On the Relative Pricing of long Maturity. S&P 500 Index Options and CDX Tranches 1

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "On the Relative Pricing of long Maturity. S&P 500 Index Options and CDX Tranches 1"

Transcription

1 On the Relative Pricing of long Maturity S&P 500 Index Options and CDX Tranches 1 Pierre Collin-Dufresne 2 Robert S. Goldstein 3 Fan Yang 4 First Version: October 2008 This Version: January 25, We thank Luca Benzoni, Josh Coval and Mike Johannes for many helpful comments. All remaining errors are our own. 2 Carson Family Professor of Finance, Columbia University and NBER, pc2415@columbia.edu 3 C. Arthur Williams Professor of Insurance, University of Minnesota, and NBER, golds144@umn.edu 4 Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota, yang0946@umn.edu

2 On the Relative Pricing of long Maturity S&P 500 Index Options and CDX Tranches Abstract We investigate a structural model of market and firm-level dynamics in order to jointly price long-dated S&P 500 options and tranche spreads on the five-year CDX index. We demonstrate the importance of calibrating the model to match the entire term structure of CDX index spreads because it contains pertinent information regarding the timing of expected defaults and the specification of idiosyncratic dynamics. Our model matches the time series of tranche spreads well, both before and during the financial crisis, thus offering a resolution to the puzzle reported by Coval, Jurek and Stafford (2009).

3 1 Introduction The explosive growth of the credit derivative market, and the ensuing economic crisis, have generated much interest in the pricing and hedging of credit derivatives. This market is composed of both single-name products, such as the credit default swap (CDS), and multiname products such as the CDX index basket default swap and tranches based on this index. While the spread on the CDX index can be mostly determined by observing the CDS spreads on the 125 underlying firms that compose the index, the pricing of CDX tranche spreads depends crucially on how one models default correlation. That is, whereas the pricing of the CDX index depends only on the marginal default probabilities of the individual firms, the pricing of the tranches depends on their joint probability distribution. One framework often used for determining spreads on individual corporate bonds is the so-called structural model of default (Merton (1974)), which is based on the insights of Black and Scholes (1973). Risk neutral dynamics are specified for firm value, and default is assumed to occur at maturity if firm value falls below a default boundary, which in the original model is specified to equal the face value of debt outstanding. One interesting prediction of this framework is that spreads depend only on the firm s total variance, and not on the fraction of variance due to market risk and idiosyncratic risk. 1 This is because only the marginal default probability is needed to determine bond or CDS spreads. In contrast, because CDX tranche spreads depend on correlation, their prices are rather sensitive to the composition of market and idiosyncratic risks of the underlying firms. One of the first frameworks for modeling default correlation were the so-called copula models (Vasicek (1987), Li (2000)). These models are effectively structural models of default embedded within a CAPM framework to model default correlation. In particular, the standard copula model can be interpreted as modeling returns as a sum of two factors: a market factor and an idiosyncratic factor. Just as in the standard structural model, default occurs if the the sum of these two factors drops below a specified default boundary. The level of correlation is driven by the relative weights specified on the market and idiosyncratic components. Un- 1 Note that if we condition on the P -measure default probability instead of the initial leverage ratio, then the fraction of risk due to systematic risk would matter. Indeed, consider two firms that have the same total risk, default probability and recovery rate. The firm with higher beta (and hence higher expected return) will need to start with higher leverage to have the same default probability as the low-beta firm. As such, the higher beta-firm will command a higher spread (Chen, Collin-Dufresne and Goldstein (2008)). 1

4 fortunately, the original copula framework is not dynamically consistent. For example, when pricing tranches with different maturities, the standard copula approach has been to specify a different default boundary location and a different market beta for each maturity, and then assume that default can occur only at the maturity of the security in question. Moreover, copula models are inherently static, and thus cannot be used, for example, to price options on CDO s (Duffie (2004)). In the original Gaussian copula models, both market and idiosyncratic factors were assumed to be normally distributed. Just as it has become standard to quote option prices in terms of its Black/Scholes implied volatility (in spite of the well-documented flaws in the model s predictions), it has become standard to quote correlations implied from the Gaussian copula. Many improvements to the Gaussian copula have been suggested to improve upon its empirical failures. 2 In a recent influential paper, Coval, Jurek and Stafford (CJS, 2009) investigate the pricing of CDO tranches within a copula framework by using S&P 500 option prices to identify the market component of returns. Their approach is motivated by Breeden and Litzenberger (1978), who show how state prices can be extracted from option prices. 3 Given state prices, CJS then calibrate the idiosyncratic component of returns from observed equity returns, and the location of the default boundary so that their model matches perfectly the fiveyear CDX index (i.e., the risk-neutral expected loss on the index). They find that observed spreads on the equity tranche are too high, and observed spreads on more senior tranches are too low relative to those predicted by their model. 4 Since their results seem robust along many dimensions, CJS conclude that sellers of senior protection were writing insurance contracts on economic catastrophe bonds without realizing the magnitude of systematic risk they were exposed to, and thus not demanding adequate compensation for that risk. They conjecture that agents had purchased senior claims solely with regard to their credit rating (which reflects their P -measure default probability), but ignored the large systematic 2 See, for example, Andersen and Sidenius (2004), Hull and White (2004), Duffie and Garleanu (2001). 3 Since it is well-known that fat tails in the common density are needed to fit tranche prices. CJS propose an out-of-sample calibration of the common market factor distribution. Other approaches to match fat tails includes Hull and White (2004), who use a double t-distribution. 4 For their benchmark case, spreads are approximately two-times too small for the 3-7% tranche, fourtimes too small for the 7-10% tranche, five-times too small for the 10-15% tranche, and three-times too small for the 15-30% tranche. 2

5 risk associated with holding a senior claim written on an underlying diversified portfolio. Their findings are puzzling, since traders in the CDX market are typically thought of as being rather sophisticated. Thus it would be surprising to find them accepting so much risk without fair compensation. In this paper, we also investigate the relative prices of S&P 500 index options and spreads on the CDX index and tranches. An important difference between our framework and that of CJS (and most other copula models) is that we specify a fully dynamic model that allows us to jointly and consistently price these securities across the maturity spectrum. Following Black and Cox (1976), we specify the default event as the first time firm value drops below the default boundary, instead of limiting default to occur only at maturity. This allows us to account for the possibility of early default, which can significantly impact the cash flows of protection buyers and sellers of CDX tranches. While there are many differences between our framework and theirs, the most crucial distinction that drives our results is that CJS calibrate their model to match only the fiveyear CDX index spread, whereas we calibrate our model to match the entire term structure of CDX index spreads that is, spreads across all maturities. Calibrating to shorter horizon CDX index spreads is important because they contain pertinent information regarding the timing of expected defaults and the specification of idiosyncratic dynamics. Using this calibration approach, we match the time series of tranche spreads well, both during and prior to the crisis period, thus providing a resolution to the puzzle of CJS. To gain some intuition for why it is essential to calibrate the model to match the term structure of CDX index levels, we recall a well-documented failure of (diffusion-based) structural models of default: they dramatically underpredict default rates for investment grade debt at short maturities. This is true both under the risk-neutral measure, where structural models predict negligible credit spreads at short maturity (Jones, Mason and Rosenfeld (1984), Eom, Helwege Huang (2005)), and under the true measure (Leland (2004)). To match short-term spreads on investment grade debt, it is necessary to include idiosyncratic jumps into firm dynamics. (e.g., Zhou (2001)). We calibrate idiosyncratic jump size and intensities to match observed CDX index spreads at short horizons. In sum then, whereas S&P 500 option prices are useful for identifying market dynamics, the term structure of CDX index levels is useful for identifying idiosyncratic dynamics. Calibrating the idiosyncratic component of return dynamics to the term structure of CDX index spreads impacts tranche spreads in two important ways. First, it increases (risk neutral) expected losses (i.e., defaults) at shorter horizons. Without this calibration 3

6 approach, defaults are backloaded, that is, occur later than actual market expectations. The timing of defaults is especially crucial for the equity tranche, where the buyer of protection gets to reduce her payments as soon as the first default occurs. This helps explain why the implied equity tranche spread in the CJS framework tends to be too low relative to the market quote. Moreover, since their model matches the five year CDX index (and therefore, five year risk neutral expected losses), the downward bias on the equity tranche spread automatically generates an upward bias on the spreads of the senior tranches. It is interesting to note that, in practice, the timing of defaults is understood to be so crucial for the determination of the equity tranche spread that it is common to contractually specify its cash flows in a different manner (i.e., with an up-front premium) compared to the other tranches (i.e., full-running premium) so as to reduce its sensitivity to the timing of defaults. 5 As we demonstrate below, our model matches observed equity tranche spreads well for both forms of contractual payments. The second important way our calibration approach impacts tranche spreads is by increasing the proportion of risk that is idiosyncratic compared to systematic. The intuition for how this impacts tranche spreads stems from the central limit theorem: if in fact all risk were idiosyncratic, then due to the large number (namely, 125) of firms in the index, the distribution of fractional losses would be tightly peaked around expected losses (which were below the 3% equity loss detachment point during the period studied by CJS ). As one increases the proportion of systematic risk, the loss distribution widens because losses become more dependent on market performance. Below we show that if the model is not calibrated to match the term structure of CDX index spreads, then there is an insufficient level of idiosyncratic risk specified, and the loss distribution is not sufficiently peaked. This forces too much of the loss distribution (compared to the market s expectations) to fall above the 3% equity loss detachment point, implying too high of a probability where sellers of protection of the more senior tranches will have to pay out, in turn biasing upward tranche spreads for the more senior tranches. Again, since CJS calibrate their model to match the 5 year CDX index, the upward bias in senior tranche spreads automatically generates a downward bias in equity tranche spreads. One more issue that arises in our investigation is that we show one cannot uniquely 5 As we discuss in equations (14)-(15) below, instead of setting the equity tranche premium so that the present value of the premium equals the present value of the protection, often there is also an up-front premium paid to sellers of equity tranche protection. 4

7 determine market dynamics from option contracts that are actually traded. This is because the strike prices of traded options do not span far enough in the moneyness dimension to identify the (risk neutral) probabilities of catastrophic crashes. As such, there are many choices of market dynamics that can be specified that generate nearly identical prices for those options with strikes that are actually traded, but generate very different prices for the super-senior tranche. Therefore, we calibrate our model to match the super-senior tranche spread, and price all other tranche spreads out-of-sample. 6 While CJS calibrate state prices only for a maturity of five years, our framework requires a dynamic model capable of producing state prices for all maturities. As documented previously in the literature, it is not a trivial task to specify market dynamics to match long maturity options, as observed option implied volatilities fail to flatten out as maturity increases, in contrast to the predictions of most models. 7 To circumvent this problem, we allow the dividend yield to be stochastic. It turns out that this can have a significant impact on the implied volatility surface, especially if the parameterization implies non-stationary dynamics under the risk neutral measure. 8 While non-stationarity may at first seem undesirable, it has a theoretical justification. Indeed, we show in the Appendix that, in the habit formation model of Campbell and Cochrane (1999), the endogenously determined dividend yield is a function of their consumption surplus habit variable and that this variable exhibits nonstationarity under the risk neutral measure (even though it is stationary under the historical measure). Moreover, this feature is responsible for their model s ability to capture long term predictability of market returns. There is a large and increasing literature on correlated defaults. 9 Our contribution with 6 We are confident we could match tranche spreads even better than what is shown below if we were to also calibrate market dynamics to match other tranche spreads. But such an additional exercise would mostly mimic the contributions inherent in papers such as Mortensen (2006), Longstaff and Rajan (2008), and Eckner (2009), who have already demonstrated the ability of a few in-sample state variables to match the cross section of tranche spreads well. 7 See Backus, Foresi and Wu (1997), Das and Sundaram (1999), Carr and Wu (2003). 8 With that said, our results for tranche spreads are not driven by our choice of modeling market returns, as we demonstrate in the robustness section. 9 Examples include Duffie and Garleanu (2001), Collin-Dufresne, Goldstein and Helwege (2003), Hull and White (2004), Longstaff, Mithal and Neis (2005), Mortensen (2006), Longstaff and Rajan (2008), Giesecke and Goldberg (2005), Bakshi, Madan and Zhang (2006), Das et al (2006), Das et al (2007), Duffie, Saita and 5

8 respect to the literature is to investigate the relative pricing across the stock option and CDO markets. 10 Further, our fully dynamic and self-consistent framework allows us to investigate the sensitivity of standard approximations made in the literature. For example, we find that accounting for firm heterogeneity, dynamic capital structure, industry correlations, or stochastic interest rates has only a secondary impact on tranche pricing. In contrast, calibrating to the term structure of CDX spreads is essential for jointly modeling S&P 500 option prices and CDX tranche spreads. The rest of the paper is as follows: In Section 2 we propose a joint model for equity index options and CDO tranches. In Section 3 we discuss the data and our calibration approach. In Section 4 we report the results for option prices as well as the cross sectional implications for tranche prices of our various model specifications. In Section 5 we investigate the time series properties of our model. In Section 6, we investigate the robustness of our results. We conclude in Section 7. 2 A joint structural model for equity index options and CDO tranches This paper investigates the relative pricing of CDX tranche spreads and S&P 500 option prices within a structural framework. In order to do so, we need a model of market returns and individual firm level returns. In this section, we introduce an affine option pricing model (SVDCJ) for market returns that extends the standard SVCJ model of Broadie, Chernov and Johannes (2009) to better account for some features inherent in the data of long-maturity option prices. We then introduce a CAPM-like structural model for firm level returns that allows us to price basket CDS and CDO tranches. 2.1 Market dynamics for long maturity option prices There is a long tradition, since Breeden and Litzenberger (1978), to extract implied state price densities from quoted option prices. One common approach, followed by CJS, is to use Wang (2007), Jorion and Zhang (2009) 10 Cremers, Driessen and Maenhout (2008) show option prices on individual firms are consistent with prices from the CDS market. 6

9 a local volatility model, which specifies a flexible form for the implied volatility function which is then calibrated to match observed option prices across strikes and maturity. 11 This approach is particularly well suited when the amount of data is large, and tends to provide accurate estimates for the implied density if the range of interpolation/extrapolation is not too far from strikes for which option prices are available. Unfortunately, to study tranche prices, and especially the super-senior tranche, we will have to extrapolate the density to regions that are far from any strikes of quoted option prices. Therefore, we prefer to use a fully dynamic model where return dynamics under the risk neutral measure are specified. This approach guarantees that our extrapolated volatility surface is both consistent (i.e., arbitrage-free) and generated from a model with economically motivated dynamics. One nice feature (and necessary for our needs) of having a fully dynamic option pricing model is that, once calibrated, we can obtain the state price density for all strikes and all maturities. In contrast, CJS focus on state prices for the 5-year maturity only, and specify a model where this information is sufficient to price tranche spreads. There is a large literature on testing parametric option pricing models. Early papers that test various specifications of option pricing models include Bates (2000), Pan (2002), Eraker, Johannes, Polson (2003), Eraker (2004), Anderson and Andreasen (2000). 12 The recent paper by Broadie, Chernov and Johannes (BCJ 2009) presents an encompassing test of various specifications proposed in the literature using an extensive data set on S&P 500 futures options. Their preferred model is the so-called SVCJ model which allows for stochastic volatility and correlated jumps in both stock returns and volatility processes. We therefore choose to build on their preferred model, which we extend by introducing a stochastic dividend yield. BCJ and indeed most of the literature has focused on options with relatively short maturity (i.e., less than 6 months). However, since our focus is the pricing of 5-year CDX tranches, it is necessary to back out long-maturity state prices, implying the need to look at long-maturity option prices. The maturity of exchange-traded options on the S&P 500 is typically limited to under three years, but on the OTC market it is possible to obtain 11 See, for example, Derman and Kani (1994), Dupire (1994) Rubinstein (1994), Dumas, Fleming and Whaley (1998). 12 More recently, researchers have investigated whether option prices are consistent with asset prices in different markets. For example, Cremers, Driessen and Maenhout (2008) demonstrate that the implied volatility smirk of option prices on individual stocks are mostly consistent with credit spreads on the same firm. 7

10 longer dated options. CJS calibrate their model to five year maturity quotes obtained from Citigroup. We perform our initial calibration by matching to the same prices as reported in CJS. While the so-called SVCJ jump-diffusion model performs very well at capturing timeseries and cross-sectional properties of option returns, it performs better for short-dated options. For longer maturity options the model-predicted implied volatility surface flattens (see Figure 1), in contradiction with the longer-term maturity option data available. This surprising pattern found in long maturity option prices, that implied volatilities, expressed as a function of a standard measure of moneyness, do not flatten out, implies a violation of the central limit theorem s underlying assumptions (Carr and Wu (2003)). Indeed, the slope and curvature of the volatility smirk are mostly controlled by the skewness and kurtosis of the distribution of market prices. But if the central limit theorem holds, it predicts that the distribution of log-returns should converge to normal over sufficiently long maturity. 13 In order to overcome the central limit theorem s implications, Carr and Wu (2003) propose a log-stable process with infinite second moments. While their model matches option prices well, one unattractive feature of their model is that the variance of log returns is infinite in their model (despite the fact that all moments of the spot price and therefore option prices are finite). This could lead to infinite prices of certain volatility derivatives for example. Instead, we propose an alternative mechanism to fit longer maturity implied volatility skews. While there are many possible choices (e.g., state variables driving interest rates, volatility, intensity, etc.), here we consider a state variable that has been mostly ignored in the options literature, even though it is fundamental in the returns literature: the dividend yield (i.e., the inverse of the price/dividend ratio that is the focus of many macro-finance papers such as Campbell and Cochrane (1999) or Bansal and Yaron (2003)). As motivation, we note that in the habit formation model of Campbell and Cochrane (1999), the price-dividend ratio is a function of a single state variable s, the so-called surplus consumption ratio, whose dynamics are stationary under the actual measure, but non-stationary under the risk-neutral measure. (See Appendix 1). Therefore we introduce a stochastic dividend yield, with possible non-stationary dynamics under the risk-neutral measure. Specifically, we define M t as the value of the market portfolio, V t the volatility of the market, and δ(t) the dividend yield of the market. We specify risk-neutral market dynamics as: dm t = (r δ) dt + V M t dw Q + (ey 1) dq µ 1 y λ Q dt (e y C 1) (dqc λ Q dt) (1) C t 13 See Das and Sundaram (1999), Backus, Foresi and Wu (2004). 8

11 Black Scholes Implied Volatilities (%) Mean diverting dividend yield 3 Year 4 Year 5 Year Black Scholes Implied Volatilities (%) Constant dividend yield 3 Year 4 Year 5 Year Moneyness Moneyness Figure 1: Implied volatility curves (IVF) as a function of moneyness for different maturities for two different models: our non-stationary dividend yield model, and constant dividend yield. We follow Carr and Wu(2003) definition of moneyness log(k/f ) σ. Note how the five-year T IVF does not flatten out compared to the three- and four-year for the non-stationary model, in contrast to the constant dividend model. dv t = κ V ( V V t )dt + σ V Vt (ρdw Q ρ 2 dw Q 2 ) + y V dq (2) dδ t = κ δ ( δ δ t ) dt + σ Vt δ (ρ 1 dw Q + ρ 1 2 dw 1 Q + ρ 2 ρ2 dwq) + y dq. (3) δ Here, dw Q 1 and dw Q 2 are Brownian motions, and dq is a jump process with a constant jump intensity λ Q. The market, the variance and the dividend yield jump contemporaneously. The jump size of the volatility follows an exponential distribution, y V exp(1/µ V ). The jump size in market is originally assumed to be normal conditional on the jump size of V t, y y V N ( ρ q y V + µ y, σ y ). The jump size in dividend yield is assumed to be independent normal, y δ N(µ d, σ d ). The compensator for the jump in the market price is 1 µ y = E [e y ] 1 = eµ y + 2 σ2 y 1. (4) 1 ρ q µ V We note that this model is the standard SVCJ model studied in the literature (e.g., BCJ (2009)) extended for a stochastic dividend yield with a correlated jump. We therefore refer to this model as the SVDCJ model. We note that in addition we have explicitly 9

12 added a jump q C with deterministic jump size y C in the market dynamics, even though it could be subsumed in the standard jump dq, because we want to emphasize the importance of a catastrophic jumps for the pricing of super-senior tranches in our calibrations. The importance of catastrophic jumps for asset pricing has been emphasized in Rietz (1983) and more recently revisited in Barro (2008), Backus, Chernov and Martin (2009) and others. We demonstrate below that there are many calibrations of this model that would match well the option prices for those strikes that are actually traded. Therefore, in order to uniquely identify market dynamics, we calibrate the model to match the data on both the supersenior tranche spreads and S&P 500 options, leaving all other tranche spreads to be priced out-of-sample. Given that the model is specified to have affine dynamics, it follows that the characteristic function is exponential affine (Duffie, Pan and Singleton (2000)). As such, European option prices can be solved numerically by applying the Fast Fourier Transformation(FFT) on the log market characteristic function (Heston (1996), Carr and Madan (1998)). The solution of the log market characteristic function is given in the Appendix Firm dynamics and structural default model Given the market dynamics, we assume that individual firm dynamics are specified as: da ( ) A + δ dt rdt = β Vt dw Q + A (ey 1) dq µ 1 y λ Q dt + (e y C 1) (dqc λ Q dt) C +σ i dw i + (e y i 1) (dqi λ Q dt). (5) i This is basically the standard CAPM like equation for individual firm s asset return, where β denotes the loading of each firm s asset return dynamics on the market return. The only difference from CAPM is that we assume each firm has a loading of 1 on the catastrophic event. That is, unlike the standard market risk, we assume that all firms have the same exposure to catastrophic events. The idiosyncratic jump size and intensity are constants. Under these specifications, the log market and log asset have dynamics ( d log M t = r δ t 1 ) 2 V t µ y λ Q (e y C 1) λ Q dt + V C t dw Q + y dq + y dq 1 C C ( d log A t = r δ A 1 2 β2 V t 1 ) 2 σ2 β µ i yλ Q (e y C 1) λ Q (ey i C 1) λ Q dt i +β V t dw Q 1 + σ i dw i + log [1 + β (ey 1)] dq + y C dq C + y i dq i. (6) 10

13 Following Black and Cox (1976) and others, we specify that default occurs the first time firm value falls below a default threshold A B. Therefore default arrival time for the typical firm i with asset dynamics A i (t) is defined as: τ i = inf{t : A i (t) A B }. (7) We assume that upon default the debt-holder recover a fraction of the remaining asset value (1 l)a B where l is the loss rate. 2.3 Basket CDS index and CDO tranche spreads We consider next the pricing of baskets of CDS and CDO tranches. Eventually, we want to use the model to price the DJ CDX North American Investment Grade Index and the tranches associated with it. This index is a basket CDS written on an equally weighted portfolio of 125 investment grade names. It can essentially be thought of as a portfolio of 125 liquid five-year credit default swaps (CDS) with investment grade status. The spread of a CDS on a firm is closely related to the credit spread of a bond on the same firm. 14 running spread on the CDX index is closely related to a weighted average of CDS spreads. 15 To determine this spread, the present value of cash flows that go to the protection buyer and protection seller are set equal to each other. These cash flows are specified as [ M ] tm V idx,prem (S) = S E e rt m (1 n(t m )) + du e ru (u t m 1 ) dn u (8) m=1 t m 1 [ T ] V idx,prot = E e rt dl t. (9) 0 14 Empirically, CDS spreads are close to credit spreads only when the risk-free benchmark is estimated to be well above Treasuries. In normal times, the swap/libor curve is a better proxy than the Treasury curve. See, for example, Blanco Brennan and Marsh (2005). Though during the crisis we have seen very negative basis for investment grade spreads. 15 There are some technical differences between the CDX contract specification and a portfolio of CDS. Most notably, the fact that the CDX is settled upfront based on a fixed running coupon spread (see Collin- Dufresne (2008)). This has only a minor impact on our analysis below, however and therefore we ignore them. The 11

14 Here, we have defined the number of defaults in the portfolio by n(t) = i 1, and the {τ i t} cumulative loss in the portfolio as: L(t) = i 1 {τi t} R i (τ i ) (10) where R i (t) is the recovery rate on firm i when it defaults at time t. In addition to the CDX index, tranches based on the index have also been created. Each tranche is characterized by its attachment points. For the CDX index, the different tranches are 0-3% (the equity tranche), 3-7% (mezzanine), 7-10%, 10-15%, 15-30% (senior), and % (super-senior). The buyer of protection pays a periodic premium in return for compensation if there are losses on the CDX index that fall within the range of the particular tranche. Once again, the spread is determined by equating the present value of the protection leg and premium leg. The tranche loss as a function of portfolio loss is T j (L(t)) T Kj 1,K j (L(t)) = max [ min(l(t), K j ) K j 1, 0 ] (11) = max [ L(t) K j 1, 0 ] max [ L(t) K j, 0 ]. (12) The initial value of the protection leg on tranche-j is [ T ] P rot j (0, T ) = E Q e rt dt j (L(t)) In terms of the tranche spread S j, the initial value of the premium leg on tranche-j (except for the equity and super-senior tranches) is [ M tm P rem j (0, T ) = S j E Q e rtm du ( K j K j 1 T j (L(u)) ) ]. (14) t m 1 m=1 There are two standard practices followed for the premium on the equity tranche. One is a so-called full running premium as in equation (14). In the other approach, which is more common, the equity tranche premium has a so-called up-front premium U combined with a set running premium of 500bps: P rem 1 (0, T ) = UK E Q [ M m=1 0 e rt m tm t m 1 du (K 1 K 0 T 1 (L(u))) ] (13). (15) The reason for these two different practices is that the pricing of the equity tranche using equation (14) is known to be very sensitive to the timing of defaults. 12 To see this

15 intuitively, note that the quarterly payment drops from (0.03) ( ) S 4 before any defaults to (0.03 (1 R) ) ( ) S after the first default. For a standard recovery rate of R = 0.4, this is approximately a 16% drop in payments. The fact that the market is so concerned about the timing of defaults for the equity tranche that it has created a different cash flow for it emphasizes that the market is very aware of this sensitivity, and no doubt calibrating their models to incorporate information regarding this. Finally, the super-senior tranche premium is specified by P rem 6 (0, T ) = S 6 E Q [ M m=1 e rt m tm t m 1 du (K 6 K 5 n u R T 6 (L(u))) ]. (16) We note that high recoveries hurt the super-senior tranches as the principal gets reduced by the amount recovered. 16 Following CJS, we first focus on the period September 2004 to September We then investigate how the model performs during the crisis. 3 Data and calibration 3.1 Data Our primary data include S&P 500 European option prices, the CDX North American Investment-Grade Index, and tranche spreads written on this index for maturities of one to five years. The option data are from OptionMetrics. The CDX index and tranche data are from J.P. Morgan. Our sample consists of two periods: the pre-crisis period (September 21, 2004 to September 20, 2007) and the crisis period (September 21, 2007 to September 20, 2008). The composition of the CDX index is refreshed every six months. The pre-crisis period includes data from Series 3 through Series 8, whereas the crisis period includes data from Series 9 through Series 10. To simplify the calibration and reduce bid-ask bounce error, we use only the closing quotes on every Wednesday in the sample. We remove options with maturities less than one year because the slope of the volatility smile of these options are highly sensitive to smaller but more frequent jumps which have little impact on the 16 Technically if recovery amounts exceeded the notional of the super-senior tranche then the notional of the adjacent senior tranche should be written down and so on. In practice, this is very unlikely to happen. The model is easily amended to account for that, however. 13

16 risk-neutral distribution of market values over long horizons. 17 There are 206 weeks in our sample. The available options vary across moneynesses and maturities (between 1 and 3 years). While we use this option data to determine the time series of our state variables, we also use five year option data from CJS to calibrate the parameters of the model. To identify asset betas, idiosyncratic volatilities and leverage ratios of firms in the collateral pool, we use daily CRSP and quarterly/annual Compustat data from 2000 to We obtain daily risk-free return from Ken French s website. Treasury yields are from FRED, the database of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. 3.2 Calibration of the option return model First, we calibrate our SVDCJ option model to the 5-year index options (Series 4) from CJS. Using estimates from BCJ, we set the correlation coefficient between the market return and the market variance to ρ = 0.48 and the volatility parameter of the market variance to σ V = Theory implies that these two parameters should remain the same under both the P-measure and Q-measures. We also choose the risk-free rate r = 0.05, and the average market dividend yield δ = The rest of the parameters are chosen to minimize the percentage root mean square error (RMSE) of the 13 implied volatilities. We fix the initial values of the state variables to their long run means V 0 = V and δ 0 = δ. The calibrated parameters correspond to Estimate 1 in Table 1. A few parameter estimates are worth mentioning. Consistent with BCJ, we find an economically insignificant point estimate for ρ q. More importantly, the point estimate for the mean reversion coefficient on dividend yield κ δ is negative, implying non-stationarity. That is, consistent with the findings of Carr and Wu (2003), fitting long maturity option data requires a violation of one of the assumptions underlying the central limit theorem. With that said, we show in the robustness section that our main results regarding the CDX tranche spreads are not driven by this result, and indeed similar results are obtained if we assume the dividend yield is constant. Figure 2 shows the fit of the model for our calibration as well as the corresponding implied risk-neutral distribution. It is apparent that the model does a very good job at 17 That is, to jointly match short and long-maturity options would necessitate us adding additional jumps which are smaller in magnitude but more frequent. As has been shown in the previous literature, these jumps have negligible impact on the prices of long dated options. 14

17 fitting the sample of 13 long-dated implied volatilities obtained by CJS. We emphasize that since the parameters are similar to those of BCJ, and that the stochastic dividend yield mainly impacts long-dated option prices, we expect the model to also fit short dated S&P 500 futures options well. The second column denoted by Estimate 2 in Table 1 corresponds to a second calibration where we set the size of the catastrophic jump to y C = 2.0 (which corresponds to a 87% drop in price) and then choose its intensity λ Q to match the average spread on C the super-senior tranche for pre-crisis period. The recovery rate for those firms that default due to this jump is specified as 20% to capture the empirical finding that recovery rate is procyclical. (See, for example, Altman et al (2005)). We will discuss this in greater detail below, but it is worth emphasizing, as shown in Figure (2), that both calibrations imply almost identical option prices for those strikes that are actually traded, that is, for option strikes with moneyness greater than 0.7. Indeed, calibrating market dynamics to match the super-senior tranche impacts state prices significantly only for moneyness levels around 0.2 or lower. This is our first indication that one cannot extrapolate the information in option prices to deduce information regarding the super-senior tranche. Instead, we calibrate our model to match the super-senior tranche, and investigate the model implications for the other CDX tranches. The third and fourth columns are parameter values for the model calibrated to match the 5-year options in September, The risk-neutral catastrophe jump intensity is calibrated to the average spread of the super-senior tranche of CDX Series 10 (March, 2008 to September, 2008). The corresponding implied volatility curve and risk-neutral dynamics are shown in Figure 3. Comparing these results to those of Figure 2, we find rather dramatic changes to market dynamics during the crisis. 3.3 Calibration of asset value process The most crucial distinction between our calibration procedure and that of CJS is the following: CJS assumes that idiosyncratic risk is driven by a diffusion process, and then set the location of the default boundary at each date to perfectly match the five-year CDX index. In contrast, we assume idiosyncratic risk is driven by both diffusions and jumps, and calibrate our model to match the entire term structure of CDX indices. In particular, as in CJS, we use equity data to specify the idiosyncratic diffusion parameter. However, we set the idiosyncratic jump size to y i = 2.0 (a value which basically guarantees default), 15

18 and then calibrate the one-year, two-year, three-year, and four-year intensities 18 on the idiosyncratic jump, and the location of the default boundary, to perfectly match the CDX indices at all five of these horizons. We argue that including jumps is essential, since it is well-documented that diffusion-based structural models of default for investment grade firms fail badly at capturing spreads (i.e, risk-neutral expected losses) at short maturities. As we demonstrate below, the pricing of tranche spreads is very sensitive to matching these (risk-neutral) expected loss rates. To estimate asset beta, we take a weighted average of equity beta and debt beta. For each publicly traded firm in the on-the-run CDX series, equity beta is estimated using backward-looking 5-year daily equity returns prior to the first trading date of the series. As shown in Table 2, equity betas varied considerably over time, ranging from 0.82 to 0.99, and increased monotonically as the crisis approached. 19 Moreover, market volatility increased, and idiosyncratic volatility decreased over our sample period. The time series of the fraction of systematic versus idiosyncratic risk implied from our model calibrated to both options, CDX index and tranches are shown in Figure 5. As discussed previously, the distribution of losses becomes more peaked around expected losses as the fraction of idiosyncratic risk increases. This is shown in Figure 4. We estimate the beta of debt by regressing the excess returns of LQD (an ETF of investment graded corporate bonds) on the excess returns of S&P 500 for the same window of each series as we estimate the equity beta. The leverage ratio is defined as the book debt divided by the sum of book debt plus market equity, where book debt is from quarterly Compustat, using the short-term debt (DATA45) plus the long-term debt (DATA51). If any of these two numbers are missing, we use the corresponding items in the annual data. The cross-sectional average of leverage ratios are also displayed in Table Time Series of default boundary Early papers (e.g., Merton (1974)) specified the default boundary to equal the face value (or book value) of debt. However, there are at least three strands of literature that suggest the location of the default boundary may be significantly lower. First, the literature on optimal capital structure (e.g., Leland (1994)) predicts that equityholders may find it optimal to 18 We set the five-year intensity equal to the four-year intensity. This way, we have five free parameters to match the five CDX index spreads. 19 We emphasize that the change in beta over time is due in part to a change in composition of the index. 16

19 cover debt payments via equity issuance in order to keep their implicit option to the firm s cash flows alive even if firm value falls well below the face value of debt. Second, since historical recovery rates have averaged approximately 45%, default at the face value of debt would imply bankruptcy costs of 55%, a number which is difficult to believe, since one would expect workouts to occur more often if so much value was on the line. Furthermore, direct estimates of bankruptcy costs are on the order of 20% (e.g., Andrade and Kaplan (1998)). Combining these two numbers gives a prediction for the ratio of default boundary to face value of debt (F) equal to A B F = Third, Leland (2004) finds that the standard structural model of default under the historical measure is generally consistent with historical default rates (for maturities greater than three years) if the default boundary is approximately 70% of the face value of debt. Similar results are obtained by Davydenko (2008), who estimates this ratio to be in the range A B F (56%, 70%). As shown in Figure 6, the ratio of our calibrated default boundary to book value of debt varies significantly over our sample period, monotonically increasing from 57% at the beginning of our sample to nearly 100% during the crisis. In the calibrations below, we set the (risk-neutral expected) recovery rate to 40% for individual defaults, consistent with market convention, and slightly below the 45% historical recovery rate on investment grade senior unsecured debt. However, there is evidence that recovery is procyclical (e.g., Altman et al (2005)). As a recent example, the recovery rate on GM debt, whose default occurred during the crisis, was approximately 10%. Therefore, in our benchmark model we set recovery rate to 20% in the event of a market collapse. λ Q C Finally, we note that the average risk-neutral intensity associated with market collapse is = That is, the market anticipates a catastrophic event to occur less than once per thousand years. Although this intensity is miniscule, it has a significant impact on the size of the more senior tranche spreads. 4 Results 4.1 Average tranche spreads: pre-crisis period In this section we report six sets of tranche spreads averaged over the pre-crisis period September September 2007: The historical values; 17

20 Benchmark model: Catastrophic jumps calibrated to match the super-senior tranche spread; Idiosyncratic jumps and default boundary calibrated to match the 1-year, 2- year, 3-year, 4-year and 5-year CDX index spreads. λ Q = 0: No catastrophic jumps; Idiosyncratic jumps and default boundary calibrated C to match the 1-year, 2-year, 3-year, 4-year and 5-year CDX index spreads; λ Q = 0: Catastrophic jumps calibrated to match the super-senior tranche spread; No i idiosyncratic jumps; Default boundary calibrated to match only the 5Y CDX index. λ Q C = 0, λq i = 0: No catastrophic jumps; No idiosyncratic jumps; Default boundary calibrated to match only the 5Y CDX index; The results reported by CJS The results are given in Table 3. As shown in the last row, our framework generates errors that are an order of magnitude smaller than errors reported by CJS. Even in absolute terms, our framework performs well. As stated earlier, given the results of the previous literature (e.g., Longstaff and Rajan (2008)), we are confident that the fit could be improved even further if we were to calibrate market dynamics to match, say, mezzanine tranche spreads, rather than pricing them out-of-sample as we do here. Here we use the results of the other three models to provide some intuition for why our model performs so much better than that of CJS. We begin with the case closest to CJS; the model with no catastrophic and no idiosyncratic jumps (λ Q C = 0, λq i = 0). As with CJS, this model is calibrated to match option prices and the 5 year CDX index (and thus, it matches 5-year risk neutral expected losses). However, without idiosyncratic jumps, this model generates short horizon CDX index spreads that are well below observation. As such, expected losses are backloaded, implying that the buyer of equity protection pays too much premium for too long, in turn biasing down the estimate for the equity tranche spread. Since the model is calibrated to match expected losses, this downward bias on the equity tranche spread automatically biases upward spreads on the more senior tranches. To see how important this backloading issue is, we determine the CDX index spreads for maturities of 1-4 years for each of the models. The results are displayed in Table 4. For example, we find that the (λ Q C = 0, λq i = 0) model predicts credit spreads of 0bp and 3bp at maturities of 1 and 2 years, respectively, well below the market quotes of 13bp and 20bp. Adding idiosyncratic jumps calibrated to match short horizon credit spreads not only solves the backloading problem, but it also generates a five-year loss distribution that is more 18

21 peaked about the risk-neutral expected losses of 2.4%. Indeed, the standard deviation of the loss distribution without idiosyncratic jumps (λ Q C = 0, λq i = 0) has a standard deviation of 2.9%, whereas the standard deviation of the loss distribution with idiosyncratic jumps (λ Q = 0) has a standard deviation of 1.7%. The implication is that adding idiosyncratic C jumps generates a smaller probability of losses falling into the more senior tranches, pushing their spreads down, and in turn the equity tranche spread up. Thus, the downward bias of the equity tranche spread in the (λ Q C = 0, λq i = 0) model has two sources: one due to backloading, and one due to an error in the idiosyncratic risk/systematic risk composition. In an attempt to decompose this bias into its components, we approximate the backloading bias by treating losses as deterministic, and equal to the risk-neutral expected losses implied in Table 4. Note that this approach will produce an equity tranche spread that is biased upward for each model, since this approach does not cut off losses at the equity detachment point of 3%. As such, we focus not on the levels generated by this approximation, but rather on the difference in levels across these two models. Specifically, we assume that the term structure of loss rates is piecewise constant over the intervals (0-1 year), (1-2 year), (2-3 year), (3-4 year), and (4-5 year). The loss rates are chosen to perfectly match the implied term structure of credit spreads in Table 4. After these loss rates are determined, they are used to calculate the protection leg and premium leg of the tranche using equations (13) and (14). Calibrated to actual data on the term structure of CDX spreads (row 1 in table 4), we find the equity tranche spread equals 1929bp. In contrast, calibrated to the term structure of CDX spreads implied by our (λ Q C = 0, λq i = 0) model (row 5 in table 4), the equity tranche spread is only 1692bp. While both of these levels are biased upward by our approximation technique, the difference between these two estimates, 237bp, provides an estimate for the amount of downward bias in the equity tranche spread that can be attributed to backloading. If we start with the case (λ Q C = 0, λq i = 0), and then add idiosyncratic jumps to match the term structure of CDX index spreads, we get the model (λ Q = 0), the results of which C are shown in the third line of Table 3. Interestingly, we find in this case that the predicted equity tranche spread is actually too high implying a problem opposite to that reported by CJS. Since the backloading problem has been resolved in this case, these results imply that the (λ Q = 0) model is too peaked that is, has too high a ratio of idiosyncratic risk to C systematic risk. But this problem is easily resolved by adding a catastrophic jump calibrated to match the super-senior tranche spread (which produces our Benchmark model). As shown previously, including a catastrophic jump has virtually no impact on the model s ability to 19

22 match option prices. In summary then, we find that in order to estimate tranche spreads, it is necessary that the model be calibrated to match the term structure of credit spreads. Specifying a model with idiosyncratic dynamics driven only by diffusive risks generates a model where the timing of defaults is backloaded. This causes counter-factually low spreads/losses at short maturities, which in turn biases down the equity tranche spread. In addition, the super-senior tranche spread (and therefore, spreads on other senior tranches) cannot be extrapolated from option prices alone. However, spreads on other tranches can be interpolated reasonably well given option prices and super-senior tranche spreads. We conclude, in contrast with the results of CJS, that S&P 500 options and CDX tranche prices market can be fairly well reconciled within our arbitrage-free model. In that sense these two markets appear to be well integrated. 4.2 Time-series of tranche spreads In the previous section we showed that our benchmark model is able to fit average historical spreads across all tranches very well, once it is calibrated to match the term structure of CDX index spreads and the super-senior claim. In this section we investigate its time-series performance. For Series 3 to Series 9, we keep the parameters for the option pricing model fixed as given in Table 1 Estimates 2. For Series 10, we use the parameter values from the column labeled Estimate 4. Then, for each week, we use option prices to identify the state variables V t and δ t. The time-series of the RMSE are provided in Figure 7. In addition, each week we calibrate the intensity of the catastrophic jump to match the super-senior tranche, and the idiosyncratic jump intensities to match the term structure of CDX index spreads with maturities of one-year to five-years. The time series for the CDX indices and the super-senior tranche used by our calibration exercise are shown in Figure 8. With this calibration, we then estimate tranche spreads. The results (which we consider to be the main contribution of this paper) are given in Figure 9. Consistent with the timeaveraged results, the picture reveals a dramatic improvement in fit relative to that proposed by CJS. 20 Note that the performance is somewhat better during the pre-crisis period than the crisis period. For example, the model-implied 7-10% mezzanine tranche spread is too low, and the 15-30% senior tranche spread is too high during the crisis. Interestingly, even if we 20 We do not plot the super-senior tranche since it is fit perfectly by construction. 20

On the relative pricing of long maturity S&P 500 index options and CDX tranches

On the relative pricing of long maturity S&P 500 index options and CDX tranches On the relative pricing of long maturity S&P 5 index options and CDX tranches Pierre Collin-Dufresne Robert Goldstein Fan Yang May 21 Motivation Overview CDX Market The model Results Final Thoughts Securitized

More information

On the Relative Pricing of Long Maturity S&P 500 Index Options and CDX Tranches

On the Relative Pricing of Long Maturity S&P 500 Index Options and CDX Tranches On the Relative Pricing of Long Maturity S&P 500 Index Options and CDX Tranches by Pierre Collin-Dufresne Discussion by Markus Leippold Swissquote Conference Ecole Polytechnique Fédérale de Lausanne October,

More information

Discussion of An empirical analysis of the pricing of collateralized Debt obligation by Francis Longstaff and Arvind Rajan

Discussion of An empirical analysis of the pricing of collateralized Debt obligation by Francis Longstaff and Arvind Rajan Discussion of An empirical analysis of the pricing of collateralized Debt obligation by Francis Longstaff and Arvind Rajan Pierre Collin-Dufresne GSAM and UC Berkeley NBER - July 2006 Summary The CDS/CDX

More information

Exhibit 2 The Two Types of Structures of Collateralized Debt Obligations (CDOs)

Exhibit 2 The Two Types of Structures of Collateralized Debt Obligations (CDOs) II. CDO and CDO-related Models 2. CDS and CDO Structure Credit default swaps (CDSs) and collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) provide protection against default in exchange for a fee. A typical contract

More information

Optimal Stochastic Recovery for Base Correlation

Optimal Stochastic Recovery for Base Correlation Optimal Stochastic Recovery for Base Correlation Salah AMRAOUI - Sebastien HITIER BNP PARIBAS June-2008 Abstract On the back of monoline protection unwind and positive gamma hunting, spreads of the senior

More information

Hedging Default Risks of CDOs in Markovian Contagion Models

Hedging Default Risks of CDOs in Markovian Contagion Models Hedging Default Risks of CDOs in Markovian Contagion Models Second Princeton Credit Risk Conference 24 May 28 Jean-Paul LAURENT ISFA Actuarial School, University of Lyon, http://laurent.jeanpaul.free.fr

More information

HOW HAS CDO MARKET PRICING CHANGED DURING THE TURMOIL? EVIDENCE FROM CDS INDEX TRANCHES

HOW HAS CDO MARKET PRICING CHANGED DURING THE TURMOIL? EVIDENCE FROM CDS INDEX TRANCHES C HOW HAS CDO MARKET PRICING CHANGED DURING THE TURMOIL? EVIDENCE FROM CDS INDEX TRANCHES The general repricing of credit risk which started in summer 7 has highlighted signifi cant problems in the valuation

More information

Pricing & Risk Management of Synthetic CDOs

Pricing & Risk Management of Synthetic CDOs Pricing & Risk Management of Synthetic CDOs Jaffar Hussain* j.hussain@alahli.com September 2006 Abstract The purpose of this paper is to analyze the risks of synthetic CDO structures and their sensitivity

More information

A Simple Robust Link Between American Puts and Credit Protection

A Simple Robust Link Between American Puts and Credit Protection A Simple Robust Link Between American Puts and Credit Protection Liuren Wu Baruch College Joint work with Peter Carr (Bloomberg) The Western Finance Association Meeting June 24, 2008, Hawaii Carr & Wu

More information

A Simple Robust Link Between American Puts and Credit Insurance

A Simple Robust Link Between American Puts and Credit Insurance A Simple Robust Link Between American Puts and Credit Insurance Peter Carr and Liuren Wu Bloomberg LP and Baruch College Carr & Wu American Puts & Credit Insurance 1 / 35 Background: Linkages between equity

More information

Pricing Default Events: Surprise, Exogeneity and Contagion

Pricing Default Events: Surprise, Exogeneity and Contagion 1/31 Pricing Default Events: Surprise, Exogeneity and Contagion C. GOURIEROUX, A. MONFORT, J.-P. RENNE BdF-ACPR-SoFiE conference, July 4, 2014 2/31 Introduction When investors are averse to a given risk,

More information

Pricing of a European Call Option Under a Local Volatility Interbank Offered Rate Model

Pricing of a European Call Option Under a Local Volatility Interbank Offered Rate Model American Journal of Theoretical and Applied Statistics 2018; 7(2): 80-84 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/ajtas doi: 10.11648/j.ajtas.20180702.14 ISSN: 2326-8999 (Print); ISSN: 2326-9006 (Online)

More information

Credit Default Swaps, Options and Systematic Risk

Credit Default Swaps, Options and Systematic Risk Credit Default Swaps, Options and Systematic Risk Christian Dorion, Redouane Elkamhi and Jan Ericsson Very preliminary and incomplete May 15, 2009 Abstract We study the impact of systematic risk on the

More information

Expected Option Returns. and the Structure of Jump Risk Premia

Expected Option Returns. and the Structure of Jump Risk Premia Expected Option Returns and the Structure of Jump Risk Premia Nicole Branger Alexandra Hansis Christian Schlag This version: May 29, 28 Abstract The paper analyzes expected option returns in a model with

More information

Introduction Credit risk

Introduction Credit risk A structural credit risk model with a reduced-form default trigger Applications to finance and insurance Mathieu Boudreault, M.Sc.,., F.S.A. Ph.D. Candidate, HEC Montréal Montréal, Québec Introduction

More information

AN IMPROVED IMPLIED COPULA MODEL AND ITS APPLICATION TO THE VALUATION OF BESPOKE CDO TRANCHES. John Hull and Alan White

AN IMPROVED IMPLIED COPULA MODEL AND ITS APPLICATION TO THE VALUATION OF BESPOKE CDO TRANCHES. John Hull and Alan White AN IMPROVED IMPLIED COPULA MODEL AND ITS APPLICATION TO THE VALUATION OF BESPOKE CDO TRANCHES John Hull and Alan White Joseph L. Rotman School of Joseph L. Rotman School of Management University of Toronto

More information

Managing the Newest Derivatives Risks

Managing the Newest Derivatives Risks Managing the Newest Derivatives Risks Michel Crouhy IXIS Corporate and Investment Bank / A subsidiary of NATIXIS Derivatives 2007: New Ideas, New Instruments, New markets NYU Stern School of Business,

More information

Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/ / 24

Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions 11/4/ / 24 Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions Liuren Wu, Baruch College and Graduate Center Joint work with Peter Carr, New York University and Morgan Stanley CUNY Macroeconomics

More information

Which GARCH Model for Option Valuation? By Peter Christoffersen and Kris Jacobs

Which GARCH Model for Option Valuation? By Peter Christoffersen and Kris Jacobs Online Appendix Sample Index Returns Which GARCH Model for Option Valuation? By Peter Christoffersen and Kris Jacobs In order to give an idea of the differences in returns over the sample, Figure A.1 plots

More information

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Dynamic Relative Valuation Dynamic Relative Valuation Liuren Wu, Baruch College Joint work with Peter Carr from Morgan Stanley October 15, 2013 Liuren Wu (Baruch) Dynamic Relative Valuation 10/15/2013 1 / 20 The standard approach

More information

Option Pricing Modeling Overview

Option Pricing Modeling Overview Option Pricing Modeling Overview Liuren Wu Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College Options Markets Liuren Wu (Baruch) Stochastic time changes Options Markets 1 / 11 What is the purpose of building a

More information

Supplementary Appendix to The Risk Premia Embedded in Index Options

Supplementary Appendix to The Risk Premia Embedded in Index Options Supplementary Appendix to The Risk Premia Embedded in Index Options Torben G. Andersen Nicola Fusari Viktor Todorov December 214 Contents A The Non-Linear Factor Structure of Option Surfaces 2 B Additional

More information

DYNAMIC CORRELATION MODELS FOR CREDIT PORTFOLIOS

DYNAMIC CORRELATION MODELS FOR CREDIT PORTFOLIOS The 8th Tartu Conference on Multivariate Statistics DYNAMIC CORRELATION MODELS FOR CREDIT PORTFOLIOS ARTUR SEPP Merrill Lynch and University of Tartu artur sepp@ml.com June 26-29, 2007 1 Plan of the Presentation

More information

Explaining the Level of Credit Spreads: Option-Implied Jump Risk Premia in a Firm Value Model

Explaining the Level of Credit Spreads: Option-Implied Jump Risk Premia in a Firm Value Model Explaining the Level of Credit Spreads: Option-Implied Jump Risk Premia in a Firm Value Model K. J. Martijn Cremers Yale School of Management, International Center for Finance Joost Driessen University

More information

Modelling Default Correlations in a Two-Firm Model by Dynamic Leverage Ratios Following Jump Diffusion Processes

Modelling Default Correlations in a Two-Firm Model by Dynamic Leverage Ratios Following Jump Diffusion Processes Modelling Default Correlations in a Two-Firm Model by Dynamic Leverage Ratios Following Jump Diffusion Processes Presented by: Ming Xi (Nicole) Huang Co-author: Carl Chiarella University of Technology,

More information

Preference-Free Option Pricing with Path-Dependent Volatility: A Closed-Form Approach

Preference-Free Option Pricing with Path-Dependent Volatility: A Closed-Form Approach Preference-Free Option Pricing with Path-Dependent Volatility: A Closed-Form Approach Steven L. Heston and Saikat Nandi Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper 98-20 December 1998 Abstract: This

More information

Explaining individual firm credit default swap spreads with equity volatility and jump risks

Explaining individual firm credit default swap spreads with equity volatility and jump risks Explaining individual firm credit default swap spreads with equity volatility and jump risks By Y B Zhang (Fitch), H Zhou (Federal Reserve Board) and H Zhu (BIS) Presenter: Kostas Tsatsaronis Bank for

More information

Simple Dynamic model for pricing and hedging of heterogeneous CDOs. Andrei Lopatin

Simple Dynamic model for pricing and hedging of heterogeneous CDOs. Andrei Lopatin Simple Dynamic model for pricing and hedging of heterogeneous CDOs Andrei Lopatin Outline Top down (aggregate loss) vs. bottom up models. Local Intensity (LI) Model. Calibration of the LI model to the

More information

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives 4.1 Volatility trading and replication of variance swaps 4.2 Volatility swaps 4.3 Pricing of discrete

More information

Valuation of Forward Starting CDOs

Valuation of Forward Starting CDOs Valuation of Forward Starting CDOs Ken Jackson Wanhe Zhang February 10, 2007 Abstract A forward starting CDO is a single tranche CDO with a specified premium starting at a specified future time. Pricing

More information

Credit-Implied Volatility

Credit-Implied Volatility Credit-Implied Volatility Bryan Kelly University of Chicago Gerardo Manzo Two Sigma Diogo Palhares AQR American Financial Association January 7, 2018 Disclaimer This document is being distributed for informational

More information

SYSTEMIC CREDIT RISK: WHAT IS THE MARKET TELLING US? Vineer Bhansali Robert Gingrich Francis A. Longstaff

SYSTEMIC CREDIT RISK: WHAT IS THE MARKET TELLING US? Vineer Bhansali Robert Gingrich Francis A. Longstaff SYSTEMIC CREDIT RISK: WHAT IS THE MARKET TELLING US? Vineer Bhansali Robert Gingrich Francis A. Longstaff Abstract. The ongoing subprime crisis raises many concerns about the possibility of much broader

More information

Credit Modeling and Credit Derivatives

Credit Modeling and Credit Derivatives IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh Credit Modeling and Credit Derivatives In these lecture notes we introduce the main approaches to credit modeling and we will largely

More information

Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting MarketAFA, Disruptions 1/7/ / 14

Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting MarketAFA, Disruptions 1/7/ / 14 Leverage Effect, Volatility Feedback, and Self-Exciting Market Disruptions Liuren Wu, Baruch College Joint work with Peter Carr, New York University The American Finance Association meetings January 7,

More information

Analytical Pricing of CDOs in a Multi-factor Setting. Setting by a Moment Matching Approach

Analytical Pricing of CDOs in a Multi-factor Setting. Setting by a Moment Matching Approach Analytical Pricing of CDOs in a Multi-factor Setting by a Moment Matching Approach Antonio Castagna 1 Fabio Mercurio 2 Paola Mosconi 3 1 Iason Ltd. 2 Bloomberg LP. 3 Banca IMI CONSOB-Università Bocconi,

More information

Lecture 4: Forecasting with option implied information

Lecture 4: Forecasting with option implied information Lecture 4: Forecasting with option implied information Prof. Massimo Guidolin Advanced Financial Econometrics III Winter/Spring 2016 Overview A two-step approach Black-Scholes single-factor model Heston

More information

1. What is Implied Volatility?

1. What is Implied Volatility? Numerical Methods FEQA MSc Lectures, Spring Term 2 Data Modelling Module Lecture 2 Implied Volatility Professor Carol Alexander Spring Term 2 1 1. What is Implied Volatility? Implied volatility is: the

More information

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com

More information

Portfolio Management Using Option Data

Portfolio Management Using Option Data Portfolio Management Using Option Data Peter Christoffersen Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto, Copenhagen Business School, and CREATES, University of Aarhus 2 nd Lecture on Friday 1 Overview

More information

Jump and Volatility Risk Premiums Implied by VIX

Jump and Volatility Risk Premiums Implied by VIX Jump and Volatility Risk Premiums Implied by VIX Jin-Chuan Duan and Chung-Ying Yeh (First Draft: January 22, 2007) (This Draft: March 12, 2007) Abstract An estimation method is developed for extracting

More information

Pricing CDOs with the Fourier Transform Method. Chien-Han Tseng Department of Finance National Taiwan University

Pricing CDOs with the Fourier Transform Method. Chien-Han Tseng Department of Finance National Taiwan University Pricing CDOs with the Fourier Transform Method Chien-Han Tseng Department of Finance National Taiwan University Contents Introduction. Introduction. Organization of This Thesis Literature Review. The Merton

More information

Model Specification and Risk Premia: Evidence from Futures Options

Model Specification and Risk Premia: Evidence from Futures Options THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXII, NO. 3 JUNE 2007 Model Specification and Risk Premia: Evidence from Futures Options MARK BROADIE, MIKHAIL CHERNOV, and MICHAEL JOHANNES ABSTRACT This paper examines model

More information

Hedging the Smirk. David S. Bates. University of Iowa and the National Bureau of Economic Research. October 31, 2005

Hedging the Smirk. David S. Bates. University of Iowa and the National Bureau of Economic Research. October 31, 2005 Hedging the Smirk David S. Bates University of Iowa and the National Bureau of Economic Research October 31, 2005 Associate Professor of Finance Department of Finance Henry B. Tippie College of Business

More information

Implied Volatility Surface

Implied Volatility Surface Implied Volatility Surface Liuren Wu Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College Options Markets (Hull chapter: 16) Liuren Wu Implied Volatility Surface Options Markets 1 / 1 Implied volatility Recall the

More information

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford. Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey

More information

Hedging under Model Mis-Specification: Which Risk Factors Should You Not Forget?

Hedging under Model Mis-Specification: Which Risk Factors Should You Not Forget? Hedging under Model Mis-Specification: Which Risk Factors Should You Not Forget? Nicole Branger Christian Schlag Eva Schneider Norman Seeger This version: May 31, 28 Finance Center Münster, University

More information

In Search of Aggregate Jump and Volatility Risk. in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns*

In Search of Aggregate Jump and Volatility Risk. in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns* In Search of Aggregate Jump and Volatility Risk in the Cross-Section of Stock Returns* Martijn Cremers a Yale School of Management Michael Halling b University of Utah David Weinbaum c Syracuse University

More information

Financial Risk Management

Financial Risk Management Financial Risk Management Professor: Thierry Roncalli Evry University Assistant: Enareta Kurtbegu Evry University Tutorial exercices #3 1 Maximum likelihood of the exponential distribution 1. We assume

More information

Correlated Default Modeling with a Forest of Binomial Trees

Correlated Default Modeling with a Forest of Binomial Trees Correlated Default Modeling with a Forest of Binomial Trees Santhosh Bandreddi Merrill Lynch New York, NY 10080 santhosh bandreddi@ml.com Rong Fan Gifford Fong Associates Lafayette, CA 94549 rfan@gfong.com

More information

Unified Credit-Equity Modeling

Unified Credit-Equity Modeling Unified Credit-Equity Modeling Rafael Mendoza-Arriaga Based on joint research with: Vadim Linetsky and Peter Carr The University of Texas at Austin McCombs School of Business (IROM) Recent Advancements

More information

Determinants of Credit Default Swap Spread: Evidence from Japan

Determinants of Credit Default Swap Spread: Evidence from Japan Determinants of Credit Default Swap Spread: Evidence from Japan Keng-Yu Ho Department of Finance, National Taiwan University, Taipei, Taiwan kengyuho@management.ntu.edu.tw Yu-Jen Hsiao Department of Finance,

More information

C ARRY MEASUREMENT FOR

C ARRY MEASUREMENT FOR C ARRY MEASUREMENT FOR CAPITAL STRUCTURE ARBITRAGE INVESTMENTS Jan-Frederik Mai XAIA Investment GmbH Sonnenstraße 19, 80331 München, Germany jan-frederik.mai@xaia.com July 10, 2015 Abstract An expected

More information

Calculation of Volatility in a Jump-Diffusion Model

Calculation of Volatility in a Jump-Diffusion Model Calculation of Volatility in a Jump-Diffusion Model Javier F. Navas 1 This Draft: October 7, 003 Forthcoming: The Journal of Derivatives JEL Classification: G13 Keywords: jump-diffusion process, option

More information

Model Estimation. Liuren Wu. Fall, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Liuren Wu Model Estimation Option Pricing, Fall, / 16

Model Estimation. Liuren Wu. Fall, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Liuren Wu Model Estimation Option Pricing, Fall, / 16 Model Estimation Liuren Wu Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College Fall, 2007 Liuren Wu Model Estimation Option Pricing, Fall, 2007 1 / 16 Outline 1 Statistical dynamics 2 Risk-neutral dynamics 3 Joint

More information

Smooth pasting as rate of return equalisation: A note

Smooth pasting as rate of return equalisation: A note mooth pasting as rate of return equalisation: A note Mark hackleton & igbjørn ødal May 2004 Abstract In this short paper we further elucidate the smooth pasting condition that is behind the optimal early

More information

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives John Crosby Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University Presentation at Baruch College, in New York, 16th November 2010

More information

1 Introduction. 2 Old Methodology BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM DIVISION OF RESEARCH AND STATISTICS

1 Introduction. 2 Old Methodology BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM DIVISION OF RESEARCH AND STATISTICS BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM DIVISION OF RESEARCH AND STATISTICS Date: October 6, 3 To: From: Distribution Hao Zhou and Matthew Chesnes Subject: VIX Index Becomes Model Free and Based

More information

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management Omar El Euch and Mathieu Rosenbaum École Polytechnique 4 October 2017 Omar El Euch and Mathieu Rosenbaum

More information

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle Resolution of a Financial Puzzle M.J. Brennan and Y. Xia September, 1998 revised November, 1998 Abstract The apparent inconsistency between the Tobin Separation Theorem and the advice of popular investment

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Online Appendix Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University Shu Wu University of Kansas August 2017 1

More information

Smile in the low moments

Smile in the low moments Smile in the low moments L. De Leo, T.-L. Dao, V. Vargas, S. Ciliberti, J.-P. Bouchaud 10 jan 2014 Outline 1 The Option Smile: statics A trading style The cumulant expansion A low-moment formula: the moneyness

More information

Factors in Implied Volatility Skew in Corn Futures Options

Factors in Implied Volatility Skew in Corn Futures Options 1 Factors in Implied Volatility Skew in Corn Futures Options Weiyu Guo* University of Nebraska Omaha 6001 Dodge Street, Omaha, NE 68182 Phone 402-554-2655 Email: wguo@unomaha.edu and Tie Su University

More information

This paper investigates whether realized and implied volatilities of individual stocks can predict the crosssectional

This paper investigates whether realized and implied volatilities of individual stocks can predict the crosssectional MANAGEMENT SCIENCE Vol. 55, No. 11, November 2009, pp. 1797 1812 issn 0025-1909 eissn 1526-5501 09 5511 1797 informs doi 10.1287/mnsc.1090.1063 2009 INFORMS Volatility Spreads and Expected Stock Returns

More information

Dynamic Models of Portfolio Credit Risk: A Simplified Approach

Dynamic Models of Portfolio Credit Risk: A Simplified Approach Dynamic Models of Portfolio Credit Risk: A Simplified Approach John Hull and Alan White Copyright John Hull and Alan White, 2007 1 Portfolio Credit Derivatives Key product is a CDO Protection seller agrees

More information

This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:

This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: Yale ICF Working Paper No. 04-14 December 2004 INDIVIDUAL STOCK-OPTION PRICES AND CREDIT SPREADS Martijn Cremers Yale School of Management Joost Driessen University of Amsterdam Pascal Maenhout INSEAD

More information

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Nicola Fusari

Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels. Nicola Fusari Parametric Inference and Dynamic State Recovery from Option Panels Nicola Fusari Joint work with Torben G. Andersen and Viktor Todorov July 2012 Motivation Under realistic assumptions derivatives are nonredundant

More information

Do rare events explain CDX tranche spreads?

Do rare events explain CDX tranche spreads? Do rare events explain CDX tranche spreads? Sang Byung Seo University of Houston Jessica A. Wachter University of Pennsylvania December 31, 215 and NBER Abstract We investigate whether a model with a time-varying

More information

Simple Robust Hedging with Nearby Contracts

Simple Robust Hedging with Nearby Contracts Simple Robust Hedging with Nearby Contracts Liuren Wu and Jingyi Zhu Baruch College and University of Utah October 22, 2 at Worcester Polytechnic Institute Wu & Zhu (Baruch & Utah) Robust Hedging with

More information

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors 3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors 1. Default dynamics of a single obligor. 2. Model the dependence structure of defaults

More information

Bachelier Finance Society, Fifth World Congress London 19 July 2008

Bachelier Finance Society, Fifth World Congress London 19 July 2008 Hedging CDOs in in Markovian contagion models Bachelier Finance Society, Fifth World Congress London 19 July 2008 Jean-Paul LAURENT Professor, ISFA Actuarial School, University of Lyon & scientific consultant

More information

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models PETER CARR Head of Quantitative Financial Research, Bloomberg LP, New York Director of the Masters Program in Math Finance, Courant Institute, NYU Stanford

More information

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes 1/ 27 Introduction Using a mixture of jump and di usion processes can model asset prices that are subject to large, discontinuous changes,

More information

Theoretical Problems in Credit Portfolio Modeling 2

Theoretical Problems in Credit Portfolio Modeling 2 Theoretical Problems in Credit Portfolio Modeling 2 David X. Li Shanghai Advanced Institute of Finance (SAIF) Shanghai Jiaotong University(SJTU) November 3, 2017 Presented at the University of South California

More information

Synthetic CDO Pricing Using the Student t Factor Model with Random Recovery

Synthetic CDO Pricing Using the Student t Factor Model with Random Recovery Synthetic CDO Pricing Using the Student t Factor Model with Random Recovery UNSW Actuarial Studies Research Symposium 2006 University of New South Wales Tom Hoedemakers Yuri Goegebeur Jurgen Tistaert Tom

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model The Black-Scholes Model Liuren Wu Options Markets Liuren Wu ( c ) The Black-Merton-Scholes Model colorhmoptions Markets 1 / 18 The Black-Merton-Scholes-Merton (BMS) model Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton

More information

A Consistent Pricing Model for Index Options and Volatility Derivatives

A Consistent Pricing Model for Index Options and Volatility Derivatives A Consistent Pricing Model for Index Options and Volatility Derivatives 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Society Thomas Kokholm Finance Research Group Department of Business Studies Aarhus School of

More information

A Simple Robust Link Between American Puts and Credit Insurance

A Simple Robust Link Between American Puts and Credit Insurance A Simple Robust Link Between American Puts and Credit Insurance Liuren Wu at Baruch College Joint work with Peter Carr Ziff Brothers Investments, April 2nd, 2010 Liuren Wu (Baruch) DOOM Puts & Credit Insurance

More information

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo

Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs. Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo Hedging Under Jump Diffusions with Transaction Costs Peter Forsyth, Shannon Kennedy, Ken Vetzal University of Waterloo Computational Finance Workshop, Shanghai, July 4, 2008 Overview Overview Single factor

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 2016 by Martin Haugh The Black-Scholes Model In these notes we will use Itô s Lemma and a replicating argument to derive the famous Black-Scholes formula

More information

Information about price and volatility jumps inferred from option prices

Information about price and volatility jumps inferred from option prices Information about price and volatility jumps inferred from option prices Stephen J. Taylor Chi-Feng Tzeng Martin Widdicks Department of Accounting and Department of Quantitative Department of Finance,

More information

CB Asset Swaps and CB Options: Structure and Pricing

CB Asset Swaps and CB Options: Structure and Pricing CB Asset Swaps and CB Options: Structure and Pricing S. L. Chung, S.W. Lai, S.Y. Lin, G. Shyy a Department of Finance National Central University Chung-Li, Taiwan 320 Version: March 17, 2002 Key words:

More information

Differential Pricing Effects of Volatility on Individual Equity Options

Differential Pricing Effects of Volatility on Individual Equity Options Differential Pricing Effects of Volatility on Individual Equity Options Mobina Shafaati Abstract This study analyzes the impact of volatility on the prices of individual equity options. Using the daily

More information

European option pricing under parameter uncertainty

European option pricing under parameter uncertainty European option pricing under parameter uncertainty Martin Jönsson (joint work with Samuel Cohen) University of Oxford Workshop on BSDEs, SPDEs and their Applications July 4, 2017 Introduction 2/29 Introduction

More information

Delta-Hedging Correlation Risk?

Delta-Hedging Correlation Risk? ISFA, Université Lyon 1 International Finance Conference 6 - Tunisia Hammamet, 10-12 March 2011 Introduction, Stéphane Crépey and Yu Hang Kan (2010) Introduction Performance analysis of alternative hedging

More information

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes

Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes Asset Pricing Models with Underlying Time-varying Lévy Processes Stochastics & Computational Finance 2015 Xuecan CUI Jang SCHILTZ University of Luxembourg July 9, 2015 Xuecan CUI, Jang SCHILTZ University

More information

FX Smile Modelling. 9 September September 9, 2008

FX Smile Modelling. 9 September September 9, 2008 FX Smile Modelling 9 September 008 September 9, 008 Contents 1 FX Implied Volatility 1 Interpolation.1 Parametrisation............................. Pure Interpolation.......................... Abstract

More information

Semi-Analytical Valuation of Basket Credit Derivatives in Intensity-Based Models

Semi-Analytical Valuation of Basket Credit Derivatives in Intensity-Based Models Semi-Analytical Valuation of Basket Credit Derivatives in Intensity-Based Models Allan Mortensen This version: January 31, 2005 Abstract This paper presents a semi-analytical valuation method for basket

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model The Black-Scholes Model Liuren Wu Options Markets (Hull chapter: 12, 13, 14) Liuren Wu ( c ) The Black-Scholes Model colorhmoptions Markets 1 / 17 The Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) model Black and Scholes

More information

Understanding the Role of VIX in Explaining Movements in Credit Spreads

Understanding the Role of VIX in Explaining Movements in Credit Spreads Understanding the Role of VIX in Explaining Movements in Credit Spreads Xuan Che Nikunj Kapadia 1 First Version: April 3, 2012 1 University of Massachusetts, Amherst. Preliminary; comments are welcome.

More information

Optimal Capital Structure, Endogenous Bankruptcy, and the Term Structure of Credit Spreads

Optimal Capital Structure, Endogenous Bankruptcy, and the Term Structure of Credit Spreads Optimal Capital Structure, Endogenous Bankruptcy, and the Term Structure of Credit Spreads The Journal of Finance Hayne E. Leland and Klaus Bjerre Toft Reporter: Chuan-Ju Wang December 5, 2008 1 / 56 Outline

More information

Calibration and Parameter Risk Analysis for Gas Storage Models

Calibration and Parameter Risk Analysis for Gas Storage Models Calibration and Parameter Risk Analysis for Gas Storage Models Greg Kiely (Gazprom) Mark Cummins (Dublin City University) Bernard Murphy (University of Limerick) New Abstract Model Risk Management: Regulatory

More information

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns?

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? University of Miami School of Business Stan Stilger, Alex Kostakis and Ser-Huang Poon MBS 23rd March 2015, Miami Alex Kostakis (MBS)

More information

Dynamic Factor Copula Model

Dynamic Factor Copula Model Dynamic Factor Copula Model Ken Jackson Alex Kreinin Wanhe Zhang March 7, 2010 Abstract The Gaussian factor copula model is the market standard model for multi-name credit derivatives. Its main drawback

More information

Factor Copulas: Totally External Defaults

Factor Copulas: Totally External Defaults Martijn van der Voort April 8, 2005 Working Paper Abstract In this paper we address a fundamental problem of the standard one factor Gaussian Copula model. Within this standard framework a default event

More information

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities Michael Schürle Institute for Operations Research and Computational Finance, University of St. Gallen, Bodanstr. 6, CH-9000 St. Gallen, Switzerland

More information

Implied Correlations: Smiles or Smirks?

Implied Correlations: Smiles or Smirks? Implied Correlations: Smiles or Smirks? Şenay Ağca George Washington University Deepak Agrawal Diversified Credit Investments Saiyid Islam Standard & Poor s. June 23, 2008 Abstract We investigate whether

More information

Chapter 18 Volatility Smiles

Chapter 18 Volatility Smiles Chapter 18 Volatility Smiles Problem 18.1 When both tails of the stock price distribution are less heavy than those of the lognormal distribution, Black-Scholes will tend to produce relatively high prices

More information

Risk and Return of Short Duration Equity Investments

Risk and Return of Short Duration Equity Investments Risk and Return of Short Duration Equity Investments Georg Cejnek and Otto Randl, WU Vienna, Frontiers of Finance 2014 Conference Warwick, April 25, 2014 Outline Motivation Research Questions Preview of

More information

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions

Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Predicting Inflation without Predictive Regressions Liuren Wu Baruch College, City University of New York Joint work with Jian Hua 6th Annual Conference of the Society for Financial Econometrics June 12-14,

More information