We consider a newsvendor who dynamically updates her forecast of the market demand over a finite

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "We consider a newsvendor who dynamically updates her forecast of the market demand over a finite"

Transcription

1 MANUFACTURING & SERVICE OPERATIONS MANAGEMENT Vol. 14, No. 3, Summer 2012, pp ISSN (print) ISSN (online) INFORMS A Multiordering Newsvendor Model with Dynamic Forecast Evolution Tong Wang NUS Business School, National University of Singapore, Singapore , tong.wang@nus.edu.sg Atalay Atasu College of Management, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia 30308, atalay.atasu@mgt.gatech.edu Mümin Kurtuluş Owen Graduate School of Management, Vanderbilt University, Nashville, Tennessee 37203, mumin.kurtulus@owen.vanderbilt.edu We consider a newsvendor who dynamically updates her forecast of the market demand over a finite planning horizon. The forecast evolves according to the martingale model of forecast evolution (MMFE). The newsvendor can place multiple orders with increasing ordering cost over time to satisfy demand that realizes at the end of the planning horizon. In this context, we explore the trade-off between improving demand forecast and increasing ordering cost. We show that the optimal ordering policy is a state-dependent base-stock policy and analytically characterize that the base-stock level depends on the information state in a linear (loglinear) fashion for additive (multiplicative) MMFE. We also study a benchmark model where the newsvendor is restricted to order only once. By comparing the multiordering and single-ordering models, we quantify the impact of the multiordering strategy on the newsvendor s expected profit and risk exposure. Key words: newsvendor; MMFE; forecast evolution; dynamic ordering History: Received: April 2, 2010; accepted: January 27, Published online in Articles in Advance May 4, Introduction Creative businesses, such as those in toy and fashion industries, have difficulty matching supply and demand due to high demand uncertainty, long supply lead times, and short selling seasons. Firms commit to orders well in advance of the selling season (e.g., up to nine months in the apparel industry) in face of high uncertainty as initial demand forecasts available for planning are highly inaccurate due to the unpredictable nature of customer preferences and constantly changing market trends (Fisher et al. 1994, Boyaci and Özer 2010, Wang and Tomlin 2009). At the same time, new information about demand gradually becomes available and the uncertainty resolves as the selling season approaches. To take advantage of more accurate demand information, firms may need to postpone their order commitment until closer to the selling season. This requires the use of more flexible production technologies and facilities or more responsive suppliers, which are often more expensive. As such, many apparel (Agrawal et al. 2002) and toy (Wong et al. 2005) companies respond to constantly evolving market information by ordering from a portfolio of sources that differ in lead times and costs. In this context, an optimally designed portfolio of early and late orders may help achieve better operational performance. This research studies a multiordering strategy for a firm that sells a seasonal product. We formulate a dynamic newsvendor model. The newsvendor has multiple opportunities to place orders at different times before the demand is realized. Multiple ordering options can be found in several practical contexts: it can be that the newsvendor sources from multiple suppliers that require different lead times and costs (Yan et al. 2003); or that the newsvendor produces inhouse using multiple technologies with different costs and lead times (Donohue 2000); or that the newsvendor orders from a single supplier offering a menu of advance purchase discounts (Tang et al. 2004). Early orders are cheaper but are exposed to higher demand uncertainty, and late orders incur cost premiums. To reduce demand uncertainty, the newsvendor constantly updates her demand forecast based on market information observed over time, before demand is realized. The information can be expert estimates (Fisher and Raman 1996), market research reports (Donohue 2000), retail test results (Fisher and Rajaram 2000), etc., which are valuable in forecasting the final demand. To model such demand information and 472

2 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 14(3), pp , 2012 INFORMS 473 forecast evolution process, we adopt the martingale model of forecast evolution (MMFE) developed by Hausman (1969), Graves et al. (1986), and Heath and Jackson (1994), which is also a special case of the generalized MMFE by Oh and Özer (2012) for a single forecaster. Observing an evolving demand forecast, the newsvendor dynamically decides on the order quantity at each possible ordering opportunity. In this setting, we explore the trade-off between increasing ordering cost and improving demand information. We provide a complete characterization of the optimal ordering policy. We show that the optimal policy is a state-dependent base-stock policy, where the state represents observed market information. Moreover, with additive forecast adjustments, there is a simple linear relationship between the optimal basestock level and the information state: the base-stock level is the sum of updated demand forecast and a safety stock term. Similarly, a log-linear relationship holds in the multiplicative case: logarithm of the base-stock level is a linear function of information state. We demonstrate how the safety stock term captures the trade-off between ordering too early and too late, in addition to the classic single-period newsvendor trade-off of ordering too much versus too little. We also show that the safety stock term is independent of the forecast evolution. It is characterized by a series of one-dimensional recursive equations, which can be solved off-line. This finding substantially simplifies the calculation of the optimal base-stock level and can be generalized for scenarios with fixed ordering costs and cancelations (see the online supplement, available at for details). Next, to illustrate the benefits of the multiordering strategy, we consider a benchmark model where the newsvendor is restricted to place a single order. We consider two scenarios. In the static singleordering model, the newsvendor chooses the timing of her order at the beginning of the planning horizon, whereas in the dynamic single-ordering model, the newsvendor decides on her order timing dynamically, based on observed demand information. We find that the newsvendor does not necessarily benefit from making the timing decision dynamically under the single-ordering benchmark. The static and dynamic single-ordering strategies result in the same expected profit under multiplicative MMFE, and the profit difference is marginal under additive MMFE. Finally, we numerically quantify the benefits of the dynamic multiordering strategy by comparing it with the single-ordering benchmark. As expected, the multiordering strategy always yields a higher expected profit. The analysis also suggests that the multiordering strategy is more valuable in boosting profit when (i) demand is highly uncertain, (ii) ordering options differ significantly in their designated order timing, and/or (iii) the ordering options lead to similar expected profits if they are the only source that can be ordered from. Our analysis also illustrates that the profit variability can sometimes be higher under the multiordering strategy, which may not be desirable. A detailed investigation of this phenomenon, however, reveals that the increase in profit variability is driven by the up-side risk, i.e., variability of outcomes with better-than-expected profits. The down-side risk, i.e., outcomes below expected profit, can be mitigated by multiple orders. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. We review the related literature in 2. Model setup and assumptions are described in 3. In 4, we analyze the optimal policies for multiordering and singleordering strategies. A numerical comparison between the two strategies is conducted in 5. In 6, we conclude with a summary of our results. All proofs are provided in the appendix. 2. Literature Review Our research contributes to the literature that incorporates forecast updating into inventory control decisions. This literature can be broadly categorized into two main streams. The first stream studies newsvendor models (i.e., short selling seasons). A series of papers in this stream focus on generating managerial insights by studying stylized models with up to two ordering periods (opportunities). Fisher and Raman (1996) consider a multiproduct capacitated production problem with demand learning from the actual sales in the first period. Gurnani and Tang (1999) analyze the tradeoff between demand uncertainty and purchasing cost uncertainty: although demand uncertainty can be reduced by forecast updating, the purchasing cost becomes uncertain in the second period. Donohue (2000) examines contracting and coordination issues when there is a cheaper production mode and a more expensive but quicker production mode with forecast updating. Özer et al. (2007) study a dual sourcing contract with a forecast update in a similar setting. Erhun et al. (2008) analyze the benefits of information updating and the strategic interactions between a buyer and a seller in a two period model with dynamic pricing and procurement. Yan et al. (2003) focus on the tradeoff between increasing cost and demand uncertainty in a dual-supplier system and present an industry application of the model. Huang et al. (2005) study a problem with costly order adjustment in the second period after obtaining an improved forecast. Our first contribution to this stream of literature is extending these models by (i) modeling a multiperiod forecast evolution by the general MMFE, (ii) allowing for

3 474 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 14(3), pp , 2012 INFORMS multiple ordering opportunities, and (iii) providing an explicit analytical characterization of the optimal order quantity. A number of other papers in this stream consider multiple ordering opportunities. Wang and Tomlin (2009) study a newsvendor that dynamically decides when to place a single order on a continuous time line. They assume a stochastic delivery lead time and model the demand forecast by a multiplicative Markovian forecast revision, which is equivalent to our multiplicative MMFE. They focus on the trade-off between improving demand information and increasing risk of not receiving the delivery on time (the ordering cost is constant in their model). Oh and Özer (2012) propose a generalized MMFE model, which allows asymmetric information to be combined into a forecast evolution, and Boyaci and Özer (2010) study a manufacturer s optimal timing of capacity commitment in a general setting with advance sales information and price dependent demand. In our dynamic single-ordering model, we study a similar optimal stopping problem as in the aforementioned papers but with different trade-offs. In addition, our main focus is on managing a portfolio of multiple ordering options. Another relevant paper in this stream is by Song and Zipken (2009), who study a problem where the initially ordered inventory can be sold off at multiple points in time when partial demand information is revealed. On the contrary, we assume that inventory can be built-up as demand information is revealed over time, and we focus on characterizing the optimal policy. The second stream is concerned with multiperiod inventory models (i.e., long selling horizons with multiple periods) under forecast evolution (Güllü 1997, Graves et al. 1998, Aviv 2001, Toktay and Wein 2001, Iida and Zipkin 2006, Lu et al. 2006, to name a few). This literature incorporates MMFE into inventory/production problems. Our research differs from this stream by incorporating MMFE into a simpler dynamic newsvendor model that only allows demand in the last period. Yet the newsvendor can order in multiple periods in response to the forecast evolution, which preserves the dynamic flavor of the ordering policy. This allows us to explicitly characterize the optimal state-dependent base-stock policy. This characterization is of theoretical significance as it demonstrates the cost-information trade-off in an intuitive and transparent way, and it is of practical interest as the obtained optimal policy is easy to calculate and implement. 3. Model Setup Throughout the paper, we refer to a period as a point on the time line; a period is equivalent to a time epoch. The planning horizon consists of N +1 periods, from 1 to N + 1. The first N periods are ordering periods, representing N ordering options available to the newsvendor at different times. Sales take place instantaneously at the end, in period N + 1, which is also referred to as the selling season. The retail price, denoted by r, is exogenously given. There is no salvage value for unsold inventory, no penalty for unsatisfied demand, and no discounting. Before the selling season, the newsvendor can order the product in periods 1 to N. Let c n be the cost of ordering one unit in period n. We assume 0 < c 1 < c 2 < < c N < r, i.e., it is cheaper to order earlier. Note that otherwise, if there exists c i c i+1 or c i r, period i can be eliminated as the newsvendor would never order in that period. We do not explicitly consider inventory holding costs that might be incurred for the goods ordered; they can be easily embedded into ordering costs. We also note that although we assume no fixed ordering costs and cancelations in our model, our results can be extended to include these under certain conditions (see the online supplement). Market demand D is a random variable and realizes in period N + 1. As market signals unveil gradually over the planning horizon, the demand forecast improves over time. Let D n be the forecast of demand D in period n. We assume that the initial forecast D 1 is given, the final forecast D N +1 is simply the realization of demand D. We model the forecast process D n n 1 N + 1 by the MMFE. We adopt a special case of the MMFE setup from Oh and Özer (2012) who provide a generalized model for multiple forecasters. We also refer the reader to Heath and Jackson (1994), Toktay (1998), and Chen and Lee (2009) for a discussion on the applicability of MMFE in operational problems. We consider both additive and multiplicative MMFE that differ in how forecasts are adjusted. In the additive model (a-mmfe), the demand forecast in period n 2 N + 1 is given by D n D n, where i represents forecast adjustments during period i 2 n. The updates are independent and normally distributed with mean 0 and variance i 2. Let D 1 be the expected demand in period 1 and I n n be the cumulative forecast adjustment up to period n for the a-mmfe case. In the multiplicative model (m-mmfe), the forecast adjustments, i.e., ratios of successive forecasts, are D n /D n 1 exp n, where n is normally distributed with mean n 2/2 and variance n 2. Let log D 1 N +1 i2 i 2 /2 be expectation of the logarithm of demand in period 1 and I n n i2 i + i 2 /2 be the mean-adjusted cumulative forecast adjustment. Then, the estimate of D after observing I n under a-mmfe (respectively, m-mmfe) is normal (log-normal) with

4 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 14(3), pp , 2012 INFORMS 475 parameters + I n n 2, where n 2 N +1 in+1 i 2 represents the residual uncertainty after period n. Both D n and I n are sufficient to represent up-to-date information and describe demand forecast evolution. Accordingly, when we formulate the dynamic program (DP), we use I n instead of D n as the information state in period n. This enables us to represent the additive and the multiplicative cases in the same formulas. 4. Analysis of the Ordering Strategies In this section, we first analyze the dynamic multiordering strategy in 4.1 and establish the structure of the optimal ordering policy. Then, in 4.2, we study a single-ordering strategy, which is used as a benchmark to illustrate the value of placing multiple orders The Multiordering Strategy With this strategy, the newsvendor can order multiple times and replenish the stock level in response to the most up-to-date demand forecast. The newsvendor can spread her orders over the planning horizon to take advantage of lower ordering costs with early orders and more accurate demand forecasts with late orders. We formulate the discrete-time dynamic program as follows. The decision periods are n 1 N. The state variables are x n 1 I n, where x n 1 is the inventory state tracking the total number of units ordered before period n (with x 0 0), and I n is the information state representing the up-to-date information about forecast adjustments (with I 1 0). The decision in period n is Q n, a nonnegative order quantity. The sequence of events in an ordering period are (1) observe I n, (2) update demand forecast, (3) review inventory position x n 1, (4) order Q n and incur cost c n Q n, and (5) raise inventory position to x n x n 1 + Q n. The events in the selling season are (1) demand D is realized, and (2) revenue r mind x N is collected. Let V n be the profit-to-go function at the beginning of period n after observing I n. Then, V n x n 1 I n max x n x n 1 E In+1 I n V n+1 x n I n+1 c n x n x n 1 V N x N 1 I N n 1 N 1 (1) max x N x N 1 E D IN r mind x N c N x N x N 1 (2) The total expected profit is M V We can rewrite (1) and (2) as V n x n 1 I n max x n x n 1 G n x n I n + c n x n 1 n 1 N (3) G n x n I n E In+1 I n V n+1 x n I n+1 c n x n n 1 N 1 (4) G N x N I N E D IN r mind x N c N x N (5) Intuitively, we can see that if the observed information state I n is large, this implies a high demand in the selling season, and the expected profit-to-go V n will increase. (Throughout the paper we use increasing and decreasing in a weak sense, i.e., increasing means nondecreasing.) Also for the ordered inventory x n 1, if it increases, the profit-to-go will also increase, but the marginal benefit of an additional unit of inventory diminishes. Proposition 1. The optimal ordering policy is a statedependent base-stock policy. In each period n, n 1 N, there exists an optimal base-stock level S n I n arg max x G n x I n, which is a function of the current information state I n. Proposition 1 states that the newsvendor should raise the inventory position up to the threshold S n I n if the inventory position is below this threshold. This threshold depends on the updated forecast through I n and is given by a function S n I n. This is an established result, and is consistent with the policy structures that can be found in both streams of research reviewed in 2. This result extends the two-period model in Özer et al. (2007) to multiple periods under MMFE, and is similar to the policy structures in the multiperiod inventory models in Burnetas and Gilbert (2001) and Iida and Zipkin (2006). However, although one can solve the two-dimensional dynamic program numerically and find the optimal base-stock level in each period for any given I n, this could be computationally intensive. In Proposition 2, we analytically show that S n I n is a linear (log-linear) function of I n for a-mmfe (m-mmfe), and further characterize the linear (log-linear) relationship. This result simplifies the calculation of the base-stock levels. Proposition 2. Under a-mmfe, the optimal basestock level for period n, S n I n, n 1 N, is a linear function of I n, and can be written as S n I n + I n + b n. The constant b n is the solution to g n y n 0, where the function g n is given by g n y n yn b n+1 / n+1 g n+1 y n n+1 d+c n+1 c n (6) ( ) yn g N y N r c N (7) N +1 Here is the standard normal cumulative distribution function (c.d.f.), and x 1 x. Under m-mmfe, the optimal base-stock level S n I n is a log-linear function of I n, and can be written as S n I n exp + I n + b n, where b n is also defined by (6) and (7).

5 476 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 14(3), pp , 2012 INFORMS The detailed proof of the above proposition is provided in the appendix. Here we sketch the proof (for a-mmfe) and discuss the key findings. Because by definition, S n I n maximizes G n I n, we check the first-order derivative of G n I n, which is of the following recursive form (n 1 N 1): G n x n I n x n n+1 G n+1 x n+1 I n + n+1 df x n+1 n+1 n+1 xn+1 x n + c n+1 c n (8) Here n+1 I n+1 I n, which follows N0 2 n+1, F n+1 is the c.d.f. of n+1, and n+1 (as a function of x n and I n ) is the threshold such that in period n + 1, the orderup-to level S n+1 I n + n+1 is less than x n if n+1 n+1, or equivalently, nothing should be ordered in n + 1 if the forecast adjustment n+1 is below the threshold. We note that the problem in the last period reduces to the standard newsvendor problem, and Equation (7) is the first-order condition of the standard problem. Expanding the recursive Equation (8), we can write G n x n I n x n c n + c n+1 P n c N P N + rp (9) where P i, i n + 1 N is the probability that after period n, the next order is placed in period i; and P is the probability that no order is placed in all the remaining periods n + 1 N and the realized demand turns out to be larger than x n. These probabilities depend on x n and I n, and computing these probabilities involves integrals and is nontrivial. Nevertheless, Equation (9) can be interpreted as being equivalent to the first-order condition in the traditional newsvendor model. In particular, if the newsvendor raises x n by one unit, then she (i) incurs an immediate ordering cost c n ; (ii) saves c n+1 if that unit was to be ordered in n+1 (with probability P n+1 ), or c n+2 if the unit was to be ordered in n + 2 (with probability P n+2 ), and so on; and (iii) collects additional revenue r if no order is placed in n + 1 N and the realized demand is larger than x n (with probability P). Note that (i) and (iii) correspond to the standard overage and underage costs in the traditional newsvendor model, and in our model, we have an extra underage cost (ii), which is the loss due to postponing orders. The optimal base-stock level is chosen to balance the overage cost (i) and the expected underage cost (ii) and (iii). Although G n is defined on the two-dimensional state space x n I n, it turns out (see the proof in the appendix) that the partial derivative G n /x n (or say probabilities P i and P in (9)) depends only on y n x n I n and can be written as g n y n defined in (6) and (7). Let b n be the optimal value of y n such that the partial derivative is equal to 0, which exists and is unique. Then yn b n implies xn I n b n. Thus, the optimal base-stock level S n I n + I n + b n is linear in I n. The significance of Proposition 2 is twofold. First, from a computational perspective, it shows that the impact of forecast adjustments on the base-stock level is all captured by the term I n in a linear fashion, whereas b n is static and is independent of I n and the forecast evolution. It is solely determined by a set of one-dimensional recursive Equations (6) and (7), which can be solved off-line. In each period, after observing I n, the newsvendor can find the optimal base-stock level by calculating + I n + b n, instead of inputting I n into the model and re-solving the twodimensional DP. This substantially simplifies the process of searching for the optimal base-stock level. We note that similar forms of linear state dependence has been assumed by a number of papers in the multiperiod inventory models literature. For instance, Chen and Lee (2009) define an affine and stationary base-stock policy for their infinite horizon problem; Schoenmeyr and Graves (2009) assume linearity when constructing the forecast-based ordering policy, and Toktay and Wein (2001) restrict their analysis to linear policies motivated by material requirements planning logic. Proposition 2, however, not only proves the linearity of the base-stock level for our setting with a finite horizon and increasing costs, but also explicitly characterizes the slope and intercept. Second, this result extends the trade-off between overage and underage costs in the traditional news vendor model. Recall that in the traditional newsvendor model with normal demand, the optimal order quantity is mean demand plus a safety stock term. The safety stock level depends on demand uncertainty and overage/underage costs (see (10) in 4.2.1). Proposition 2 shows a similar relationship: in each period n, the optimal base-stock level can also be written as the last-updated demand forecast + I n plus a safety stock term b n. The meaning of b n here is richer as it captures not only the impact of future demand uncertainty and overage/underage concerns but also the intertemporal trade-off between ordering too early and too late (see Wang and Tomlin 2009 for a similar discussion in a single-ordering setting). Corollary 1 summarizes some properties of the safety stock term b n. Everything else being equal, the newsvendor should stock more if it is cheaper to buy in period n, or if it is more expensive to buy later, or if the selling price is higher. Furthermore, the optimal safety stock level is always lower than the myopic safety stock level (ˆb n ) that neglects future ordering opportunities (or equivalently, the safety stock level for the single order model in the following section defined by Equation (10)).

6 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 14(3), pp , 2012 INFORMS 477 Corollary 1. The safety stock term b n is independent of c 1 c n 1, decreasing in c n, and increasing in c n+1 c N, and r, for all n 1 N. Furthermore, let ˆb n be the myopic safety stock level when future ordering opportunities are neglected, then b n ˆb n The Single-Ordering Strategy To evaluate the benefits the of multiordering strategy, we next consider a benchmark model where the newsvendor is restricted to place a single order. She can still acquire market information and update her forecast as before. In this context, there are two decisions for the newsvendor to make: (1) timing when to place the single order, and (2) quantity how much to order (for similar discussions, see Milner and Kouvelis 2005, Oh and Özer 2012, Boyaci and Özer 2010). Depending on how the timing decision is made, there are two possible models: static and dynamic The Static Policy. The newsvendor chooses the time to order statically at the beginning of the planning horizon. The quantity decision is delayed until the chosen period, i.e., if she is to order in period n, she waits until period n to decide the order quantity. By then, she will have observed I n and updated the demand forecast accordingly. The optimal policy is as follows. Proposition 3. If the newsvendor decides to order in period n, where Z n 1 1 c n /r, the optimal order quantity and the corresponding expected profit are given by + I n + n Z S n I n a-mmf E n exp + I n + n Z n m-mmf E n 1 N (10) r c n + I n r n Z n a-mmf E n I n r exp + I n + n 2 /2 n Z n m-mmf E n 1 N (11) Let N +1 0 be a dummy option standing for not ordering in any period. The optimal profit of the static single-ordering model is Ss max n1n +1 E n I n, and the optimal timing is n arg max n1n +1 E n I n The Dynamic Policy. Under this policy, the time to order is contingent on the observed information. The newsvendor observes the forecast evolution process and decides on the timing and quantity of the single order dynamically. In other words, the newsvendor not only enjoys quantity flexibility but also timing flexibility. This is an optimal stopping problem. In any period n (if she has not ordered yet), after observing I n, the newsvendor faces two options: to wait or to order. If she chooses to wait, nothing happens in n and she moves on to the next period. The payoff will be the expected profit if the order is placed later, conditional on I n. If she chooses to order, then she determines the order quantity according to (10) and collects her profit as in (11), both of which are functions of I n. Let W n I n be the optimal profit-to-go given that the observed information is I n and that the newsvendor has not yet ordered in periods 1 2 n 1. We can write the DP as W n I n maxew n+1 I n+1 I n n I n n 1 2 N (12) W N +1 I N +1 0 (13) As before, period N + 1 is the dummy option of not ordering anything. The optimal profit of the dynamic single-ordering model Sd W 1 0. Proposition 4 characterizes the optimal policy for the a-mmfe case and establishes the equivalence of the expected profits in static and dynamic single-ordering models for the m-mmfe. Proposition 4. For a-mmfe, the optimal order policy is a threshold policy. In each period n, there exists a threshold Ĩ n such that the newsvendor should wait if I n < Ĩ n, otherwise she should order the quantity given in (10). The resulting expected profit is larger than that of the static single-ordering strategy, i.e., Sd Ss. For m-mmfe, the order timing decision is independent of I n, so the dynamic single-ordering strategy reduces to the static strategy and leads to the same expected profit, i.e., Sd Ss. The dynamic single-ordering problem is of similar flavor to Wang and Tomlin (2009) and Boyaci and Özer (2010), and is a special case of Oh and Özer (2012), who study an optimal stopping problem with a generalized MMFE model that allows asymmetric demand information from multiple parties to be combined into a forecast evolution. The threshold policy obtained in Proposition 4 is a special case of the control band policies studied in Oh and Özer (2012) and Boyaci and Özer (2010) as well. The second part of Proposition 4 shows that the optimal policy boils down to a state-independent policy and that the static and dynamic single-order strategies are equivalent under m-mmfe. Oh and Özer (2012) also show, under different conditions, the optimality of static ordering strategy for their capacity planning problem. We note that although one would expect additional benefits from timing flexibility in the dynamic singleordering model, in our setting it is only true for

7 478 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 14(3), pp , 2012 INFORMS the a-mmfe case but not for m-mmfe. Three key observations help us build an intuitive explanation of this result in hindsight. First, although the demand forecast evolves randomly, the change of the key trade-off between decreasing uncertainty and increasing ordering cost is deterministic. Second, because of the martingale nature of the demand process, the expectation of the future is equal to the current state. Third, which is specific for m-mmfe, the effect of forecast evolution (the term exp + I n + n 2 /2 in Equation (11)) and the effect of cost-uncertainty tradeoff (the term n Z n in Equation (11)) are nicely decoupled such that the optimal timing decision is independent of the forecast evolution. 5. Numerical Comparison of the Ordering Strategies In this section, we conduct numerical experiments to investigate the benefits of dynamic decision making and multiple orders similarly to Erhun et al. (2008). We provide insights on how uncertainty reduction, time span, and cost differentials between procurement options affect the benefits of multiple orders. We run two sets of experiments for a-mmfe and m-mmfe, respectively. We consider a continuous time line starting at time t 0 and ending at t 1. The selling season (period N + 1) takes place at t 1. There are three ordering opportunities (N 3), and ordering period n, n 1 3, is located at t n on the time line. We fix t 1 0, i.e., the first ordering period is at time 0. The other periods are evenly spaced within the range from 0 to T, i.e., t 2 T /2, t 3 T. The last possible ordering point, T, takes values Ordering cost in period n is given by c n 1+n 1, where captures the magnitude of cost difference between order options and takes values The retail price is fixed at r 2. Initial demand information is fixed at 1, and, the parameter capturing overall market uncertainty, takes values for a-mmfe and for m-mmfe. We let the uncertainty diminish linearly over time, i.e., 2 n t n t n 1 2, and residual uncertainty is given by 2 n 1 t n 2. Under a-mmfe (m-mmfe), this linear reduction in uncertainty is equivalent to assuming that forecast evolves according to a Brownian (geometric Brownian) motion. With this parameter set, we have 540 scenarios for both models. For each scenario, we first calculate the optimal ordering policies by applying the results from the previous section, then simulate 10,000,000 sample paths of forecast evolution, evaluate performance of the optimal policies obtained from the single-ordering and multiordering strategies under each sample path, and summarize the differences Comparison of Expected Profits We first compare the expected profits under static and dynamic single-ordering strategies, Ss and Sd, under a-mmfe. Define the profit gap between the two strategies as Sd Ss / Ss 100%. The gap represents the benefit of dynamic order timing in the single-ordering model. Our numerical result suggests that the benefit is marginal: among the 540 scenarios, the gap ranges from 0% to 0.084%, with an average being less than 0.001%. This observation, combined with the m-mmfe result in Proposition 4, leads to an important insight: being dynamic and being able to incorporate real-time forecast evolution into the order timing decision does not help much if the newsvendor is restricted to order only once. On the other hand, the newsvendor can obtain significant benefits when a dynamic policy is coupled with the flexibility of placing multiple orders, that is, when she adopts the dynamic multiordering strategy. Hence, we next compare the expected profits under single-ordering and multiordering strategies. Hereafter, single-ordering strategy means the static single-ordering strategy, unless explicitly noted. Define the profit gap between the two strategies as M Ss / Ss 100%. This gap is always nonnegative as the multiordering strategy is at least as good as the static single-ordering strategy (Table 1 reports the minimum, maximum, and average of among the scenarios studied). We are also interested in understanding how the profit gap is affected by our model parameters:, T, and. These parameters capture the magnitude of market uncertainty, time span of ordering options, and cost differences, respectively. Figure 1 illustrates the average profit gaps subtotaled with regard to the three parameters for a-mmfe (with the graphs being very similar for m-mmfe). For example, among a total of 540 scenarios of a-mmfe, Table 1 Statistics of the Gaps in Expected Profit, Vairance, Semivariances, and Coefficient of Variation a-mmfe m-mmfe (%) Var (%) CV (%) Var (%) Var + (%) (%) Var (%) CV (%) Var (%) Var + (%) Min Max Average

8 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 14(3), pp , 2012 INFORMS 479 Figure 1 Comparison of the Expected Profits Between the Multiordering and Static Single-Ordering Strategies: a-mmfe Π (%) T are with T 01, 60 are with T 02, and so on. Profit gaps are averaged within the nine subcategories for the nine values of T, and the average gaps are plotted in the second graph of Figure 1. The plots in Figure 1 reveal several interesting patterns. First, the profit gap is larger when market demand is more uncertain. This is intuitive as the multiordering strategy provides extra flexibility for the newsvendor to respond to unexpected market conditions. Second, the profit gap is increasing in T. When T is large, ordering options are spread out on the time line. Having a portfolio of spread out ordering options helps the newsvendor take advantage of the low-cost of early orders and low-uncertainty of late orders. Finally, for parameter, the profit gap appears to be first increasing and then decreasing. When is very low (high), the cost increases slowly (quickly), thus it will be optimal for the newsvendor to order all at once in the very last (first) period. Therefore, toward the two extremes, benefits of multiordering strategy diminish. A more interesting question is at what value of the newsvendor can expect the most benefit from the multiordering strategy. A further detailed numerical analysis (available from the authors) reveals that benefits from the multiordering strategy ( ) peaks when is at a moderate level such that ordering solely from any of the three options would lead to roughly the same expected profit. In other words, when ordering options are similar in terms of their expected profits when considered individually, dynamic ordering from the portfolio is most valuable. It can also be shown that the benefit of multiordering strategy is increasing and concave in the number of ordering opportunities N : the marginal benefit of one more ordering opportunity is diminishing Comparison of Profit Variability Next, we study the profit variability gap, which is defined as Var Var M Var Ss /Var Ss 100% Although there are scenarios with negative gaps of profit variability (i.e., the multiordering strategy reduces profit variability), there are also scenarios with a positive profit variability gap, suggesting that multiordering strategy can accentuate profit variability. Even in terms of coefficient of variation (reported under the column CV in Table 1), results are mixed (though on average, the CV under multiordering is lower). This may not sound appealing at first. One possible explanation is that compared to the static single-ordering strategy, the multiordering strategy is capable of adapting to market changes better, so its profit is more closely pegged to market condition and fluctuates more as the market demand varies. To understand this, we investigate the corresponding semi-variances (Markowitz 1959, Jin et al. 2006). Clearly, for the newsvendor s profit considered in this paper, high upside semivariance is preferable whereas high downside semivariance is not. An examination of semivariances (also reported in Table 1 under columns Var and Var +) reveals that on average, the multiordering strategy helps boost the more preferable upside semivariance, which reflects a superior match of supply and demand, and mitigate the downside semivariance, which is a more accurate measure of the newsvendor s risk exposure. The fact that the multiordering strategy results in higher upside semivariances and lower downside semivariance on the average suggests that the multiordering strategy can also reduce the newsvendor s risk exposure. 6. Summary of Results and Conclusion The analytical model presented in this paper extends the traditional newsvendor model by incorporating dynamic forecast evolution (the MMFE model) and multiple ordering opportunities with increasing

9 480 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 14(3), pp , 2012 INFORMS ordering costs to solve a practical operational problem. Our main contribution is identifying the optimal ordering policy and its structural properties when firms face short selling seasons and multiple ordering opportunities from a variety of sources with different costs and order timing requirements. The significance of our work lies in the analytical characterization of the linear/log-linear structure of the state-dependent base-stock policy, which allows for a simple way to find and implement the optimal ordering policy in a general setting. From a practical point of view, the explicit analytical form of the optimal policy we identify makes it easy for it to be built into decision support systems. We also note that these structural results can be extended to allow order cancelations and fixed ordering costs under certain conditions (see the online supplement). This analysis also helps improve our understanding of the cost-information trade-off in our context. Although the forecast evolves stochastically, the cost increases and the uncertainty diminishes in a deterministic manner. We demonstrate that a safety stock term, which is independent of the forecast evolution, is sufficient to capture the trade-off between ordering too early and too late, in addition to the classic singleperiod newsvendor trade-off of ordering too much versus too little. The single-ordering model sheds light on when dynamic order timing based on forecast evolution is valuable. We find that a dynamic order timing decision does not necessarily increase the expected profit if the newsvendor orders only once. Making the single-order timing choice statically at the beginning of the horizon without being contingent on the particular realization of forecast evolution leads to a negligible loss (if any) in expected profit relative to the dynamic single-ordering strategy. However, when a portfolio of ordering options are available (as in our multiordering model), dynamic ordering based on forecast evolution is significantly more valuable in boosting profit. The numerical analysis quantifies the value of the multiordering strategy relative to the singleordering strategy. Understanding the magnitude and the drivers of the profit difference between the two models helps us identify the operating conditions where the multiordering strategy can be most valuable. In particular, we find that multiple orders are most valuable when the market is highly uncertain, the ordering options are widely spread on the time line, and when no option clearly dominates others if they are considered individually. Our analysis on profit variability also leads to an important insight from a risk management perspective. Although the multiordering strategy may seem riskier (as it is likely to augment overall profit variability), this risk may not necessarily be bad. The analysis on semivariances reveals that the multiordering strategy helps reduce down-side risk and boost up-side variability. Electronic Companion An electronic companion to this paper is available as part of the online version that can be found at Acknowledgments The authors thank Nils Rudi, Beril Toktay, and Ilia Tsetlin for comments on an earlier version of this paper. The authors also thank Stephen Graves, the anonymous associate editor, and three reviewers for their constructive suggestions. The first author s research was supported in part by National University of Singapore s academic research [Grants R , R ]. Appendix. Omitted Proofs Proof of Proposition 1. First we show that G n x n I n is increasing in I n and concave in x n ; V n x n 1 I n is increasing in I n and x n 1 and concave in x n 1 for all n 1 N. Note the fact that the demand estimate D I n is stochastically increasing in I n. For a-mmfe, it is straightforward as D I n is N + I n n 2, whereas for m-mmfe, D I n LogN + I n n 2. The following result in Levy (1973) is sufficient to complete the proof of this part: Let X 1 and X 2 be two log-normally distributed random variables with parameters and 2 2 2, respectively. Random variable X 1 stochastically dominates X 2 in a first-order sense if and only if 1 > 2 and We can then prove the monotonicities of G n and V n with regard to I n. Consider G N. Demand estimate D I N is stochastically increasing in I N because of the abovementioned result. Because mind x N is an increasing function of D, E D IN r mind x N is increasing in I N, so is G N. Then it follows that V N is increasing in I N. Now suppose V n+1 is increasing in I n+1, then G n is increasing in I n because I n+1 I n is stochastically increasing in I n. In the end we have that V n is increasing in I n, which completes the induction argument. Next, we prove the properties with regard to x by induction. It is obvious that G N I N is concave. Moreover, G N /x N goes from r c N to c N. Letting S N I N be the global maximizer of G N I N, we know that V N x N 1 I N max G N x N I N + c N x N 1 x N x N 1 G N S N I N I N + c N x N 1 if x N 1 < S N I N G N x N 1 I N + c N x N 1 if x N 1 S N I N is continuous, increasing, and concave in x N 1 for any I N. Now it is straightforward to show G N 1 I N 1, which is equal to EV N plus a linear term, is concave, and the derivative goes from c N c N 1 to c N 1 monotonically. Applying the argument to periods N 1 N 2 1, we are able to show that all the G n I n s are concave and all the V n I n s are increasing and concave. Finally, a base-stock policy is optimal because function G n, n 1 N is concave in x n for any given I n and has

10 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 14(3), pp , 2012 INFORMS 481 an internal maximum. The optimal base-stock level S n I n is given by S n I n arg max x G n x I n. Proof of Proposition 2. The a-mmfe Case. The proof is by induction. First, in period N with I N being observed, the problem reduces to single-period newsvendor problem with overage cost c N, underage cost r c N and the demand being normal with mean and variance + I N N The optimal stock level is S N +I N + N +1 Z N, where N r c N /r is the critical fractile and Z 1 is the associated z-value. Leting b N N +1 Z N, we can write S N + I N + b N. Moreover, G N x N I N /x N rf N x N c N r x N I N / N +1 c N, where F N is the normal c.d.f. of D I N and is the c.d.f. of standard normal random variable. This implies that the first-order derivative is actually a function of y N x N I N. So, it can be written as g N y N g N x N I N G N x N I N /x N, and, by definition, g N b N 0. Suppose in period n + 1, S n+1 I n+1 + I n+1 + b n+1, and G n+1 x n+1 I n+1 /x n+1 only depends on x n+1 I n+1. Similarly, we define g n+1 y n+1 g n+1 x n+1 I n+1 G n+1 x n+1 I n+1 /x n+1, and g n+1 b n+1 0. Now consider period n. We need to show what holds in n + 1 also holds in n. Recall that V n+1 x n I n+1 max G n+1 x n+1 I n+1 + c n+1 x n x n+1 x n G n+1 I n+1 + c n+1 x n if x n < S n+1 I n+1 G n+1 x n I n+1 + c n+1 x n if x n S n+1 I n+1 where G n+1 I n+1 G n+1 S n+1 I n+1 I n+1. Note that n+1 I n+1 I n N0 2 n+1. Substitute into G nx n I n, G n x n I n E In+1 I n V n+1 x n I n+1 c n x n E n+1 V n+1 x n I n + n+1 c n x n n+1 G n+1 I n + n+1 df n+1 n+1 + n+1 + c n+1 c n x n G n+1 x n I n + n+1 df n+1 n+1 where n+1 is defined such that S n+1 I n + n+1 x n (so it is a function of x n and I n, or more precisely, n+1 x n I n b n+1 ), and F n+1 is the c.d.f. of n+1. Since S n I n maximizes G n I n, we need to check the first-order derivative: G n x n I n x n n+1 G n+1 x n+1 I n + n+1 x x n+1 x n df n+1 n+1 + c n+1 c n n+1 xn I n b n+1 xn I n b n+1 / n+1 g n+1 x n I n n+1 df n+1 n+1 +c n+1 c n g n+1 x n I n n+1 d+c n+1 c n Now it is clear that the derivative depends only on x n I n. We can write the derivative as a function of y n x n I n, i.e., g n y n yn b n+1 / n+1 g n+1 y n n+1 d + c n+1 c n Let b n be the solution to g n y n 0 (such a b n must exist because it can be checked recursively that g n y n, n 1 N 1, goes from c n+1 c n to c n continuously and monotonically as y n goes from to ), then, by definition, the optimal base-stock level is such that S n I n yn b n, or equivalently S n + I n + b n, which completes the induction argument. The m-mmfe Case. Proof for the m-mmfe case follows the same logic. Below we highlight the differences. In period N with I N being observed, the demand is lognormal with parameters + I N N Therefore, the optimal stock level is S N exp + I N + b N, and G N x N I N x N ( rf log xn I N x N c N r N N +1 ) c N The first-order derivative is actually a function of y N log x N I N. So it can be written as g N y N g N log x N I N G N x N I N x N Suppose in period n + 1, S n+1 I n+1 exp + I n+1 + b n+1, and G n+1 x n+1 I n+1 /x n+1 only depends on log x n+1 I n+1. Let n+1 I n+1 I n n+1 + n+1 2 /2, which follows N0 n+1 2. Also let n+1 log x n I n b n+1 be the threshold such that S n+1 I n + n+1 x n. Then G n x n I n x n n+1 G n+1 x n I n + n+1 df x n+1 n+1 + c n+1 c n n log xn I n b n+1 + c n+1 c n logxn I n b n+1 / n+1 + c n+1 c n g n+1 log x n I n n+1 df n+1 n+1 g n+1 logx n I n n+1 d Now it is clear that the derivative depends only on y n log x n I n. Let b n be the solution to g n y n 0, then, by definition, the optimal base-stock level is such that log S n I n y n b n, or equivalently S n exp + I n + b n, which completes the induction argument. Proof of Corollary 1. We first prove the monotonicity by induction. Consider period N. By definition, g N b N r b N / N +1 c N 0. It is easy to see that g N is independent of c 1 c N 1. In addition, we can verify ( ) ( ) bn bn < 0 > 0 and g N r b N N +1 N +1 g N r g N 1 < 0 c N By the implicit function theorem, we have N +1 b N r g / N gn > 0 and b N g / N gn < 0 r b N c N c N b N

11 482 Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 14(3), pp , 2012 INFORMS Now suppose in period n + 1, g n+1 is independent of c 1 c n and g n+1 /b n+1 < 0, g n+1 /r > 0, g n+1 / c n+1 1. Then in period n, g n b n bn b n+1 / n+1 g n+1 b n n+1 d + c n+1 c n 0 It is clear that g n is independent of c 1 c n 1 and g n b n bn b n+1 / n+1 b n g n+1 b n n+1 d < 0 g bn bn+1/n+1 n r r g n+1b n n+1 d > 0 g n 1 < 0 c n g bn b n+1 / n+1 n g c n+1 c n+1 b n n+1 d + 1 > 0 n+1 In addition, the last inequality implies, for k 2 N n, g n c n+k bn b n+1 / n+1 c n+k g n+1 b n n+1 d > 0 We can then apply the implicit function theorem and complete the proof. With the result above, the proof of b n ˆb n follows directly. In any period n with I n being observed, b n is determined by (6) and (7). The myopic safety stock level ˆb n is essentially the optimal b n obtained with parameters c n+1 c n+2 c N all being augmented to be equal to r hence, future ordering options have no value. From the monotonicity result above, we know that b n is increasing in c n+1 c n+2 c N ; hence, b n ˆb n. Proof of Proposition 3. For a given order period n, the newsvendor decides on the order quantity after observing I n to maximize the expected profit n S n I n E D In r mind S n c n S n, where the demand estimate D I n follows N + I n n 2 for a-mmfe (or LogN + I n n 2 for m-mmfe). This is a typical newsvendor problem. The optimal order quantity is given by + I n + n Z S n I n (a-mmfe) n exp + I n + n Z n (m-mmfe) Substituting the optimal order quantity back into the profit function, we have the newsvendor s optimal profit if the order is made in period n and the realized forecast adjustment is I n : r c n + I n r n Z n I n (a-mmfe) n r exp + I n + n 2/2 n Z n (m-mmfe) Taking the expectation with respect to I n, we have the expected profit at the beginning of the planning horizon if the newsvendor orders in n. Denote this expected profit by n : n E n I n r c n r n Z n (a-mmfe) r exp + 1 2/2 n Z n (m-mmfe) Let N +1 0 be a dummy option standing for not ordering in any period. Then, the optimal profit of the static singleordering model Ss max n1n +1 n. Proof of Proposition 4. The a-mmfe Case. In any period n, the newsvendor needs to decide whether to wait, which leads to a profit EW n+1 I n+1 I n (the first component in max of W n I n ), or to order, which leads to a profit n I n (the second component in max). According to (11), n I n is linearly increasing in I n with a strictly positive slope r c n. We first show by induction that the following properties hold for n 1 N +1, (1) W n 0, (2) W n is increasing and convex, (3) W n r c n, and (4) lim In W n I n 0. In period N + 1, W N +1 0, so the properties are trivially true. Suppose they are also true in period n + 1, then in period n, W n I n maxew n+1 I n + n+1 n I n maxew n+1 I n + n+1 r c n + I n r n Z n Inside the max, the second component is linearly increasing in I n with a strictly positive slope r c n. Regarding the first component, we know that because of the induction assumptions, W n+1 is nonnegative, increasing and convex, and W n+1 r c n+1. So the expectation EW n+1 I n + n+1 is also nonnegative and increasing and convex in I n with slope being less than or equal to r c n+1. It is then straightforward to verify that W n I n, the maximum of the two components, is (1) nonnegative, (2) increasing and convex, and (3) its slope is less than or equal to r c n. When I n, the first component goes to 0 and the second component goes to. So property (4) also holds. This completes the induction argument. Having the four properties, we can study the optimal stopping policy by investigating the difference between the first and second component. Let Ĩ n be the threshold such that the two components are equal, i.e., EW n+1 I n+1 Ĩ n n Ĩ n 0. By property (4), as I n, the difference EW n+1 I n+1 I n n I n goes to infinity, implying the newsvendor will prefer waiting in extremely bad market condition. Moreover, EW n+1 I n+1 I n n I n I n EW n+1i n+1 I n I n c n c n+1 < 0 n I n I n r c n+1 r c n suggesting that the difference is strictly decreasing in I n, which assures the existence and uniqueness of threshold Ĩ n in period n. It is optimal to order if I n Ĩ n and wait otherwise. Next, we prove Sd Ss. Again, we show by induction that W n I n max in N +1 i I n. It is trivially true for

A Newsvendor Model with Initial Inventory and Two Salvage Opportunities

A Newsvendor Model with Initial Inventory and Two Salvage Opportunities A Newsvendor Model with Initial Inventory and Two Salvage Opportunities Ali CHEAITOU Euromed Management Marseille, 13288, France Christian VAN DELFT HEC School of Management, Paris (GREGHEC) Jouys-en-Josas,

More information

EE266 Homework 5 Solutions

EE266 Homework 5 Solutions EE, Spring 15-1 Professor S. Lall EE Homework 5 Solutions 1. A refined inventory model. In this problem we consider an inventory model that is more refined than the one you ve seen in the lectures. The

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

A Newsvendor Model with Initial Inventory and Two Salvage Opportunities

A Newsvendor Model with Initial Inventory and Two Salvage Opportunities A Newsvendor Model with Initial Inventory and Two Salvage Opportunities Ali Cheaitou Euromed Management Domaine de Luminy BP 921, 13288 Marseille Cedex 9, France Fax +33() 491 827 983 E-mail: ali.cheaitou@euromed-management.com

More information

,,, be any other strategy for selling items. It yields no more revenue than, based on the

,,, be any other strategy for selling items. It yields no more revenue than, based on the ONLINE SUPPLEMENT Appendix 1: Proofs for all Propositions and Corollaries Proof of Proposition 1 Proposition 1: For all 1,2,,, if, is a non-increasing function with respect to (henceforth referred to as

More information

Optimal Inventory Policies with Non-stationary Supply Disruptions and Advance Supply Information

Optimal Inventory Policies with Non-stationary Supply Disruptions and Advance Supply Information Optimal Inventory Policies with Non-stationary Supply Disruptions and Advance Supply Information Bilge Atasoy (TRANSP-OR, EPFL) with Refik Güllü (Boğaziçi University) and Tarkan Tan (TU/e) July 11, 2011

More information

MYOPIC INVENTORY POLICIES USING INDIVIDUAL CUSTOMER ARRIVAL INFORMATION

MYOPIC INVENTORY POLICIES USING INDIVIDUAL CUSTOMER ARRIVAL INFORMATION Working Paper WP no 719 November, 2007 MYOPIC INVENTORY POLICIES USING INDIVIDUAL CUSTOMER ARRIVAL INFORMATION Víctor Martínez de Albéniz 1 Alejandro Lago 1 1 Professor, Operations Management and Technology,

More information

An optimal policy for joint dynamic price and lead-time quotation

An optimal policy for joint dynamic price and lead-time quotation Lingnan University From the SelectedWorks of Prof. LIU Liming November, 2011 An optimal policy for joint dynamic price and lead-time quotation Jiejian FENG Liming LIU, Lingnan University, Hong Kong Xianming

More information

All-or-Nothing Ordering under a Capacity Constraint and Forecasts of Stationary Demand

All-or-Nothing Ordering under a Capacity Constraint and Forecasts of Stationary Demand All-or-Nothing Ordering under a Capacity Constraint and Forecasts of Stationary Demand Guillermo Gallego IEOR Department, Columbia University 500 West 120th Street, New York, NY 10027, USA and L. Beril

More information

Handout 8: Introduction to Stochastic Dynamic Programming. 2 Examples of Stochastic Dynamic Programming Problems

Handout 8: Introduction to Stochastic Dynamic Programming. 2 Examples of Stochastic Dynamic Programming Problems SEEM 3470: Dynamic Optimization and Applications 2013 14 Second Term Handout 8: Introduction to Stochastic Dynamic Programming Instructor: Shiqian Ma March 10, 2014 Suggested Reading: Chapter 1 of Bertsekas,

More information

TWO-STAGE NEWSBOY MODEL WITH BACKORDERS AND INITIAL INVENTORY

TWO-STAGE NEWSBOY MODEL WITH BACKORDERS AND INITIAL INVENTORY TWO-STAGE NEWSBOY MODEL WITH BACKORDERS AND INITIAL INVENTORY Ali Cheaitou, Christian van Delft, Yves Dallery and Zied Jemai Laboratoire Génie Industriel, Ecole Centrale Paris, Grande Voie des Vignes,

More information

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions. Suppose that a representative consumer receives an endowment of a non-storable consumption good. The endowment evolves exogenously according to ln

More information

JOINT PRODUCTION AND ECONOMIC RETENTION QUANTITY DECISIONS IN CAPACITATED PRODUCTION SYSTEMS SERVING MULTIPLE MARKET SEGMENTS.

JOINT PRODUCTION AND ECONOMIC RETENTION QUANTITY DECISIONS IN CAPACITATED PRODUCTION SYSTEMS SERVING MULTIPLE MARKET SEGMENTS. JOINT PRODUCTION AND ECONOMIC RETENTION QUANTITY DECISIONS IN CAPACITATED PRODUCTION SYSTEMS SERVING MULTIPLE MARKET SEGMENTS A Thesis by ABHILASHA KATARIYA Submitted to the Office of Graduate Studies

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION SILAS A. IHEDIOHA 1, BRIGHT O. OSU 2 1 Department of Mathematics, Plateau State University, Bokkos, P. M. B. 2012, Jos,

More information

Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items

Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items Nir Shabbat - 05305311 December 5, 2012 Introduction The paper I read is called Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items by Sergiu Hart

More information

A lower bound on seller revenue in single buyer monopoly auctions

A lower bound on seller revenue in single buyer monopoly auctions A lower bound on seller revenue in single buyer monopoly auctions Omer Tamuz October 7, 213 Abstract We consider a monopoly seller who optimally auctions a single object to a single potential buyer, with

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

Department of Social Systems and Management. Discussion Paper Series

Department of Social Systems and Management. Discussion Paper Series Department of Social Systems and Management Discussion Paper Series No.1252 Application of Collateralized Debt Obligation Approach for Managing Inventory Risk in Classical Newsboy Problem by Rina Isogai,

More information

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis 16 MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis Contents 2 Interest Rates 16 2.1 Definitions.................................... 16 2.1.1 Rate of Return..............................

More information

EE365: Risk Averse Control

EE365: Risk Averse Control EE365: Risk Averse Control Risk averse optimization Exponential risk aversion Risk averse control 1 Outline Risk averse optimization Exponential risk aversion Risk averse control Risk averse optimization

More information

A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales

A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance Volume 8 Issue 1 Spring 2003 Article 7 12-2003 A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales Robert Dubil San Jose State University Follow this and additional

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 207 Introduction This note works through some simple two-period consumption-saving problems. In

More information

Bid-Ask Spreads and Volume: The Role of Trade Timing

Bid-Ask Spreads and Volume: The Role of Trade Timing Bid-Ask Spreads and Volume: The Role of Trade Timing Toronto, Northern Finance 2007 Andreas Park University of Toronto October 3, 2007 Andreas Park (UofT) The Timing of Trades October 3, 2007 1 / 25 Patterns

More information

The value of foresight

The value of foresight Philip Ernst Department of Statistics, Rice University Support from NSF-DMS-1811936 (co-pi F. Viens) and ONR-N00014-18-1-2192 gratefully acknowledged. IMA Financial and Economic Applications June 11, 2018

More information

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi 10.1287/mnsc.1110.1334ec e-companion ONLY AVAILABLE IN ELECTRONIC FORM informs 2011 INFORMS Electronic Companion Trust in Forecast Information Sharing by Özalp Özer, Yanchong Zheng,

More information

Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification

Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification General Idea Standard dsge model assumes borrowers and lenders are the same people..no conflict of interest. Financial friction

More information

Infinite Horizon Optimal Policy for an Inventory System with Two Types of Products sharing Common Hardware Platforms

Infinite Horizon Optimal Policy for an Inventory System with Two Types of Products sharing Common Hardware Platforms Infinite Horizon Optimal Policy for an Inventory System with Two Types of Products sharing Common Hardware Platforms Mabel C. Chou, Chee-Khian Sim, Xue-Ming Yuan October 19, 2016 Abstract We consider a

More information

Approximation Algorithms for Stochastic Inventory Control Models

Approximation Algorithms for Stochastic Inventory Control Models Approximation Algorithms for Stochastic Inventory Control Models Retsef Levi Martin Pal Robin Roundy David B. Shmoys Abstract We consider stochastic control inventory models in which the goal is to coordinate

More information

Revenue Management Under the Markov Chain Choice Model

Revenue Management Under the Markov Chain Choice Model Revenue Management Under the Markov Chain Choice Model Jacob B. Feldman School of Operations Research and Information Engineering, Cornell University, Ithaca, New York 14853, USA jbf232@cornell.edu Huseyin

More information

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited Leonardo P. Santiago & Pirooz Vakili November 2004 Abstract In this paper we consider the question of whether an increase in uncertainty increases

More information

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand Alfredo Garcia and Robert L. Smith Department of Industrial and Operations Engineering Universityof Michigan, Ann Arbor MI 48109 December

More information

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions? March 3, 215 Steven A. Matthews, A Technical Primer on Auction Theory I: Independent Private Values, Northwestern University CMSEMS Discussion Paper No. 196, May, 1995. This paper is posted on the course

More information

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria and Rational Expectations Equilibria 1 Basic Setup Two periods: 0 and 1 One riskless asset with interest rate r One risky asset which pays a normally distributed

More information

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints 1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints In this section we study conditions under which savings react to changes in income uncertainty. Recall that in the PIH, when you abstract from

More information

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 implied Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 : May 7, 2015 1 / 28 implied 1 implied 2 / 28 Motivation and setup implied the goal of this chapter is to treat the implied which requires an algorithm

More information

Stochastic Optimal Control

Stochastic Optimal Control Stochastic Optimal Control Lecturer: Eilyan Bitar, Cornell ECE Scribe: Kevin Kircher, Cornell MAE These notes summarize some of the material from ECE 5555 (Stochastic Systems) at Cornell in the fall of

More information

Competition among Risk-Averse Newsvendors

Competition among Risk-Averse Newsvendors Competition among Risk-Averse Newsvendors Philipp Afèche Nima Sanajian Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto February 2013 We study in the classic newsvendor framework inventory competition

More information

1 The Solow Growth Model

1 The Solow Growth Model 1 The Solow Growth Model The Solow growth model is constructed around 3 building blocks: 1. The aggregate production function: = ( ()) which it is assumed to satisfy a series of technical conditions: (a)

More information

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours Ekonomia nr 47/2016 123 Ekonomia. Rynek, gospodarka, społeczeństwo 47(2016), s. 123 133 DOI: 10.17451/eko/47/2016/233 ISSN: 0137-3056 www.ekonomia.wne.uw.edu.pl Aggregation with a double non-convex labor

More information

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II Dynamic Portfolio Choice II Dynamic Programming Leonid Kogan MIT, Sloan 15.450, Fall 2010 c Leonid Kogan ( MIT, Sloan ) Dynamic Portfolio Choice II 15.450, Fall 2010 1 / 35 Outline 1 Introduction to Dynamic

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

Application of the Collateralized Debt Obligation (CDO) Approach for Managing Inventory Risk in the Classical Newsboy Problem

Application of the Collateralized Debt Obligation (CDO) Approach for Managing Inventory Risk in the Classical Newsboy Problem Isogai, Ohashi, and Sumita 35 Application of the Collateralized Debt Obligation (CDO) Approach for Managing Inventory Risk in the Classical Newsboy Problem Rina Isogai Satoshi Ohashi Ushio Sumita Graduate

More information

To wait or not to wait: Optimal ordering under lead time. uncertainty and forecast updating

To wait or not to wait: Optimal ordering under lead time. uncertainty and forecast updating To wait or not to wait: Optimal ordering under lead time uncertainty and forecast updating Yimin Wang, Brian Tomlin W. P. Carey School of Business, Arizona State University Kenan-Flagler Business School,

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

Online Appendix. ( ) =max

Online Appendix. ( ) =max Online Appendix O1. An extend model In the main text we solved a model where past dilemma decisions affect subsequent dilemma decisions but the DM does not take into account how her actions will affect

More information

Market Risk: FROM VALUE AT RISK TO STRESS TESTING. Agenda. Agenda (Cont.) Traditional Measures of Market Risk

Market Risk: FROM VALUE AT RISK TO STRESS TESTING. Agenda. Agenda (Cont.) Traditional Measures of Market Risk Market Risk: FROM VALUE AT RISK TO STRESS TESTING Agenda The Notional Amount Approach Price Sensitivity Measure for Derivatives Weakness of the Greek Measure Define Value at Risk 1 Day to VaR to 10 Day

More information

Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information. Appendix

Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information. Appendix Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information Ilan Lobel Appendix Wenqiang iao {ilobel, wxiao}@stern.nyu.edu Stern School of Business, New York University Appendix A: Proofs Proof

More information

Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty

Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty Chifeng Dai Department of Economics Southern Illinois University Carbondale, IL 62901, USA August 2014 Abstract We study optimal

More information

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation May 1, 1997 On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation Yoshitsugu Kanemoto 1 Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo 7-3-1 Hongo, Bunkyo-ku, Tokyo 113 Japan Abstract The most important drawback

More information

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Evaluating Strategic Forecasters Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Motivation Forecasters are sought after in a variety of

More information

Provably Near-Optimal Balancing Policies for Multi-Echelon Stochastic Inventory Control Models

Provably Near-Optimal Balancing Policies for Multi-Echelon Stochastic Inventory Control Models Provably Near-Optimal Balancing Policies for Multi-Echelon Stochastic Inventory Control Models Retsef Levi Robin Roundy Van Anh Truong February 13, 2006 Abstract We develop the first algorithmic approach

More information

Lecture Notes 1

Lecture Notes 1 4.45 Lecture Notes Guido Lorenzoni Fall 2009 A portfolio problem To set the stage, consider a simple nite horizon problem. A risk averse agent can invest in two assets: riskless asset (bond) pays gross

More information

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation Journal of Economics and Finance Volume 24 Number 1 Spring 2000 Pages 56-63 Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation Veronika Grimm and Ulrich Schmidt* Abstract This paper considers the classical independent

More information

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis

MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis 16 MTH6154 Financial Mathematics I Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis Contents 2 Interest Rates and Present Value Analysis 16 2.1 Definitions.................................... 16 2.1.1 Rate of

More information

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Peter Carr NYU CBOE Conference on Derivatives and Volatility, Chicago, Nov. 10, 2017 Peter Carr (NYU) Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns 11/10/2017 1 / 33 Interest Rates

More information

Lecture 5 January 30

Lecture 5 January 30 EE 223: Stochastic Estimation and Control Spring 2007 Lecture 5 January 30 Lecturer: Venkat Anantharam Scribe: aryam Kamgarpour 5.1 Secretary Problem The problem set-up is explained in Lecture 4. We review

More information

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia Marco Frittelli Università degli Studi di Firenze Winter School on Mathematical Finance January 24, 2005 Lunteren. On Utility Maximization in Incomplete Markets. based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini

More information

New Policies for Stochastic Inventory Control Models: Theoretical and Computational Results

New Policies for Stochastic Inventory Control Models: Theoretical and Computational Results OPERATIONS RESEARCH Vol. 00, No. 0, Xxxxx 0000, pp. 000 000 issn 0030-364X eissn 1526-5463 00 0000 0001 INFORMS doi 10.1287/xxxx.0000.0000 c 0000 INFORMS New Policies for Stochastic Inventory Control Models:

More information

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012. Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012. You have 3 hours to answer the questions in the final exam. We will collect the exams at 2.30 sharp. Show your work, and good luck! Problem 1. Utility Maximization.

More information

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING Version date: June 3, 017 C:\CLASSES\TEACHING NOTES\TN98-04.WPD The exchange option, first developed by Margrabe (1978), has proven to be an extremely powerful

More information

Report for technical cooperation between Georgia Institute of Technology and ONS - Operador Nacional do Sistema Elétrico Risk Averse Approach

Report for technical cooperation between Georgia Institute of Technology and ONS - Operador Nacional do Sistema Elétrico Risk Averse Approach Report for technical cooperation between Georgia Institute of Technology and ONS - Operador Nacional do Sistema Elétrico Risk Averse Approach Alexander Shapiro and Wajdi Tekaya School of Industrial and

More information

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES 1. Introduction One-period models, which were the subject of Lecture 1, are of limited usefulness in the pricing and hedging of derivative securities. In real-world

More information

A Cournot-Stackelberg Model of Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging

A Cournot-Stackelberg Model of Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging A Cournot-Stackelberg Model of Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging René Caldentey Booth School of Business, The University of Chicago, Chicago, IL 6637. Martin B. Haugh Department of IE and OR, Columbia

More information

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Ahmer Tarar Department of Political Science Texas A&M University 4348 TAMU College Station, TX 77843-4348 email: ahmertarar@pols.tamu.edu

More information

A Cournot-Stackelberg Model of Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging

A Cournot-Stackelberg Model of Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging A Cournot-Stackelberg Model of Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging René Caldentey Stern School of Business, New York University, New York, NY 1001, rcaldent@stern.nyu.edu. Martin B. Haugh Department

More information

Online Appendix: Extensions

Online Appendix: Extensions B Online Appendix: Extensions In this online appendix we demonstrate that many important variations of the exact cost-basis LUL framework remain tractable. In particular, dual problem instances corresponding

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 and 2 in the first Blue Book and Problems 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A

More information

Portfolio Optimization using Conditional Sharpe Ratio

Portfolio Optimization using Conditional Sharpe Ratio International Letters of Chemistry, Physics and Astronomy Online: 2015-07-01 ISSN: 2299-3843, Vol. 53, pp 130-136 doi:10.18052/www.scipress.com/ilcpa.53.130 2015 SciPress Ltd., Switzerland Portfolio Optimization

More information

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory Chapter Microeconomics of Consumer Theory The two broad categories of decision-makers in an economy are consumers and firms. Each individual in each of these groups makes its decisions in order to achieve

More information

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets Chapter 5: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets It is easy to argue that Brownian motion paths cannot model actual stock price movements properly in reality,

More information

ROBUST OPTIMIZATION OF MULTI-PERIOD PRODUCTION PLANNING UNDER DEMAND UNCERTAINTY. A. Ben-Tal, B. Golany and M. Rozenblit

ROBUST OPTIMIZATION OF MULTI-PERIOD PRODUCTION PLANNING UNDER DEMAND UNCERTAINTY. A. Ben-Tal, B. Golany and M. Rozenblit ROBUST OPTIMIZATION OF MULTI-PERIOD PRODUCTION PLANNING UNDER DEMAND UNCERTAINTY A. Ben-Tal, B. Golany and M. Rozenblit Faculty of Industrial Engineering and Management, Technion, Haifa 32000, Israel ABSTRACT

More information

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS 253 16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS Let us associate each state S with a numeric utility U(S), which expresses the desirability of the state A nondeterministic action a will have possible outcome states Result(a)

More information

Valuing Lead Time. Valuing Lead Time. Prof. Suzanne de Treville. 13th Annual QRM Conference 1/24

Valuing Lead Time. Valuing Lead Time. Prof. Suzanne de Treville. 13th Annual QRM Conference 1/24 Valuing Lead Time Prof. Suzanne de Treville 13th Annual QRM Conference 1/24 How compelling is a 30% offshore cost differential? Comparing production to order to production to forecast with a long lead

More information

A NEW NOTION OF TRANSITIVE RELATIVE RETURN RATE AND ITS APPLICATIONS USING STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Burhaneddin İZGİ

A NEW NOTION OF TRANSITIVE RELATIVE RETURN RATE AND ITS APPLICATIONS USING STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Burhaneddin İZGİ A NEW NOTION OF TRANSITIVE RELATIVE RETURN RATE AND ITS APPLICATIONS USING STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS Burhaneddin İZGİ Department of Mathematics, Istanbul Technical University, Istanbul, Turkey

More information

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

1 Two Period Exchange Economy University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 502) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout # 2 1 Two Period Exchange Economy We shall start our exploration of dynamic economies with

More information

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives Department of Mathematics MA408 Mathematics of Financial Derivatives Thursday 15th January, 2009 2pm 4pm Duration: 2 hours Attempt THREE questions MA408 Page 1 of 5 1. (a) Suppose 0 < E 1 < E 3 and E 2

More information

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS 247 16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS Let us associate each state S with a numeric utility U(S), which expresses the desirability of the state A nondeterministic action A will have possible outcome states Result

More information

Haiyang Feng College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin , CHINA

Haiyang Feng College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin , CHINA RESEARCH ARTICLE QUALITY, PRICING, AND RELEASE TIME: OPTIMAL MARKET ENTRY STRATEGY FOR SOFTWARE-AS-A-SERVICE VENDORS Haiyang Feng College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin 300072,

More information

The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility

The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility Harjoat S. Bhamra Sauder School of Business University of British Columbia Raman

More information

The Role of Financial Services in Procurement Contracts

The Role of Financial Services in Procurement Contracts The Role of Financial Services in Procurement Contracts René Caldentey Stern School of Business, New York University, 44 West Fourth Street, Suite 8-77, New York, NY 112, rcaldent@stern.nyu.edu. Xiangfeng

More information

An Approximation Algorithm for Capacity Allocation over a Single Flight Leg with Fare-Locking

An Approximation Algorithm for Capacity Allocation over a Single Flight Leg with Fare-Locking An Approximation Algorithm for Capacity Allocation over a Single Flight Leg with Fare-Locking Mika Sumida School of Operations Research and Information Engineering, Cornell University, Ithaca, New York

More information

Problem 1: Random variables, common distributions and the monopoly price

Problem 1: Random variables, common distributions and the monopoly price Problem 1: Random variables, common distributions and the monopoly price In this problem, we will revise some basic concepts in probability, and use these to better understand the monopoly price (alternatively

More information

Information aggregation for timing decision making.

Information aggregation for timing decision making. MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Information aggregation for timing decision making. Esteban Colla De-Robertis Universidad Panamericana - Campus México, Escuela de Ciencias Económicas y Empresariales

More information

Homework Assignments

Homework Assignments Homework Assignments Week 1 (p. 57) #4.1, 4., 4.3 Week (pp 58 6) #4.5, 4.6, 4.8(a), 4.13, 4.0, 4.6(b), 4.8, 4.31, 4.34 Week 3 (pp 15 19) #1.9, 1.1, 1.13, 1.15, 1.18 (pp 9 31) #.,.6,.9 Week 4 (pp 36 37)

More information

The internal rate of return (IRR) is a venerable technique for evaluating deterministic cash flow streams.

The internal rate of return (IRR) is a venerable technique for evaluating deterministic cash flow streams. MANAGEMENT SCIENCE Vol. 55, No. 6, June 2009, pp. 1030 1034 issn 0025-1909 eissn 1526-5501 09 5506 1030 informs doi 10.1287/mnsc.1080.0989 2009 INFORMS An Extension of the Internal Rate of Return to Stochastic

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology

Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE81.98 School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology January Semester Presented by Dr. Thitisak Boonpramote Department

More information

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20135 Theory of Finance, Part I (Sept. October) Fall 2014 Outline and objectives The backward, three-step solution

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University April 12, 2008 Abstract A model of mixed oligopoly is constructed in which a Home public firm

More information

THE LYING ORACLE GAME WITH A BIASED COIN

THE LYING ORACLE GAME WITH A BIASED COIN Applied Probability Trust (13 July 2009 THE LYING ORACLE GAME WITH A BIASED COIN ROBB KOETHER, Hampden-Sydney College MARCUS PENDERGRASS, Hampden-Sydney College JOHN OSOINACH, Millsaps College Abstract

More information

Single item inventory control under periodic review and a minimum order quantity Kiesmuller, G.P.; de Kok, A.G.; Dabia, S.

Single item inventory control under periodic review and a minimum order quantity Kiesmuller, G.P.; de Kok, A.G.; Dabia, S. Single item inventory control under periodic review and a minimum order quantity Kiesmuller, G.P.; de Kok, A.G.; Dabia, S. Published: 01/01/2008 Document Version Publisher s PDF, also known as Version

More information

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress Stephen D. Williamson Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis May 14, 015 1 Introduction When a central bank operates under a floor

More information

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index Marc Ivaldi Vicente Lagos Preliminary version, please do not quote without permission Abstract The Coordinate Price Pressure

More information

STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION

STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION BINGCHAO HUANGFU Abstract This paper studies a dynamic duopoly model of reputation-building in which reputations are treated as capital stocks that

More information

Dynamic Pricing and Inventory Management under Fluctuating Procurement Costs

Dynamic Pricing and Inventory Management under Fluctuating Procurement Costs 1 Dynamic Pricing and Inventory Management under Fluctuating Procurement Costs Philip (Renyu) Zhang (Joint work with Guang Xiao and Nan Yang) Olin Business School Washington University in St. Louis June

More information

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching Science Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics 2016; 4(6): 263-268 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/sjams doi: 10.11648/j.sjams.20160406.13 ISSN: 2376-9491 (Print); ISSN: 2376-9513 (Online)

More information

E-companion to Coordinating Inventory Control and Pricing Strategies for Perishable Products

E-companion to Coordinating Inventory Control and Pricing Strategies for Perishable Products E-companion to Coordinating Inventory Control and Pricing Strategies for Perishable Products Xin Chen International Center of Management Science and Engineering Nanjing University, Nanjing 210093, China,

More information