The consequences of an endogenous discounting depending on environmental quality

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The consequences of an endogenous discounting depending on environmental quality"

Transcription

1 The consequences of an endogenous discounting depending on environmental quality A A K Université de Grenoble 2, Commissariat général du Plan and EUREQua, Université de Paris 1 adayong@univ-paris1fr K S EUREQua, Université de Paris 1 schubert@univ-paris1fr May 2002 Abstract Our intention is to study, in the framework of a very simple optimal growth model, the consequences on the optimal paths followed by consumption and environmental quality of an endogenous discounting Consumption directly comes from the use of environmental services and so is a direct cause of environmental degradation The environmental renewable resource is valued both as a source of consumption and as an amenity For a sustainability concern, we introduce an endogenous discount rate depending on the stock of environmental resource, and compare the optimal growth paths with the ones obtained in the usual case of eogenous and constant discounting We show that endogenous discounting can change qualitatively the nature of the optimal growth path, and, more precisely, that there eists a case in which consumption and environmental quality optimally decrease towards zero under eogenous discounting while they converge towards a positive stationary state with endogenous discounting Keywords: Endogenous discounting, Sustainability, Environment JEL codes: O41,Q0,E6 1 Introduction Optimal growth models usually make the assumption of a constant and strictly positive utility social discount rate This usual practice has been long questioned, but is still widely used, maybe because of the lack of a convincing alternative (Heal (2001) The first doubt goes back to the well known Ramsey and Harrod s criticisms of a strictly positive social discount rate (Ramsey (1928), Harrod (1948)), and has led to the so-called undiscounted utilitarianism But Koopmans (1960) has stressed the drawbacks of this approach: it usually leads to unrealistically high optimal saving rates for the present and near generations, andsotoasacrifice of the present and of the near future instead of the sacrifice of the far future implied by a positive discount rate Nevertheless, the temptation of a zero rate of discount is still very present as far as environment is concerned (see, for a comprehensive view of discounting and the environment, the contributions gathered in the book edited by Portney and Weyant (1999)) The usual approach has then been challenged by authors arguing that the discount rate should neither be constant and positive nor zero, but should be decreasing in the course of Corresponding author Address: EUREQua,UMRn 8594 CNRS, Université Paris I, Maison des Sciences Économiques, bd de l Hôpital, Paris Cede 13, France 1

2 time They claim that empirical evidence support that Both Harvey (1994) and Heal (1998) propose formulas of declining discounting Papers in the spirit of Laibson (see Laibson (1996 and 1997), Cropper and Laibson (1999) among others) use hyperbolic discounting based upon considerations of individual psychology Li and Löfgren (2001) analyse the Brock (1973) growth and environment model with hyperbolic discounting But the choice of a utility discount rate in normative models is an ethical choice, as stressed by Heal (1998 and 2001) or Ayong Le Kama (2001), and it is less than obvious than a central planner should only reflect in this choice the representative consumer s psychology On what basis should then this ethical choice be made? Another strand of literature, disconnected from environmental concerns, studies the question of habit formation, and introduces a utility discount factor depending on past consumption levels (Epstein (1987), Obstfeld (1990)) Obstfeld (1990) gives a formal treatment of the simple optimal growth model with this utility discount factor, and concludes that most of the time this assumption does not qualitatively change the optimal growth paths, in comparison with the case of an eogenous constant discount rate We want here to etend Obstfeld s approach to a model where environment matters We consider two ways by which environmental quality could affect the social intertemporal welfare: the usual direct effect of the current level of environmental quality on instantaneous utility (amenity effect), and a less usual indirect effect of current and past levels of environmental quality on the utility discount factor This discount factor now depends on the path of environmental quality through time Utility is no more time-separable, social tastes are intertemporally dependant Therationalizationoftheethicalchoiceofanendogenousdiscountfactordependingon environmental quality could be a sustainable development motive Society could epress this way a form of intergenerational concern, consisting in deciding to discount the future at a rate all the lower than environmental quality is and has been low That could be a way of implementing sustainability concerns in optimal growth models We then try to elucidate the consequences of such an ethical choice These consequences are very hard to assess in comple growth models with capital accumulation We thus use here a simple framework where consumption directly comes from the use of environmental services, and so directly causes environmental degradation It is in some sense the worst possible case: there eist neither a technical progress enhancing the transformation of environmental services into consumption, nor substitution possibilities between environmental services and man-made capital There is no means of improving environmental quality ecept natural regeneration In such a framework, consumption and environmental quality necessarily evolve together in the long run: both increase, or both decrease, or both converge towards a stationary state We study the evolution of the economy and the environment with an eogenous and constant discount rate (section 2), and then with the endogenous discount factor (section 3) Our objective is to compare the growth paths implied by the two possible choices (eogenous or endogenous discount rate) We show that endogenous discounting can change qualitatively the nature of the optimal growth path, contrary to what Obstfeld (1990) suggests More precisely, there eists a case in which consumption and environmental quality optimally decrease towards zero under eogenous discounting (doomsday) while they converge towards a positive stationary state with endogenous discounting Section 4 gives a comparison of the eogenous and endogenous discounting cases in terms of instantaneous utilities Finally, we try in section 5 to clarify the different concepts of discount rates that are used in the litterature, and to compare them in the endogenous and the eogenous cases 2

3 2 The economy with a constant discount rate 21 The model We introduce an optimal growth model with a renewable resource This resource is valued both as a source of consumption and also as a stock of amenities One interpretation, between many others 1, would be forests, which contribute to welfare both as sources of timber and also as stocks, which provide many ecosystem services to society (carbon s sequestration, preservation of biodiversity, etc) For simplification, we will consider that the stock of renewable resource, S, corresponds to an inde of environmental quality which is depleted by consumption C, but regenerates itself at the constant rate m>0 Its dynamics is then described by: St= ms t C t (1) The objective of the central planner is to maimize the present value of life-time utility of the representative consumer over an infinite horizon The representative consumer derives felicity 2 u() not only from consumption, but also from environmental quality The future felicities are discounted at the constant rate ρ > 0 The social planner s program is the following: ma U (C, S) = + 0 e ρt u (C t,s t ) dt Ṡ t = ms t C t st C t 0,S t 0 S 0 given The felicity function u () is continuous, twice differentiable, and possesses the following properties 3 : u C > 0, u S > 0, u CC 0 We also suppose that the felicity function is concave with respect to its two arguments: u CC u SS (u CS ) 2 0 The current-value Hamiltonian associated to the problem (2) writes: H = u (C, S)+λ [ms C], where λ 0 is the costate variable associated to environmental quality The first order necessary conditions then give us: (2) λ = u C λ λ = ρ m u S = ρ m φ (C, S) C u C S, and the transversality condition writes: lim t e ρt λ t S t =0 (3a) (3b) (3c) φ (C, S) Su S Cu C is the ratio of the values of environmental quality and consumption, both evaluated at their marginal felicity φ () then reflects the relative preference for environment of the representative agent Logdifferentiation of equation (3a) leads to the following result: λ λ = η C CC C + η S CS S, 1 For a precise interpretation of the role of this resource, see Heal (1998) and Daily (1977) and for more on ecosystem services, see Heal (2000) 2 We follow the convention of Arrow and Kurz (1970) in referring to the subutility functions as felicities In contrast, the term utility always refers to the planner s intertemporal objective 3 u C and u S are the first partial derivatives of the function u () with respect to its arguments C and S u CC is likewise the second partial derivative, using obvious notation 3

4 where η CC = Cu CC / u C < 0 is the elasticity of the marginal felicity of consumption with respect to the level of consumption and η CS = Su CS / u C 0 is the elasticity of the same quantity with respect to the level of environmental quality Substituting this relationship into (3b) gives the following relationship: η CC 22 The balanced growth path (BGP) 221 Eistence of a BGP C C + η S CS S = ρ m φ (C, S) C S (4) Given the equation of motion of environmental quality (1), if the growth rate of environmental quality is constant along the optimal path then the ratio C/S is also constant, which indicates that C and S grow at the same rate Let g be this common rate We have C/S = m g Substituting g into (4) leads to the following: ρ (1 + φ (C, S))m g = η CC + η CS φ(c, S) Therefore, the feasibility of the BGP, that is the constancy of g requires: Assumption 1 (i) The elasticities of the marginal felicity of consumption with respect to consumption, η CC, and environmental quality, η CS, are constant and (ii) the relative preference for environment is constant, ie φ (C, S) =φ, (C, S) 4 These restrictions 5 give rise to felicity functions of the Cobb-Douglas form, such as: CS φ 1 1/σ u (C, S) = 1 1/σ, (5) where σ = 1/η CC is the intertemporal elasticity of substitution for consumption We suppose that σ < 1, whichissufficient to ensure the concavity of the felicity function and implies also that the marginal felicity of consumption decreases with the level of environmental quality: u CS < 0 Thus, this negative felicity function (u () 0) is imposed hereafter It is easy to show that, with the specification of the felicity function (5), the growth rate along the BGP is: g = σ m ρ, (6) 1+φ which may be positive or negative, depending on the parameters 6 We can also notice that the optimal growth rate is bounded from above (g σm = lim ρ 0 g) σm therefore reflects the highest growth rate that society can epect; it depends on the regenerative capacities of the resource Besides, as S is growing along the BGP at the rate g and λ at the rate ρ m φ(m g), the transversality condition (3c) is fulfilled if and only if (g m)(1 + φ) < 0 ie g<mgiven that we have assumed σ < 1, the upper bound of g is strictly lower than m: g σm <mthe transversality condition is always satisfied 4 Smulders and Gradus (1996) show that (ii) is a necessary condition for the eistence of a balanced growth path when the stock of environmental resource is a source of felicity 5 Despite the lack of generality that these restrictions imply, they allow us to study the effect of endogenous discounting in a framework where the benchmark the case with constant and eogenous discounting consists in abalancedgrowthpath 6 The growth rate of consumption and environmental quality along the BGP will be positive if the natural regeneration and the preference for environment are sufficiently high, and if the discount rate is low enough 4

5 222 Properties of the BGP Introducing the stationary variable = C S, we easily show, using the equation of motion of environmental quality (1) and equation (4), that the dynamic system characterizing the evolution of the economy and the environment reduces to a single equation in, which writes: ẋ =(1+φ)( ), (7) where >0 is the stationary ratio of consumption to environmental quality along the BGP By (1) and (6), we have: = m g =(1 σ)m + σρ 1+φ (8) Equation (7) is unstable The ratio then takes from the initial time its stationary value, and initial consumption is: C 0 = S 0 = (1 σ)m + σρ S 0 (9) 1+φ 3 The economy with an endogenous discount rate 31 The model We now introduce an economy where the central planner uses a discount factor based on the historical path of environmental quality In all other respects, the economy is the same as in the previous section The intertemporal discounted utility function, with variable discount rate, of a representative consumer is now given by: U (C, S) = + 0 e t u (C t,s t ) dt, (10) where the felicity function u () has the same properties as in the previous model The future felicities are discounted at time t at the cumulated discount rate t 0, whichisassumedto depend on the past and current levels of environmental quality, as described by the following equation: t = t 0 θ(s τ )dτ, (11) where θ(s t ) 0, S t, denotes the discount rate at time t We also require: Assumption 2 (i) θ (S) > 0, and θ (S) < 0 S >0 and (ii) 0 =0 Note that in the case of an endogenous discounting depending on the past and current levels of consumption, there is a considerable disagreement over whether the marginal discount rate should be positive or negative 7 However, our assumption of a discount rate increasing with environmental quality reflects the sustainability motive that underlies in our model endogenous discounting: concerned by intergenerational equity, the society chooses to discount at a rate all the smaller than environmental quality is low, because in this case environmental questions become pressing The idea, that must be confirmed, is that a lower discount rate should in this case help to prevent or to limit further deterioration of environmental quality 7 See Epstein (1987) and Obstfeld (1990) 5

6 Following Obstfeld (1990), we consider t as a second state variable that accounts for accumulated impatience 8 Differentiating (11) with respect to time yields: t = θ(s t ) (12) The central planner s program is therefore to maimize (10) subjects to (1) and (12) together with the initial conditions (S 0 and 0 given) and non-negativity constraints (C t 0,S t 0) As in Palivos, Wang and Zhang (1997), we further impose the following assumption: Assumption 3 u (C, S)/θ(S) Qe β (S) C, S > 0, where <Q<0 and β < 1 This assumption ensures that the intertemporal utility function U () in (10), because u () is taken to be negative, is bounded from below and hence the optimization problem is well-defined 9 See Palivos, Wang and Zhang (1997) for a proof The constant-value Hamiltonian associated to the central planner s problem writes: H C, S,, λ, µ = u (C, S) e + λ [ms C] µθ(s), where λ 0 is the costate variable associated to environmental quality, and µ is the costate variable associated to the stock of accumulated impatience (Obstfeld (1990)) Given assumption 1 and applying the Pontryagin s maimum principle, the first-order necessary optimality conditions are: u C = λ λ λ = θ(s) m φc S + µ λ θ (S) µ u(c, S) = θ(s) µ µ (13a) (13b) (13c) where λ = λe and µ = µe (thus λ θ(s)λ = λ e ), together with (1) and (12) and the transversality condition 10 : lim H (t) =0 (14d) t First, note that, as Obstfeld (1990) pointed out, when µ converges to a definite long term value, as it will be the case below (given assumption 3), the third equation (13c) of this system can be integrated into: µ t = u(c s,s s )e s t θ(sτ )dτ ds = e t e s u(c s,s s )ds (14) t which means that µ t corresponds to the discounted present value of the future flow of felicities from the standpoint of time t Given that we have assumed a negative felicity function, we also have µ t 0 Net, we reduce the system (13a)-(14d) into a more tractable one Following Palivos et al (1997), recall that, along the optimal path, dh/ dt = H/ t Since the central planner s 8 Due to the non constant discount rate, Pontryagin s maimum principle cannot be applied directly We need this state variable to solve the problem within the standard optimal control approach 9 For the optimization problem to be completely well-defined, that is for the problem to satisfy the entire conditions for monotonicity and concavity in Epstein (1987), we suppose also that the current value Hamiltonian (specified below) is jointly strictly concave in C and S 10 On the transversality conditions in infinite horizon problems, see Michel (1982) t 6

7 program considered here is autonomous, H/ t =0, thus the Hamiltonian is independent of time along the optimal path This and the transversality condition (14d) imply that: H (t) =0 t along the optimal path We therefore can deduce: The system (13a)-(13b) then writes: 32 The optimal paths µ = 1 [u (C, S)+λ (ms C)] (15) θ(s) λ = u C (16a) λ λ = θ(s) m φc S + θ (S) u (C, S) (C ms)u C (16b) θ(s) u C Given the felicity function in (5) and assumption 1, the differentiation of the first-order condition (16a) with respect to time gives: λ λ = 1 C σ C + φ(1 1 σ )Ṡ S, and so, substituting the dynamics of the environmental quality (1) and the first-order condition (16b) into this equation, we show that the dynamics of consumption along the optimal path is: C C = φc S 1 C σθ(s)+(σ φ(1 σ)) m + σε(s) 1 σ S m, (17) where ε(s) = Sθ (S) θ(s) is the elasticity of utility discount rate θ () with respect to environmental quality ε(s) is positive under assumption 2 Now, if we reintroduce the stationary variable = C/S, the dynamic system characterizing the evolution of this endogenous discounted economy is then given by the motion of the ratio of consumption to environmental quality along the optimal path: = 1+φ + σ 1 σ ε(s) [ (1 σ)m] σθ(s), (18) together with the one of environmental quality (1) 321 The asymptotically balanced growth path Eistence of an asymptotically BGP Following Palivos et al (1997), let us first try to find an asymptotically balanced growth solution of the system (1), (18) Palivos et al (1997) show that necessary and sufficient conditions for the eistence of an asymptotically BGP solution of this type of problems is an asymptotically constant discount rate and an asymptotically constant elasticity of marginal felicity The second condition is by assumption fulfilled here Let us then assume that the utility discount rate is bounded from above: Assumption 4 (i) lim S θ(s) =θ is finite, and (ii) lim S 0 θ(s) =θ 0 7

8 The first part of this assumption seams reasonable: it means that when environmental quality becomes very high the discount rate remains bounded θ can be interpreted as the utility discount rate that the central planner would choose if economic activity did not harm environmental quality, which could remain always high The second part of this assumption just introduces the notation used for the lower bound of the utility discount rate, eventually equal to zero With this assumption, we obtain the following Proposition 1 :Underassumptions1-4,ifθ <m(1 + φ) (ie if the upper bound of the utility discount rate is low enough vis-à-vis the preference for environment and the natural regeneration rate), there eists an asymptotically balanced growth path characterized by: g = σ m 1+φ θ =(1 σ)m + σθ 1+φ (19) Proof Let us suppose that there eists a constant and positive growth rate g such that Ṡ lim t S = lim t Ċ C = g Because g>0, wehavelim t S =+ and assumption 4 can be used Moreover, Palivos et al (1997) show (Lemma 1) that under assumption 4 we have lim S Sθ (S) =0, ie lim S ε(s) =0 The long term of the system (1), (18) is then given by: g = m 0=(1+φ)( (1 σ)m) σθ, from which we deduce (19) By construction, this solution is valid if and only if g>0, ie θ <m(1 + φ), ie if and only if the maimal utility discount rate is sufficiently low vis-à-vis the preference for environment and the natural regeneration rate We may notice that the asymptotic growth rate g is eactly the same than the balanced growth rate g of the problem with eogenous discounting, provided that θ = ρ (see equation (6)) Then if the upper bound of the utility discount rate is eactly the rate that would be choosen by the central planner in case of eogenous discounting, the endogenous discounting economy follows in the long run the same path that the eogenous one, provided that this rate is low enough Convergence towards the asymptotically BGP The system (1), (18) is a dynamic system involving two variables: the environmental quality S, which grows asymptotically at a constant rate, and the ratio of consumption to environmental quality which is stationary in the long run Moreover, the second equation makes the growth rate of depend on the level of S, and so S cannot be easily eliminated to obtain a system involving two variables stationary in the long run Nevertheless, we obtain the following results Proposition 2 : Under assumption 1-4, if the upper bound of the utility discount rate is low enough (ie if θ <m(1 + φ)), then along the transition towards the asymptotically BGP: (i) is lower than its long run value, ie t < t; (ii) the growth rate of environmental quality is higher than its long run value, ie Ṡ t /S t > g t Proof It is easy to show that equation (18) can be written as: = 1+φ + σ 1 σ ε(s) ( )+σ θ θ(s) σ 2 θε(s) + (1 σ)(1+φ) 8

9 This equation shows that if, then ẋ/ > 0: diverges, which is impossible We therefore deduce that < t (this shows the first part of the proposition) We then have Ṡ/S = m = g + >g Propositions 1 and 2 indicate that endogenous discounting associated with an upper bound of the utility discount rate relatively low leads to an asymptotic growth path identical to the growth path of the eogenous discounting case (provided that the upper bound in the endogenous case is equal to the eogenous rate), but that in the short run environmental quality grows faster at the epense of a lower consumption Society is less impatient to consume, as long as environmental quality is not high enough See figure 1 m = eogenous disc endogenous disc ẋ =0 Ṡ =0 S Figure 1: The (asymptotically) balanced growth paths Case θ = ρ <m(1 + φ) ie <m 322 The stationary state Eistence of a stationary state Let us now suppose that the condition on parameters for a positive g is not fulfilled, ie θ m(1 + φ) (the upper bound of the utility discount rate is relatively high) In this case, an asymptotically balanced growth path does not eist, and we then look at the eistence of a stationary state of the dynamic system (1), (18) A stationary solution (,S ) of this dynamic system is characterized by ẋ=ṡ =0 Thus, equation (1) implies = m Substituting this into (18), we easily show that there will eist stationary solutions if values S eist such that: θ(s) =m 1+φ + σ 1 σ ε(s) (20) Assumption 5 Sθ (S) θ (S) 1 ε(s), S This assumption demands that the elasticity of marginal discounting, θ (S), is sensitive enough with respect to changes in the level of environmental quality Proposition 3 : Under assumptions 1-5, for high enough values of the upper bound of the utility discount rate (ie θ m(1 + φ)), there eists a unique stationary equilibrium (,S ) 9

10 characterized by: = m θ(s )=m 1+φ + σ 1 σ ε(s ) if and only if m 1+φ + σ 1 σ ε(0) > θ ie if and only if θ is low enough 11 Proof Let us consider the function f (S) =m 1+φ + σ 1 σ ε(s) > 0 which corresponds to the RHS of (20) A solution S of (20) will be such that θ(s )=f(s ) We know, by assumptions 2, 4 and 6, that θ(s) is strictly increasing from its lower bound θ (eventually equal to zero) to its upper bound θ Now, it easy to show that the first derivative of f () with respect to S is f (S) =m σ 1 σ ε(s) S 1 ε(s)+ Sθ (S) θ (S) f (S) is positive and decreases monotically for S =0to + from f(0) = m (21) Thus, under assumptions 2 and 5 above, f (S) < 0, and 1+φ + σ 1 σ ε(0) to m(1 + φ) There eists therefore a unique point S so that θ(s )=f (S ) provided that f(0) > θ Convergence towards the stationary state Proposition 4 : Under assumptions 1-5, the unique stationary equilibrium (,S ) is a saddlepoint Proof We can show that the Jacobian matri of the dynamic system is: 0 S J = σm σ 1 σ mε (S ) θ (S ) θ(s ) We then have the following determinant: σ det J = σms 1 σ mε (S ) θ (S ), with ε (S )= ε(s ) S 1 ε(s )+ S θ (S ) θ (S ) 0 by assumptions 2 and 5 So det J<0 Furthermore,wehavetrJ = θ(s ) > 0 Propositions 3 and 4 state that endogenous discounting associated with a high upper bound of the utility discount rate and a small lower bound of this rate leads to the convergence of the economy towards a locally stable stationary state (assumption 5 is also needed), while in the eogenous discounting case with a discount rate equal to the upper bound the economy follows a path where consumption and environmental quality continuously decrease towards zero This result means that endogenous discounting with a utility discount rate becoming sufficienty high when environmental quality is high and sufficiently low when environment is very depleted prevents any solution of collapse of environmental quality, as it would be the case with eogenous discounting See figure 2, where the ẋ =0curve is growing under assumption 5, and admits as an asymptot On figure 2 is depicted the case S 0 >S Then, in the eogenous discounting case, S decreases towards 0 while remains constant at, while in the endogenous dicounting case S and decrease, respectively towards S and Notice that when S 0 <S, the growth path does not change in the eogenous discounting case, while and S now grow towards their stationary values in the endogenous discounting case 11 If θ =0, this condition is always fulfilled 10

11 = m eogenous discounting endogenous discounting ẋ =0 Ṡ =0 S S Figure 2: The optimal paths Case θ = ρ m(1 + φ) ie m and θ <f(0) ie <m 323 The asymptotical depletion of environmental quality Eistence We now consider the last feasible case This case involves a high upper bound of the utility discount rate (ie θ m(1 + φ)), as in the previous case, but also a high lower bound, such that f(0) < θ and a stationary state no longer eists Proposition 5 : Under assumptions 1 5, if θ >m 1+φ + 1 σ σ ε(0) (ie if the lower bound of the utility discount rate is high enough vis-à-vis the preference for environment and the natural regeneration rate), an symptotical depletion of environmental quality occurs, with: g = σ m < 0 =(1 σ)m + θ 1+φ+ σ 1 σ ε(0) σθ (22) 1+φ+ σ ε(0) 1 σ Proof When environmental quality decreases towards 0, the long term of the system (1), (18) is given by: g = m 0=(1+φ + 1 σ σ ε(0))( (1 σ)m) σθ, from which we deduce (22) By construction, this solution is valid if and only if g < 0, ie θ >m 1+φ + 1 σ σ ε(0) = f(0) Convergence Proposition 6 : Under assumptions 1 5, if θ >m 1+φ + 1 σ, σ ε(0) then along the transition towards the asymptotical depletion of environmental quality: (i) is higher than its long run value, ie t > t; (ii) the growth rate of environmental quality is lower than its long run value, ie Ṡ t /S t <g t Proof It is easy to show that equation (18) can be written as: = 1+φ + σ 1 σ ε(s) σ 2 θ (ε(s) ε(0)) ( )+σ (θ θ(s)) + (1 σ) 1+φ + 1 σ σ ε(0) 11

12 This equation shows that if, then ẋ/ < 0: diverges, which is impossible We therefore deduce that > t (this shows the first part of the proposition) We then have Ṡ/S = m = g + <g Propositions 5 and 6 indicate that endogenous discounting associated with an upper bound of the utility discount rate relatively high and a lower bound also relatively high leads to an optimal depletion of environmental quality, as in the eogenous discounting case (provided that the upper bound in the endogenous case is equal to the eogenous rate), and that in the short run environmental quality decreases faster, which allows to consume more See figure 3 eogenous discounting = ẋ =0 endogenous discounting m Ṡ =0 Figure 3: The (asymptotically) balanced growth paths Case θ = ρ m(1 + φ) ie m and θ f(0) ie m S 4 A comparison of the two cases We can now try to compare the optimal paths involved by the choice of an eogenous or an endogenous discounting, in the specific framework we have used in this paper To make this comparison possible, that is to say to have a common reference for the two cases, we have made the assumption that the utility discount rate that would be choosen by the central planner in the constant and eogenous case is also the upper bound of the variable endogenous rate We then see that in some cases the asymptotic behaviour of the endogenous discounting economy is the same that the one of the eogenous one, but that there eists a situation in which it is fundamentally different Namely, endogenous discounting associated with a high upper bound of the utility discount rate and a small lower bound of this rate leads to the convergence of the economy towards a stationary state, while in the eogenous discounting case the economy follows a path where consumption and environmental quality continuously decrease towards zero: economy and environment stabilize in the first case while they optimally collapse in the second one This situation occurs when the upper bound of the utility discount rate is high enough and the lower one small enough, this latter characteristic of the endogenous discount function being the important one: the discount rate must become very small when environmental quality is very low for this situation to happen Figure 4 shows the evolution of felicity over time In the eogenous discounting case, for an initial value of the stock of environment S 0, felicity is at the beginning of the trajectory equal to u(s 0,S 0 ) and then decreases at a rate equal to (1 + φ) 1 σ σ g as S decreases at a rate equal to g < 0 In the endogenous discounting case, felicity is at the beginning of the trajectory equal to u( 0 S 0,S 0 ) andthenconvergestou(ms,s ) Figure 4 shows the case where 12

13 S 0 >S : environmental quality is better in the short term that it will be in the stationary state Then 0 <m< (see figure 2) and u( 0 S 0,S 0 ) <u(ms,s ) Felicity is non-decreasing over time, and the growth path is sustainable in this sense, contrary to the optimal path of the eogenous discounting case Endogenous discounting allows, under mild assumptions, to obtain a sustainable growth u(c t,s t ) u( S 0,S 0 ) u(ms,s ) t u( 0 S 0,S 0 ) endogenous discounting eogenous discounting Figure4:Evolutionoffelicityovertimeinthecasesofeogenousandendogenousdiscounting Case θ = ρ m(1 + φ), θ <f(0) and S 0 <S 5 Discount rates: a clarification of the concepts We now try to clarify the different concepts of discount rates that are used in the litterature, and to compare them in the eogenous and the endogenous cases 12 We can find for eample in Dasgupta (2000) the following definition: Let a numeraire be chosen for the accounting price system At any given date, the social rate of discount is the percentage rate at which the accounting price of the numeraire declines Formally, let R t be the quantity of the numeraire to be delivered at time t along the optimal programme Assuming continuous time and a differentiable accounting price, R 1 dr t t dt is the social rate of discount at t We must specify what eactly is the accounting price of the numeraire It is defined as the value of an increment of the numeraire at some date t in terms of its contribution to the objective function, along the optimal path (see for eample Heal (2001)) Let us first take felicity as the numeraire Then the quantity of numeraire you have to pay today for a unit of numeraire at time t is simply R t = e ρt in the eogenous case, and R t = e t in the endogenous one We have called in what precedes this quantity the utility discount factor We have also called the corresponding discount rate the utility discount rate Wecouldhave called it, following several authors, the pure rate of time preference Itisequaltoρ in the eogenous case, and t = θ(s t ) in the endogenous one It is a measure of the impatience of society This impatience is constant in the eogenous case, variable in the endogenous one, where it is low when environmental quality is low, and vice versa The ethical choice of society lies in this characterization of its impatience 12 This presentation is slightly different from the one of Epstein (1987) 13

14 But felicity is not generally chosen as numeraire It is consumption that usually plays this part We then define the consumption discount rate Ψ C t astherateatwhichtheaccounting price of consumption declines This price is simply the present value of the marginal utility of consumption at t, ie R t = e ρt u C (C t,s t ) in the eogenous case, and R t = e t u C (C t,s t ) in the endogenous one We then have: Ct Ṡt ρ η CC C t η CS S t Ψ C t = 1 R t dr t dt = θ(s t ) η CC Ct C t η CS Ṡt S t in the eogenous case in the endogenous case, (23) with η CC = Cu CC / u C and η CS = Su CS / u C the elasticities of the marginal utility of consumption previously defined The consumption discount rate then depends on the pure rate of time preference and on the growth rates of consumption and environmental quality As the elasticity η CC is negative, a positive growth rate of consumption makes the consumption discount rate higher than the pure rate of time preference It is the so-called wealth effect Besides this wealth effect appears an effect of the growth rate of environmental quality For intertemporal cost-benefit analysis the consumption discount rate is not sufficient We must also describe the evolution of the system of relative prices, which reduces here to the accounting price of environmental quality relative to consumption This relative price is the ratio of the value of an increment of environmental quality at some date t in terms of its contribution to the objective function to the value of an increment of consumption in terms of its contribution to the objective function We have just seen that for consumption this value is simply e ρt u C (C t,s t ) in the eogenous case, and e t u C (C t,s t ) in the endogenous one As far as environmental quality is concerned, this value is equivalently e ρt u S (C t,s t ) in the eogenous case, and the relative price is then simply p t = u S(C t,s t) u C (C t,s t) Things are less simple in the endogenous case Then the preference structure, as specified in (10), is recursive in the sense that is allowed to depend on the past and current levels of environmental quality, as described by equation (11) Thus, a change in the present level of environmental quality will not only have an effect on the current level of felicity, but also on the entire future felicity stream The contribution to the objective function must be measured by the increase in the lifetime utility function at time t caused by an increment of environmental quality at and near its starting point (see Obstfeld (1990)) This is a generalization of the notion of marginal utility at time t, correspondingtothevolterra derivative 13 Using the Volterra derivative, it can be shown 14 that the marginal utility of environmental quality at time t is e t u S (C t,s t ) µ t θ (S t ), with µ definedin(14) Giventhepropertiesofthefelicity function (u () 0, thus µ 0 and u C > 0, u S > 0) and assumption 2, this marginal utility is positive The relative price is then p t = u S(C t,s t) µ t θ (S t) u c(c t,s t) Everything being equal, it is higher than in the eogenous case For the specifications used here, we can sum up the previous results along the optimal paths: eogenous case endogenous case pure rate of time preference ρ θ(s t ) consumption discount rate Ψ C t ρ + 1+φ(1 σ) σ g θ(s t )+ σ 1 ẋt t + 1+φ(1 σ) Ṡ t σ S t relative price of environment p t φ φ t ε(s t ) m 1 1 σ t In the eogenous case, the pure rate of time preference, the consumption discount rate and the relative price of environment are constant along the optimal path, while neither of them are constant in the endogenous case, ecept of course in the long run, where they are equal to the 13 For more on the application of this concept see Ryder and Heal (1973), Epstein (1987) and Obstfeld (1990) 14 For the details of calculus see Pittel (2000) 14

15 corresponding values of the eogenous case, with θ = ρ If society makes the ethical choice of endogenous discounting, these results can provide a guideline for cost-benefit analysis, as they allow to calculate variable rates of discount and relative price of environment References Arrow, K & Kurz, M, 1970, Public Investment, the Rate of Return and Optimal Fiscal Policy, JohnsHopkinsPress Ayong Le Kama, A, 2001, Sustainable Growth, Renewable Resources and Pollution, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 25(12), Brock, W, 1973, A Polluted Golden Age, in Economics of Natural and Environmental Resources,VLSmith,chapter25 Cropper, M & Laibson, D, 1999, The implications of Hyperbolic Discounting for Project Evaluation, in P Portney & J Weyant, eds, Discounting and Intergenerational Equity, Resources for the Future, chapter 16, pp Daily, G, 1977, Nature s Services: Societal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems, Island Press, Washington DC Epstein, L, 1987, A Simple Dynamic General Equilibrium Model, Journal of Economic Theory 41, Harvey, C, 1994, The Reasonableness of Non-Constant Discounting, Journal of Public Economics 53, Heal, G, 1998, Valuing the Future: Economic Theory and Sustainability, Columbia University Press Heal, G, 2000, Nature and the Marketplace: Capturing the Value of the Ecosystem Services, Island Press, Washington DC Heal, G, 2001, Intertemporal Welfare Economics and the Environment, mimeo, University of Columbia Koopmans, T, 1960, Stationary Ordinal Utility and Impatience, Econometrica 28, Laibson, D, 1996, Hyperbolic Discount Functions, Undersaving and Saving Policy, NBER Working Paper Laibson, D, 1997, Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting, Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, Li, C-Z & Lofgren, K-G, 2001, Economic Growth, Environmental Quality and Hyperbolic Discounting, mimeo Michel, P, 1982, On the Transversality Conditions in Infinite Horizon Problems, Econometrica 50(4), Obstfeld, M, 1990, Intertemporal Dependence, Impatience, and Dynamics, Journal of Monetary Economics 26,

16 Palivos, T, Wang, P & Zhang, J, 1997, On the Eistence of Balanced Growth Equilibrium, International Economic Review 38(1), Pittel, K, 2000, Sustainable Growth and Endogenous Discount Rates, mimeo, Chemnitz University of Technology Portney, P R & Weyant, J P, 1999, Discounting and Intergenerational Equity, Resources for the Future Ramsey, F P, 1928, A Mathemathical Theory of Saving, Economic Journal 138, Ryder, H & Heal, G, 1973, Optimal Growth with Intertemporally Dependent Preferences, Review of Economic Studies 40, 1 31 Smulders, S & Gradus, R, 1996, Pollution Abatement and Long-term Growth, European Journal of Political Economy 12,

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomics, 2016 Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model The representative household model is a dynamic general equilibrium model, based on the assumption that the

More information

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 3 : The Ramsey Growth Model

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 3 : The Ramsey Growth Model 2012-2013 Master 2 Macro I Lecture 3 : The Ramsey Growth Model Franck Portier (based on Gilles Saint-Paul lecture notes) franck.portier@tse-fr.eu Toulouse School of Economics Version 1.1 07/10/2012 Changes

More information

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Problem Set 2: Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Exercise 2.1: An infinite horizon problem with perfect foresight In this exercise we will study at a discrete-time version of Ramsey

More information

Documento de Trabajo. ISSN (edición impresa) ISSN (edición electrónica)

Documento de Trabajo. ISSN (edición impresa) ISSN (edición electrónica) Nº 227 Octubre 2002 Documento de Trabajo ISSN (edición impresa) 0716-7334 ISSN (edición electrónica) 0717-7593 The Effect of a Constant or a Declining Discount Rate on Optimal Investment Timing. Gonzalo

More information

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics Chapter 11 AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics The simplest model featuring fully-endogenous exponential per capita growth is what is known as the AK model. Jones

More information

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Chapter 11 AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. In his Chapter 11 Acemoglu discusses simple fully-endogenous growth models in the form of Ramsey-style AK and reduced-form AK models, respectively.

More information

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation Fujisaki Seiya and Mino Kazuo Institute of Economic Research, Kyoto University 20. October 2010

More information

Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium. Abstract

Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium. Abstract Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium Seiya Fujisaki Graduate School of Economics Kazuo Mino Graduate School of Economics Abstract This paper re-examines equilibrium determinacy

More information

1 The Solow Growth Model

1 The Solow Growth Model 1 The Solow Growth Model The Solow growth model is constructed around 3 building blocks: 1. The aggregate production function: = ( ()) which it is assumed to satisfy a series of technical conditions: (a)

More information

A Note on the Relation between Risk Aversion, Intertemporal Substitution and Timing of the Resolution of Uncertainty

A Note on the Relation between Risk Aversion, Intertemporal Substitution and Timing of the Resolution of Uncertainty ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 2, 251 256 (2006) A Note on the Relation between Risk Aversion, Intertemporal Substitution and Timing of the Resolution of Uncertainty Johanna Etner GAINS, Université du

More information

Lecture 3 Growth Model with Endogenous Savings: Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Lecture 3 Growth Model with Endogenous Savings: Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model Lecture 3 Growth Model with Endogenous Savings: Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model Rahul Giri Contact Address: Centro de Investigacion Economica, Instituto Tecnologico Autonomo de Mexico (ITAM). E-mail: rahul.giri@itam.mx

More information

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies Geo rey Heal and Bengt Kristrom May 24, 2004 Abstract In a nite-horizon general equilibrium model national

More information

Assets with possibly negative dividends

Assets with possibly negative dividends Assets with possibly negative dividends (Preliminary and incomplete. Comments welcome.) Ngoc-Sang PHAM Montpellier Business School March 12, 2017 Abstract The paper introduces assets whose dividends can

More information

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far.

More information

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 The Ramsey Model Lectures 11 to 14 Topics in Macroeconomics November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 Lecture 11, 12, 13 & 14 1/50 Topics in Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model: Introduction 2 Main Ingredients Neoclassical

More information

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model 1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model We look at a standard neoclassical growth model. The representative consumer maximizes U = β t u(c t ) (1) t=0 where c t is consumption in period

More information

Growth Effects of the Allocation of Government Expenditure in an Endogenous Growth Model with Physical and Human Capital

Growth Effects of the Allocation of Government Expenditure in an Endogenous Growth Model with Physical and Human Capital Growth Effects of the Allocation of Government Expenditure in an Endogenous Growth Model with Physical and Human Capital Christine Achieng Awiti The growth effects of government expenditure is a topic

More information

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy George Alogoskoufis* Athens University of Economics and Business September 2012 Abstract This paper examines

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Online Appendix Optimal Time-Consistent Government Debt Maturity D. Debortoli, R. Nunes, P. Yared. A. Proofs

Online Appendix Optimal Time-Consistent Government Debt Maturity D. Debortoli, R. Nunes, P. Yared. A. Proofs Online Appendi Optimal Time-Consistent Government Debt Maturity D. Debortoli, R. Nunes, P. Yared A. Proofs Proof of Proposition 1 The necessity of these conditions is proved in the tet. To prove sufficiency,

More information

Measuring Sustainability in the UN System of Environmental-Economic Accounting

Measuring Sustainability in the UN System of Environmental-Economic Accounting Measuring Sustainability in the UN System of Environmental-Economic Accounting Kirk Hamilton April 2014 Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment Working Paper No. 154 The Grantham

More information

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form Saddle Path Halvor Mehlum Abstract Following up a 50 year old suggestion due to Solow, I show that by including a Ramsey consumer in the Harrod-Domar

More information

Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing

Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing Richard M. H. Suen University of Leicester 29 March 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/86499/ MPRA Paper

More information

A Re-examination of Economic Growth, Tax Policy, and Distributive Politics

A Re-examination of Economic Growth, Tax Policy, and Distributive Politics A Re-examination of Economic Growth, Tax Policy, and Distributive Politics Yong Bao University of California, Riverside Jang-Ting Guo University of California, Riverside October 8, 2002 We would like to

More information

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth In the models we have presented so far there is no role for money. Yet money performs very important

More information

Markets Do Not Select For a Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk

Markets Do Not Select For a Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk Markets Do Not Select For a Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk Thorsten Hens a Klaus Reiner Schenk-Hoppé b October 4, 003 Abstract Tobin 958 has argued that in the face of potential capital

More information

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics June. - 2011 Trade, Development and Growth For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option Instructions

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics Tutorial #2: Solutions

Advanced Macroeconomics Tutorial #2: Solutions ECON40002 Chris Edmond dvanced Macroeconomics Tutorial #2: Solutions. Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model. Suppose the planner seeks to maximize the intertemporal utility function t u C t, 0 < < subject to the

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

The Representative Household Model

The Representative Household Model Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model The representative household class of models is a family of dynamic general equilibrium models, based on the assumption that the dynamic path of aggregate consumption

More information

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis Answer each question in three or four sentences and perhaps one equation or graph. Remember that the explanation determines the grade. 1. Question

More information

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence A The infinite horizon model This section defines the equilibrium of the infinity horizon model described in Section III of the paper and characterizes

More information

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Journal of Economic Integration 20(4), December 2005; 631-643 Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Noritsugu Nakanishi Kobe University Toru Kikuchi Kobe University

More information

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014 I. The Solow model Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis Universidad Autónoma de Madrid Autumn 2014 Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) I. The Solow model Autumn 2014 1 / 33 Objectives In this first lecture

More information

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model George Alogoskoufis* Athens University of Economics and Business October 2012 Abstract This paper compares the predictions of

More information

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE Macroeconomic Dynamics, (9), 55 55. Printed in the United States of America. doi:.7/s6559895 ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE KEVIN X.D. HUANG Vanderbilt

More information

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth In this chapter we introduce the government into the exogenous growth models we have analyzed so far. We first introduce and discuss the intertemporal budget

More information

Macroeconomics and finance

Macroeconomics and finance Macroeconomics and finance 1 1. Temporary equilibrium and the price level [Lectures 11 and 12] 2. Overlapping generations and learning [Lectures 13 and 14] 2.1 The overlapping generations model 2.2 Expectations

More information

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

1 Two Period Exchange Economy University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 502) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout # 2 1 Two Period Exchange Economy We shall start our exploration of dynamic economies with

More information

Online Appendix: Extensions

Online Appendix: Extensions B Online Appendix: Extensions In this online appendix we demonstrate that many important variations of the exact cost-basis LUL framework remain tractable. In particular, dual problem instances corresponding

More information

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130 Notes on Macroeconomic Theory Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130 September 2006 Chapter 2 Growth With Overlapping Generations This chapter will serve

More information

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Spring Trade and Development. Instructions

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Spring Trade and Development. Instructions WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION Department of Applied Economics Spring - 2005 Trade and Development Instructions (For students electing Macro (8701) & New Trade Theory (8702) option) Identify yourself

More information

Economic Growth: Lectures 2 and 3 The Solow Growth Model

Economic Growth: Lectures 2 and 3 The Solow Growth Model 14.452 Economic Growth: Lectures 2 and 3 The Solow Growth Model Daron Acemoglu MIT November 1 and 3. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lectures 2-3 November 1 and 3. 1 / 87 Solow Growth Model Solow

More information

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES 1. REVIEW: SMALL TAXES SMALL DEADWEIGHT LOSS Static analysis suggests that deadweight loss from taxation at rate τ is 0(τ 2 ) that is, that for small tax rates the

More information

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization Notes on Intertemporal Optimization Econ 204A - Henning Bohn * Most of modern macroeconomics involves models of agents that optimize over time. he basic ideas and tools are the same as in microeconomics,

More information

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation I. Introduction Thus far, we have considered time-separable lifetime utility specifications such as E t Z T t U[C(s), s]

More information

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014 I. The Solow model Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis Universidad Autónoma de Madrid Autumn 2014 Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) I. The Solow model Autumn 2014 1 / 38 Objectives In this first lecture

More information

Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development. H. Uzawa. Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan. (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting)

Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development. H. Uzawa. Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan. (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting) Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development H. Uzawa Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting) In this paper, we prove in terms of the prototype model of

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 Instructions: Read the questions carefully and make sure to show your work. You

More information

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Robert J. Barro 1990 Represented by m.sefidgaran & m.m.banasaz Graduate School of Management and Economics Sharif university of Technology 11/17/2013

More information

Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8

Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8 Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8 1 Cagan Model of Money Demand 1.1 Money Demand Demand for real money balances ( M P ) depends negatively on expected inflation In logs m d t p t =

More information

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013 Comprehensive Exam August 19, 2013 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question. Good luck! 1 1 Menu

More information

Nonlinear Tax Structures and Endogenous Growth

Nonlinear Tax Structures and Endogenous Growth Nonlinear Tax Structures and Endogenous Growth JEL Category: O4, H2 Keywords: Endogenous Growth, Transitional Dynamics, Tax Structure November, 999 Steven Yamarik Department of Economics, The University

More information

Economic Growth: Lectures 1 (second half), 2 and 3 The Solow Growth Model

Economic Growth: Lectures 1 (second half), 2 and 3 The Solow Growth Model 14.452 Economic Growth: Lectures 1 (second half), 2 and 3 The Solow Growth Model Daron Acemoglu MIT Oct. 31, Nov. 5 and 7, 2013. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lectures 1-3 Oct. 31, Nov. 5 and 7,

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS

RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS 1 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS Lars Peter Hansen Bendheim Lectures, Princeton University 2 / 32 RECURSIVE VALUATION AND SENTIMENTS ABSTRACT Expectations and uncertainty about growth rates that

More information

Essays on weakly sustainable local development in Indonesia

Essays on weakly sustainable local development in Indonesia Essays on weakly sustainable local development in Indonesia Gindo Tampubolon Institute for Social Change October 2009 The sustainable development rule identified by Hartwick [1977] provides a working hypothesis

More information

Neoclassical Growth Theory

Neoclassical Growth Theory Neoclassical Growth Theory Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis January 2018 1 A. What Motivates Neoclassical Growth Theory? 1. The Kaldorian observations: On-going increasing

More information

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

Oil Monopoly and the Climate Oil Monopoly the Climate By John Hassler, Per rusell, Conny Olovsson I Introduction This paper takes as given that (i) the burning of fossil fuel increases the carbon dioxide content in the atmosphere,

More information

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings Econ 20200 - Elements of Economics Analysis 3 (Honors Macroeconomics) Lecturer: Chanont (Big) Banternghansa TA: Jonathan J. Adams Spring 2013 Introduction Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

Human capital formation and public debt: Growth and welfare effects of three different deficit policies

Human capital formation and public debt: Growth and welfare effects of three different deficit policies Faculty of Business Administration and Economics Working Papers in Economics and Management No. 05-2015 May 2015 Human capital formation and public debt: Growth and welfare effects of three different deficit

More information

The Yield Envelope: Price Ranges for Fixed Income Products

The Yield Envelope: Price Ranges for Fixed Income Products The Yield Envelope: Price Ranges for Fixed Income Products by David Epstein (LINK:www.maths.ox.ac.uk/users/epstein) Mathematical Institute (LINK:www.maths.ox.ac.uk) Oxford Paul Wilmott (LINK:www.oxfordfinancial.co.uk/pw)

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

The Value of Information in Central-Place Foraging. Research Report

The Value of Information in Central-Place Foraging. Research Report The Value of Information in Central-Place Foraging. Research Report E. J. Collins A. I. Houston J. M. McNamara 22 February 2006 Abstract We consider a central place forager with two qualitatively different

More information

1 Continuous Time Optimization

1 Continuous Time Optimization University of British Columbia Department of Economics, International Finance (Econ 556) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout #6 1 1 Continuous Time Optimization Continuous time optimization is similar to dynamic

More information

Intergenerational transfers, tax policies and public debt

Intergenerational transfers, tax policies and public debt Intergenerational transfers, tax policies and public debt Erwan MOUSSAULT February 13, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the impact of the tax system on intergenerational family transfers in an overlapping

More information

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS) ECO 521 Fall 216 TAKE-HOME EXAM The exam is due at 9AM Thursday, January 19, preferably by electronic submission to both sims@princeton.edu and moll@princeton.edu. Paper submissions are allowed, and should

More information

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION SILAS A. IHEDIOHA 1, BRIGHT O. OSU 2 1 Department of Mathematics, Plateau State University, Bokkos, P. M. B. 2012, Jos,

More information

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples Jinill Kim, Korea University Sunghyun Kim, Sungkyunkwan University March 015 Abstract This paper provides two illustrative examples

More information

Liquidity and Risk Management

Liquidity and Risk Management Liquidity and Risk Management By Nicolae Gârleanu and Lasse Heje Pedersen Risk management plays a central role in institutional investors allocation of capital to trading. For instance, a risk manager

More information

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk Vasia Panousi Catarina Reis April 27 WP 27/64 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

The Life Cycle Model with Recursive Utility: Defined benefit vs defined contribution.

The Life Cycle Model with Recursive Utility: Defined benefit vs defined contribution. The Life Cycle Model with Recursive Utility: Defined benefit vs defined contribution. Knut K. Aase Norwegian School of Economics 5045 Bergen, Norway IACA/PBSS Colloquium Cancun 2017 June 6-7, 2017 1. Papers

More information

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015 I. The Solow model Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis Universidad Autónoma de Madrid September 2015 Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) I. The Solow model September 2015 1 / 43 Objectives In this first lecture

More information

Exercises in Growth Theory and Empirics

Exercises in Growth Theory and Empirics Exercises in Growth Theory and Empirics Carl-Johan Dalgaard University of Copenhagen and EPRU May 22, 2003 Exercise 6: Productive government investments and exogenous growth Consider the following growth

More information

On a Manufacturing Capacity Problem in High-Tech Industry

On a Manufacturing Capacity Problem in High-Tech Industry Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 11, 217, no. 2, 975-983 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com https://doi.org/1.12988/ams.217.7275 On a Manufacturing Capacity Problem in High-Tech Industry Luca Grosset and

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

1 No capital mobility

1 No capital mobility University of British Columbia Department of Economics, International Finance (Econ 556) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout #7 1 1 No capital mobility In the previous lecture we studied the frictionless environment

More information

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Transport Costs and North-South Trade Transport Costs and North-South Trade Didier Laussel a and Raymond Riezman b a GREQAM, University of Aix-Marseille II b Department of Economics, University of Iowa Abstract We develop a simple two country

More information

Can Borrowing Costs Explain the Consumption Hump?

Can Borrowing Costs Explain the Consumption Hump? Can Borrowing Costs Explain the Consumption Hump? Nick L. Guo Apr 23, 216 Abstract In this paper, a wedge between borrowing and saving interest rates is incorporated into an otherwise standard life cycle

More information

Mandatory Social Security Regime, C Retirement Behavior of Quasi-Hyperb

Mandatory Social Security Regime, C Retirement Behavior of Quasi-Hyperb Title Mandatory Social Security Regime, C Retirement Behavior of Quasi-Hyperb Author(s) Zhang, Lin Citation 大阪大学経済学. 63(2) P.119-P.131 Issue 2013-09 Date Text Version publisher URL http://doi.org/10.18910/57127

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

A Two-sector Ramsey Model

A Two-sector Ramsey Model A Two-sector Ramsey Model WooheonRhee Department of Economics Kyung Hee University E. Young Song Department of Economics Sogang University C.P.O. Box 1142 Seoul, Korea Tel: +82-2-705-8696 Fax: +82-2-705-8180

More information

In the Name of God. Macroeconomics. Sharif University of Technology Problem Bank

In the Name of God. Macroeconomics. Sharif University of Technology Problem Bank In the Name of God Macroeconomics Sharif University of Technology Problem Bank 1 Microeconomics 1.1 Short Questions: Write True/False/Ambiguous. then write your argument for it: 1. The elasticity of demand

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

A Note on the Extinction of Renewable Resources

A Note on the Extinction of Renewable Resources JOURNAL OF ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT &64-70 (1988) A Note on the Extinction of Renewable Resources M. L. CROPPER Department of Economics and Bureau of Business and Economic Research, University

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL SUPPLY CHAINS AND WAGE INEQUALITY. Arnaud Costinot Jonathan Vogel Su Wang

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL SUPPLY CHAINS AND WAGE INEQUALITY. Arnaud Costinot Jonathan Vogel Su Wang NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL SUPPLY CHAINS AND WAGE INEQUALITY Arnaud Costinot Jonathan Vogel Su Wang Working Paper 17976 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17976 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 23 Dec 2010

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 23 Dec 2010 ASYMPTOTIC PROPERTIES OF OPTIMAL TRAJECTORIES IN DYNAMIC PROGRAMMING SYLVAIN SORIN, XAVIER VENEL, GUILLAUME VIGERAL Abstract. We show in a dynamic programming framework that uniform convergence of the

More information

The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility

The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility Harjoat S. Bhamra Sauder School of Business University of British Columbia Raman

More information

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Michael Schürle Institute for Operations Research and Computational Finance, University of St. Gallen, Bodanstr. 6, CH-9000 St. Gallen, Switzerland

More information

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model Suppose that there are H households who live two periods They are endowed with E 1 units of labor in period 1 and E 2 units of labor in period 2, which they

More information

Part II Money and Public Finance Lecture 7 Selected Issues from a Positive Perspective

Part II Money and Public Finance Lecture 7 Selected Issues from a Positive Perspective Part II Money and Public Finance Lecture 7 Selected Issues from a Positive Perspective Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Monetary and Fiscal Policy Issues in General Equilibrium

More information

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010 Problem set 5 Asset pricing Markus Roth Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz Juli 5, 200 Markus Roth (Macroeconomics 2) Problem set 5 Juli 5, 200 / 40 Contents Problem 5 of problem

More information

Income Inequality and Economic Growth: A Simple Theoretical Synthesis *

Income Inequality and Economic Growth: A Simple Theoretical Synthesis * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 6, 319 329 (2005) Income Inequality and Economic Growth: A Simple Theoretical Synthesis * Been-Lon Chen Institute of Economics, Academia Sinica, 128 Academic Road, Section

More information

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3)

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3) FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS These notes are missing interpretation of the results, and especially toward the end, skip some steps in the mathematics. But they should be useful

More information

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018 Introduction Intermediate Macroeconomics Consumption/Saving, Ricardian

More information

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M VIALE 1 Behavioral Asset Pricing 11 Prospect theory based asset pricing model Barberis, Huang, and Santos (2001) assume a Lucas pure-exchange economy with three types of assets:

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information