Risk Aversion and the Variance Decomposition of the Price-Dividend Ratio

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Risk Aversion and the Variance Decomposition of the Price-Dividend Ratio"

Transcription

1 Risk Aversion and the Variance Decomposition of the Price-Dividend Ratio Kevin J. Lansing Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Stephen F. LeRoy y UC Santa Barbara and Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco February 27, 204 Abstract This paper employs a standard asset pricing model with power utility to derive an analytical variance decomposition for the price-dividend ratio. We show that the fraction of the variance coming from future dividend growth rates and future risk-free rates depends exclusively on the value of the risk aversion coe cient. Higher risk aversion lowers the contribution from future dividend growth rates but raises the contribution from future risk free rates. The variance contribution from future excess returns on equity is exactly zero, in stark contrast to empirical ndings which attribute nearly all of the variance in the pricedividend ratio to this source. Keywords: Asset Pricing, Excess Volatility, Risk Aversion, Variance Decomposition. JEL Classi cation: E44, G2. Corresponding author. Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco, CA , (45) , FAX: (45) , kevin.j.lansing@sf.frb.org, homepage: y Department of Economics, University of California, Santa Barbara, CA 9306, (805) , sleroy@econ.ucsb.edu, homepage:

2 Introduction Empirical studies starting with Shiller (98) and LeRoy and Porter (98) have shown that stock prices exhibit excess volatility when compared to the value of ex post realized dividends discounted at a constant rate. Campbell and Shiller (988) addressed the issue using a log-linear decomposition of the equity return identity. They showed that the observed volatility of the log stock price-dividend ratio can be attributed mainly to the fact that future equity returns contain a predictable component, contrary to the Shiller-LeRoy-Porter speci cation. This result suggests that the assumption underlying constant discount rates risk neutrality is a misspeci - cation. To investigate this one would like to have in hand a variance decomposition based on a theoretical asset-pricing model that incorporates risk aversion. The Campbell- Shiller variance decomposition of the price-dividend ratio, being based on the identity de ning the equity return and on that alone, cannot deliver results that depend on such model speci cs. However, if one conducts a variance decomposition based on linearization of the Euler equation of an explicit consumption-based asset pricing model incorporating risk aversion, one can see how risk aversion ts in. We conduct this analysis in the present paper. Speci cally, we use a log-linearization of the representative agent s Euler equation to derive expressions for () log dividend growth, (2) discounted risk-free returns, and (3) discounted excess returns as functions of the measure of relative risk aversion. Then we use the Campbell-Shiller log-linearization of the return identity to break down the variance of the log price-dividend ratio into the sum of the covariances of the log price-dividend ratio with each of these terms. Our results are striking. First, the variance decomposition of the theoretical assetpricing model shows that future excess returns do not covary with the current pricedividend ratio, implying that they contribute nothing to the volatility of the pricedividend ratio. The result that excess stock returns are unforecastable is familiar from the case of risk neutrality. One might have anticipated that the absence of correlation between the price-dividend ratio and future excess returns would not carry over when agents are interested in the higher moments of future payo s, as is true under strict risk aversion, rather than just expected future payo s, as under risk neutrality. However, our result is that, contrary to this intuition, the zero-covariance For summaries of this extensive literature, see West (988), Gilles and LeRoy (99), Shiller (2003), and LeRoy (200).

3 result does carry over to the case of risk aversion. Thus regardless of the degree of risk aversion future excess returns are unforecastable, and therefore they make zero contribution to the volatility of the price-dividend ratio. 2 The empirical results of Campbell-Shiller and Cochrane (992), (2005), (20) sharply contradict the nding from the theoretical model that future excess returns do not contribute to the volatility of the current price-dividend ratio. On the contrary, they conclude that more than 00% of the variation in price-dividend ratios comes from this source (re ecting the fact that future dividend growth covaries positively with the current price-dividend ratio, whereas future returns covary negatively). Thus we con rm in a particularly simple setting the ndings of others that the theory of consumption-based asset pricing, at least in its basic versions, does not come anywhere near tting the data. Given the model s result that future excess returns do not covary with the log price-dividend ratio, the variance decomposition based on the return identity implies that the variance of the log price-dividend ratio can be decomposed into the sum of a term that depends on the predictability of future dividend growth rates and a term that depends on the predictability of future risk-free returns. Remarkably, the model implies that the proportion of total variance accounted for by each of these terms depends only on the agents risk aversion it does not depend on the discount factor or the degree of persistence of dividend growth. Low risk aversion results in a small contribution to variance from future risk-free rates and a large contribution from future dividend growth rates, and vice-versa for high risk aversion. The fact that the weights in this decomposition depend only on relative risk aversion implies that empirical estimates of these weights can be converted into measures of risk aversion. We nd that this conversion results in estimated levels of relative risk aversion around 5. Of course, this result cannot be taken as providing a serious estimator for the risk aversion parameter: our main result is that the model must be rejected in its entirety due to its misdiagnosis of the sources of volatility of price-dividend ratio. 2 The result is not completely general. In the model of LeRoy (973) future returns have a forecastable component under strictly positive risk aversion. Also, Lansing and LeRoy (203) nd that, when agents have partial information about future dividend payo s, future returns contain a forecastable component. Even in this case, however, in the example they studied the contribution of future returns to the volatility of the price-dividend ratio is not large. Thus the nding that empirically return forecastability is large remains a puzzle. 2

4 2 Asset Pricing Model We employ a frictionless pure exchange model along the lines of Lucas (978). A representative investor can purchase shares to transfer wealth from one date to another. Each share pays an exogenous stream of stochastic dividends in perpetuity. The representative investor s problem is to maximize ( ) X E 0 t c t subject to the budget constraint t=0 c t + p t s t = (p t + d t ) s t ; c t ; s t > 0; (2) where c t is the investor s consumption in period t; is the coe cient of relative risk aversion, and s t is the number of shares held in period t: The rst-order condition that governs the investor s share holdings is p t = E t ct+ c t (p t+ + d t+)# () ; (3) where E t is the expectation operator conditional on information available at time t. Equity shares are assumed to exist in unit net supply such that s t = for all t: Market clearing therefore implies c t = d t for all t: We assume that the investor s information set consists of current and past values of consumption/dividends. 3 The rst-order condition can be iterated forward to substitute out p t+j for j = ; 2; ::. Applying the law of iterated expectations and imposing the condition that the limiting discounted terminal value of any optimal portfolio strategy is zero, we can exclude bubble solutions. 4 expression for the equilibrium equity price: Exclusion of bubble solutions yields the following X p t = E t M t; t+j d t+j ; (4) j= 3 Lansing and LeRoy (203) consider alternative information sets that allow for investor knowledge about future dividend realizations or imperfect information about the growth rate of dividends. 4 This condition is often called a transversality condition, but this is at best a very loose usage of terminology. More precisely stated, the result is that under appropriate boundedness and nonnegativity restrictions on consumption and portfolio strategies, maximization of the assumed utility function implies a necessary transversality condition (see Kamihigashi [?]). This transversality condition in turn implies the statement in the text. Thus the statement in the text is an implication of a transversality condition, but is not itself a transversality condition. 3

5 where M t;t+j j (c t+j =c t ) is the stochastic discount factor. We assume that the growth rate of dividends x t log (d t =d t ) is governed by the following AR() process: x t+ = x t + ( ) x + t+j N 0; 2 ; iid; t+; jj < : (5) By substituting the equilibrium condition c t = d t into the rst-order condition (3) and de ning the price-dividend ratio as y t p t =d t ; we obtain the following transformed version of the rst-order condition in terms of stationary variables y t = E t f exp [( ) x t+ ] (y t+ + )g : (6) 2. Variance of the Price-Dividend Ratio We now derive an approximate analytical solution for the variance of log(y t ) : This involves solving the transformed rst-order condition (6) subject to the dividend growth process (5). To do so, it is convenient to de ne the following nonlinear change of variables: z t exp [( ) x t ] (y t + ) ; (7) where z t represents a composite variable that depends on both the growth rate of dividends and the price-dividend ratio. The rst-order condition (6) becomes y t = E t z t+ ; (8) which shows that y t is simply the rational forecast of the composite variable z t+ : Combining (7) and (8) yields the following transformed version of the equilibrium condition: z t = exp [( ) x t ] (E t z t+ + ) : (9) Proposition. An approximate analytical solution for the equilibrium value of the composite variable z t is given by z t = a 0 exp [a (x t x)] ; where a solves a = h i exp ( )x + 2 (a ) 2 2 and a 0 exp fe [log (z t )]g is given by a 0 = exp [( )x] h i; exp ( )x + 2 (a ) 2 2 4

6 h i provided that exp ( )x + 2 (a ) 2 2 < : Proof : See Appendix A. Two values of a satisfy the nonlinear equation in Proposition. The inequality restriction selects the value of a with lower magnitude to ensure that a 0 is positive. 5 Given the approximate solution for the composite variable z t, we can recover the solution for the equilibrium price-dividend ratio y t as follows: y t = E t z t+ = a 0 exp a (x t x) + 2 (a ) 2 2 : (0) As shown in Appendix B, the above solution can be used to derive the following unconditional variance of the log price-dividend ratio: 2.2 Variance of Returns V ar [log (y t )] = (a ) 2 V ar (x t ) : () The gross rate of return on equity can be written as R t+ = p t+ + d t+ yt+ + = exp (x t+ ) p t y t (2) = zt+ exp ( x t+ ) ; (3) E t z t+ where we have eliminated y t using the equilibrium condition (8) and eliminated y t+ + using the de nitional relationship which follows directly from (7). y t+ + = exp [ ( )x t+ ] z t+ ; (4) In Appendix B, we show that the approximate law of motion for log(r t+ ) is log(r t+ ) E[log(R t+ )] = (x t+ x) + a t+ (5) where a is given by Proposition. Given the above law of motion for the log equity return, it is straightforward to compute the following unconditional variance: V ar[log(r t+ )] = 2 V ar (x t ) + a [a + 2] 2 ; (6) 5 Lansing (200) compares the approximate solution from Proposition to the exact theoretical solution derived by Burnside (998). The approximate solution is extremely accurate for low and moderate levels of risk aversion ( ' 2) : But even for high levels of risk aversion ( ' 0) ; the approximation error for the equilibrium price-dividend ratio remains below 5 percent. 5

7 where V ar (x t ) = 2 = 2 from (5). by In Appendix B, we show that the law of motion for the log risk-free rate is given log(r f t+ ) E[log(Rf t+ )] = (x t x) ; = (x t+ x) t+; (7) Subtracting the risk-free rate equation (7) from the equity return equation (5) yields the following law of motion for the excess return on equity, i.e., the equity premium: log(r t+ ) log(r f t+ ) = ( + a ) t+ + 2 h 2 (a ) 2i 2 ; (8) where we have substituted in E[log(R t+ )] E[log(R f t+ )] as derived in Appendix B. 3 Mapping to the Campbell-Shiller Framework Campbell and Shiller (988), Campbell (99), and Cochrane (992, 2005) show that a log-linear approximation of the equity return identity implies that the variance of the log price-dividend ratio must equal the sum of the ratio s covariances with: () future dividend growth rates, (2) future risk-free rates, and (3) future excess returns on equity. This variance decomposition, being derived from an identity rather than a theoretical model, cannot be used to ascertain the theoretical connections between risk aversion and asset price volatility. Its use up to now in the nance literature has been to determine the relative empirical importance of the three separate components in explaining the volatility of observed stock prices relative to dividends. However, since the return identity is valid in fully-speci ed theoretical models, it is possible to evaluate the model by performing the variance decomposition analytically and then using a calibrated version of the model to compute the contributions from each of the three components noted above for comparison with the results obtained from U.S. data. This is what we do next. Following the methodology of Campbell and Shiller (988), the de nition of the log equity return (2) can be approximated as follows: log(r t+ ) log (y t+ + ) + x t+ log (y t ) ; ' 0 + log (y t+ ) + x t+ log (y t ) ; (9) 6

8 where 0 and = exp [E log (y t )] = f + exp [E log (y t )]g are Taylor-series coe cients. Solving equation (9) for log (y t ) and then successively iterating the resulting expression forward to eliminate log(y t++j ) for j = 0; ; 2::: yields the following approximate identity: log (y t ) ' 0 P + j=0 ( ) j [x t++j log(r t++j )] ; (20) which shows that movements in the log price-dividend ratio must be accounted for by movements in either future dividend growth rates or future log equity returns. The variables in the approximate identity (20) can be expressed as deviations from their unconditional means while the means are consolidated into the constant term. Multiplying both sides of the resulting expression by log (y t ) then taking the unconditional expectation of both sides yields # P V ar [log (y t )] = Cov log (y t ) ; ( ) j x t++j Cov log (y t ) ; = Cov Cov log (y t ) ; log (y t ) ; j=0 # P ( ) j x t++j j=0 Cov log (y t ) ; E [log (y t )] and # P ( ) j log(r t++j ) ; j=0 # P ( ) j log(r f t++j ) j=0 # P ( ) j log(r t++j =R f t++j ) : (2) j=0 Here the second version of the expression breaks up future log equity returns into two parts: future log risk free rates, denoted by log(r f t++j ); and future excess returns on equity, as given by log(r t++j =R f t++j ). The above equation states that the variance of the log price-dividend ratio must be accounted for by the covariance of the ratio with future dividend growth rates, future risk free rates, or future excess returns on equity. The magnitude of each covariance term is a measure of the predictability of each component when the current price-dividend ratio is employed as the sole regressor in a forecasting equation. The approximate law of motion for the log equity return is given by equation (5). The corresponding law of motion for the log risk-free rate is given by equation (7). Using the approximate laws of motion for the relevant variables, we can analytically compute the three covariance terms in equation (2). Details are provided in Appendix C. The results of the theoretical variance decomposition are as follows: V ar [log (y t )] = a 2 V ar (x t ) a 2 V ar (x t ) 0; (22) where the three terms in the above equation correspond to the three possible sources 7

9 of variation: () future dividend growth rates, (2) future risk free rates, and (3) future excess returns on equity. Equation (22) shows that the variance contribution from excess returns (the third term in the equation) is exactly zero. This result can be understood by examining the law of motion for excess returns on equity as given by equation (8). Equation (8) shows that excess returns are iid in the power-utility model. Hence, the covariance between the log price-dividend ratio at time t and future excess returns must be zero. The theoretical variance decomposition in equation (22) can be expressed more concisely by dividing both sides of the decomposition by the variance of the log pricedividend ratio, as given by equation ().To avoid division by zero, we rule out = 0 and = ; since these result in zero volatility for the price-dividend ratio. Doing this implies that the contributions to variance from each source can be expressed as fractions that sum to unity. Details of this computation are provided in Appendix C. The results of the fractional decomposition are summarized in Table. Table : Analytical variance decomposition for the log price-dividend ratio Fraction of variance attributable to: Future Dividend Growth Future Risk-Free Rates Future Excess Returns 0 Table shows that the fractional variance decomposition depends only on the risk aversion coe cient ; and does not depend on or : When the representative investor is risk neutral, we have = 0: In this case, future dividend growth rates account for 00% of the variance of the log price-dividend ratio, while the fraction of the variance attributable to other sources is zero. For > 0 dividend growth explains more than 00% of the variation in the price-dividend ratio. Accordingly, the contribution of the stochastic discount factor is negative, so as to reduce the sum of the two to 00%. At higher levels of (but maintaining < ) uctuations in future dividends are nearly o set by inverse uctuations in their marginal utilities, implying a low variance of the price-dividend ratio. The weights on dividend growth and stochastic discount factors approach and as approaches. With = ; the log price-dividend ratio is constant and hence there is no variance to be decomposed. 8

10 For > uctuations in dividends are more than o set by inverse uctuations in marginal utilities. As a result the weights on the dividend component and the returns component reverse signs: the former becomes negative and the latter positive. When = 5; we have = ( ) = 0:25 and = ( ) = :25. In this case, 25% of the variance of the log price dividend ratio is attributable to movements in future dividend growth, 25% is attributable to movements in future risk free rates, and 0% is attributable to movements in future excess returns. 6 The variance decomposition computed analytically from the model can be compared to the decomposition obtained from the data without imposing any particular model. Cochrane (2005, p. 400) presents an empirical variance decomposition of the log price-dividend ratio for the value-weighted basket of stocks traded on the New York Stock Exchange using annual data for the period 928 to 988. The data show that 34% of the variance of the log price-dividend ratio is attributable to movements in future dividend growth, while 38% is attributable to movements in future equity returns (i.e., the sum of future risk free rates and future excess returns). WHY DON T THESE SUM TO? The corresponding percentages from our model are 25% and 25% when = 5, which are not too di erent from Cochrane s results. The model can match the 34% gure from Cochrane s empirical decomposition by setting = 3:9; and can match the 38% gure from Cochrane s empirical decomposition by setting = 3:6. However, if the variance contribution from future equity returns is broken down into separate contributions from future risk-free rates and future excess returns, then the results obtained from the model are very di erent from the data. As we have noted, in the data more than 00% of the variation in the log price-dividend ratio is attributable to movements in future excess returns, i.e., the third term in equation (2), while almost nothing can be attributed to movements in future risk-free rates. The power-utility model generates the opposite result: more than 00% of the variation in the log price-dividend ratio is attributable to movements in future risk-free rates, while exactly nothing is attributable to movements in future excess returns. One way in which empirical decomposition manifests itself in the data is the fact that the dividend yield (the inverse of the price-dividend ratio) forecasts excess returns on equity over long horizons, whereas empirical proxies for the risk-free rate do not predict future excess returns (Campbell and Shiller 988). More recently, Cochrane (2008, p. 545) obtains a statistically signi cant long-horizon regression 6 Since the variance decomposition does not require the sources of variation to be orthogonal to one another, the percentage from each source may fall outside the range of 0% to 00%. 9

11 coe cient of.23 when forecasting excess returns using the current dividend yield. His result implies that 23% of the dividend yield variance in the data is coming from future excess returns. The power utility model attributes zero percent of the variance in the dividend yield to this source. 4 Alternative Models Some recent contributions that allow for bubbles or employ models with time-varying risk aversion or time-varying volatility of consumption growth have achieved more success in matching the empirical variance decomposition than we report here. These features introduce persistence (i.e., predictability) in the law of motion for excess returns. Models by Campbell and Cochrane (999) and Bansal and Yaron (2004) are the most notable examples that employ time-varying risk aversion or time-varying volatility of consumption growth, respectively. However, these models must still rely on the assumption of extremely high risk aversion to match observed features of the data. From equation (8), it is straightforward to see how the inclusion of time-varying risk aversion or time-varying volatility of consumption growth could be used to introduce persistence (or predictability) into excess returns. Allowing the risk aversion coe cient to depend on lagged values of consumption growth could be interpreted as a reduced-form version of the habit formation model of Campbell and Cochrane (999). Introducing persistent stochastic variation in the innovation variance 2 (which also appears in the expression for a in Proposition ) would mimic the stochastic volatility setup employed by Bansal and Yaron (2004). It is important to note that our analytical variance decomposition for the powerutility model ruled out the presence of bubbles. Engsted et al. (202) introduce a periodically-collapsing rational bubble into a simple asset pricing model with riskneutral investors. They show that predictability regressions using simulated data from the model yield results that are very similar to those obtained by Cochrane (2008) using U.S. data. Speci cally, in deriving the approximate return identity (20), we applied the transversality condition lim j! ( ) j log (y t+j ) = 0. In the presence of an explosive rational bubble, the transversality condition would not hold. Recent work by Engsted, et al. (202) shows that the introduction of a periodically-collapsing rational bubble is successful in allowing their theoretical asset pricing model to generate predictability regressions that are very similar to those obtained by Cochrane (2008) using U.S. data. The model employed by Engsted et al. is a special case of the 0

12 power-utility model considered here with = = 0: Hence, while Cochrane s empirical results may be interpreted as showing that expected excess returns in the data are predictable, this interpretation is conditioned on the assumption of no bubbles. If one allows for the presence of bubbles, a risk neutral version of the power-utility model can produce data in which the price-dividend ratio has substantial predictive power for future excess returns. I DON T UNDERSTAND THE DISCUSSION OF THIS PARA. YOU DON T GET A CHOICE ABOUT WHETHER OR NOT TO IMPOSE THE TVC. IF THERE IS A NECESSARY TVC THEN IF YOU TRY TO RELAX IT, WHAT YOU GET IS NOT AN OPTIMUM, THEREFORE NOT AN EQUILIBRIUM. NOT HAVING READ ENGSTED, I DON T KNOW HOW TO HANDLE THIS DISCUS- SION. MAYBE WE SHOULD JUST DELETE IT. 5 Conclusion We mapped a standard asset pricing model with power utility into the Campbell- Shiller (988) variance decomposition framework. We showed that the fraction of the variance of the log price dividend ratio coming from future dividend growth rates and future risk free rates depends on a single parameter: the coe cient of relative risk aversion. Moreover, we showed that the fraction of the variance coming from future excess returns on equity is identically zero, in stark contrast to the large contribution to variance from this source found in the data. Our results help to shed light on some elements of a theoretical model that could be used to generate a variance decomposition similar to that in the data. It would appear that a successful asset pricing model must incorporate either time-varying risk aversion and/or time-varying volatility of consumption growth. In this way, excess returns on equity can be made to exhibit signi cant persistence and volatility, in contrast to the basic power-utility model considered here which implies that excess returns are iid; as shown by equation (8). Allowing for the possibility of bubbles is another way in which the basic power-utility model can produce an empiricallyplausible variance decomposition, as demonstrated recently by Engsted et al. (202). Campbell and Cochrane (999) achieve persistent and volatile excess returns on equity by introducing time-varying risk aversion via habit formation. The law of motion for the habit stock in their model is reverse-engineered to deliver a constant risk-free rate, thereby allowing excess returns to make a large contribution to the variance of the log price-dividend ratio, as in the data. However, their calibrated model

13 requires an extremely high coe cient of relative risk aversion to match the various empirical facts around 80 in the model steady state. Moreover, the habit formation model predicts that rational investors expected returns on equity will be low when risk aversion is low a situation that should occur near market peaks when the pricedividend ratio is high. But survey evidence reveals the opposite: investor expectations about future returns on risky assets tend to be high near market peaks when the price-dividend ratio is high suggestive of extrapolative expectations. 7 Bansal and Yaron (2004) introduce exogenous time-varying volatility in the stochastic processes for consumption and dividend growth which also share a persistent component. In addition, they consider Epstein-Zin (989) preferences which allow the elasticity of intertemporal substitution to be varied independently of the risk aversion coe cient. Nevertheless, their model continues to underpredict the volatility of the log pricedividend ratio in the data even when the risk aversion coe cient is raised to a value of 0. Overall, it remains a challenge for fundamentals-based asset pricing models to fully explain observed stock market behavior. 7 For a review of the evidence, see Greenwood and Shleifer (203), Jurgilas and Lansing (203), and Williams (203). 2

14 Appendix A Proof of Proposition Iterating ahead the law of motion for z t speci ed in Proposition and taking the conditional expectation yields h i E t z t+ = y t = a 0 exp a (x t x) + 2 (a ) 2 2 : (A.) Substituting the above expression into the rst-order condition (9) and then taking logarithms yields log (z t ) = F (x t ) = log () + ( )x t n + log a 0 exp h a (x t x) + 2 (a ) 2 2 i o + ; ' log (a 0 ) + a (x t x) ; (A.2) where the Taylor-series coe cients a 0 and a are given by n h i o log (a 0 ) = F (x) = log () + ( ) x + log a 0 exp 2 (a ) ;(A.3) t = + x h i a a 0 exp 2 (a ) 2 2 h i : (A.4) a 0 exp 2 (a ) Solving equation (A.3) for a 0 yields a 0 = exp fe [log (z t )]g = exp [( ) x] h i; (A.5) exp ( ) x + 2 (a ) 2 2 which can be substituted into equation (A.4) to yield the following nonlinear equation that determines a : a = + a exp ( ) x + 2 a2 2 : (A.6) Rearranging equation (A.6) yields the expression shown in Proposition h. There are i two solutions, but only one solution satis es the condition exp ( ) x + 2 (a ) 2 2 < ; which is veri ed after solving (A.6) using a nonlinear equation solver. 3

15 B Asset Pricing Moments This section brie y outlines the derivation of equations (), (6), and (7). Taking the unconditional expectation of log (y t ) in equation (0) yields E [log (y t )] = log (a 0 ) + 2 (a ) 2 2 : (B.) We then have log (y t ) E [log (y t )] = a (x t x) ; (B.2) which in turn implies V ar [log (y t )] = (a ) 2 V ar (x t ) : (B.3) As described in the text, the equity return (3) can be rewritten as R t+ = zt+ exp ( x t+ ) : (B.4) E t z t+ Substituting in E t z t+ from equation (A.) and z t+ = a 0 exp [a (x t+ Proposition and then taking the unconditional mean of log(r t+ ) yields We then have which in turns implies x)] from E[log(R t+ )] = log () + x 2 (a ) 2 2 : (B.5) log(r t+ ) E[log(R t+ )] = (x t+ x) + a t+ ; (B.6) V ar[log(r t+ )] = 2 V ar (x t ) + (a ) a Cov (x t+ ; t+ ) : {z } (B.7) = 2 The log risk free rate is determined by the following rst-order condition ( #) log(r f t+ ) = log ct+ E t ; c t = log fe t [ exp ( x t+ )]g ; = log () + [x t + ( ) x] ; (B.8) where we have made the substitution c t+ =c t = d t+ =d t = exp (x t+ ) and then inserted the law of motion for x t+ from equation (5) before taking the conditional expectation. Taking the unconditional mean of log(r f t+ ) and then subtracting the unconditional mean from equation (B.8) yields the law of motion (7). 4

16 C Variance Decomposition The Taylor series coe cient in the approximate return identify (9) is given by h = exp [E log (y a t)] 0 exp + exp [E log (y t )] = 2 (a ) 2 i 2 h i h i = exp ( ) x + + a 0 exp 2 (a ) (a ) 2 2 ; (C.) where we have made use of equations (A.5) and (B.). Using the law of motion for log (y t ) given by (B.2) and the law of motion for x t+ given by (5), we can compute the following covariance which is the rst term in equation (2): Cov log (y t ) ; # P ( ) j x t++j j=0 = E fa (x t x) (x t+ x) + a (x t x) (x t+2 x) o + ( ) 2 a (x t x) (x t+3 x) + ::: ; n o = a 2 V ar (x t ) + + ( ) 2 + ( ) 3 + ::: ; = a 2 V ar (x t ) : (C.2) Similarly, using the law of motion for log(r f t+ ) given by (7) we can compute the following covariance which is the second term in equation (2): # P Cov log (y t ) ; ( ) j log(r f t++j ) = E fa (x t x) (x t x) j=0 + a (x t x) (x t+2 x) o + ( ) 2 a (x t x) (x t+3 x) + ::: ; n o = a 2 V ar (x t ) + + ( ) 2 + ( ) 3 + ::: ; = a 2 V ar (x t ) : (C.3) The law of motion for excess returns (8) shows that excess returns are iid: Hence, the third covariance term in equation (2) is identically zero. Dividing both sides of equation (2) by V ar [log (y t )] from (B.3) and then substituting in the appropriate 5

17 moments yields = a ( ) a ( ) 0; = 0; (C.4) where we make use of ( ) = ( ) =a from equations (A.6) and (C.). 6

18 References Bansal, R., and A. Yaron 2004 Risks for the long run: A potential resolution of asset pricing puzzles, Journal of Finance 59, Burnside, C. 998 Solving asset pricing models with Gaussian shocks, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 22, Campbell, J.Y. 99 A variance decomposition for stock returns, Economic Journal, 0, Campbell, J.Y. and J.H. Cochrane 999 By force of habit: A consumption-based explanation of aggregate stock market behavior, Journal of Political Economy, 07, Campbell, J.Y. and R.J. Shiller 988 The dividend-price ratio and expectations of future dividends and discount factors, Review of Financial Studies,, Cochrane, J.H. 992 Explaining the variance of price-dividend ratios, Review of Financial Studies, 5, Cochrane, J.H Asset Pricing, Revised Edition. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. Cochrane, J.H The dog that did not bark: A defense of return predictability, Review of Financial Studies, 2, Engsted, T., T.Q. Pedersen, and C. Tanggaard 202 The log-linear return approximation, bubbles and predictability, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 47, Epstein, L. G., and S. E. Zin 989 Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: A theoretical framework, Econometrica 57, Gilles, C. and S.F. LeRoy 99 Econometric aspects of variance-bounds tests: A survey, Review of Financial Studies, 4, Greenwood, R. and A. Shleifer 203 Expectations of returns and expected returns, NBER Working Paper Jurgilas, M. and K.J. Lansing. 203 Housing bubbles and expected returns to home ownership: Lessons and policy implications, in M. Balling and J. Berg, (eds.), Property Prices and Real Estate Financing in a Turbulent World. Vienna/Brussels: Société Universitaire Européenne de Recherches Financières (SUERF), vol 203/4. Lansing, K.J. 200 Rational and near-rational bubbles without drift, Economic Journal, 20, Lansing, K.J. and S.F. LeRoy 203 Risk aversion, investor information, and stock market volatility, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Working Paper LeRoy, S.F. and R.D. Porter 98 The present-value relation: Tests based on implied variance bounds, Econometrica 49, LeRoy, S.F. 200 Excess volatility tests, in: Durlauf, S.N. and Blume, L.E., (Eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition, Macmillan. Lucas, R.E. 978 Asset prices in an exchange economy, Econometrica 46, Shiller, R.J. 98 Do stock prices move too much to be justi ed by subsequent changes in dividends? American Economic Review 7, Shiller, R.J From e cient markets theory to behavioral nance, Journal of Economic Perspectives 7 (Winter),

19 West, K.D. 988 Bubbles, fads, and stock price volatility tests: A partial evaluation, Journal of Finance, 43, Williams, J.C. 203 Bubbles tomorrow, yesterday, but never today?, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Letter (September 23). 8

Risk Aversion and Stock Price Volatility

Risk Aversion and Stock Price Volatility FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Risk Aversion and Stock Price Volatility Kevin J. Lansing Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Stephen F. LeRoy UC Santa Barbara and Federal

More information

Risk Aversion, Investor Information, and Stock Market Volatility

Risk Aversion, Investor Information, and Stock Market Volatility Risk Aversion, Investor Information, and Stock Market Volatility Kevin J. Lansing y Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco and Norges Bank Stephen F. LeRoy z UC Santa Barbara and Federal Reserve Bank of

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES ISSN 1471-0498 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES HOUSING AND RELATIVE RISK AVERSION Francesco Zanetti Number 693 January 2014 Manor Road Building, Manor Road, Oxford OX1 3UQ Housing and Relative

More information

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints The University of Hong Kong From the SelectedWorks of Yulei Luo 00 Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints Yulei Luo, The University of Hong Kong Eric Young, University of Virginia Available

More information

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing /49 Introduction We present models of asset pricing where investors preferences are subject to psychological biases or where investors

More information

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function Eurilton Araújo Insper Working Paper WPE: 23/2008 Copyright Insper. Todos os direitos reservados. É proibida a reprodução

More information

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY

CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ECONOMIC ANNALS, Volume LXI, No. 211 / October December 2016 UDC: 3.33 ISSN: 0013-3264 DOI:10.2298/EKA1611007D Marija Đorđević* CONSUMPTION-BASED MACROECONOMIC MODELS OF ASSET PRICING THEORY ABSTRACT:

More information

Asset Pricing with Concentrated Ownership of Capital

Asset Pricing with Concentrated Ownership of Capital FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Asset Pricing with Concentrated Ownership of Capital Kevin J. Lansing Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco March 2011 Working Paper 2011-07 http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/papers/2011/wp11-07bk.pdf

More information

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2) MakØk3, Fall 2010 (blok 2) Business cycles and monetary stabilization policies Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

More information

E ects of di erences in risk aversion on the. distribution of wealth

E ects of di erences in risk aversion on the. distribution of wealth E ects of di erences in risk aversion on the distribution of wealth Daniele Coen-Pirani Graduate School of Industrial Administration Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, PA 15213-3890 Tel.: (412) 268-6143

More information

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

1. Money in the utility function (continued) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (continued) a. Welfare costs of in ation b. Potential non-superneutrality

More information

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Stephen R. Bond Institute for Fiscal Studies and Nu eld College, Oxford Måns Söderbom Centre for the Study of African Economies,

More information

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010

Booms and Busts in Asset Prices. May 2010 Booms and Busts in Asset Prices Klaus Adam Mannheim University & CEPR Albert Marcet London School of Economics & CEPR May 2010 Adam & Marcet ( Mannheim Booms University and Busts & CEPR London School of

More information

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Abdulrahman Alharbi 1 Abdullah Noman 2 Abstract: Bansal et al (2009) paper focus on measuring risk in consumption especially

More information

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate University of British Columbia Department of Economics, International Finance (Econ 556) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout #3 1 1 on-traded goods and the real exchange rate So far we have looked at environments

More information

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing Consumption-Savings, State Pricing 1/ 40 Introduction We now consider a consumption-savings decision along with the previous portfolio choice decision. These

More information

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result Arantza Gorostiaga Rubio-Ramírez Juan F. Universidad del País Vasco Duke University and Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Abstract

More information

Disappearing money illusion

Disappearing money illusion Disappearing money illusion Tom Engsted y Thomas Q. Pedersen z August 2018 Abstract In long-term US stock market data the price-dividend ratio strongly predicts future in ation with a positive slope coe

More information

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II ECON 532) Practice Problems III Q: Consumption Theory CARA utility) Consider an individual living for two periods, with preferences Uc 1 ; c 2 ) = uc 1

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty Chapter 8 Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty In this chapter we examine dynamic models of consumer choice under uncertainty. We continue, as in the Ramsey model, to take the decision of

More information

ECON Micro Foundations

ECON Micro Foundations ECON 302 - Micro Foundations Michael Bar September 13, 2016 Contents 1 Consumer s Choice 2 1.1 Preferences.................................... 2 1.2 Budget Constraint................................ 3

More information

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing Guido Ascari and Lorenza Rossi University of Pavia Abstract Calvo and Rotemberg pricing entail a very di erent dynamics of adjustment

More information

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying September 10, 2007 Introduction In the recent literature of empirical asset pricing there has been considerable evidence of time-varying

More information

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Advanced Modern Macroeconomics Asset Prices and Finance Max Gillman Cardi Business School 0 December 200 Gillman (Cardi Business School) Chapter 7 0 December 200 / 38 Chapter 7: Asset Prices and Finance

More information

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 26/2 2013 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case

More information

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure Comment on Dewachter and Lyrio s "Learning, Macroeconomic Dynamics, and the Term Structure of Interest Rates" 1 by Jordi Galí (CREI, MIT, and NBER) August 2006 The present paper by Dewachter and Lyrio

More information

Appendix for The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment

Appendix for The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment Appendix for The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment Jason Beeler and John Y. Campbell October 0 Beeler: Department of Economics, Littauer Center, Harvard University,

More information

Statistical Evidence and Inference

Statistical Evidence and Inference Statistical Evidence and Inference Basic Methods of Analysis Understanding the methods used by economists requires some basic terminology regarding the distribution of random variables. The mean of a distribution

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model Guido Ascari University of Pavia Nicola Branzoli University of Pavia October 27, 2006 Abstract This note shows that full price indexation

More information

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment Yi Wen Department of Economics Cornell University Ithaca, NY 14853 yw57@cornell.edu Abstract

More information

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010 Problem set 5 Asset pricing Markus Roth Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Juli 5, 200 Markus Roth (Macroeconomics 2) Problem set 5 Juli 5, 200 / 40 Contents Problem 5 of problem

More information

ASSET PRICING WITH ADAPTIVE LEARNING. February 27, 2007

ASSET PRICING WITH ADAPTIVE LEARNING. February 27, 2007 ASSET PRICING WITH ADAPTIVE LEARNING Eva Carceles-Poveda y Chryssi Giannitsarou z February 27, 2007 Abstract. We study the extent to which self-referential adaptive learning can explain stylized asset

More information

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth Florian Misch a, Norman Gemmell a;b and Richard Kneller a a University of Nottingham; b The Treasury, New Zealand March

More information

Prospect Theory and Asset Prices

Prospect Theory and Asset Prices Prospect Theory and Asset Prices Presenting Barberies - Huang - Santos s paper Attila Lindner January 2009 Attila Lindner (CEU) Prospect Theory and Asset Prices January 2009 1 / 17 Presentation Outline

More information

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy Ozan Eksi TOBB University of Economics and Technology November 2 Abstract The standard new Keynesian

More information

Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning

Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning Tongbin Zhang Univeristat Autonoma de Barcelona and Barcelona GSE April 2016 Tongbin Zhang (Institute) Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning April 2016 1 / 31

More information

Lecture Notes 1

Lecture Notes 1 4.45 Lecture Notes Guido Lorenzoni Fall 2009 A portfolio problem To set the stage, consider a simple nite horizon problem. A risk averse agent can invest in two assets: riskless asset (bond) pays gross

More information

Equilibrium Asset Returns

Equilibrium Asset Returns Equilibrium Asset Returns Equilibrium Asset Returns 1/ 38 Introduction We analyze the Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model (ICAPM) of Robert Merton (1973). The standard single-period CAPM holds when

More information

Microeconomics 3. Economics Programme, University of Copenhagen. Spring semester Lars Peter Østerdal. Week 17

Microeconomics 3. Economics Programme, University of Copenhagen. Spring semester Lars Peter Østerdal. Week 17 Microeconomics 3 Economics Programme, University of Copenhagen Spring semester 2006 Week 17 Lars Peter Østerdal 1 Today s programme General equilibrium over time and under uncertainty (slides from week

More information

Tries to understand the prices or values of claims to uncertain payments.

Tries to understand the prices or values of claims to uncertain payments. Asset pricing Tries to understand the prices or values of claims to uncertain payments. If stocks have an average real return of about 8%, then 2% may be due to interest rates and the remaining 6% is a

More information

Optimal Portfolio Composition for Sovereign Wealth Funds

Optimal Portfolio Composition for Sovereign Wealth Funds Optimal Portfolio Composition for Sovereign Wealth Funds Diaa Noureldin* (joint work with Khouzeima Moutanabbir) *Department of Economics The American University in Cairo Oil, Middle East, and the Global

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

Multiperiod Market Equilibrium

Multiperiod Market Equilibrium Multiperiod Market Equilibrium Multiperiod Market Equilibrium 1/ 27 Introduction The rst order conditions from an individual s multiperiod consumption and portfolio choice problem can be interpreted as

More information

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and investment is central to understanding the business

More information

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY Multi-Period Model The agent acts as a price-taker in asset markets and then chooses today s consumption and asset shares to maximise lifetime utility. This multi-period

More information

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics ISSN 974-40 (on line edition) ISSN 594-7645 (print edition) WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY

More information

The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge

The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge Stefano Eusepi y Marc Giannoni z Bruce Preston x February 15, 2014 JEL Classi cations: E32, D83, D84 Keywords: Optimal Monetary Policy, Expectations

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model T.Huw Edwards Dept of Economics, Loughborough University and CSGR Warwick UK Tel (44)01509-222718 Fax 01509-223910 T.H.Edwards@lboro.ac.uk

More information

Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing

Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing Georg Kaltenbrunner and Lars Lochstoer ;y First draft: May 2006 December, 2008 Abstract We examine how long-run consumption risk arises endogenously in a standard

More information

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )] Problem set 1 Answers: 1. (a) The first order conditions are with 1+ 1so 0 ( ) [ 0 ( +1 )] [( +1 )] ( +1 ) Consumption follows a random walk. This is approximately true in many nonlinear models. Now we

More information

E cient Minimum Wages

E cient Minimum Wages preliminary, please do not quote. E cient Minimum Wages Sang-Moon Hahm October 4, 204 Abstract Should the government raise minimum wages? Further, should the government consider imposing maximum wages?

More information

Chasing the Gap: Speed Limits and Optimal Monetary Policy

Chasing the Gap: Speed Limits and Optimal Monetary Policy Chasing the Gap: Speed Limits and Optimal Monetary Policy Matteo De Tina University of Bath Chris Martin University of Bath January 2014 Abstract Speed limit monetary policy rules incorporate a response

More information

EIEF, Graduate Program Theoretical Asset Pricing

EIEF, Graduate Program Theoretical Asset Pricing EIEF, Graduate Program Theoretical Asset Pricing Nicola Borri Fall 2012 1 Presentation 1.1 Course Description The topics and approaches combine macroeconomics and finance, with an emphasis on developing

More information

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports Alexandre Dmitriev University of New South Wales Ivan Roberts Reserve Bank of Australia and University of New South Wales February 2, 2011 Abstract Two-country,

More information

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies Geo rey Heal and Bengt Kristrom May 24, 2004 Abstract In a nite-horizon general equilibrium model national

More information

Faster solutions for Black zero lower bound term structure models

Faster solutions for Black zero lower bound term structure models Crawford School of Public Policy CAMA Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis Faster solutions for Black zero lower bound term structure models CAMA Working Paper 66/2013 September 2013 Leo Krippner

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing

Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing Georg Kaltenbrunner and Lars Lochstoer yz First draft: 31 May 2006. COMMENTS WELCOME! October 2, 2006 Abstract Whenever agents have access to a production technology

More information

1. Money in the utility function (start)

1. Money in the utility function (start) Monetary Policy, 8/2 206 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic money-in-the-utility function model b. Optimal behavior and steady-state

More information

Dividend Volatility and Asset Prices: A Loss Aversion/Narrow Framing Approach

Dividend Volatility and Asset Prices: A Loss Aversion/Narrow Framing Approach Dividend Volatility and Asset Prices: A Loss Aversion/Narrow Framing Approach Yan Li and Liyan Yang Abstract This paper documents that the aggregate dividend growth rate exhibits strong volatility clustering.

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios Alberto Bisin Corporate Finance: Lecture Notes Class 1: Valuation updated November 17th, 2002 1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios Consider an economy with two states of nature {s 1, s 2 } and with

More information

Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing

Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing Georg Kaltenbrunner and Lars Lochstoer y;z First draft: 31 May 2006 December 15, 2006 Abstract We show that a standard production economy model where consumers

More information

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring 2006 Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle 1 Overview This lecture derives the consumption-based capital asset pricing

More information

The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment

The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment The Long-Run Risks Model and Aggregate Asset Prices: An Empirical Assessment The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters.

More information

Adaptive Learning in In nite Horizon Decision Problems

Adaptive Learning in In nite Horizon Decision Problems Adaptive Learning in In nite Horizon Decision Problems Bruce Preston Columbia University September 22, 2005 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract Building on Marcet and Sargent (1989) and Preston (2005)

More information

Euler Equation Errors

Euler Equation Errors Euler Equation Errors Martin Lettau New York University, CEPR, NBER Sydney C. Ludvigson New York University and NBER PRELIMINARY Comments Welcome First draft: September 1, 2004 This draft: February 22,

More information

1 Unemployment Insurance

1 Unemployment Insurance 1 Unemployment Insurance 1.1 Introduction Unemployment Insurance (UI) is a federal program that is adminstered by the states in which taxes are used to pay for bene ts to workers laid o by rms. UI started

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks The historical data on financial asset returns show that one dollar invested in the Dow- Jones yields 6 times more than one dollar invested in U.S. Treasury bonds. The return

More information

Simple e ciency-wage model

Simple e ciency-wage model 18 Unemployment Why do we have involuntary unemployment? Why are wages higher than in the competitive market clearing level? Why is it so hard do adjust (nominal) wages down? Three answers: E ciency wages:

More information

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS. No 449. Pursuing the Wrong Options? Adjustment Costs and the Relationship between Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS. No 449. Pursuing the Wrong Options? Adjustment Costs and the Relationship between Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS No 449 Pursuing the Wrong Options? Adjustment Costs and the Relationship between Uncertainty and Capital Accumulation Stephen R. Bond, Måns Söderbom and Guiying Wu May 2010

More information

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13

Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle. E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 Asset Pricing and Equity Premium Puzzle 1 E. Young Lecture Notes Chapter 13 1 A Lucas Tree Model Consider a pure exchange, representative household economy. Suppose there exists an asset called a tree.

More information

The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility

The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility Harjoat S. Bhamra Sauder School of Business University of British Columbia Raman

More information

Predictability of Stock Market Returns

Predictability of Stock Market Returns Predictability of Stock Market Returns May 3, 23 Present Value Models and Forecasting Regressions for Stock market Returns Forecasting regressions for stock market returns can be interpreted in the framework

More information

Experience Research Advisor Present Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

Experience Research Advisor Present Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Kevin J. Lansing April 3, 2018 Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702 San Francisco CA 94120-7702, (415)-974-2393, email: kevin.j.lansing@sf.frb.org Education Ph.D. Economics,

More information

Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle

Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle Return Decomposition over the Business Cycle Tolga Cenesizoglu March 1, 2016 Cenesizoglu Return Decomposition & the Business Cycle March 1, 2016 1 / 54 Introduction Stock prices depend on investors expectations

More information

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1

Random Walk Expectations and the Forward. Discount Puzzle 1 Random Walk Expectations and the Forward Discount Puzzle 1 Philippe Bacchetta Eric van Wincoop January 10, 007 1 Prepared for the May 007 issue of the American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings.

More information

Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation

Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation 200 2 Ó Ó 4 4 Dec., 200 OR Transactions Vol.4 No.4 Influence of Real Interest Rate Volatilities on Long-term Asset Allocation Xie Yao Liang Zhi An 2 Abstract For one-period investors, fixed income securities

More information

Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing

Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Expository note for the course MakØk3 Blok 2, 200/20 January 7, 20 This note shows in

More information

Relations between Prices, Dividends and Returns. Present Value Relations (Ch7inCampbell et al.) Thesimplereturn:

Relations between Prices, Dividends and Returns. Present Value Relations (Ch7inCampbell et al.) Thesimplereturn: Present Value Relations (Ch7inCampbell et al.) Consider asset prices instead of returns. Predictability of stock returns at long horizons: There is weak evidence of predictability when the return history

More information

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Introducing nominal rigidities. Introducing nominal rigidities. Olivier Blanchard May 22 14.452. Spring 22. Topic 7. 14.452. Spring, 22 2 In the model we just saw, the price level (the price of goods in terms of money) behaved like an

More information

Essays on the Term Structure of Interest Rates and Long Run Variance of Stock Returns DISSERTATION. Ting Wu. Graduate Program in Economics

Essays on the Term Structure of Interest Rates and Long Run Variance of Stock Returns DISSERTATION. Ting Wu. Graduate Program in Economics Essays on the Term Structure of Interest Rates and Long Run Variance of Stock Returns DISSERTATION Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Doctor of Philosophy in the Graduate

More information

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM GMM Estimation 1 Introduction Modern macroeconomic models are typically based on the intertemporal optimization and rational expectations. The Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) is an econometric framework

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LONG-RUN RISKS MODEL AND AGGREGATE ASSET PRICES: AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT. Jason Beeler John Y.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LONG-RUN RISKS MODEL AND AGGREGATE ASSET PRICES: AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT. Jason Beeler John Y. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LONG-RUN RISKS MODEL AND AGGREGATE ASSET PRICES: AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT Jason Beeler John Y. Campbell Working Paper 14788 http://www.nber.org/papers/w14788 NATIONAL BUREAU

More information

Labor Force Participation Dynamics

Labor Force Participation Dynamics MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Labor Force Participation Dynamics Brendan Epstein University of Massachusetts, Lowell 10 August 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/88776/ MPRA Paper No.

More information

Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations

Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations J. Scott Davis y Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas February 202 Abstract This paper introduces a model where agents are unsure

More information

Expected Utility and Risk Aversion

Expected Utility and Risk Aversion Expected Utility and Risk Aversion Expected utility and risk aversion 1/ 58 Introduction Expected utility is the standard framework for modeling investor choices. The following topics will be covered:

More information

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus Summer 2009 examination EC202 Microeconomic Principles II 2008/2009 syllabus Instructions to candidates Time allowed: 3 hours. This paper contains nine questions in three sections. Answer question one

More information

Fuel-Switching Capability

Fuel-Switching Capability Fuel-Switching Capability Alain Bousquet and Norbert Ladoux y University of Toulouse, IDEI and CEA June 3, 2003 Abstract Taking into account the link between energy demand and equipment choice, leads to

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice 1/ 57 Introduction Assuming that asset prices follow di usion processes, we derive an individual s continuous

More information

Comprehensive Review Questions

Comprehensive Review Questions Comprehensive Review Questions Graduate Macro II, Spring 200 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims Disclaimer: These questions are intended to guide you in studying for nal exams, and, more importantly,

More information

Demographics Trends and Stock Market Returns

Demographics Trends and Stock Market Returns Demographics Trends and Stock Market Returns Carlo Favero July 2012 Favero, Xiamen University () Demographics & Stock Market July 2012 1 / 37 Outline Return Predictability and the dynamic dividend growth

More information

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7 Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7 1 Imperfect Credibility of Policy: Trade Reform 1.1 Model Assumptions Output is exogenous constant endowment (y), not useful for consumption, but can be exported

More information

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality . 1 Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality Lutz Hendricks Iowa State University, CESifo, CFS March 28, 2004. 1 Introduction 2 Wealth is highly concentrated in U.S. data: The richest 1% of households

More information

Using Executive Stock Options to Pay Top Management

Using Executive Stock Options to Pay Top Management Using Executive Stock Options to Pay Top Management Douglas W. Blackburn Fordham University Andrey D. Ukhov Indiana University 17 October 2007 Abstract Research on executive compensation has been unable

More information

A Continuous-Time Asset Pricing Model with Habits and Durability

A Continuous-Time Asset Pricing Model with Habits and Durability A Continuous-Time Asset Pricing Model with Habits and Durability John H. Cochrane June 14, 2012 Abstract I solve a continuous-time asset pricing economy with quadratic utility and complex temporal nonseparabilities.

More information

Is the US current account de cit sustainable? Disproving some fallacies about current accounts

Is the US current account de cit sustainable? Disproving some fallacies about current accounts Is the US current account de cit sustainable? Disproving some fallacies about current accounts Frederic Lambert International Macroeconomics - Prof. David Backus New York University December, 24 1 Introduction

More information

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption Toulouse School of Economics Notes written by Ernesto Pasten (epasten@cict.fr) Slightly re-edited by Frank Portier (fportier@cict.fr) M-TSE. Macro I. 200-20. Chapter 3: Consumption Macroeconomics I Chapter

More information