 1 / 37

More information

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Macro II Chapter 5 Macro and Finance 1 Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Main references : - L. Ljundqvist and T. Sargent, Chapter 7 - Mehra and Prescott 1985 JME paper - Jerman 1998 JME paper - J.

More information

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism RIETI Discussion Paper Series 09-E-05 Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism INABA Masaru The Canon Institute for Global Studies KOBAYASHI Keiichiro RIETI The

More information

Slides III - Complete Markets

Slides III - Complete Markets Slides III - Complete Markets Julio Garín University of Georgia Macroeconomic Theory II (Ph.D.) Spring 2017 Macroeconomic Theory II Slides III - Complete Markets Spring 2017 1 / 33 Outline 1. Risk, Uncertainty,

More information

Towards a General Equilibrium Foundation for the Observed Term Structure and Design in Sovereign Bonds

Towards a General Equilibrium Foundation for the Observed Term Structure and Design in Sovereign Bonds 1 / 34 Towards a General Equilibrium Foundation for the Observed Term Structure and Design in Sovereign Bonds K. Wada 1 1 Graduate School of Economics, Hitotsubashi University November 4, 2017 @HIAS. IER,

More information

Sovereign Default Risk with Working Capital in Emerging Economies

Sovereign Default Risk with Working Capital in Emerging Economies Sovereign Default Risk with Working Capital in Emerging Economies Kiyoung Jeon Zeynep Kabukcuoglu January 13, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract What is the role of labor markets in the default

More information

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from: Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez Federal

More information

Growth-Indexed Bonds in Emerging Markets: a Quantitative Approach

Growth-Indexed Bonds in Emerging Markets: a Quantitative Approach Growth-Indexed Bonds in Emerging Markets: a Quantitative Approach André L. Faria February 2005 Abstract In the aftermath of sovereign defaults and financial crises in the 1990s, there have been calls for

More information

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ECONOMIC ANNALS, Volume LXI, No. 211 / October December 2016 UDC: 3.33 ISSN: 0013-3264 DOI:10.2298/EKA1611007D Marija Đorđević* CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ABSTRACT:

More information

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Homework 3: Asset Pricing Homework 3: Asset Pricing Mohammad Hossein Rahmati November 1, 2018 1. Consider an economy with a single representative consumer who maximize E β t u(c t ) 0 < β < 1, u(c t ) = ln(c t + α) t= The sole

More information

Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk

Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk Javier Bianchi 1 César Sosa-Padilla 2 2018 SED Annual Meeting 1 Minneapolis Fed & NBER 2 University of Notre Dame Motivation EMEs with

More information

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez January 15, 2009 Abstract This paper extends the baseline framework used in recent quantitative studies of sovereign default

More information

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach Gianluca Benigno 1 Andrew Foerster 2 Christopher Otrok 3 Alessandro Rebucci 4 1 London School of Economics and

More information

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez January 30, 2009 Abstract This paper extends the baseline framework used in recent quantitative studies of sovereign default

More information

The Demand and Supply of Safe Assets (Premilinary)

The Demand and Supply of Safe Assets (Premilinary) The Demand and Supply of Safe Assets (Premilinary) Yunfan Gu August 28, 2017 Abstract It is documented that over the past 60 years, the safe assets as a percentage share of total assets in the U.S. has

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized Default

Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized Default RESEARCH SEMINAR IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy The University of Michigan Ann Arbor, Michigan 48109-3091 Discussion Paper No. 596 Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized

More information

Growth Regimes, Endogenous Elections, and Sovereign Default Risk

Growth Regimes, Endogenous Elections, and Sovereign Default Risk Growth Regimes, Endogenous Elections, and Sovereign Default Risk Satyajit Chatterjee and Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2016 Abstract A model in which the sovereign derives

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Sudden Stops and Output Drops NEW PERSPECTIVES ON REPUTATION AND DEBT Sudden Stops and Output Drops By V. V. CHARI, PATRICK J. KEHOE, AND ELLEN R. MCGRATTAN* Discussants: Andrew Atkeson, University of California; Olivier Jeanne, International

More information

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell National Institute of Economic and Social Research 1. Introduction

More information

A simple wealth model

A simple wealth model Quantitative Macroeconomics Raül Santaeulàlia-Llopis, MOVE-UAB and Barcelona GSE Homework 5, due Thu Nov 1 I A simple wealth model Consider the sequential problem of a household that maximizes over streams

More information

The Zero Lower Bound

The Zero Lower Bound The Zero Lower Bound Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 4 Introduction In the standard New Keynesian model, monetary policy is often described by an interest rate rule (e.g. a Taylor rule) that

More information

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez February 6, 2009 Abstract This paper extends the baseline framework used in recent quantitative studies of sovereign default

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

News and sovereign default risk in small open economies

News and sovereign default risk in small open economies News and sovereign default risk in small open economies Ceyhun Bora Durdu Federal Reserve Board Ricardo Nunes Federal Reserve Board Horacio Sapriza Rutgers University and Federal Reserve Board January

More information

Schäuble versus Tsipras: a New-Keynesian DSGE Model with Sovereign Default for the Eurozone Debt Crisis

Schäuble versus Tsipras: a New-Keynesian DSGE Model with Sovereign Default for the Eurozone Debt Crisis Schäuble versus Tsipras: a New-Keynesian DSGE Model with Sovereign Default for the Eurozone Debt Crisis Mathilde Viennot 1 (Paris School of Economics) 1 Co-authored with Daniel Cohen (PSE, CEPR) and Sébastien

More information

Sovereign Risk, Private Credit, and Stabilization Policies

Sovereign Risk, Private Credit, and Stabilization Policies Sovereign Risk, Private Credit, and Stabilization Policies Roberto Pancrazi University of Warwick Hernán D. Seoane UC3M Marija Vukotic University of Warwick February 11, 2014 Abstract Taking into account

More information

Liquidity Crises, Liquidity Lines and Sovereign Risk

Liquidity Crises, Liquidity Lines and Sovereign Risk Liquidity Crises, Liquidity Lines and Sovereign Risk Yasin Kürşat Önder Central Bank of Turkey February 3, 2016 Abstract This paper delivers a framework to quantitatively investigate the introduction of

More information

Working Paper Series Long-Duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults WP 08-02R

Working Paper Series Long-Duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults WP 08-02R Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/economic_ research/working_papers/index.cfm Long-Duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults Juan

More information

Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized Default

Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized Default Decentralized Borrowing and Centralized Default Yun Jung Kim Jing Zhang University of Michigan University of Michigan February 3, 212 Abstract In the past, foreign borrowing by developing countries was

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 207 Introduction This note works through some simple two-period consumption-saving problems. In

More information

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle 1 E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 1 A Lucas Tree Model Consider a pure exchange, representative household economy. Suppose there exists an asset called a tree.

More information

A Model with Costly Enforcement

A Model with Costly Enforcement A Model with Costly Enforcement Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania December 25, 2012 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-Enforcement December 25, 2012 1 / 43 A Model with Costly

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EXCESSIVE VOLATILITY IN CAPITAL FLOWS: A PIGOUVIAN TAXATION APPROACH. Olivier Jeanne Anton Korinek

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EXCESSIVE VOLATILITY IN CAPITAL FLOWS: A PIGOUVIAN TAXATION APPROACH. Olivier Jeanne Anton Korinek NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES EXCESSIVE VOLATILITY IN CAPITAL FLOWS: A PIGOUVIAN TAXATION APPROACH Olivier Jeanne Anton Korinek Working Paper 5927 http://www.nber.org/papers/w5927 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Professor Dr. Holger Strulik Open Economy Macro 1 / 34

Professor Dr. Holger Strulik Open Economy Macro 1 / 34 Professor Dr. Holger Strulik Open Economy Macro 1 / 34 13. Sovereign debt (public debt) governments borrow from international lenders or from supranational organizations (IMF, ESFS,...) problem of contract

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks The historical data on financial asset returns show that one dollar invested in the Dow- Jones yields 6 times more than one dollar invested in U.S. Treasury bonds. The return

More information

BIS Working Papers. No 620 Commodity price risk management and fiscal policy in a sovereign default model. Monetary and Economic Department

BIS Working Papers. No 620 Commodity price risk management and fiscal policy in a sovereign default model. Monetary and Economic Department BIS Working Papers No 620 Commodity price risk management and fiscal policy in a sovereign default model by Bernabe Lopez-Martin, Julio Leal and Andre Martinez Fritscher Monetary and Economic Department

More information

Devaluation Risk and the Business Cycle Implications of Exchange Rate Management

Devaluation Risk and the Business Cycle Implications of Exchange Rate Management Devaluation Risk and the Business Cycle Implications of Exchange Rate Management Enrique G. Mendoza University of Pennsylvania & NBER Based on JME, vol. 53, 2000, joint with Martin Uribe from Columbia

More information

The Twin Ds. Optimal Default and Devaluation

The Twin Ds. Optimal Default and Devaluation Optimal Default and Devaluation by Na, Schmitt-Grohé, Uribe, and Yue June 30, 2017 1 Motivation There is a strong empirical link between sovereign default and large devaluations. Reinhart (2002) examines

More information

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University April 12, 2008 Abstract A model of mixed oligopoly is constructed in which a Home public firm

More information

Reputational Effects in Sovereign Default

Reputational Effects in Sovereign Default Reputational Effects in Sovereign Default Konstantin Egorov 1 Michal Fabinger 2 1 Pennsylvania State University 2 University of Tokyo OAP-PRI Economic Workshop Konstantin Egorov, Michal Fabinger Reputational

More information

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete R. Anton Braun Tomoyuki Nakajima 2 University of Tokyo, and CREI 2 Kyoto University, and RIETI December 9, 28 Outline Introduction 2 Model Individuals

More information

Interest rate policies, banking and the macro-economy

Interest rate policies, banking and the macro-economy Interest rate policies, banking and the macro-economy Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California and CEPR November 10, 2017 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract Low interest rates may stimulate

More information

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing I. The Consumption - Portfolio Choice Problem We have studied the portfolio choice problem of an individual

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010 Problem set 5 Asset pricing Markus Roth Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Juli 5, 200 Markus Roth (Macroeconomics 2) Problem set 5 Juli 5, 200 / 40 Contents Problem 5 of problem

More information

Pension Funds Performance Evaluation: a Utility Based Approach

Pension Funds Performance Evaluation: a Utility Based Approach Pension Funds Performance Evaluation: a Utility Based Approach Carolina Fugazza Fabio Bagliano Giovanna Nicodano CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto and University of of Turin CeRP 10 Anniversary Conference Motivation

More information

Working Paper S e r i e s

Working Paper S e r i e s Working Paper S e r i e s W P 0-5 M a y 2 0 0 Excessive Volatility in Capital Flows: A Pigouvian Taxation Approach Olivier Jeanne and Anton Korinek Abstract This paper analyzes prudential controls on capital

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 5 - Money Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 February A brief history of money in macro 1. 1. Hume: money has a wealth effect more money increase in aggregate demand Y 2. Friedman

More information

Problem set Fall 2012.

Problem set Fall 2012. Problem set 1. 14.461 Fall 2012. Ivan Werning September 13, 2012 References: 1. Ljungqvist L., and Thomas J. Sargent (2000), Recursive Macroeconomic Theory, sections 17.2 for Problem 1,2. 2. Werning Ivan

More information

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies Tarishi Matsuoka Tokyo Metropolitan University May, 2015 Tarishi Matsuoka (TMU) Banking Crises in Emerging Market Economies May, 2015 1 / 47 Introduction

More information

Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982

Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982 Interest Rates and Currency Prices in a Two-Country World Robert E. Lucas, Jr. 1982 Contribution Integrates domestic and international monetary theory with financial economics to provide a complete theory

More information

Discussion of Qian, Reinhart, and Rogoff s On Graduation from Default, Inflation and Banking Crises: Ellusive or Illusion

Discussion of Qian, Reinhart, and Rogoff s On Graduation from Default, Inflation and Banking Crises: Ellusive or Illusion Discussion of Qian, Reinhart, and Rogoff s On Graduation from Default, Inflation and Banking Crises: Ellusive or Illusion Mark Aguiar University of Rochester and NBER April 9, 2010 1 Introduction Qian

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade

A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade Grace W. Gu February 22, 2015 (click here for the latest version) Abstract This paper explores the impacts of sovereign defaults on

More information

Did the 1980s in Latin America Need to Be a Lost Decade?

Did the 1980s in Latin America Need to Be a Lost Decade? Did the 1980s in Latin America Need to Be a Lost Decade? Victor Almeida Carlos Esquivel Timothy J. Kehoe Juan Pablo Nicolini Ÿ February 15, 2018 Abstract In 1979, the Federal Reserve Board, led by Chairman

More information

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk Zhiguo He, University of Chicago and NBER Arvind Krishnamurthy, Northwestern University and NBER December 2013 He and Krishnamurthy (Chicago, Northwestern)

More information

1 Modelling borrowing constraints in Bewley models

1 Modelling borrowing constraints in Bewley models 1 Modelling borrowing constraints in Bewley models Consider the problem of a household who faces idiosyncratic productivity shocks, supplies labor inelastically and can save/borrow only through a risk-free

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007) Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007) Virginia Olivella and Jose Ignacio Lopez October 2008 Motivation Menu costs and repricing decisions Micro foundation of sticky

More information

IS FINANCIAL REPRESSION REALLY BAD? Eun Young OH Durham Univeristy 17 Sidegate, Durham, United Kingdom

IS FINANCIAL REPRESSION REALLY BAD? Eun Young OH Durham Univeristy 17 Sidegate, Durham, United Kingdom IS FINANCIAL REPRESSION REALLY BAD? Eun Young OH Durham Univeristy 17 Sidegate, Durham, United Kingdom E-mail: e.y.oh@durham.ac.uk Abstract This paper examines the relationship between reserve requirements,

More information

Dynamic Contracts. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. December 5, Econ720

Dynamic Contracts. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. December 5, Econ720 Dynamic Contracts Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ720 December 5, 2016 1 / 43 Issues Many markets work through intertemporal contracts Labor markets, credit markets, intermediate input supplies,... Contracts

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Kenichi Ueda* *The University of Tokyo PRI-ADBI Joint Workshop January 13, 2017 The views are those of the author and should not be attributed

More information

Macroeconomics and finance

Macroeconomics and finance Macroeconomics and finance 1 1. Temporary equilibrium and the price level [Lectures 11 and 12] 2. Overlapping generations and learning [Lectures 13 and 14] 2.1 The overlapping generations model 2.2 Expectations

More information

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals Klaus Adam and Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. xxx October 213 Abstract We reconsider the role of an inflation conservative

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A MODEL OF THE TWIN DS: OPTIMAL DEFAULT AND DEVALUATION. Seunghoon Na Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martin Uribe Vivian Z.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A MODEL OF THE TWIN DS: OPTIMAL DEFAULT AND DEVALUATION. Seunghoon Na Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martin Uribe Vivian Z. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A MODEL OF THE TWIN DS: OPTIMAL DEFAULT AND DEVALUATION Seunghoon Na Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martin Uribe Vivian Z. Yue Working Paper 20314 http://www.nber.org/papers/w20314 NATIONAL

More information

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence Loyola University Chicago Loyola ecommons Topics in Middle Eastern and orth African Economies Quinlan School of Business 1999 Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MEA Countries: Theory

More information

Sovereign Debt Crises: Some Data and Some Theory

Sovereign Debt Crises: Some Data and Some Theory Sovereign Debt Crises: Some Data and Some Theory Harold L. Cole PIER Lecture 1 / 57 Debt Crises Debt Crises = government has trouble selling new debt. Trouble selling includes large jump in the spread

More information

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets M. Grasselli Mathematics and Statistics McMaster University IMPA - June 28, 2006 Strategic Decision Making Suppose we want to assign monetary values to

More information

Heterogeneous borrowers in quantitative models of sovereign default

Heterogeneous borrowers in quantitative models of sovereign default Heterogeneous borrowers in quantitative models of sovereign default Juan Carlos Hatchondo Leonardo Martinez Horacio Sapriza PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper allows policymakers of different

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A SOLUTION TO THE DISCONNECT BETWEEN COUNTRY RISK AND BUSINESS CYCLE THEORIES. Enrique G. Mendoza Vivian Z.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A SOLUTION TO THE DISCONNECT BETWEEN COUNTRY RISK AND BUSINESS CYCLE THEORIES. Enrique G. Mendoza Vivian Z. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A SOLUTION TO THE DISCONNECT BETWEEN COUNTRY RISK AND BUSINESS CYCLE THEORIES Enrique G. Mendoza Vivian Z. Yue Working Paper 13861 http://www.nber.org/papers/w13861 NATIONAL BUREAU

More information

Center for Quantitative Economic Research WORKING PAPER SERIES. A Model of the Twin Ds: Optimal Default and Devaluation

Center for Quantitative Economic Research WORKING PAPER SERIES. A Model of the Twin Ds: Optimal Default and Devaluation Center for Quantitative Economic Research WORKING PAPER SERIES A Model of the Twin Ds: Optimal Default and Devaluation Seunghoon Na, Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé, Martin Uribe, and Vivian Yue CQER Working Paper

More information

Asset Pricing in Production Economies

Asset Pricing in Production Economies Urban J. Jermann 1998 Presented By: Farhang Farazmand October 16, 2007 Motivation Can we try to explain the asset pricing puzzles and the macroeconomic business cycles, in one framework. Motivation: Equity

More information

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Class Notes on Chaney (2008) Class Notes on Chaney (2008) (With Krugman and Melitz along the Way) Econ 840-T.Holmes Model of Chaney AER (2008) As a first step, let s write down the elements of the Chaney model. asymmetric countries

More information

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Sudden Stops and Output Drops Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 353 January 2005 Sudden Stops and Output Drops V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Patrick J.

More information

A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade

A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade A Tale of Two Countries: Sovereign Default, Exchange Rate, and Trade Grace W. Gu February 12, 2015 (click here for the latest version) Abstract This paper explores the impacts of sovereign defaults on

More information

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks Giancarlo Corsetti Luca Dedola Sylvain Leduc CREST, May 2008 The International Consumption Correlations Puzzle

More information

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria and Rational Expectations Equilibria 1 Basic Setup Two periods: 0 and 1 One riskless asset with interest rate r One risky asset which pays a normally distributed

More information

Default Risk and Aggregate Fluctuations in Emerging Economies

Default Risk and Aggregate Fluctuations in Emerging Economies Default Risk and Aggregate Fluctuations in Emerging Economies Cristina Arellano University of Minnesota Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis First Version: November 2003 This Version: February 2005 Abstract

More information