Information Paper. Financial Capital Maintenance and Price Smoothing

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Information Paper. Financial Capital Maintenance and Price Smoothing"

Transcription

1 Information Paper Financial Capital Maintenance and Price Smoothing February 2014

2 The QCA wishes to acknowledge the contribution of the following staff to this report: Ralph Donnet, John Fallon and Kian Nam Loke Queensland Competition Authority 2013 The Queensland Competition Authority supports and encourages the dissemination and exchange of information. However, copyright protects this document. The Queensland Competition Authority has no objection to this material being reproduced, made available online or electronically ver 1 but only if it is recognised as the owner of the copyright 2 and this material remains unaltered. Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

3 Queensland Competition Authority Table of Contents Table of Contents GLOSSARY OF ACRONYMS, TERMS AND CONDITIONS 36 THE ROLE OF THE QCA TASK AND CONTACTS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY IV V 1 FINANCIAL CAPITAL MAINTENANCE Definitions Literature review Implications of financial capital maintenance Summary 7 2 BUILDING BLOCKS APPROACH Return on and return of capital Indexation of the asset value Summary 13 3 PRICE SMOOTHING Smoothing Smoothing period Smoothing period matches the asset life Smoothing period differs from the asset life Changing demand Practical considerations Summary 29 4 CONCLUSION 31 APPENDIX A 32 REFERENCES ver 1 iii Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

4 Queensland Competition Authority The Role of the QCA Task and Contacts THE ROLE OF THE QCA TASK AND CONTACTS The Queensland Competition Authority (QCA) is an independent statutory authority that promotes competition as the basis for enhancing efficiency and growth in the Queensland economy. The QCA s primary role is to ensure that monopoly businesses operating in Queensland, particularly in the provision of key infrastructure, do not abuse their market power through unfair pricing or restrictive access arrangements. In 2012, that role was expanded to allow the QCA to be directed to investigate, and report on, any matter relating to competition, industry, productivity or best practice regulation; and review and report on existing legislation. Task This information paper explains and explores the financial capital maintenance (or NPV=0) principle and documents methods of price smoothing that have been applied by the QCA. The paper was motivated by the need to document methods the QCA has applied and to highlight a number of issues that arise in the context of determining price paths over time. Contacts Comments and enquiries regarding this paper should be directed to: ATTN: Kian Nam Loke Tel (07) research@qca.org.au ver 1 iv Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

5 Queensland Competition Authority Executive Summary EXECUTIVE SUMMARY This paper discusses: (1) the ex ante financial capital maintenance (FCM) principle (also known as the NPV=0 principle); and (2) price smoothing. While an appropriate form of price smoothing can take on various forms, it should always be subject to the FCM principle. The FCM or NPV=0 principle refers to the requirement that the present value of expected capital charges for an asset over its economic life should be equal to the initial asset value or purchase cost. The capital charge for all assets (i.e. the RAB) for a regulatory year comprises both the return on and return of capital. The FCM principle also holds that at any given point in time the present value of expected capital charges over the remaining life of the asset should equal the current value (initial value less allowed depreciation from previous periods) of such an asset. The paper reviews some key papers on rate base and depreciation, and presents a mathematical model that illustrates the implications for depreciation and the evolution of the asset value if the FCM principle is applied over the full life of the asset. This model shows that in order to meet such a principle for a particular asset, the regulator has three options: (a) (b) (c) Specify a schedule for capital charges with a present value that matches the initial asset value. This is typically in the form of an annuity, which is a series of constant or indexed annual capital charges applicable over the life of the asset. Specify a schedule for depreciation amounts that add up to the initial asset cost over the asset life. There are four standard depreciation profiles, namely straight-line, front-end loaded, back-end loaded, and one-hoss shay. In practice, any profile that satisfies the FCM principle can be adopted. Specify the evolution of the asset value. Since the change in the asset value between periods is the applicable depreciation amount, setting the evolution of the asset value is equivalent to setting the depreciation profile provided the FCM principle is satisfied. A smoothed revenue or price path is typically obtained by regulators adjusting the building block annual revenue requirement (ARR) to produce either a smoothed revenue or price path. This paper derives the smoothing formulae and provides various examples of smoothing. In applying smoothing, there can be abrupt and largely arbitrary changes in prices between regulatory periods, depending on the choice of depreciation method adopted when the building blocks revenue is calculated. For example, straight-line depreciation produces capital charges that are larger in absolute terms in the beginning of the asset life relative to those in the later years. This typically means that applying straight-line depreciation will result in lower prices in the future relative to prices in the present. As a result smoothed prices can be materially different between regulatory periods. The differences in prices may be exacerbated when demand is growing over time. While this issue is not as apparent in the case where the firm makes investments over time, the contributions by customers to the capital recovery of regulated assets in one period may differ materially from contributions in another period. The time path of capital charges as a whole often receives less attention than the depreciation profile. While straight-line depreciation, the most commonly applied depreciation profile, produces equal depreciation amounts (in real terms under the QCA's approach) over the life of the asset, the resulting capital charge is in fact decreasing in value over time. This result is often neglected by regulators. A backend loaded depreciation profile can produce a more balanced capital charge that might be considered as ver 1 v Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

6 Queensland Competition Authority Executive Summary more 'equitable', especially if there is excess capacity and the demand is expected to rise significantly over time. The paper concludes that the optimal profile of capital charges needs to be determined by separate efficiency or equity considerations. For example, considerations of excess capacity, growth of demand, potential for asset stranding and intergenerational equity would all be relevant in determining the optimal time profile of prices for a regulated entity ver 1 vi Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

7 Financial Capital Maintenance 1 FINANCIAL CAPITAL MAINTENANCE Biggar (2011) prepared brief summaries of The Fifty Most Important Papers in the Economics of Regulation'. These papers are divided into fifteen topics one of which, 'Rate Base and Depreciation' is considered here. This topic focuses on the regulated firm's recovery of invested capital. Biggar highlights the conclusion drawn by Greenwald (1984) that 'as long as the regulatory regime ensures that the change in the asset base over the regulatory period is equal to the present value of the payments to investors (discounted at the appropriate cost of capital), investors will be adequately compensated for their investments in the long run'. This is commonly referred to as the financial capital maintenance (FCM) principle, or the NPV=0 principle, in regulatory economics. This: (a) (b) (c) 1.1 Definitions provides an initial understanding of the concept of financial capital maintenance and its origins outlines the findings of some key papers on rate base and depreciation discusses the implications for depreciation and the asset value if the FCM principle is applied over the full life of an asset. Capital maintenance is a longstanding financial accounting concept that can be related to economic notions of the recovery of capital. Financial capital refers to the value of business assets as measured by the value of equity and debt, while physical capital is the productive or operating capacity of the assets. Financial capital maintenance (FCM) is the maintenance of the initial value of a business as measured by the value of assets at the time of investment. Under the accounting definition of FCM, a profit is earned only if the financial value of net assets at the end of the period exceeds the financial value of net assets at the beginning of the period, after excluding any distributions to, and contributions from owners during the period. In the regulatory context, FCM is applied in an ex ante sense, meaning that investors of a regulated firm can expect to recover the opportunity cost of their capital and the nominal value of their initial investment over time. This is referred to as the FCM principle. As long as the present value (PV) of future regulated returns, calculated on the basis of an appropriate opportunity cost discount rate, is equal to the value of the regulatory asset base (RAB), the FCM principle is achieved. The FCM principle in an exact sense is often referred to as the NPV=0 principle. In contrast, physical or operating capital maintenance (OCM) focuses on maintaining the productive capacity of physical assets over time, rather than the financial value of assets. In the accounting context, this means that profit is only recognised after the operating capacity of assets has been maintained or when the operating capacity of the enterprise at the end of the period exceeds the operating capacity at the beginning of the period, after excluding any changes to capacity associated with additions or disposals of assets during the period. OCM determines asset prices and depreciation charges based on the cost of replacing assets in order to maintain operational capability at a defined level ver 1 1 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

8 Financial Capital Maintenance For a defined level of operational capability, FCM differs from OCM in an accounting sense by recognising capital gains and losses associated with holding the assets as well as the standard OCM charge. 1.2 Literature review This section reviews the four seminal papers highlighted by Biggar (2011) on the cost recovery of sunk investment in the context of economic regulation. To achieve this cost recovery, Australian regulators typically apply a form of building blocks model, where prices are set to allow regulated firms to earn expected revenue (after deducting operating expenditure and taxes) that provides a 'fair' rate of return on the RAB plus an allowance for economic depreciation. Biggar (2011) notes that there are at least three approaches for setting the RAB: (a) the historical cost of the assets of the firm; (b) the replacement cost of the assets of the firm; and (c) the historical cost of the assets of the firm adjusted for inflation. 12 The first paper reviewed by Biggar is Greenwald (1984). Greenwald's model, which focuses on the evolution of the RAB, shows that under certain conditions, as long as (a) depreciation is defined as the change in the RAB each period, and (b) the regulator sets the allowed rate of return equal to the firm's true cost of capital, the three asset valuation approaches above are consistent with investors earning a fair and normal return. According to Greenwald, the RAB should satisfy the following conditions: (a) (b) (c) The RAB cannot be negative. The RAB must be at all times be less than the market value of a profit-maximising unconstrained monopolist, hence ensuring that no regulated firm can earn more than it could if it were unregulated. The RAB should start at zero before any investment is sunk and should finish at zero when the firm ceases to exist. Greenwald (1984) argues that the concept of the RAB avoids the "dynamic consistency" problem as it ensures that the firm will always be adequately compensated for its investments in the long run, regardless of the form of regulatory regime in place. For example, suppose that a regulator had traditionally set prices that would yield optimal behaviour by the firm, but for a specific period, perhaps due to political pressure, the regulator decided to alter its approach and specified prices that sought to minimise customer costs. As long as the change in the RAB over this period reflected the present value of the payments to the firm, the firm would still earn a normal return on its investments. This provides a strong argument for the use of the building blocks model, as it ensures that the regulated firm will always be allowed an expected return consistent with the normal return on investments, regardless of any future changes in operating and borrowing costs, as well as demand. Biggar (2011) also reviews research by Schmalensee (2011). Schmalensee shows that, provided the regulator sets the allowed rate of return equal to the firm s true cost of capital, virtually any path of depreciation is consistent with investors receiving a normal return on capital. When it comes to ensuring that investors are adequately compensated, the choice of the path of 1 Options (a) and (b) are equivalent if the cost of capital parameter applied is adjusted appropriately for inflation. 2 An application of option (b) in Australia is known as depreciated optimised replacement cost, commonly abbreviated to DORC ver 1 2 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

9 Financial Capital Maintenance depreciation is essentially arbitrary (from an NPV=0 perspective). This point is illustrated in the next section. However, Schmalensee emphasises that this does not necessarily mean that all schedules of depreciation are socially equally desirable. This is because the sequence of depreciation has implications for the allowed revenues and prices. In this respect, Biggar quotes Baumol (1971):... there may be many alternative revenue streams, each of which can give investors their required returns. The choice of depreciation policy may then be defined as the selection of one of these inter-temporal patterns of prices which will yield one of the revenue streams adequate to compensate investors It should now be clear in what sense one depreciation policy may be better than another. One set of inter-temporal patterns of product prices may yield a better allocation of resources than another. According to Biggar (2011), some authors, such as Rogerson (1992), have suggested the choice of depreciation should result in 'inter-temporal Ramsey prices'. The third paper discussed is Crew and Kleindorfer (1992). In this paper, the authors consider the possibility of an emergence of external forces, such as market competition, that may affect the firm's ability to recover its sunk costs in the future. Crew and Kleindorfer (1992) argue that the regulator must take such a possibility into account when setting the schedule of depreciation. If there was an expectation that the regulated firm would be constrained in how much it could recover in the future, a front-end loaded capital recovery, such as a tilted annuity could be applied. The final paper reviewed in Biggar is Salinger (1998). According to Salinger, since cost-based prices are associated with zero economic profit, and there are many streams of future prices that are consistent with such a condition, there is a need to impose further constraints on the path of desired prices. Salinger suggests that if minimising deadweight loss is the ultimate goal, the regulator should first specify those prices that will achieve such a goal (e.g. Ramsey prices), then work backwards to work out the depreciation. Nevertheless, this approach is not supported by Biggar (2011), who points out that such 'price-based costs' will incur high transaction cost and hence may not be practical. Salinger also makes the point that the required revenue is higher when there is a chance that the asset will be stranded in the future. Biggar (2011) recognises that none of these papers addresses how the regulator should set the 'opening RAB' at the time of transition into a new regulatory regime. However, these papers all adopt or are consistent with the FCM principle. The latter is the focus of this paper. 1.3 Implications of financial capital maintenance This section presents a model illustrating the implications for depreciation and the evolution of the asset value if the FCM principle is applied over the full life of the asset. This model is adopted from Diewert, Lawrence and Fallon (2009). To simplify, the focus is on the cost recovery of a single asset. Suppose that at the beginning of period one, the regulated firm completes a project and the total cost is. 3 This asset is expected to yield a stream of services for periods before it is retired. The salvage value and decommissioning costs associated with disposing of the asset are assumed to be zero. 3 Alternatively, the firm may have purchased a long-lived asset that costs at the beginning of period one ver 1 3 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

10 Financial Capital Maintenance The regulated firm faces a weighted average cost of capital (WACC) of in period, where. 4 The WACC parameter of a given period can represent either the actual or expected opportunity cost of capital applicable to such a period, depending on the time it is evaluated. For instance, evaluated at the beginning of period one, here is the actual cost of capital in period one, while the rest of represent the regulator's view of future cost of capital. To recover the sunk cost of this investment, the firm is allowed by the regulator to impose capital charges over periods. Period 's capital charge amount is denoted by. One can interpret as the sum of charges paid by all customers in period for services provided by such an asset, excluding charges for the recovery of other costs. Assume that these capital charges are paid at the end of each period. The FCM principle will be met if the period-by-period capital charges satisfy the following fundamental equation: (1) The present value (PV) of future income generated from capital charges is equivalent to the initial cost of the asset. That is, the firm can expect to fully recover its sunk investment over time, including the opportunity cost of capital. Equation (1) shows that if the series of future opportunity cost of capital is reasonably accurate, then the regulator can choose any schedule of capital charges over the asset life that satisfies equation (1). The regulated firm should have no grounds for complaint, as it will recover the cost of its sunk investment in present value terms under this condition. Box 1: Indexation of capital charges Suppose that the regulator decides to index the periodic capital charge for a new asset by the expected inflation rate. Let the anticipated rate of inflation for period be, where. The capital charge in period can be defined as: (a) Using the equation above, the FCM principle will imply: (b) In order to satisfy the NPV=0 principle, the base capital charge has to be set such that equation (b) holds. Once is determined, the capital charge in period is then calculated using equation (a). Regulators typically apply a constant indexation rate, such that the capital charge grows at a constant rate annually. This is akin to the annuity approach explored in Chapter 2. It is useful to convert the choice of paths for capital charges into a choice of paths for asset value or depreciation. If the expected cash flow for period one turns out to be accurate (i.e. there is no significant under- or over-recovery of ), the discounted stream of capital charges that the regulator will allow over periods two to is equivalent to the asset value at the beginning of period two,, and it is defined as follows: 4 Either a real or a nominal discount rate can be applied. If a real discount rate is used, the capital charges calculated will be expressed in real terms, while if a nominal discount rate is applied, the capital charges will be nominal values ver 1 4 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

11 Financial Capital Maintenance (2) Period one's depreciation,, can be defined as the decline in the asset value going from the beginning of period one to the beginning of period two (which is also the end of period one): (3) Using equations (1) and (2), the initial asset value, (4), can be expressed as: Equation (4) can now be rearranged, and used together with equation (3) to provide the following equation for period one's capital charge : 5 (5) Thus period one's capital charge can be expressed as times the asset value at the beginning of period one,, plus period one's depreciation amount,. A general formula similar to (5) can be obtained for the capital charge of any period. Define the asset value at the beginning of period, and period 's depreciation,, respectively by equations (6) and (7) below: (6) (7) Note that is defined to be zero (i.e. the asset has no residual value). Period 's counterpart to equation (4) is: (8). Equation (8) can now be rearranged and used together with equation (7) to provide the following formula for period 's capital charge : (9) The last line of equation (9) applies (7) repeatedly. Equation (9) shows that the sequence of capital charges is completely determined by the initial cost of the asset ( ), the sequence of costs of capital ( ), and the sequence of nonnegative depreciation amounts where the sum over periods must equal to the initial value of the asset (i.e. ). 6 5 See Schmalensee (1989, p. 294) and Johnstone (2003,p. 4) for a similar formula. 6 Consider a three-period model where:,, and. Then:. This means that when a nominal discount rate is applied, the compensation for inflation is included in the discount rate, rather than depreciation. However, many regulators (including the QCA) index the RAB value (using the CPI), use a nominal discount rate and then deduct the inflationary gain to avoid double ver 1 5 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

12 Financial Capital Maintenance Thus, to meet the FCM principle, the regulator has three options: (a) Specify a schedule for capital charges that satisfies equation (1) over the life of the asset. (b) Specify a schedule for depreciation amounts that add up to the initial asset cost over the asset life. The capital charge for each period is then calculated using equation (9). (c) Specify the evolution of the asset value (i.e. the schedule for over the asset life). Since the change in the asset value between periods is the applicable depreciation amount, setting the evolution of the asset value is equivalent to setting the schedule for depreciation. The capital charge is calculated using equation (9). Note that the third line in equation (9) comprises the two capital cost components of the building blocks methodology applied by Australian regulators in deriving the allowed revenue for a particular regulatory year. The product of represents the return on capital, while the depreciation amount is referred to as the return of capital. As a regulated firm has more than one asset, the return on capital is calculated on the firm's regulatory asset base (RAB), which records the initial value of all assets less the total depreciated amount from previous periods. This is equivalent to calculating the return on capital separately for each asset in the RAB and subsequently summing them up. The return of capital is the sum of depreciation amounts for all assets of the firm for a particular regulatory year. It is easier to work with equation (9) in practice than to work with equation (1). Applying equation (9) repeatedly at the beginning of each period (or prior to the commencement of the next regulatory pricing period) requires only the knowledge of the prevailing opportunity cost of capital (or expected cost of capital over the pricing period) and the depreciation amount for this period (or over the pricing period). This means that the regulator will not have to commit ex ante to a single depreciation path each period's depreciation (or depreciation over the regulatory period) can be determined separately as long as at the end of the asset life the sum of the depreciation amounts from all periods equals the initial value. Conversely, working with equation (1) at the beginning of the period where the asset is commissioned requires the knowledge of the entire sequence of expected cost of capital over the life of the asset, which can easily change over time. 7 The use of forecast cost of capital over an extended period can provoke strong disagreements from stakeholders. The regulator is also required to commit to a path of capital charges determined ex ante. Note that the regulated firm will always recover its going opportunity cost of capital if the period-by-period capital charges satisfy equation (1) and the anticipated future period actually materialise. To see this, rearrange the first equation in (9) as follows: (10). This equation shows that the asset value at the beginning of period,, times one plus the prevailing WACC,, is equivalent to the regulator s allowable period 's capital charge,, plus counting of inflation. In this case, the depreciation amounts over the life of the asset will not sum up to the initial asset value,. Rather, the FCM principle requires the sum of depreciation amounts less the nominal asset value gains arising from indexation over the life of the asset to be equal to. This is explored further in Section If equation (9) is used and the cost of capital changes over time, then the resulting user charges will not be the same as the original planned sequence of capital charges which satisfied equation (1) using the original sequence of anticipated ver 1 6 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

13 Financial Capital Maintenance the asset value of which the regulator will allow the firm to have at the beginning of period. Thus period 's capital charge,, plus the asset value at the end of period,, will be just large enough for the regulated firm to recover its initial asset value plus earn a rate of return of on its investment in this asset the asset will earn the going cost of capital during period. The period-by-period capital charges are largely arbitrary at this point (they need only satisfy equation (1) in order for the firm to recover its cost of capital and the sunk cost associated with the investment). Similarly, the period-by-period depreciation amounts are arbitrary (except that they must sum to the initial asset value over the asset life). This proposition was demonstrated in Schmalensee (1989). At this point, if the allowed rates of return are 'fair' from an investor's perspective and the investors are not concerned about stranded assets, then the regulated firm has no particular incentive to contest whatever pattern of periodic capital charges or depreciation that the regulator chooses. However, it is unlikely that the will in fact correspond exactly to appropriate weighted costs of capital, and thus depending on whether the allowed rates are too high or too low, the firm will have incentives to either postpone depreciation (the allowed is too high) or to lobby for accelerated depreciation (the allowed is too low). In reality, the regulator s choice problem is also typically much more complex, particularly where there is scope for asset stranding or excess capacity. 1.4 Summary In the regulatory context, the FCM principle is equivalent to the NPV=0 principle, where the investors of a regulated firm can expect to earn a series of regulated returns with a present value (discounted at the appropriate cost of capital) equal to the initial capital investment. The model shows that, given the FCM principle is satisfied, the regulator should be indifferent in terms of specifying a sequence for capital charges (to cover return on and return of capital), a sequence for depreciation, or the evolution of the asset value. This point has been made in the existing literature. However, in practice, it is easier to apply the building blocks approach, where the allowed cost of capital can be updated at the beginning of the pricing period, and the depreciation amount for each period can be determined separately (the regulator does not have to commit to a path of capital charges or depreciation). Such an approach is commonly applied by Australian regulators. The existing literature also highlights that while there can be many schedules of depreciation amounts (capital charges or the evolution of asset value) that meet the FCM principle, this does not necessarily imply that all paths are equally desirable. Some paths produce more efficient outcomes than the others, but at the same time they may not be considered as socially equitable as others. These factors should be taken into account when the regulator determines the appropriate series of allowable returns for the investors ver 1 7 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

14 Building Blocks Approach 2 BUILDING BLOCKS APPROACH This chapter presents four standard conventional methods for setting the depreciation profile of an asset, as well as the annuity approach. This is followed by a discussion of the method for calculating capital charges when the RAB value is indexed by the inflation rate and nominal discount rates are used, where adjustments to the return on capital are required to avoid double counting of inflation. 2.1 Return on and return of capital In Australia, regulated prices are commonly set to allow the regulated firm to recover the annual revenue requirement (ARR). The ARR is a series of notional annual revenue allowances, and is calculated by using a building blocks approach. The allowed building blocks revenue for a particular regulatory year is made up of the following components: (a) (b) (c) (d) return on capital return of capital efficient operating costs taxation allowance. As most regulated firms tend to be capital-intensive, the largest components of the building blocks ARR are typically the return on and return of capital. These two components, amounting to the total capital charge for the RAB in a regulatory year, enable the firm to recover its sunk capital investments. As described in Chapter 1, the return on capital is calculated on the firm's RAB, while the return of capital is the sum of all assets' depreciation amounts. There are four common approaches for setting the depreciation profile of an asset: (a) (b) (c) (d) Straight-line where the initial value of an asset is recovered in equal annual amounts over its productive life. For a given asset, straight-line depreciation is calculated by dividing the prevailing value of the asset (i.e. the initial value less the sum of depreciated amounts from previous periods) by its remaining productive life. Front-end loaded where the amount of depreciation decreases progressively for each year of the productive life of an asset. Back-end loaded where the amount of depreciation increases progressively for each year of the productive life of an asset. One-hoss shay where the value of an asset is maintained until the end of its productive life, at which the value declines significantly or to zero. That is, there is no deprecation until the final year of the life of the asset. Alternatively, rather than setting its depreciation profile, the regulator can specify a schedule of periodic capital charges with a present value equal to the initial asset value. Recall that the FCM principle provides substantial flexibility for the regulator to specify a sequence for either capital charges or depreciation, as long as over the life of the asset the NPV=0 principle is satisfied. One way of calculating the capital charge streams is to apply the annuity approach, which produces a series of constant or indexed capital charges applicable over the asset life. Each periodic amount embodies both the return on and return of capital components for such an asset. In the case where the annuity approach is applied to some but not all assets, the return ver 1 8 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

15 Building Blocks Approach on and return of capital will only be calculated separately on the assets where the annuity approach is not applied. This means that a record of asset values, adjusted for previous allowed depreciation, such as the RAB, will no longer be required for pricing purposes if the annuity approach is applied to all assets. A simple example below illustrates the application of the four standard depreciation methods as well as an annuity. It relies on the following assumptions: (a) All values are expressed in real terms. (b) Initial purchase price of asset = $1000. (c) (d) (e) Asset life = 5 years. Allowed real rate of return = 10 per cent. Capital charges are received at the end of each period. The different outcomes are shown in the Table 1. The present value is evaluated at the beginning of Year 1. Table 1 Comparison of recovery of capital Method Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 1. Straight-line depreciation Opening asset value $1000 $800 $600 $400 $200 Depreciation $200 $200 $200 $200 $200 Return on capital $100 $80 $60 $40 $20 Capital charge $300 $280 $260 $240 $220 Present value $ Front-end loaded depreciation Opening asset value $1000 $700 $450 $250 $100 Depreciation $300 $250 $200 $150 $100 Return on capital $100 $70 $45 $25 $10 Capital charge $400 $320 $245 $175 $110 Present value $ Back-end loaded depreciation Opening asset value $1000 $900 $750 $550 $300 Depreciation $100 $150 $200 $250 $ ver 1 9 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

16 Building Blocks Approach Method Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 Return on capital $100 $90 $75 $55 $30 Capital charge $200 $240 $275 $305 $330 Present value $ One-hoss shay depreciation Opening asset value $1000 $1000 $1000 $1000 $1000 Depreciation $0 $0 $0 $0 $1000 Return on capital $100 $100 $100 $100 $100 Capital charge $100 $100 $100 $100 $1100 Present value $ Constant annuity Annual charge $264 $264 $264 $264 $264 Capital charge $264 $264 $264 $264 $264 Present value $1000 The streams of capital charges produced under the four methods of depreciation and a constant annuity are all equivalent in a present value sense, hence satisfying the FCM principle. Regardless of the depreciation method applied, depreciation over five years must total $1000 in order to satisfy the NPV=0 principle. Under the depreciation approach, the capital charge for each year is calculated using equation (9). Given that customers are liable for capital charges, not just the depreciation allowances, it is important to take into account the resulting paths of capital charges under varying methods of depreciation. For example, straight-line depreciation does not lead to a path of constant capital charges, but rather the capital charge decreases over time, as shown in Table 1. This has implications for pricing, and is discussed further in Chapter 3. In the example above, a constant annuity has been applied (fifth scenario in Table 1). The annuity approach provides the flexibility for the annual charge to be defined to have any growth patterns. Suppose the regulator decides to escalate the annual charge at a constant rate of 20 per cent per annum. Then, the capital charge for period will be defined as: where. Now substitute the equation above into equation (1) to get the following equation: A base annuity charge of approximately $153 solves the equation above. Hence, the annual charges will be as follows: ver 1 10 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

17 Building Blocks Approach Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 Annual charge $183 $220 $264 $317 $380 The discounted stream of annual charges above is equivalent to $1000. Compared with the constant annuity in Table 1, the annual charges of this indexed annuity are lower in the first two years, the same in year three, and higher in the final two years. 2.2 Indexation of the asset value Thus far, indexation of the asset value has not been considered. The equations in Chapter 1 and the example above assume no indexation of the asset value (the change in the asset value between periods is simply the depreciation amount). However, in practice the RAB value is typically adjusted for inflation. Furthermore, nominal values are commonly used as it is more convenient to report building blocks components such as operating costs as well as prices on a nominal basis. The QCA's approach is to index the RAB value by the CPI inflation rate and use a nominal WACC to calculate the return on capital. An adjustment is then made to eliminate the double counting of inflation that would otherwise occur from the use of an asset value indexed for inflation and a nominal rate of return that also includes compensation for inflation. Over the full life of an asset, the PVs of capital charges will be identical if the calculations are done correctly. Table 2 presents a comparison of nominal capital charges under two scenarios: with (the QCA's approach) and without indexation of the asset value respectively. Both apply straight-line depreciation. The asset value is $1000, with a productive life of five years, a residual value of zero, an inflation rate of 2.5 per cent and a nominal WACC of per cent. The indexation rate for the asset value is the inflation rate. Table 2 Comparison of capital charges under two scenarios Scenario Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 1. Without indexation of the asset value Opening asset value $1000 $800 $600 $400 $200 less Depreciation 8 $200 $200 $200 $200 $200 Closing asset value $800 $600 $400 $200 $0 Return of capital (depreciation) $200 $200 $200 $200 $200 Return on capital $128 $102 $77 $51 $26 8 To calculate the depreciation amount for a given year, divide the opening asset value in that year by the length of the remaining asset life. If the asset value is escalated for inflation, include the inflationary gain amount in the opening asset value before performing the division ver 1 11 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

18 Building Blocks Approach Scenario Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 Capital charges $328 $302 $277 $251 $226 Present value (12.75% nominal WACC) $ With indexation of the asset value (the QCA's approach) Opening asset value $1000 $820 $630 $431 $221 add Inflationary gain $25 $21 $16 $11 $6 less Depreciation $205 $210 $215 $221 $226 Closing asset value $820 $630 $431 $221 $0 Return of capital (depreciation) $205 $210 $215 $221 $226 Return on capital $128 $105 $80 $55 $28 less Inflationary gain $25 $21 $16 $11 $6 Capital charges $308 $294 $280 $265 $249 Present value (12.75% nominal WACC) $1000 When there is no indexation of the asset value (first scenario in Table 2), the total capital charge is calculated using equation (9) the return on capital is the product of the opening asset value and nominal WACC, while the return of capital is the specified depreciation amount. Note that each year's depreciation amount is $200, and over the life of the asset they add up to the initial asset value. In contrast, under the QCA's approach (second scenario in Table 2), an inflationary gain component is added annually to the opening asset value. This component, amounting to the product of the opening asset value and inflation rate, ensures that the asset value is indexed by the inflation rate. For example, in year one the inflationary gain is $25. The FCM principle requires the sum of depreciation amounts less the inflationary gains over the life of the asset to be equal to $1000, as above. When the asset value is escalated annually by the inflation rate, and a nominal rate of return is applied, it is necessary to adjust the return on capital (the product of the opening asset value and nominal WACC) by deducting an amount equivalent to the gain in the RAB value from indexation. This avoids the double counting of inflation that would otherwise occur from indexing the capital base by inflation and applying a nominal rate of return that embodies the same inflation rate. The downward adjustment in the first year is $25. Note that straight-line depreciation has been applied in both scenarios, but there are some technical differences between them. When there is no indexation of the asset value, the ver 1 12 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

19 Building Blocks Approach nominal depreciation allowance remains at $200 over the five-year period. Under the QCA's approach, the nominal depreciation allowance grows at a rate of 2.5 per cent per year, but the real depreciation allowance is a constant real value of $200. In this example, the indexation rate is also the CPI inflation rate, and this has resulted in a path of annual depreciation allowances that maintain the same value in real terms over time. Given both scenarios follow different paths of depreciation, their respective paths of return on capital (after deducting the inflationary gain under the QCA's approach) are also different. Nevertheless, as seen above, the PVs of capital charges are identical under both scenarios, and they are equal to the initial value of the asset ($1000). To be consistent with the normal practice and for expositional convenience, the QCA's approach is adopted for the remainder of this paper. 2.3 Summary This chapter presents four standard methods of depreciation, and also the annuity approach. The four standard methods of depreciation are: (1) straight-line; (2) front-end loaded; (3) backend loaded; and (4) one-hoss shay. Regardless of the depreciation method applied, the depreciation amounts over the life of the asset must sum to the initial asset value in order to satisfy the NPV=0 principle (when there is no indexation of the asset value). The annuity approach produces a series of constant or indexed capital charges applicable over the asset life. Each periodic amount resembles both the return on and return of capital for a particular asset. The annuity approach provides the flexibility for the annual capital charge to be defined to have any growth pattern. This chapter also introduces the method for calculating capital charges when the asset value is indexed. The QCA's approach is to index the RAB value by the CPI inflation rate and use the nominal WACC to calculate the return on capital. Under such an approach, it is necessary to adjust the return on capital by deducting an amount equivalent to the change in the RAB value from indexation ver 1 13 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

20 Price Smoothing 3 PRICE SMOOTHING This chapter explains how price or revenue smoothing is typically implemented in a regulatory context. Depending on the estimates of the building blocks ARR and forecast demand, prices can fluctuate significantly between years without smoothing. The smoothing technique is used to achieve a smooth price (or revenue) path within a regulatory period. However, smoothing per se does not fully address the issue of price (or revenue) fluctuations over a longer time frame then the current regulatory period. As smoothing is typically limited to the building blocks ARR within each regulatory period, there may be abrupt changes in prices (or revenues) from one period to the next. The choice of depreciation method adopted also has implications for smoothed prices (or revenues).additionally, should demand grow over time, prices or (revenue) may show increased fluctuation as a result. 3.1 Smoothing The previous chapter explained the building blocks approach typically applied by Australian regulators for calculating the ARR. Once the ARR has been determined, prices can then be generated. There are two approaches for calculating prices: (a) (b) Building blocks prices dividing the building blocks revenues by their respective forecast annual volumes. Depending on fluctuations of the building blocks revenues and forecast demand, prices determined in this manner can vary significantly from year to year. Smoothing in order to counter fluctuations described above, the regulator can either apply a smoothed price or revenue path for the regulated firm. Smoothed revenues (or prices) may be subject to a defined rate of escalation (e.g. the expected inflation rate), and are calculated on the basis that the present value (PV) of smoothed revenues (or revenues arising from smoothed prices) is equivalent to the PV of the building blocks revenues. However, if smoothed revenues are applied, resulting prices can still fluctuate between years depending on the forecast demand. Likewise, forecast demand patterns may result in fluctuating revenues despite price smoothing.. The derivation of smoothed revenues and prices is presented below. The focus is on price smoothing as the calculation of smoothed revenues is relatively simple. The formulae below are applicable to both nominal and real analyses. For a nominal analysis, smoothed prices are calculated using a nominal discount rate, while for a real analysis they are calculated using a real discount rate. Calculation of constant prices This subsection demonstrates the derivation of constant prices. The starting proposition is revenue equivalence the PV of revenues arising from smoothed prices (denoted by ) must equal the PV of the building blocks allowed revenues (denoted by ). Consider the following: (11) (12) ver 1 14 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

21 Price Smoothing where: = building blocks revenue for period = constant price = forecast volume for period = total length of the smoothing period = period within the smoothing period, where = discount rate (real or nominal) applicable. Note that the price,, is fixed over time in this case. The present value equivalence proposition can be expressed as follows: (13) (14) The constant price is then calculated as: (15) The fixed price is derived by dividing the PV of the building blocks revenues by the PV of the forecast demand. If the building blocks revenues and the discount rate are expressed in real (nominal) terms, the resulting prices will also be in real (nominal) terms. Note that if nominal prices are constant over time, they will be declining in value in real terms as a result of inflation. To calculate a path of constant revenues, simply replace the term ( ) in equation (12) with a constant revenue term (denoted by ), and solve for this term. It can be shown that the constant revenue is calculated as: (16). The annual prices are then calculated by dividing the constant revenue term by their respective forecast annual volumes. The prices in this case can fluctuate significantly depending on the forecast demand. Calculation of smoothed prices escalated at a specific rate This subsection illustrates how prices can be defined to escalate annually at a specific rate. In practice, prices typically rise annually at the expected percentage change in the CPI to reflect the general movement in prices within the economy. Similar to the case of constant prices, the starting proposition is that the PV of the revenues arising from smoothed prices must equal the PV of the building blocks revenues. Consider the following: (17) (18) where: = building blocks revenue for period = base price ver 1 15 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

22 Price Smoothing = forecast volume for period = total length of the smoothing period = price escalation rate = period within the smoothing period, where = discount rate (real or nominal) applicable. Note in equation (18) the annual price is set to grow at the rate of each year. Following similar steps illustrated in the previous subsection, the base price can be derived as: (19) This can be re-expressed as: (20) The indexed price for period can then be expressed as follows: (21) Note that if the escalation rate is set at 0%, equations (15) and (19) are identical the smoothed price for each period is simply the base price and hence is constant over time. To calculate an indexed revenue stream, replace the term, and solve for. Then the base revenue is: in equation (18) by, and the smoothed revenue for period is: (22). The annual prices are then calculated by dividing the smoothed revenues by their respective forecast annual volumes. Similar to the case of constant revenues, prices can fluctuate significantly depending on the forecast demand. Prices in nominal terms escalated at the inflation rate In a nominal analysis, where nominal values and nominal discount rate are applied, equation (19) can be further simplified if the price escalation rate is set to equal the expected percentage change of the CPI. Firstly, note that the Fisher equation specifies the following relationship between nominal and real interest rates:, where is the nominal discount rate, is the inflation rate, and is the real discount rate. Given the Fisher equation, if the escalation rate is the inflation rate, and is the nominal discount rate, equation (19) can be re-stated as follows: (23), where the term has been replaced by ver 1 16 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

23 Price Smoothing Note that the term appears in both the denominator and the numerator in equation (11). Hence, the formula can be simplified to be: (24). This shows that when nominal values are applied and smoothed prices escalate at the expected inflation rate ( ), the real discount rate should be applied to discount the forecast demand in a nominal analysis (but note that the nominal discount rate is still being used to discount the nominal building blocks revenues). Prices escalated at the discount rate In contrast, if the escalation rate is set to be equal the discount rate equation (19) then becomes: (real or nominal), (25). In this special case, there is no need to discount the stream of volumes. The denominator of the base price formula is simply the summation of the forecast volumes over the smoothing period. 3.2 Smoothing period Smoothing period (also known as planning period) refers to the period used for smoothing of revenues or prices. Denoted by in the smoothing formulae, this parameter effectively determines the number of years of building blocks revenues that are included in the applicable smoothing formula to generate a base price (or revenue). In this paper, target prices (or revenues) refer to the final allowed prices (or revenues) adopted by the regulator. This is to distinguish between the smoothed prices (or revenues) calculated and the actual allowed prices (or revenues) adopted. Consider the following example of price smoothing. Suppose that the regulatory pricing period is five years and the building blocks revenues for the next 10 years have been specified. In determining the regulated prices for the next 10 years, the regulator can apply a 10-year smoothing period. In this case, the building blocks revenues and forecast volumes for this period will be used to produce a single base price, which is then escalated annually to generate prices for the next 10 years. Under this approach, target prices for the two successive pricing periods are made up of a single smoothed path. Alternatively, the regulator can apply a five-year smoothing period. This involves firstly applying the applicable smoothing formula to the building blocks revenues and forecast volumes for the first five years; then repeating it for years six to 10. This will produce two base prices, in which the first is escalated to derive prices for the first five years, and the second is used to determine prices for the remaining years. Under this approach, target prices for the 10 years consist of two separate smoothed paths. As shown below, the smoothed prices (or revenues) under varying smoothing periods can be significantly different, depending on the underlying building blocks revenues the smoothing applies to. While the smoothing period applied by the regulator may be equal or greater than the regulatory pricing period, in practice this choice is constrained by the number of years of building blocks revenues available to the regulator. Regulators typically only forecast building blocks revenues for the current regulatory period because of the risk of unavailability of data needed for forecasts in the long term ver 1 17 Draft as at 04/02/14 9:06

Information Paper. The Split Cost of Capital Concept

Information Paper. The Split Cost of Capital Concept Information Paper The Split Cost of Capital Concept February 2014 We wish to acknowledge the contribution of the following staff to this report: Michael S. Blake, Ralph Donnet, John Fallon, Dan Kelley

More information

Asset Valuation and The Post-Tax Rate of Return Approach to Regulatory Pricing Models. Kevin Davis Colonial Professor of Finance

Asset Valuation and The Post-Tax Rate of Return Approach to Regulatory Pricing Models. Kevin Davis Colonial Professor of Finance Draft #2 December 30, 2009 Asset Valuation and The Post-Tax Rate of Return Approach to Regulatory Pricing Models. Kevin Davis Colonial Professor of Finance Centre of Financial Studies The University of

More information

The Construction of DORC From ORC

The Construction of DORC From ORC The Construction of DORC From ORC Agility Management August 2000 The construction of DORC from ORC 1. Purpose: Given the definition and interpretation of DORC available in: (i) (ii) Final Decision on Access

More information

Response to the QCA approach to setting the risk-free rate

Response to the QCA approach to setting the risk-free rate Response to the QCA approach to setting the risk-free rate Report for Aurizon Ltd. 25 March 2013 Level 1, South Bank House Cnr. Ernest and Little Stanley St South Bank, QLD 4101 PO Box 29 South Bank, QLD

More information

Non-replicable assets and forward-looking cost

Non-replicable assets and forward-looking cost Non-replicable assets and forward-looking cost Dr Tom Hird Jason Ockerby August 2014 Table of Contents 1 Overview 2 1.1 Introduction 2 1.2 Summary of WIK s position 2 1.3 Our comments on WIK s approach

More information

Asset valuation and productivity based regulation taking account of sunk costs and financial capital maintenance

Asset valuation and productivity based regulation taking account of sunk costs and financial capital maintenance Asset valuation and productivity based regulation taking account of sunk costs and financial capital maintenance Report prepared for Commerce Commission 11 June 2009 Erwin Diewert, Denis Lawrence and John

More information

The use of actual or forecast depreciation in energy network regulation

The use of actual or forecast depreciation in energy network regulation 999 The use of actual or forecast depreciation in energy network regulation Report prepared for Australian Energy Market Commission 31 May 2012 Denis Lawrence and John Kain Economic Insights Pty Ltd 6

More information

QUEENSLAND COMPETITION AUTHORITY

QUEENSLAND COMPETITION AUTHORITY QUEENSLAND COMPETITION AUTHORITY TRANSFERRED INFRASTRUCTURE & GIFTED CAPITAL: CONSIDERATION IN PRICE SETTING FOR URBAN WATER BUSINESSES 26 November 1999 Marsden Jacob A s s o c i a t e s Consulting Economists

More information

COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. Time Value of Money Toolbox CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION CASH FLOWS

COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. Time Value of Money Toolbox CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION CASH FLOWS E1C01 12/08/2009 Page 1 CHAPTER 1 Time Value of Money Toolbox INTRODUCTION One of the most important tools used in corporate finance is present value mathematics. These techniques are used to evaluate

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk Chapter 23: Choice under Risk 23.1: Introduction We consider in this chapter optimal behaviour in conditions of risk. By this we mean that, when the individual takes a decision, he or she does not know

More information

Global Financial Management

Global Financial Management Global Financial Management Valuation of Cash Flows Investment Decisions and Capital Budgeting Copyright 2004. All Worldwide Rights Reserved. See Credits for permissions. Latest Revision: August 23, 2004

More information

Depreciation of assets under the National Gas Rules Expert report

Depreciation of assets under the National Gas Rules Expert report pwc.com.au Depreciation of assets under the National Gas Rules Expert report November 2012 Contents 1 Introduction and overview 2 1.1 Introduction 2 2 What are the principles relevant to Rule 89(1)(a)?

More information

Independent Pricing and Regulatory Tribunal. Comparison of financial models - IPART and Australian Energy Regulator

Independent Pricing and Regulatory Tribunal. Comparison of financial models - IPART and Australian Energy Regulator Independent Pricing and Regulatory Tribunal Comparison of financial models - IPART and Australian Energy Regulator Research Research Paper November 2009 Comparison of financial models IPART and Australian

More information

Electricity Distribution Industry Productivity Analysis:

Electricity Distribution Industry Productivity Analysis: Electricity Distribution Industry Productivity Analysis: 1996 2013 Report prepared for Commerce Commission 24 June 2014 Denis Lawrence and John Kain Economic Insights Pty Ltd 10 By Street, Eden, NSW 2551,

More information

Lease Evaluation and Dividend Imputation. Kevin Davis Department of Accounting and Finance University of Melbourne ABSTRACT

Lease Evaluation and Dividend Imputation. Kevin Davis Department of Accounting and Finance University of Melbourne ABSTRACT Draft 4 August, 1994 Lease Evaluation and Dividend Imputation Kevin Davis Department of Accounting and Finance University of Melbourne ABSTRACT The conventional approach to analysing lease versus buy decisions

More information

Estimating gamma for regulatory purposes

Estimating gamma for regulatory purposes Estimating gamma for regulatory purposes REPORT FOR AURIZON NETWORK November 2016 Frontier Economics Pty. Ltd., Australia. November 2016 Frontier Economics i Estimating gamma for regulatory purposes 1

More information

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income 1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income Until now, we have assumed that government policy is exogenously given, so the government had a very passive role. Its only concern was balancing the intertemporal budget.

More information

(Transpower) Reasons paper December 2010

(Transpower) Reasons paper December 2010 Individual price-quality path (Transpower) Reasons paper December 2010 Regulation Branch Commerce Commission Wellington NEW ZEALAND 22 December 2010 ISBN: 978-1-869450-95-3 Commerce Commission i Table

More information

5. Equity Valuation and the Cost of Capital

5. Equity Valuation and the Cost of Capital 5. Equity Valuation and the Cost of Capital Introduction Part Two provided a detailed explanation of the investment decision with only oblique reference to the finance decision, which determines a company

More information

ECON 314: MACROECONOMICS II CONSUMPTION AND CONSUMER EXPENDITURE

ECON 314: MACROECONOMICS II CONSUMPTION AND CONSUMER EXPENDITURE ECON 314: MACROECONOMICS II CONSUMPTION AND CONSUMER 1 Explaining the observed patterns in data on consumption and income: short-run and cross-sectional data show that MPC < APC, whilst long-run data show

More information

Appendix A Financial Calculations

Appendix A Financial Calculations Derivatives Demystified: A Step-by-Step Guide to Forwards, Futures, Swaps and Options, Second Edition By Andrew M. Chisholm 010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Appendix A Financial Calculations TIME VALUE OF MONEY

More information

Revenue model. Instructions Water and Sewerage Price Proposal. 30 June 2017

Revenue model. Instructions Water and Sewerage Price Proposal. 30 June 2017 Revenue model Instructions 30 June 2017 2018 23 Water and Sewerage Price Proposal Icon Water Page 2017 Icon Water Limited (ABN 86 069 381 960) This publication is copyright and is the property of Icon

More information

Independent Pricing and Regulatory Tribunal. Comparison of financial models - IPART and Australian Energy Regulator

Independent Pricing and Regulatory Tribunal. Comparison of financial models - IPART and Australian Energy Regulator Independent Pricing and Regulatory Tribunal Comparison of financial models - IPART and Australian Energy Regulator Research Information Paper July 2012 Comparison of financial models IPART and Australian

More information

TIME PASSING AND THE MEASUREMENT OF DEPLETION

TIME PASSING AND THE MEASUREMENT OF DEPLETION TIME PASSING AND THE MEASUREMENT OF DEPLETION Peter Comisari Centre of Environment and Energy Statistics Australian Bureau of Statistics Note prepared for the London Group meeting on Environmental and

More information

Consultation paper. Review of Guaranteed Service Levels to apply in Queensland from 1 July 2020

Consultation paper. Review of Guaranteed Service Levels to apply in Queensland from 1 July 2020 Consultation paper Review of Guaranteed Service Levels to apply in Queensland from 1 July 2020 February 2018 Queensland Competition Authority 2018 The Queensland Competition Authority supports and encourages

More information

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence A The infinite horizon model This section defines the equilibrium of the infinity horizon model described in Section III of the paper and characterizes

More information

MFE8812 Bond Portfolio Management

MFE8812 Bond Portfolio Management MFE8812 Bond Portfolio Management William C. H. Leon Nanyang Business School January 16, 2018 1 / 63 William C. H. Leon MFE8812 Bond Portfolio Management 1 Overview Value of Cash Flows Value of a Bond

More information

8: Economic Criteria

8: Economic Criteria 8.1 Economic Criteria Capital Budgeting 1 8: Economic Criteria The preceding chapters show how to discount and compound a variety of different types of cash flows. This chapter explains the use of those

More information

IN D EC. consulting. A Review of the Regulatory Framework for Development of Costing Principles for Rail Access in WA

IN D EC. consulting. A Review of the Regulatory Framework for Development of Costing Principles for Rail Access in WA Discussion Paper A Review of the Regulatory Framework for Development of Costing Principles for Rail Access in WA IN D EC consulting Prepared for: Mr Jock Irvine Alcoa World Alumina Australia Booragoon

More information

Web Extension: The ARR Method, the EAA Approach, and the Marginal WACC

Web Extension: The ARR Method, the EAA Approach, and the Marginal WACC 19878_12W_p001-010.qxd 3/13/06 3:03 PM Page 1 C H A P T E R 12 Web Extension: The ARR Method, the EAA Approach, and the Marginal WACC This extension describes the accounting rate of return as a method

More information

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations 19.1: Introduction This chapter is interesting and important. It also helps to answer a question you may well have been asking ever since we studied quasi-linear

More information

(a) (ii) There are some problems with the DVM s underlying assumptions, as follows:

(a) (ii) There are some problems with the DVM s underlying assumptions, as follows: MARK PLAN AND EXAMINER S COMMENTARY Financial Management - Professional Stage December 2011 The marking plan set out below was that used to mark this question. Markers were encouraged to use discretion

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Port of Melbourne tariff compliance statement

Port of Melbourne tariff compliance statement 2017-18 Port of Melbourne tariff compliance statement Interim commentary 9 November 2017 An appropriate citation for this paper is: Essential Services Commission 2017, 2017-18 Port of Melbourne tariff

More information

Comparison of OLS and LAD regression techniques for estimating beta

Comparison of OLS and LAD regression techniques for estimating beta Comparison of OLS and LAD regression techniques for estimating beta 26 June 2013 Contents 1. Preparation of this report... 1 2. Executive summary... 2 3. Issue and evaluation approach... 4 4. Data... 6

More information

Investment Appraisal

Investment Appraisal Investment Appraisal Introduction to Investment Appraisal Whatever level of management authorises a capital expenditure, the proposed investment should be properly evaluated, and found to be worthwhile

More information

Mathematics of Finance

Mathematics of Finance CHAPTER 55 Mathematics of Finance PAMELA P. DRAKE, PhD, CFA J. Gray Ferguson Professor of Finance and Department Head of Finance and Business Law, James Madison University FRANK J. FABOZZI, PhD, CFA, CPA

More information

3: Balance Equations

3: Balance Equations 3.1 Balance Equations Accounts with Constant Interest Rates 15 3: Balance Equations Investments typically consist of giving up something today in the hope of greater benefits in the future, resulting in

More information

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks The historical data on financial asset returns show that one dollar invested in the Dow- Jones yields 6 times more than one dollar invested in U.S. Treasury bonds. The return

More information

Term Structure Lattice Models

Term Structure Lattice Models IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh Term Structure Lattice Models These lecture notes introduce fixed income derivative securities and the modeling philosophy used to

More information

Which WACC when? A cost of capital puzzle

Which WACC when? A cost of capital puzzle Agenda 10 years Advancing economics in business A cost of capital puzzle Originally published in September 2005. 2015 commentary by Oxera Real or nominal? Pre-tax or post-tax? (Or even vanilla?) The number

More information

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University April 12, 2008 Abstract A model of mixed oligopoly is constructed in which a Home public firm

More information

Annual risk measures and related statistics

Annual risk measures and related statistics Annual risk measures and related statistics Arno E. Weber, CIPM Applied paper No. 2017-01 August 2017 Annual risk measures and related statistics Arno E. Weber, CIPM 1,2 Applied paper No. 2017-01 August

More information

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory Chapter Microeconomics of Consumer Theory The two broad categories of decision-makers in an economy are consumers and firms. Each individual in each of these groups makes its decisions in order to achieve

More information

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction By: Stephen P. Holland Holland, Stephen P. (2003) Extraction Capacity and the Optimal Order of Extraction, Journal of Environmental Economics and

More information

Default price quality path reset

Default price quality path reset Default price quality path reset October 2012 Project team: Dr Tom Hird Daniel Young CEG Asia Pacific Suite 201, 111 Harrington Street Sydney NSW 2000 Australia T +61 3 9095 7570 F +61 2 9252 6685 www.ceg-ap.com

More information

Interest Rate Derivatives Price and Valuation Guide Australia

Interest Rate Derivatives Price and Valuation Guide Australia Interest Rate Derivatives Price and Valuation Guide Australia The pricing conventions used for most ASX 24 interest rate futures products differ from that used in many offshore futures markets. Unlike

More information

Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25 Department of Applied Economics Johns Hopkins University Economics 60 Macroeconomic Theory and Policy Midterm Exam Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 00 NAME: The Exam has a total of four

More information

Chapter 4. Consumption and Saving. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Chapter 4. Consumption and Saving. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada Chapter 4 Consumption and Saving Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada Where we are going? Here we will be looking at two major components of aggregate demand: Aggregate consumption or what is the same

More information

TREATMENT OF INTEREST ON INDEX-LINKED DEBT INSTRUMENTS 1

TREATMENT OF INTEREST ON INDEX-LINKED DEBT INSTRUMENTS 1 UPDATE OF THE 1993 SNA - ISSUE No. 43a ISSUE PAPER FOR THE JULY 2005 AEG MEETING SNA/M1.05/11.1 TREATMENT OF INTEREST ON INDEX-LINKED DEBT INSTRUMENTS 1 Manik Shrestha Statistics Department International

More information

Final decision. Cost of capital: market parameters

Final decision. Cost of capital: market parameters Final decision Cost of capital: market parameters August 2014 We wish to acknowledge the contribution of the following staff to this report: Michael S Blake, Daniel Kelley, Darren Page and Zach Zhang We

More information

UNITED STATES TAX CALCULATORS

UNITED STATES TAX CALCULATORS INTRODUCTION TEXT FINANCIAL CALCULATIONS FOR LAWYERS LECTURES INDEX GLOSSARY PRESENT VALUE OF A SUM FUTURE VALUE OF A SUM SINKING FUND AMORTIZATION WITH CHART PRESENT VALUE OF AN ANNUITY FUTURE VALUE OF

More information

Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright

Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals Donald J. Wright January 2014 VERY PRELIMINARY DRAFT School of Economics, Faculty of Arts and Social Sciences, University of Sydney, NSW, 2006, Australia, Ph:

More information

Cost of Debt Comparative Analysis. (For discussion at stakeholder workshop to be held on 7 November 2013)

Cost of Debt Comparative Analysis. (For discussion at stakeholder workshop to be held on 7 November 2013) Chairmont Consulting Cost of Debt Comparative Analysis (For discussion at stakeholder workshop to be held on 7 November 2013) Version: Final Dated: 5 November 2013 Table of Contents 1 Executive Summary...

More information

The Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting

The Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting The Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting The Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting (the Conceptual Framework) was issued by the International Accounting Standards Board in September 2010.

More information

The Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting

The Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting The Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting The Conceptual Framework was issued by the International Accounting Standards Board in September 2010. It superseded the Framework for the Preparation and

More information

*Efficient markets assumed

*Efficient markets assumed LECTURE 1 Introduction To Corporate Projects, Investments, and Major Theories Corporate Finance It is about how corporations make financial decisions. It is about money and markets, but also about people.

More information

Chapter 14 Solutions Solution 14.1

Chapter 14 Solutions Solution 14.1 Chapter 14 Solutions Solution 14.1 a) Compare and contrast the various methods of investment appraisal. To what extent would it be true to say there is a place for each of them As capital investment decisions

More information

CHAPTER 18: TRANSFER PRICES

CHAPTER 18: TRANSFER PRICES 1 CHAPTER 18: TRANSFER PRICES A. The Transfer Price Problem A.1 What is a Transfer Price? 18.1 When there is a international transaction between say two divisions of a multinational enterprise that has

More information

Breakeven Periods For Individual Retirement Accounts With Partial Withdrawals

Breakeven Periods For Individual Retirement Accounts With Partial Withdrawals Breakeven Periods For Individual Retirement Accounts With Partial Withdrawals Premal P. Vora, 1 Pennsylvania State University Great Valley If the money invested through an IRA is withdrawn before the investor

More information

CHAPTER 17. Payout Policy

CHAPTER 17. Payout Policy CHAPTER 17 1 Payout Policy 1. a. Distributes a relatively low proportion of current earnings to offset fluctuations in operational cash flow; lower P/E ratio. b. Distributes a relatively high proportion

More information

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES 1. Introduction One-period models, which were the subject of Lecture 1, are of limited usefulness in the pricing and hedging of derivative securities. In real-world

More information

HOW TO CALCULATE PRESENT VALUES

HOW TO CALCULATE PRESENT VALUES HOW TO CALCULATE PRESENT VALUES Chapter 2 Brealey, Myers, and Allen Principles of Corporate Finance 11 th Global Edition Basics of this chapter Cash Flows (and Free Cash Flows) Definition and why is it

More information

fig 3.2 promissory note

fig 3.2 promissory note Chapter 4. FIXED INCOME SECURITIES Objectives: To set the price of securities at the specified moment of time. To simulate mathematical and real content situations, where the values of securities need

More information

HKICPA Qualification Programme

HKICPA Qualification Programme HKICPA Qualification Programme Module B Corporate Financing KPMG Mock Exam Answers http://www.kaplanfinancial.com.hk Copyright Kaplan Financial (HK) Limited All rights reserved. No part of this examination

More information

Cash Flow and the Time Value of Money

Cash Flow and the Time Value of Money Harvard Business School 9-177-012 Rev. October 1, 1976 Cash Flow and the Time Value of Money A promising new product is nationally introduced based on its future sales and subsequent profits. A piece of

More information

Request for Advice on Cost Recovery for Mandated Smart Metering Infrastructure

Request for Advice on Cost Recovery for Mandated Smart Metering Infrastructure FINAL REPORT Request for Advice on Cost Recovery for Mandated Smart Metering Infrastructure Commissioners Pierce Henderson Spalding 30 November 2010 Reference: EPR0018 Final Report EMBARGO until 22 December

More information

Handout 4: Deterministic Systems and the Shortest Path Problem

Handout 4: Deterministic Systems and the Shortest Path Problem SEEM 3470: Dynamic Optimization and Applications 2013 14 Second Term Handout 4: Deterministic Systems and the Shortest Path Problem Instructor: Shiqian Ma January 27, 2014 Suggested Reading: Bertsekas

More information

The MM Theorems in the Presence of Bubbles

The MM Theorems in the Presence of Bubbles The MM Theorems in the Presence of Bubbles Stephen F. LeRoy University of California, Santa Barbara March 15, 2008 Abstract The Miller-Modigliani dividend irrelevance proposition states that changes in

More information

An easier to understand version of Melitz (2003)

An easier to understand version of Melitz (2003) n easier to understand version o Melitz (2003) Daniel Nguyen, University o Copenhagen International Trade, 2 December, 2008 This handout presents a very simpli ed version o Melitz (2003) that ocuses on

More information

Compliance with Control Mechanisms. October 2014

Compliance with Control Mechanisms. October 2014 04.01.00 Compliance with Control Mechanisms October 2014 Contents 1 Introduction... 2 1.1 Overview... 2 1.2 Allocation of services to controls... 3 2 Compliance with Control Mechanism for Standard Control

More information

Ergon Energy s Building Block Components

Ergon Energy s Building Block Components 03.01.01 Ergon Energy s Building Block Components Contents 1 Introduction... 3 1.1 Overview... 3 1.2 Purpose of this document... 3 1.3 NER requirements... 4 1.4 Structure of this document... 5 2 Regulatory

More information

Understanding goal-based investing

Understanding goal-based investing Understanding goal-based investing By Joao Frasco, Chief Investment Officer, STANLIB Multi-Manager This article will explain our thinking behind goal-based investing. It is important to understand that

More information

REVIEW OF ARGUMENTS ON THE TERM OF THE RISK FREE RATE. Dr Martin Lally Capital Financial Consultants Ltd. 20 November 2015

REVIEW OF ARGUMENTS ON THE TERM OF THE RISK FREE RATE. Dr Martin Lally Capital Financial Consultants Ltd. 20 November 2015 REVIEW OF ARGUMENTS ON THE TERM OF THE RISK FREE RATE Dr Martin Lally Capital Financial Consultants Ltd 20 November 2015 1 CONTENTS Executive Summary 3 1. Introduction 4 2. Review of ERAWA Arguments 4

More information

REVIEW OF PENSION SCHEME WIND-UP PRIORITIES A REPORT FOR THE DEPARTMENT OF SOCIAL PROTECTION 4 TH JANUARY 2013

REVIEW OF PENSION SCHEME WIND-UP PRIORITIES A REPORT FOR THE DEPARTMENT OF SOCIAL PROTECTION 4 TH JANUARY 2013 REVIEW OF PENSION SCHEME WIND-UP PRIORITIES A REPORT FOR THE DEPARTMENT OF SOCIAL PROTECTION 4 TH JANUARY 2013 CONTENTS 1. Introduction... 1 2. Approach and methodology... 8 3. Current priority order...

More information

In terms of covariance the Markowitz portfolio optimisation problem is:

In terms of covariance the Markowitz portfolio optimisation problem is: Markowitz portfolio optimisation Solver To use Solver to solve the quadratic program associated with tracing out the efficient frontier (unconstrained efficient frontier UEF) in Markowitz portfolio optimisation

More information

(a) (i) Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 $ $ $ $ Lease Lease payment (55,000) (55,000) (55,000) Borrow and buy Initial cost (160,000) Residual value 40,000

(a) (i) Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 $ $ $ $ Lease Lease payment (55,000) (55,000) (55,000) Borrow and buy Initial cost (160,000) Residual value 40,000 Answers Applied Skills, FM Financial Management (FM) September/December 2018 Sample Answers Section C 31 Melanie Co (a) (i) Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 $ $ $ $ Lease Lease payment (55,000) (55,000) (55,000)

More information

Valuation Issues Relating to the Local Loop. Martin Cave. August 2005

Valuation Issues Relating to the Local Loop. Martin Cave. August 2005 Valuation Issues Relating to the Local Loop Martin Cave August 2005 As part of the market reviews required under the new European regulatory framework, ARCEP must conduct an analysis of copper local loops.

More information

Zero-Coupon Bonds (Pure Discount Bonds)

Zero-Coupon Bonds (Pure Discount Bonds) Zero-Coupon Bonds (Pure Discount Bonds) By Eq. (1) on p. 23, the price of a zero-coupon bond that pays F dollars in n periods is where r is the interest rate per period. F/(1 + r) n, (9) Can be used to

More information

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

Oil Monopoly and the Climate Oil Monopoly the Climate By John Hassler, Per rusell, Conny Olovsson I Introduction This paper takes as given that (i) the burning of fossil fuel increases the carbon dioxide content in the atmosphere,

More information

Lags in the Transmission of Inflation: Some Preliminary Estimates

Lags in the Transmission of Inflation: Some Preliminary Estimates Lags in the Transmission of Inflation: Some Preliminary Estimates PATRICK T. GEARY* Precis: This paper provides some preliminary estimates of the structure of the lags in the relationships between the

More information

Statistics 431 Spring 2007 P. Shaman. Preliminaries

Statistics 431 Spring 2007 P. Shaman. Preliminaries Statistics 4 Spring 007 P. Shaman The Binomial Distribution Preliminaries A binomial experiment is defined by the following conditions: A sequence of n trials is conducted, with each trial having two possible

More information

Measuring Interest Rates

Measuring Interest Rates Measuring Interest Rates Economics 301: Money and Banking 1 1.1 Goals Goals and Learning Outcomes Goals: Learn to compute present values, rates of return, rates of return. Learning Outcomes: LO3: Predict

More information

Tables of discount factors and annuity factors are provided in the appendix at the end of the paper.

Tables of discount factors and annuity factors are provided in the appendix at the end of the paper. UNIVERSITY OF EAST ANGLIA Norwich Business School Main Series UG Examination 2016-17 BUSINESS FINANCE NBS-5008Y Time allowed: 3 hours Answer FOUR questions out of six ALL questions carry EQUAL marks Tables

More information

The Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting

The Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting The Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting The Conceptual Framework was issued by the IASB in September 2010. It superseded the Framework for the Preparation and Presentation of Financial Statements.

More information

The following points highlight the three time-adjusted or discounted methods of capital budgeting, i.e., 1. Net Present Value

The following points highlight the three time-adjusted or discounted methods of capital budgeting, i.e., 1. Net Present Value Discounted Methods of Capital Budgeting Financial Analysis The following points highlight the three time-adjusted or discounted methods of capital budgeting, i.e., 1. Net Present Value Method 2. Internal

More information

12.3 Geometric Series

12.3 Geometric Series Name Class Date 12.3 Geometric Series Essential Question: How do you find the sum of a finite geometric series? Explore 1 Investigating a Geometric Series A series is the expression formed by adding the

More information

1.1 Interest rates Time value of money

1.1 Interest rates Time value of money Lecture 1 Pre- Derivatives Basics Stocks and bonds are referred to as underlying basic assets in financial markets. Nowadays, more and more derivatives are constructed and traded whose payoffs depend on

More information

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice

Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice Lecture 3: Factor models in modern portfolio choice Prof. Massimo Guidolin Portfolio Management Spring 2016 Overview The inputs of portfolio problems Using the single index model Multi-index models Portfolio

More information

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium 2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium Partial equilibrium tax incidence misses out on a lot of important aspects of economic activity. Among those aspects : markets are interrelated, so that prices of

More information

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Problem Set 2: Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Exercise 2.1: An infinite horizon problem with perfect foresight In this exercise we will study at a discrete-time version of Ramsey

More information

USO cost allocation rules and welfare

USO cost allocation rules and welfare USO cost allocation rules and welfare Andreas Haller Christian Jaag Urs Trinkner Swiss Economics Working Paper 0049 August 2014 ISSN 1664-333X Presented at the 22 nd Conference on Postal and Delivery Economics,

More information

Reply to the Second Referee Thank you very much for your constructive and thorough evaluation of my note, and for your time and attention.

Reply to the Second Referee Thank you very much for your constructive and thorough evaluation of my note, and for your time and attention. Reply to the Second Referee Thank you very much for your constructive and thorough evaluation of my note, and for your time and attention. I appreciate that you checked the algebra and, apart from the

More information

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005 Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation Practice Problems (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005 {This posting has more information than is needed for the corporate

More information

Examiner s report F9 Financial Management March 2016

Examiner s report F9 Financial Management March 2016 Examiner s report F9 Financial Management March 2016 Introduction The overall performance at the March 2016 diet could have been better, although there were some excellent individual performances. General

More information

Enhancing Singapore s Pension Scheme: A Blueprint for Further Flexibility

Enhancing Singapore s Pension Scheme: A Blueprint for Further Flexibility Article Enhancing Singapore s Pension Scheme: A Blueprint for Further Flexibility Koon-Shing Kwong 1, Yiu-Kuen Tse 1 and Wai-Sum Chan 2, * 1 School of Economics, Singapore Management University, Singapore

More information

Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures. Board of the International Organization of Securities Commissions. Technical Guidance

Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures. Board of the International Organization of Securities Commissions. Technical Guidance Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures Board of the International Organization of Securities Commissions Technical Guidance Harmonisation of the Unique Transaction Identifier February 2017 This

More information

3. Time value of money. We will review some tools for discounting cash flows.

3. Time value of money. We will review some tools for discounting cash flows. 1 3. Time value of money We will review some tools for discounting cash flows. Simple interest 2 With simple interest, the amount earned each period is always the same: i = rp o where i = interest earned

More information

What is the impact of ORR s inflation proposals on Network Rail?

What is the impact of ORR s inflation proposals on Network Rail? What is the impact of ORR s inflation proposals on Network Rail? Note prepared for Network Rail September 3rd 2012 1 Introduction and summary There is a well-established precedent for using some form of

More information