From Individual to Aggregate Labor Supply

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "From Individual to Aggregate Labor Supply"

Transcription

1 From Individual to Aggregate Labor Supply Yongsung Chang Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania 3718 Locust Walk Philadelphia, PA Sun-Bin Kim Department of Economics Concordia University 1455 de Maisonneuve Blvd, W. Montreal, QC, H3G 1M8 March 27, 2002 Abstract Macroeconomists often assume an elastic labor supply, despite the low estimates from various micro studies. The extensive margin (entry-exit margin) has been recognized as a potential resolution. We construct a model economy in which heterogeneous agents decide on labor-market participation and the capital market is incomplete. Heterogeneity of the workforce is designed such that the evolution of wages, worker flows between employment and nonemployment, and cross-sectional earnings distribution are consistent with micro data. We find the aggregate labor-supply elasticity of such an economy less than 1, smaller than those assumed in aggregate models. Keywords: Aggregate Labor-Supply Elasticity, Heterogeneity, Indivisible Labor JEL Classifications: E24, E32, J21, J22 We thank Olivier Blanchard for sharing the worker-flow data with us. We thank Jose-Victor Rios-Rull for helpful comments. Chang gratefully acknowledges the financial support of the University of Pennsylvania Research Foundation.

2 1 Introduction Despite enormous heterogeneity, both in productivity and preferences in the workforce, economists often postulate and analyze an economy populated by identical agents for its simplicity and tractability. A fully specified representative-agent model has become a workhorse in macroeconomics, since Lucas and Rapping (1969) s pioneering work on aggregate labor-market fluctuations. It is now a common practice to rely on micro evidence to pin down the key parameters of highly aggregated models (e.g., Kydland and Prescott, 1982; Prescott, 1986; King, Plosser, and Rebelo, 1988). Unfortunately, however, this practice often creates a conflict between micro and macro observations. One of the stylized facts in economic fluctuations is that total hours vary greatly over the business cycle without much variation in wages. Among many, one explanation is substitution of leisure over time by workers, requiring an elastic labor supply beyond the admissible estimates based on micro data (e.g., Ghez and Becker, 1975; MaCurdy, 1981; Altonji, 1986; Abowd and Card, 1989). 1 The participation margin the so-called extensive margin has been recognized as a potential resolution, as the variation in the number of employees is the dominant source of fluctuations in total hours worked (e.g., Coleman, 1984; Heckman, 1984). For example, Prescott (1986) refers to this margin as a rationale for an elasticity higher than micro estimates. Another prominent example is Hansen (1985) s a linear utility in leisure, derived from the indivisible labor and employment lottery of Rogerson (1988). An economy with indivisibility at the micro level may be approximated by a representativeagent economy with divisible labor, as the indivisibility is smoothed by an aggregation over hetero- 1 See Pencavel (1986) for a survey on labor-supply elasticity. See also Mulligan (1998) on how the current micro estimates may underestimate the workers willingness to substitute leisure over time. 1

3 geneous agents. While this point is well illustrated in Mulligan (2001), we have yet to investigate its quantitative implications, because the mapping from the micro to the macro function depends crucially on the nature of heterogeneity in the workforce. 2 Heckman (1984, p. 210), in his comments on Kydland (1984), argues A fictional macro function must be created which is related to the true micro behavior by an aggregation process that Kydland and others for some reason feel they can safely ignore. The literature, so far, has not echoed to this concern. 3 In this paper we examine the aggregate labor-supply of an economy in which population possesses a serious heterogeneity in earnings and preference. Our strategy and main findings can be illustrated as follows. We construct a dynamic general equilibrium model economy populated by many workers. A worker faces idiosyncratic shocks to his productivity and preference, and the capital market is incomplete. Workers decide on labor supply in a discrete manner labor is indivisible. Heterogeneity in the workforce is disciplined by the two sets of micro data. The stochastic process of idiosyncratic productivity shocks is estimated by the wage process from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID). Conditional on the idiosyncratic productivity process, the stochastic process of individual preference shocks is specified to match the average worker flows between employment and nonemployment in the Blanchard and Diamond (1990) data based on the Current Population Survey (CPS) for In order to assess the validity of the heterogeneity in the model, we compare the cross-sectional distributions of earnings and wealth to those in Diaz-Gimenez, Quadrini, and Rios-Rull (1997), 2 For example, suppose there is a mass of workers, almost indifferent about either working or not working at the current wage. A small wage increase induces a large increase in participation. Alternatively, if the reservation-wage distribution is scattered, the same wage increase ends up with a small variation in total hours. 3 See also Browning, Hansen, and Heckman (1999) that raises warning flags about the current use of micro evidence in calibrating macro models. 2

4 documented from the Survey of Consumer Finance (SCF). The model economy reproduces the earnings and wealth distributions in the SCF reasonably well. We then introduce exogenous shifts in labor demand through the variation of aggregate productivity. We find the response of total hours from our heterogeneous-agent economy comparable to those from the economies with laborsupply elasticity between 0.6 and 0.8, which is much smaller than those often assumed in aggregate models. Among others, earlier important works on the labor-market heterogeneity in the context of a stochastic growth model include Kydland (1984), Cho (1995), Andolfatto and Gomme (1996), Castaneda, Diaz-Gimenez, and Rios-Rull (1998), Merz (1999), and Gomes, Greenwood, and Rebelo (2001). Kydland and Cho are the closest to our work as they focus on labor supply. Kydland constructs an economy with two types of workers, skilled and unskilled, and reproduces some labor-market regularity in relative wages and hours. However, this approach does not reflect the participation margin, a dominant source of variation in total hours. Cho first incorporates the extensive margin into the real-business-cycle model in which workers are ex ante identical and ex post heterogeneous. This considerably simplifies the computation since the consumption is shared among workers. It is, however, clear in the data that persons with greater hours or greater earnings per hour consume more. We argue that realistic ex ante heterogeneity is important because workers take into account their ability and preference in making decisions on consumption, savings, and labor supply. The recent advance made by Krusell and Smith (1998), also adopted in Castaneda et al. and Gomes et al., allows us to characterize the equilibrium fluctuations in incomplete market. Gomes et al. examine the cyclical behavior of unemployment rates; Andolfatto and Gomme the Canadian unemployment insurance policy; Castaneda et al. the income distribution and unemployment spells; Merz the cyclical behavior of labor turnover. 3

5 The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the model. Section 3 calibrates the parameters of the model, including the heterogeneity in productivity and preference. In Section 4, we characterize the steady state and fluctuations of the model, including the response of aggregate labor supply to exogenous shifts in (labor) demand. Section 5 is the conclusion. 2 The Model 2.1 Environment The model economy is a version of the stochastic-growth model with a large (measure one) population of infinitely lived workers. Individual workers differ from each other in productivity and preference for leisure. Each worker maximizes the expected discounted lifetime utility: U = max {c t,h t} t=0 E 0 { t=0 } β t u(c t, h t ; z t ), with (1 h t ) 1 1/γ u(c t, h t ; z t ) = ln c t + Bz t, 1 1/γ where E 0 [ ] denotes the expectation operator conditional on information available at time 0, β is the discount factor, c t consumption, and h t hours worked at time t. The utility is separable between consumption and leisure and across times. The assumption about the form of utility is popular in both business-cycle analysis (e.g., Hansen, 1985; King, Plosser, and Rebelo, 1988) and the empirical labor-supply literature (e.g., MaCurdy, 1981; Altonji, 1986). The parameter γ denotes the intertemporal substitution elasticity of leisure. Log utility in consumption supports a balanced growth path. The individual preference shock z t, affecting the marginal rate of substitution between goods and leisure, varies exogenously over time according to a stochastic process with a transition probability distribution function, π z (z z) = Pr(z t+1 z z t = z). 4

6 According to our production technology, which will be specified below, labor input enters simply as an effective unit. Thus, a worker who supplies h t units of time earns w t x t h t, where w t is the market wage rate for the efficiency unit of labor, and x t represents the worker s productivity. We assume that individual productivity x t exogenously varies over time according to a stochastic process with a transition probability distribution function π x (x x) = Pr(x t+1 x x t = x). Following Hansen and Rogerson, we abstract from an intensive margin and assume that labor supply is indivisible; i.e., h t takes either zero or h(< 1). A worker can save and borrow by trading a claim for physical capital, which yields the rate of return r t and depreciates at rate δ. Workers face a borrowing constraint; the level of asset holdings, a t, cannot be negative at any time. The capital market is incomplete; the physical capital is the only asset available to insure against idiosyncratic risks in x and z. A worker s budget constraint is: c t = w t x t h t + (1 + r t )a t a t+1, and a t+1 0. Firms produce output according to constant-returns Cobb-Douglas technology in capital, K t, and effective labor, L t : Y t = F (L t, K t, λ t ) = λ t L α t K 1 α t, where λ t is aggregate productivity, following a stochastic process with a transition probability distribution function, π λ (λ λ) = Pr(λ t+1 λ λ t = λ). It is useful to consider a recursive equilibrium definition, including the law of motion for aggregate state of the economy. Suppose µ(a, x, z) denotes the distribution (measure) of workers Let A, X and Z denote sets of all possible realizations of a, x and z, respectively. The measure µ(a, x, z) is defined over a σ-algebra of A X Z. 5

7 Let V E and V N denote the values of employed and nonemployed. If a worker decides to work, she solves the following Bellman equation by choosing the next period asset holdings a : { V E (a, x, z; λ, µ) = max u(c, 1 h; z) a A [ + βe max { V E (a, x, z ; λ, µ ), V N (a, x, z ; λ, µ ) } ] } (1) x, z, λ subject to c = wx h + (1 + r)a a, a 0, and µ = T(λ, µ). where T denotes a transition operator for µ. If the worker decides not to work, her Bellman equation is: { u(c, 1; z) V N (a, x, z; λ, µ) = max a A subject to [ + βe max { V E (a, x, z ; λ, µ ), V N (a, x, z ; λ, µ ) } ] } (2) x, z, λ c = (1 + r)a a, a 0, and µ = T(λ, µ). Having solved (1) and (2), it is straightforward to deal with worker s labor-supply decision: { } V (a, x, z; λ, µ) = max h { h,0} V E (a, x, z; λ, µ), V N (a, x, z; λ, µ). (3) 6

8 2.2 Equilibrium Equilibrium consists of a set of decision rules of an individual for consumption, asset holding, and labor supply, {c(a, x, z; λ, µ), a (a, x, z; λ, µ), h(a, x, z; λ, µ)}, the value function, V (a, x, z; λ, µ), functions for aggregate inputs, {K(λ, µ), L(λ, µ)}, functions for factor prices, {w(λ, µ), r(λ, µ)}, and a law of motion for the distribution µ = T(λ, µ) such that: 1. Individual optimization: Given w(λ, µ) and r(λ, µ), the individual decision rules c(a, x, z; λ, µ), a (a, x, z; λ, µ), and h(a, x, z; λ, µ) solve (1), (2), and (3). 2. The firm s profit maximization: w(λ, µ) = F 1 ( L(λ, µ), K(λ, µ), λ ) (4) r(λ, µ) = F 2 ( L(λ, µ), K(λ, µ), λ ) δ (5) for all (λ, µ). 3. The goods market clears: {a (a, x, z; λ, µ) + c(a, x, z; λ, µ) } dµ = F ( L(λ, µ), K(λ, µ), λ ) + (1 δ)k (6) for all (λ, µ). 4. Factor markets clear: L(λ, µ) = xh(a, x, z; λ, µ)dµ (7) K(λ, µ) = adµ (8) for all (λ, µ). 7

9 5. Consistency of individual and aggregate behavior: µ (A 0, X 0, Z 0 ) = A 0,X 0,Z 0 { A,X,Z for all A 0 A, X 0 X and Z 0 Z. } 1 a =a (a,x,z;λ,µ) dπ x (x x)dπ z (z z)dµ da dx dz (9) 3 Calibration A key element in the mapping from individual to aggregate labor supply is the nature of heterogeneity in the workforce. In our model this amounts to properly specifying the stochastic process of x and z. We assume that the individual productivity follows an AR(1) process in logs: ln x = ρ x ln x + ε x, ε x N(0, σ 2 x). (10) Panel data from the PSID for the period of are used to estimate this process. Appendix A.1 describes the PSID data we use in detail. According to our model, the log wage for individual i at time t, denoted by ln wt, i can be written as ln wt i = ln w t + ln x i t, where w t and x i t denote the market wage rate for an effective unit of labor and individual i s productivity, respectively. When quasi-differenced, individual wage evolves as: ln w i t = ρ x ln w i t 1 + (ln w t ρ x ln w t 1 ) + ε i x,t. (11) Equation (11) is estimated with year dummies which capture aggregate effects including ln w t ρ x ln w t 1. The OLS estimate for ρ x is with a standard error of (R 2 = 0.69). 5 This is an annual estimate, and we uncover the quarterly values ρ x = 0.95 and σ x = as described in Appendix A.2. 5 When we include age, sex, and years of schooling in the regression to control for individual characteristics, the persistence decreases from to Both estimates are somewhat lower than the persistence of idiosyncratic labor-income risks reported in Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (1999). 8

10 Labor economists and econometricians (e.g., Heckman 1978; Burtless and Hausman, 1978; MaCurdy, Green, and Paarsch, 1990) have found enormous heterogeneity in the marginal rate of substitution between goods and leisure. While this rate tends to depend on observed characteristics, such as marital status and number of children, the magnitude of unobserved component is not only large but also persistent over time. We assume that the preference shock z follows an AR(1) process in logs and is independent of productivity x. ln z = ρ z ln z + ε z, ε z N(0, σ 2 z). (12) We do not see a practical way to estimate this directly. Thus, we simply set ρ z = ρ x. Concerning the standard deviation σ z, we use a model-based approach. In steady state, there are constant flows of workers between employment and nonemployment. Conditional on the stochastic process for productivity, we search for a magnitude of preference shock σ z such that the steady-state worker flows from the model match the average gross-worker flows in the data. According to our calculation based on Blanchard and Diamond (1990) data, which we describe in Appendix A.3, during , on average 5.15 percent of the population moved from employment to nonemployment each quarter; however, 5.35 percent of the population moved in the opposite direction, from nonemployment to employment. 6 With σ z = 0.45 we obtain 5.25 percent for both flows in the steady state. Other parameters of the model are in accord with business-cycle analysis and empirical laborsupply literature. According to the Michigan Time-Use Survey, a typical married couple allocates about 33 percent of its discretionary time for paid compensation (e.g., Hill, 1984; Juster and Stafford, 1991): we set h = 1/3. Regarding the intertemporal substitution elasticity of leisure 6 Nonemployment includes both unemployment and non-labor-force. According to Blanchard and Diamond, the flows between employment and non-labor-force are as big as as those between employment and unemployment. 9

11 γ, most estimates based on micro labor-supply data fall between 0 and 0.5: we use The labor share, α, is 0.64, and the quarterly depreciation rate, δ, is 2.5 percent. When we search for the value of σ z that matches the average worker flows, we jointly search for B such that the steady-state employment rate is 65 percent, the sample average in Blanchard-Diamond data. The discount factor β is chosen so that the real rate of return to capital is 4 percent annually. 8 Table 1 summarizes the parameter values. Finally, when we investigate the response of hours with fluctuations, we introduce exogenous shifts in aggregate productivity that resembles the total factor productivity from the post-war U.S. data: λ can take two values, ln λ { , }, and its transition matrix between the two states is π λ = [ ]. 4 Results We solve the worker s problem by computing an approximation to value functions (1), (2), and (3) on a discrete-state space. Tauchen s (1986) algorithm is used to approximate the transition probabilities when evaluating the conditional expectations in value functions. For the steady state, we use the algorithm described in Rios-Rull (1999) to find the invariant distribution of workers. When we introduce aggregate fluctuations, we adopt the bounded rationality method developed by Krusell and Smith, in which agents are assumed to make use of a finite set of moments of 7 With discrete choice of hours of work, the value of γ by itself is not so important. Given the level of consumption, the utilities of the employed and the non-employed differ by a constant term. 8 The discount factor is lower than that in the representative-agent model, because market incompleteness increases savings as noted in Aiyagari (1994). 10

12 the distribution µ. The justification of this method is that by using partial information about µ, households do almost as well as by using all the information in µ when predicting future prices. In fact, Krusell and Smith show that use of the first moment only provides a remarkably good approximation in a stochastic-growth model. We show that this is the case in our economy as well. A detailed description of the computational procedures is provided in Appendix A The Steady State We first characterize the steady state of the model economy in which there is no aggregate uncertainty, and the distribution of workers is invariant. As described in the previous section, we have calibrated B and σ z such that employment rate and worker flows replicate the data in the steady state. Table 2 confirms this. Employment rate, gross worker flows into and out of employment, and hazard rates of worker flows are very close to those in the data. The data statistics are quarterly averages for 1968 to 1986 computed from the Blanchard-Diamond data. We ask whether the model generates a reasonable cross-sectional distribution of wealth and earnings. While our primary objective is not to explain the income inequality, we view this as an indirect way of assessing our calibration of idiosyncratic productivity and preference shocks. Figure 1 shows the Lorenz curves of the wealth distribution for the U.S. and the model. The statistics for the U.S. are from Diaz-Gimenez, Quadrini, and Rios-Rull, which is based on the 1992 SCF. The wealth is much more concentrated in the data than our economy. In terms of earnings, however, both economies exhibit similar inequality, as shown in Figure 2. Table 3 reports the Gini indices. For earnings, it is 0.56 in the model, close to 0.63 in the U.S. data; for wealth, it is 0.49, much lower than 0.78 in the data. Table 4 shows the detailed comparison between the model and 1992 SCF, again, documented 11

13 by Diaz-Gimenez et al. For each quintile group of the wealth distribution, we calculate the wealth share, ratio of group average to economy-wide average, and earnings share. In 1992 households in the 4th and 5th quintile of the wealth distribution own and percent of total wealth, respectively. According to the model, they own and percent, respectively. The average asset holdings of the households in the 5th quintile is 3.97 times larger than that of a typical household in the data, while this ratio is 2.64 according to our model. For earnings, households in the 5th quintile of the wealth distribution earn percent of total earnings in the data, whereas they earn percent in the model. Overall, the wealth is more concentrated in the data. In particular, the model fails to match the highly concentrated wealth in the right tail of the distribution. According to Diaz-Gimenez et. al, about half of total wealth is held by the top 5 percent of the population in the U.S., whereas only 18.5 percent of total wealth is held by them in our model (not shown in the Table). However, our primary objective is not to explain the income inequality or the behavior of the top 1 or 5 percent of population. The model economy seems to possess a reasonably large heterogeneity for our purpose, to study aggregate labor supply; that is, the stochastic process of wages is directly estimated from the panel data and the cross-sectional earnings distribution is, by and large, consistent with micro data. Before we introduce aggregate uncertainty, we illustrate the labor-market participation and consumption decisions of workers in the model. Figure 3 shows the combination of ln x and ln z that makes the worker indifferent between working and not-working. Each line corresponds to the workers at the 1st, 2nd, 3rd, and 4th quintile of the wealth distribution. At a given asset level, workers with productivity above the cutoff line choose to work. Equivalently, workers with preference below the cutoff choose to work. As the asset increases, from the 1st quintile to the 2nd, and so forth, the line shifts to the right; the richer individuals are, the more selective in working. To illustrate, consider a worker on the 4th quintile of the wealth distribution with average 12

14 productivity and preference (ln x = 0 and ln z = 0). According to Figure 3, he is indifferent between working and not-working. Suppose, for example, his hourly wage was 20 dollars. A worker on the 1st quintile with the same preference is indifferent in working at hourly wage of 5 dollars 50 cents (= $20 exp 1.3 ). Figure 4 shows the average consumption of employed and nonemployed individual for each asset holdings. Given the separable utility and no risk-sharing, the consumption of employed is greater than that of nonemployed at all asset levels. Also, note that the consumption, so is savings, is close to linear in assets in most range except for those near the borrowing constraint Fluctuations In the model, exogenous shifts in productivity generate aggregate fluctuations. We do not take a stand on the sources of the business cycle here, but we intentionally exclude other types of aggregate disturbances, especially those that shift the labor-supply curve. Aggregate productivity shocks act like an instrument, shifting the labor-demand curve (marginal product of labor), to identify the slope of the aggregate labor-supply curve. Table 5 summarizes the cyclicality and volatility of three labor-market variables: employment and worker flows into and out of employment. Since we assume a single aggregate disturbance, we do not expect our economy to replicate the labor-market fluctuation in the data. However, it is still of interest to see the response of key labor-market variables to aggregate disturbances. The model statistics are calculated from 5,000 periods of simulated data. As a reference, we report the comparable statistics for the post-war U.S. economy. Employment is less volatile than the data; the standard deviation relative to output is 0.36 in our model, whereas it is 0.46 in the data. 9 This partially justifies our approximation procedure which uses the first moment only in computing equilibria under aggregate fluctuations below. 13

15 Employment is highly correlated with output (0.84) as in the data (0.77). The cyclical behavior of the flow out of employment is somewhat close to that in the data; the relative standard deviation and the correlation with output are 2.71 and in the model, respectively, while they are 2.39 and -0.21, respectively, in the data. The flow into employment is almost a mirror image to the flow out-of employment in the model, whereas it is somewhat less volatile and virtually uncorrelated with output in the data. We now investigate the elasticity of aggregate labor supply. We do so by comparing with the divisible-labor representative-agent economies under the same economic environment. For a representative-agent economy, the Frisch labor-supply equation around the steady state is ĥ t = ψ(ŵ t ĉ t ), ψ = 1 h γ, (13) h where the circumflexes denote the variable s percentage deviation from its steady-state value. The Frisch labor-supply elasticity ψ, also known as lamda-constant-labor-supply elasticity or the compensated labor-supply elasticity, represents the response of hours with respect to wages holding consumption (or wealth) constant. We consider four economies with ψ equaling to 0.4, 0.6, 0.8, and 1. With h = 1/3, these correspond to γ of 0.2, 0.3, 0.4, and 0.5, respectively. 10 The representativeagent economies have the same parameter values in Table 1 except for γ. 11 We compute the equilibria of all model economies by the same method. Table 6 summarizes the main findings of the paper. It displays the statistics of five model economies (our indivisible-labor heterogeneous-agent economy and four representative-agent economies) and the U.S economy. The upshot is that the response of hours in the heterogenous-agent economy is similar to that from the representative-agent economies with labor-supply elasticity between For example, Prescott (1986) uses ψ = 2 by supposing γ = 1 and h = 1/3. 11 For each representative economy, the parameter B is also adjusted to yield h = 1/3 in the steady state. 14

16 and 0.8. Regarding the labor-market variables in the 4th row, the volatility of aggregate hours for our model is 0.53; they are 0.47 and 0.59 for the economies with labor-supply elasticity of 0.6 and 0.8, respectively. The volatility of hours relative to labor productivity is 0.46, falls between those with ψ = 0.6 (0.43). The volatility of hours relative to output is 0.34, close to that with ψ = 0.8 (0.36). 12 A similar comparison applies to other aggregate variables. The volatility of output (1.56) is close to that with ψ=0.6 (1.56), the volatility of consumption (0.42) is close to that of the economy with ψ=0.8 (0.41), the volatility of investment (5.16) is close to that of the economy with ψ=0.6 (5.20). Aggregate labor supply is not sensitive to fluctuations in productivity, because of the large heterogeneity in the workforce. The dispersion of individual productivity (measured by the crosssectional standard deviation of log wages in the PSID) is larger than that of aggregate productivity (measured by the time-series standard deviation of aggregate TFP) by a factor of nearly 27. The standard deviation of individual preference shocks is at least twice as big as that of individual productivity. The implied reservation-wage distribution is scattered. As a result, a temporary high wage, say, a few percents above the steady state, does not generate a big increase in participation. In sum, under the heterogeneity we have, designed to match the certain aspects of the labor market, the aggregate labor-supply elasticity is slightly bigger than micro estimates, but smaller than those often assumed in macro models. 13 A highly elastic labor supply resulting from the indivisible labor 12 Given the single aggregate disturbance which shifts the labor demand, one might be tempted to determine the aggregate labor-supply elasticity of the model simply by estimating Equation (13) using the model-generated aggregate time-series data. However, with an incomplete market, the aggregation theorem does not hold. When we actually estimate (13) based on model-generated data, the value for ψ is 0.4 by OLS (with R 2 of only 0.45) and 0.27 by IV with lagged consumption and wages as instruments. 13 Since the variation of hours in the model stems sorely from the extensive margin, allowing for an intensive margin may generate a bigger response of aggregate labor supply. However, under the small intertemporal substitution 15

17 and employment lottery does not survive a serious heterogeneity and market incompleteness. 5 Conclusion The labor supply is at the heart of macroeconomic research. It is a cornerstone of the equilibrium approach that relies on intertemporal substitution of leisure. In a disequilibrium approach, in which the role of labor supply is dismissed in the short run, the labor supply is still crucial for the welfare loss of the economy departing from the equilibrium. Aggregate models often assume elastic labor supply, despite the low estimates from empirical studies based on individual data. The extensive margin, a major source of hours variation over the business cycle, has been proposed as a potential resolution. We construct and compute the equilibrium of an economy where heterogeneous agents decide on labor-market participation and the capital market is incomplete. Heterogeneity of workforce is designed such that evolution of wages, gross worker flows, and cross-sectional income distribution are consistent with the micro data. We find the responses of hours from such an economy comparable to those from an economy with labor-supply elasticity between 0.6 and 0.8, which is much lower than those often assumed in aggregate models. elasticity, this will not increase the aggregate labor-supply elasticity substantially. 16

18 References [1] Abowd, John. M., and David Card, 1989, On the Covariance Structure of Earnings and Hours Changes, Econometrica, 57, [2] Abowd, John. M., and Arnold Zellner, 1985, Estimating Gross Labor Force Flows, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 3, [3] Aiyagari, Rao S., 1994, Uninsured Idiosyncratic Risk and Aggregate Savings, Quarterly Journal of Economics, CIX, [4] Altonji, Joseph, 1986, Intertemporal Substitution in Labor Supply: Evidence from Micro Data, Journal of Political Economy 94, s176-s215. [5] Andolfatto, David and Paul Gomme, 1996, Unemployment Insurance and Labor Market Activity in Canada, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 44, [6] Blanchard, Olivier J., and Peter Diamond, 1990, The Cyclical Behavior of the Gross Flows of U.S. Workers, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, [7] Browning, Martin, Lars Hansen, and James Heckman, 1999, Micro Data and General Equilibrium Models, in J. Taylor and M. Woodford eds., Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol 1A, [8] Burtless, G., and Jerry Hausman, 1993, The Effect of Taxes on Labor Supply; Evaluating the Gary Negative Income Tax Experiment, Journal of Political Economy 86 (6), [9] Cho, Jang-Ok, 1995, Ex-post Heterogeneity and the Business Cycle, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 19,

19 [10] Coleman, T., 1984, Essays on Aggregate Labor Market Business Cycle Fluctuations, Ph. D. thesis, University of Chicago. [11] Diaz-Gimenez, Javier, Vincenzo Quadrini, and Jose-Victor Rios-Rull, 1997, Dimensions of Inequality: Facts on the U.S. Distributions of Earnings, Income, and Wealth, Quarterly Review 21 (2), [12] Ghez, G. Ricardo. and Gary Becker, 1975, The Allocation of Time and Goods over the Life Cycle, New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, Columbia University Press. [13] Gomes, Joao, Jeremy Greenwood, and Sergio Rebelo, 2001, Equilibrium Unemployment, Journal of Monetary Economics, 48, [14] Hansen, Gary D., 1985, Indivisible Labor and the Business Cycle, Journal of Monetary Economics, 16, [15] Heckman, James, 1978, Effects of Child-Care Programs on Women s Work Effort in: T.W. Schultz, ed., Economics of the Family: Marriage, Children, and Human Capital, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, [16] Heckman, James, 1984, Comments on Ashenfelter and Kydland Papers, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 21, [17] Hill, M. S. 1984, Pattern of Time Use, in Time, Goods and Well-Being, F. Thomas Juster and Frank P. Stafford, eds., Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. [18] Juster, F. T., and F. P. Stafford, 1991, The Allocation of Time: Empirical Findings, Behavior Models, and Problems of Measurement, Journal of Economic Literature 29, [19] King, Robert, Charles Plosser, and Sergio Rebelo, 1988, Production, Growth, and Business Cycles I: Basic Neo-classical Model Journal of Monetary Economics 21,

20 [20] Krusell, Per, and Anthony Smith, 1998, Income and Wealth Heterogeneity in the Macroeconomy, Journal of Political Economy, 106, [21] Kydland, Finn, 1984, Heterogeneity in Labor Market and Business Cycles, Carnegie- Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 21, [22] Kydland, Finn, and Edward Prescott, 1982, Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations, Econometrica 50, [23] Lucas, Robert, and Leonard Rapping, 1969, Real Wages, Employment, and Inflation, Journal of Political Economy 77, [24] MaCurdy, Thomas, 1981, An Empirical Model of Labor Supply in a Life Cycle Setting, Journal of Political Economy, 88, [25] MaCurdy, Thomas, D. Green, and H. Paarsch, 1990, Assessing Empirical Approaches to Analyzing Taxes and Labor Supply, Journal of Huamn Resources, 25(3), [26] Merz, Monika, 1999, Heterogeneous Job-Matches and the Cyclical Behavior of Labor Turnover, Journal of Monetary Economics, 43, [27] Mulligan, Casey B., 1998, Substitution Over Time: Another Look at Life-Cycle Labor Supply, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 13, [28] Mulligan, Casey B., 2001, Aggregate Implications of Indivisible Labor, Advances in Macroeconomics Vol. 1: No. 1, Article 4. [29] Pencavel, J., 1986, Labor Supply of Men, Handbook of Labor Economics, edited by O. Ashenfelter and R. Layards. Amsterdam: North Holland. 19

21 [30] Prescott, Edward, 1986, Theory Ahead of Business-Cycle Measurement, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series of Public Policy, 25, [31] Rios-Rull, Jose-Victor, 1999, Computation of Equilibria in Heterogeneous-Agents Models, in Computational Methods for the Study of Dynamic Economies, Ramon Marimon and Andrew Scott eds., Oxford University Press. [32] Rogerson, Richard, 1988, Indivisible Labor, Lotteries and Equilibrium, Journal of Monetary Economics, 21, [33] Storesletten, Kjetil, Chris Telmer, and Amir Yaron, 1999, The Risk-Sharing Implications of Alternative Social Security Arrangement, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 50, [34] Tauchen, George, 1986, Finite State Markov-Chain Approximations to Univariate and Vector Autoregressions, Economics Letters, 20,

22 A Appendix A.1 The PSID Data The PSID sample period used is The sample consists of heads of households and wives. We start in 1979 because the wage data for wives are available only since Wages are annual hourly earnings (annual labor incomes divided by annual hours). Nominal wages are deflated by the Consumer Price Index. The base year is Workers who worked less than 100 hours per year or whose hourly wage rate was below $1 (in 1983 dollars) are viewed as nonemployed even though their employment status is reported as employed in the survey. We use workers who were employed in non-agricultural sectors and not self-employed. We also restrict the sample to hourly earnings less than or equal to $500. The descriptive statistics for our PSID data are summarized in Table A.1. Table A.1: Summary Statistics for the PSID Variable Mean S.D. Obs. Real Wage Rate (in 1983 $) Log Real Wage Log Real Wage (net of aggregate effect) Annual Hours of work Age Years of schooling Sex (male =1) Note: Log real wages (net of aggregate effect) are the residuals from the regression of log wages on year dummies. 21

23 A.2 Conversion between Annual and Quarterly Variances After controlling for aggregate price of an effective unit of labor, the wage evolves according to x. Since the wages in the PSID are annual averages: 14 ln x τ = 1 4 { ln x (τ,1) + ln x (τ,2) + ln x (τ,3) + ln x (τ,4) }, where x τ is annual average and x (τ,q) denotes the wage of the qth quarter in year τ. According to a AR(1) process for x, the quarterly persistence ρ x is simply 0.95(= ) where is the annual estimate from the PSID. Furthermore, ln x τ = 1 4 {(1 + ρ x + ρ 2 x + ρ 3 x) ln x τ 1 + (1 + ρ x + ρ 2 x)ε x,(τ,2) + (1 + ρ x )ε x,(τ,3) + ε x,(τ,4) }. The standard deviation of annual average is: σ(ln x) = 1 4 σ x { (1 + ρx + ρ 2 x + ρ 3 x) 2 1 ρ 2 x + (1 + ρ x + ρ 2 x) 2 + (1 + ρ x ) 2 + 1} 1/2. When we replace σ(ln x) with 0.601, the standard deviation of log annual hourly earning (net of aggregate effects) from the PSID, we obtain σ x = A.3 The Blanchard-Diamond Data The Blanchard and Diamond (1990) data, which is preceded by Abowd and Zellner (1985), is based on monthly CPS. We convert the monthly worker-flow series into the quarterly data consistent with our model. We also normalize them by dividing by the noninstitutional population of age 65 or less. There are three possible labor-market status: employment, unemployed, and non-labor-force, denoted by e, u, and n, respectively. The following formula is used to construct the flow of workers from labor-market status i to j during the quarter, denoted by f ij : f ij = ī h 1 ik h2 kl h3 lj, i, j {e, u, n}, k,l {e,u,n} 14 Note that 1 4 P 4 q=1 ln x (τ,q) can be interpreted as a log-linear approximation of the arithmetic average ln ex τ = ln[ 1 4 P 4 q=1 x (τ,q)]. 22

24 where ī denotes the number of workers in status i in the beginning of the quarter, and h m kl the monthly hazard rate from status k to l in the m-th month of the quarter. This takes into account all possible paths, direct and indirect, from i to j during a quarter, and avoids a potential double counting in a simple sum of monthly flows. A.4 Computational Procedures A.4.1 Steady-State Equilibrium The distribution of workers is invariant in the steady state; so are the factor prices. We search for the discount factor β that clears the capital market given an quarterly rate of return of 1 percent. Computing the steady-state equilibrium amounts to finding the value functions, the associated decision rules, and the time-invariant measure of workers. Details are as follows: 1. Choose 936 grid points for asset holdings, a i, in the range of [0, 199], where average asset holding is The grid points of assets are not equally spaced. We assign more points on the lower asset range to better approximate savings decisions of workers with lower assets. For productivity, x j, and preference for leisure, z k, we construct grid vectors of 9 equally spaced points in which ln x j s lie on the range of ±3σ x / 1 ρ 2 x and ln z k s on the range of ±3σ z / 1 ρ 2 z. 2. Given β, we solve the individual optimization problem in (1), (2), and (3) at each grid point of the individual states. In this step, we also obtain the optimal decision rules for asset holdings a (a i, x j, z k ) and labor supply h(a i, x j, z k ). This step involves the following procedure: (a) Initialize value functions V E 0 (a i, x j, z k ), V N 0 (a i, x j, z k ), and V 0 (a i, x j, z k ). (b) Update value functions by evaluating the discretized versions of (1), (2), and (3): { V1 E (a i, x j, z k ) = max u ( w hx j + (1 + r)a i a, 1 h; ) z k (A.4.1) 23

25 + β 9 9 j =1 k =1 { V1 N (a i, x j, z k ) = max u ( (1 + r)a i a ), 1; z k and + β 9 9 j =1 k =1 [ ] } max V0 E (a, x j, z k ), V0 N (a, x j, z k ) π x (x j x j )π z (z k z k ), (A.4.2) [ ] } max V0 E (a, x j, z k ), V0 N (a, x j, z k ) π x (x j x j )π z (z k z k ), { } V 1 (a i, x j, z k ) = max V1 E (a i, x j, z k ), V1 N (a i, x j, z k ), (A.4.3) where π x (x j x j ) and π z (z k z k ) are the transition probabilities of x and z respectively, which are approximated using Tauchen s (1986) algorithm. (c) If V 1 and V 0 are close enough for all grid points, then we found the value functions. Otherwise, set V0 E = V 1 E and V0 N = V1 N, and go back to step 2-(b). 3. Using a (a i, x j, z k ), π x (x j x j ) and π z (z k z k ) obtained from step 2, we obtain time-invariant measures µ (a i, x j, z k ) as follows: (a) Initialize the measure µ 0 (a i, x j, z k ). (b) Update the measure by evaluating the discretized version of (9): µ 1 (a i, x j, z k ) = i=1 j=1 k=1 9 1 ai =a (a i,x j,z k )µ 0 (a i, x j, z k )π x (x j x j )π z (z k z k ) (A.4.4) (c) If µ 1 and µ 0 are close enough for all grid points, then we found the time-invariant measure. Otherwise, replace µ 0 with µ 1, and go back to step 3(b). 4. We calculate the real interest rate as a function of β, i.e., r(β) = α ( K(β)/L(β) ) 1 α δ, where K(β) = i=1 j=1 k=1 a iµ (a i, x j, z k ) and L(β) = i=1 j=1 k=1 x jh(a i, x j, z k )µ (a i, x j, z k ). Other aggregate variables of interest are calculated using µ and decision rules. If r(β) is close enough to the assumed value of the real interest rate, we found the steady state. Otherwise, choose a new β and go back to step 2. 24

26 A.4.2 Equilibrium with Aggregate Fluctuations Approximating the equilibrium in the presence of aggregate fluctuations requires us (i) to include the measure of workers and the aggregate productivity shock in the list of state variables, and (ii) to keep track of the evolution of the measure µ over time. Since µ is an infinite dimensional object, it is almost impossible to implement these tasks as they are. We follow the procedure suggested by Krusell and Smith (1998). We assume that agents make use of its first moment only. The law of motion for aggregate capital stock is restricted to the log-linear function. Therefore, computing the equilibrium with aggregate fluctuations amounts to finding the value functions, decision rules, and law of motion for the aggregate capital within the class of a parametric form of the log linear in K and λ. Details are as follows: 1. In addition to the grids for individual state variables specified above, we choose 7 grid points for the aggregate capital K in the range of [0.93K, 1.07K ], where K denotes the steadystate aggregate capital. In our numerous simulations, the capital stock has never reached the upper or lower bound. The stochastic process for the aggregate productivity shock π λ (λ λ) is described in the text. 2. Let the parametric law of motion for the aggregate capital take a log linear in K and λ: ln K t+1 = κ κ 0 1 ln K t + κ 0 2 ln λ t. (A.4.5) In order for individuals to make their decisions on savings and labor supply they have to know (or predict) the interest rate and wage rate for an effective unit of labor. While the factor prices depend on aggregate capital and labor aggregate labor input is not known to individuals at the moment when they make decisions. Thus, individuals need to predict the factor prices. These predictions on factor prices, in turn, must be consistent with the 25

27 outcome of individual actions the factor market clearing in (7) and (8). We also assume that individuals predict the market wage and the interest rate using a log-linear function of K and λ: ln w t = b b 0 1 ln K t + b 0 2 ln λ t. (A.4.6) and ln r t = d d 0 1 ln K t + d 0 2 ln λ t (A.4.7) 3. We choose the initial values for the coefficients κ 0 s, b 0 s and d 0 s. Good initial values may come from a representative-agent model. 4. Given the law of motion for the aggregate capital and the prediction functions for factor prices, we solve the individual optimization problem in (1), (2), and (3). This step is analogous to step 2 in the steady-state computation: (a) We have to solve for the value functions and the decision rules over a bigger state space. Now the state variables are (a, x, z, K, λ). (b) Computation of the conditional expectation involves the evaluation of the value functions not on the grid points along the K dimension since K predicted by (A.4.5) need not be a grid point. We polynomial-interpolate the value functions along K dimension when necessary. 5. Using a (a i, x j, z k, K l, λ m ), h(a i, x j, z k, K l, λ m ), π x (x j x j ), π z (z k z k ), π λ (λ m λ m ), and the assumed law of motion for the aggregate capital, we generate a set of artificial time series data {K t, w t, r t } of the length of 5,000 periods. Each period, {K t, w t, r t } is calculated by aggregating labor supply and asset holdings of 50,000 individuals. 6. We obtain new values for coefficients κ 1 s, b 1 s and d 1 s by the OLS from the simulated data. 26

28 If κ 1 s, b 1 s and d 1 s are close enough to κ 0 s, b 0 s, and d 0 s, respectively, we found the law of motion. Otherwise, update coefficients by setting κ 0 = κ 1, b 0 = b 1 s and d 0 = d 1 s, and go back to step 4. The estimated law of motion for capital and prediction functions and their accuracy, measured by R 2 for the prediction equations are as follows. the law of motion for aggregate capital in equation (A.4.5): ln K t+1 = ln K t ln λ t, R 2 = the market wage rate in equation (A.4.6): ln w t = ln K t ln λ t, R 2 = the interest rate in equation (A.4.7): ln r t = ln K t ln λ t, R 2 = The law of motion for aggregate capital provides the highest accuracy. The wage function is more accurate than the interest rate function. Overall, predictions functions are fairly precise as R 2 s are close to 1. 27

29 Table 1: Parameters of the Benchmark Economy Parameter α = 0.64 β = γ = 0.2 B = 0.65 h = 1/3 ρ x = 0.95 σ x = ρ z = 0.95 σ z = 0.45 Description Labor share in production function Discount factor Intertemporal substitution elasticity of leisure Utility parameter Steady-state hour Persistence of idiosyncratic productivity shock Standard deviation of innovation to idiosyncratic productivity Persistence of idiosyncratic preference shock Standard deviation of innovation to idiosyncratic preference Table 2: Labor Market Steady States Variable Data Model Employment rate Flow out of employment Flow into employment Hazard rate out of nonemployment Hazard rate into employment Note: All variables are in percentage. Data are quarterly averages for based on Blanchard and Diamond (1990) as described in Appendix A.3. 28

30 Table 3: Gini Indices for Wealth and Earnings Variable Data Model Wealth Earnings Note: Data statistics are from Diaz-Gimenez, Quadrini, and Rios-Rull (1997) based on 1992 Survey of Consumer Finance. Table 4: Characteristics of Wealth Distribution Quintile 1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th Total U.S. Data Share of wealth Group average/population average Share of earnings Model Share of wealth Group average/population average Share of earnings Note: Data statistics are from Diaz-Gimenez, Quadrini, and Rios-Rull (1997) based on 1992 Survey of Consumer Finance. 29

31 Table 5: Cyclical Behavior of Labor Market Variable Volatility Cyclicality Data Model Data Model Employment rate Flow out of employment Flow into employment Hazard rate out of employment Hazard rate into employment Note: Variables are in percentage and detrended by the H-P filter. Volatility denotes the standard deviation of the variables divided by the standard deviation of output. Cyclicality denotes the correlation with output. Table 6: Comparison with Divisible Labor Economies Indivisible Divisible U.S. Data ψ = 0.4 ψ = 0.6 ψ = 0.8 ψ = :I-1998:4 σ(y ) σ(c) σ(i) σ(n) σ(n)/σ(y/n) σ(n)/σ(y ) Note: ψ denotes the Frisch labor-supply elasticity. Data are from the DRI data base. Y = GDP-government spending; C = consumption of non durables and services; I = nonresidential fixed investment; N = total employed hours in non-agricultural private sector from the establishment survey. All variables are divided by civilian noninstitutional population over 16. All variables are detrended by the H-P filter. 30

32 Figure 1: Lorenz Curves for Wealth o line Model U.S Figure 2: Lorenz Curves for Earnings o line Model U.S

33 Figure 3: Cutoff (x, z) for Work Decision for Selected Asset Levels ln z st Quintile 2nd Quintile 3rd Quintile 4th Quintile ln x Figure 4: Consumption by Employment Status Consumption Employed Non Employed Asset Holdings 32

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from: Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ From Individual to Aggregate Labor Supply: A Quantitative Analysis based on a Heterogeneous

More information

Issues of labor supply are at the heart of macroeconomic studies of large

Issues of labor supply are at the heart of macroeconomic studies of large On the Aggregate Labor Supply Yongsung Chang and Sun-Bin Kim Issues of labor supply are at the heart of macroeconomic studies of large cyclical fluctuations. The population puts forth more work effort

More information

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar, and Peter Rupert Can the neoclassical growth model generate fluctuations in the return to capital similar to those observed in

More information

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics Department of Economics HKUST August 7, 2018 Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics 1 / 48 Reference Krueger, Dirk, Kurt Mitman, and Fabrizio Perri. Macroeconomics

More information

The Idea. Friedman (1957): Permanent Income Hypothesis. Use the Benchmark KS model with Modifications. Income Process. Progress since then

The Idea. Friedman (1957): Permanent Income Hypothesis. Use the Benchmark KS model with Modifications. Income Process. Progress since then Wealth Heterogeneity and Marginal Propensity to Consume Buffer Stock Saving in a Krusell Smith World Christopher Carroll 1 Jiri Slacalek 2 Kiichi Tokuoka 3 1 Johns Hopkins University and NBER ccarroll@jhu.edu

More information

Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks

Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks Eunseong Ma September 27, 218 Department of Economics, Texas A&M University, College Station,

More information

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective Alisdair McKay Boston University June 2013 Microeconomic evidence on insurance - Consumption responds to idiosyncratic

More information

The Aggregate Implications of Individual Labor Supply Heterogeneity. José Mustre-del-Río December 2011 RWP 11-09

The Aggregate Implications of Individual Labor Supply Heterogeneity. José Mustre-del-Río December 2011 RWP 11-09 The Aggregate Implications of Individual Labor Supply Heterogeneity José Mustre-del-Río December 2011 RWP 11-09 The Aggregate Implications of Individual Labor Supply Heterogeneity José Mustre-del-Río Federal

More information

Exploring the income distribution business cycle dynamics

Exploring the income distribution business cycle dynamics Exploring the income distribution business cycle dynamics Ana Castañeda Universitat Pompeu Fabra Javier Díaz-Giménez Universidad Carlos III de Madrid José-Victor Ríos-Rull Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

Optimal Income tax rates with non-democratic political constraints: case of Armenia

Optimal Income tax rates with non-democratic political constraints: case of Armenia Optimal Income tax rates with non-democratic political constraints: case of Armenia Vardan Baghdasaryan * Hayk Hambardzumyan Abstract Tax is the main source for a government to finance its expenditures

More information

Behavioral Theories of the Business Cycle

Behavioral Theories of the Business Cycle Behavioral Theories of the Business Cycle Nir Jaimovich and Sergio Rebelo September 2006 Abstract We explore the business cycle implications of expectation shocks and of two well-known psychological biases,

More information

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours Ekonomia nr 47/2016 123 Ekonomia. Rynek, gospodarka, społeczeństwo 47(2016), s. 123 133 DOI: 10.17451/eko/47/2016/233 ISSN: 0137-3056 www.ekonomia.wne.uw.edu.pl Aggregation with a double non-convex labor

More information

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of Intermediation Costs Antnio Antunes Tiago Cavalcanti Anne Villamil November 2, 2006 Abstract This paper studies the distributional implications of intermediation

More information

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of Intermediation Costs Tiago V. de V. Cavalcanti Anne P. Villamil July 14, 2005 Abstract This paper studies the distributional implications of intermediation

More information

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting Masaru Inaba and Kengo Nutahara Research Institute of Economy, Trade, and

More information

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) ....... Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO) Rapid Aging and Chinese Pension Reform, June 3, 2014 SHUFE, Shanghai ..... The results in this

More information

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 April Last week two benchmarks: autarky and complete markets non-state contingent bonds:

More information

Discussion of Heaton and Lucas Can heterogeneity, undiversified risk, and trading frictions solve the equity premium puzzle?

Discussion of Heaton and Lucas Can heterogeneity, undiversified risk, and trading frictions solve the equity premium puzzle? Discussion of Heaton and Lucas Can heterogeneity, undiversified risk, and trading frictions solve the equity premium puzzle? Kjetil Storesletten University of Oslo November 2006 1 Introduction Heaton and

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Ming-Jen Chang, Shikuan Chen and Yen-Chen Wu National DongHwa University Thursday 22 nd November 2018 Department of Economics,

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Comparative Advantage and Labor Market Dynamics

Comparative Advantage and Labor Market Dynamics Comparative Advantage and Labor Market Dynamics Weh-Sol Moon* The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the official views of the Bank of Korea. When reporting or

More information

Intrepreting Labor Supply Regressions in a Model of Full and Part-Time Work

Intrepreting Labor Supply Regressions in a Model of Full and Part-Time Work Intrepreting Labor Supply Regressions in a Model of Full and Part-Time Work Yongsung Chang University of Rochester Yonsei University Sun-Bin Kim Yonsei University Richard Rogerson Arizona State University

More information

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt WORKING PAPER NO. 08-15 THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt Keith Kuester Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Final version

More information

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility Christiano Economics 416 Advanced Macroeconomics Take home midterm exam. 1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility The purpose of this question is to explore a labor market puzzle that has bedeviled business

More information

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar Linda Goldberg and Joseph Tracy Federal Reserve Bank of New York and NBER April 2001 Abstract Although the dollar has been shown to influence

More information

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation Andrew Keinsley Weber State University Version 5.02 May 1, 2017 Abstract Under the assumption that different measures of inflation draw on the same

More information

Zipf s Law, Pareto s Law, and the Evolution of Top Incomes in the U.S.

Zipf s Law, Pareto s Law, and the Evolution of Top Incomes in the U.S. Zipf s Law, Pareto s Law, and the Evolution of Top Incomes in the U.S. Shuhei Aoki Makoto Nirei 15th Macroeconomics Conference at University of Tokyo 2013/12/15 1 / 27 We are the 99% 2 / 27 Top 1% share

More information

Balance Sheet Recessions

Balance Sheet Recessions Balance Sheet Recessions Zhen Huo and José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Minnesota Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis CAERP CEPR NBER Conference on Money Credit and Financial Frictions Huo & Ríos-Rull

More information

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting Roberto M. Billi Sveriges Riksbank 3 January 219 Abstract I evaluate the welfare performance of a target for the level of nominal GDP in the context

More information

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls Lucas (1990), Supply Side Economics: an Analytical Review, Oxford Economic Papers When I left graduate school, in 1963, I believed that the single most desirable change in the U.S. structure would be the

More information

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application Russell Cooper, John Haltiwanger and Jonathan Willis January 2005 Abstract This paper studies capital adjustment costs. Our goal here

More information

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk Vasia Panousi Catarina Reis April 27 WP 27/64 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This

More information

STUDIES ON EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF MA Title MODELS WITH HETEROGENEOUS AGENTS

STUDIES ON EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF MA Title MODELS WITH HETEROGENEOUS AGENTS STUDIES ON EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF MA Title MODELS WITH HETEROGENEOUS AGENTS Author(s) YAMANA, Kazufumi Citation Issue 2016-10-31 Date Type Thesis or Dissertation Text Version ETD URL http://doi.org/10.15057/28171

More information

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals Selahattin İmrohoroğlu 1 Shinichi Nishiyama 2 1 University of Southern California (selo@marshall.usc.edu) 2

More information

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism Árpád Ábrahám João Brogueira de Sousa Ramon Marimon Lukas Mayr European University Institute and Barcelona GSE - UPF, CEPR & NBER ADEMU Galatina

More information

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis Answer each question in three or four sentences and perhaps one equation or graph. Remember that the explanation determines the grade. 1. Question

More information

Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity

Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity Greg Kaplan José-Víctor Ríos-Rull University of Pennsylvania University of Minnesota, Mpls Fed, and CAERP EFACR Consumption

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 2521 Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model Vincent Bodart Olivier Pierrard Henri R. Sneessens December 2006 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for

More information

Precautionary Savings or Working Longer Hours?

Precautionary Savings or Working Longer Hours? Precautionary Savings or Working Longer Hours? Josep Pijoan-Mas CEMFI and CEPR November 2005 Abstract This paper quantifies the macroeconomic implications of the lack of insurance against idiosyncratic

More information

A simple wealth model

A simple wealth model Quantitative Macroeconomics Raül Santaeulàlia-Llopis, MOVE-UAB and Barcelona GSE Homework 5, due Thu Nov 1 I A simple wealth model Consider the sequential problem of a household that maximizes over streams

More information

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier Faculty of Social Sciences Jeppe Druedahl (Ph.d. Student) Department of Economics 16th of December 2013 Slide 1/29 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 16th of December 2013 Slide 2/29 The For Today 1 Some 2 A Benchmark

More information

Syllabus of EC6102 Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

Syllabus of EC6102 Advanced Macroeconomic Theory Syllabus of EC6102 Advanced Macroeconomic Theory We discuss some basic skills of constructing and solving macroeconomic models, including theoretical results and computational methods. We emphasize some

More information

Business Cycles in the Equilibrium Model of Labor Market Search and Self-Insurance

Business Cycles in the Equilibrium Model of Labor Market Search and Self-Insurance Business Cycles in the Equilibrium Model of Labor Market Search and Self-Insurance Makoto Nakajima University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign May 2007 First draft: December 2005 Abstract The standard Mortensen-Pissarides

More information

Inflation & Welfare 1

Inflation & Welfare 1 1 INFLATION & WELFARE ROBERT E. LUCAS 2 Introduction In a monetary economy, private interest is to hold not non-interest bearing cash. Individual efforts due to this incentive must cancel out, because

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho Beggar-thy-parents? A Lifecycle Model of Intergenerational Altruism Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho University of New South Wales March 2009 Motivation & Question Since Becker (1974), several studies analyzing

More information

Movements on the Price of Houses

Movements on the Price of Houses Movements on the Price of Houses José-Víctor Ríos-Rull Penn, CAERP Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Universidad de Cantabria, Penn Tue Dec 14 13:00:57 2004 So Preliminary, There is Really Nothing Conference on

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Economics 3307 - Intermediate Macroeconomics Aaron Hedlund Baylor University Fall 2013 Econ 3307 (Baylor University) The Real Business Cycle Model Fall 2013 1 / 23 Business

More information

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary) Yan Bai University of Rochester NBER Dan Lu University of Rochester Xu Tian University of Rochester February

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Sources of Lifetime Inequality

Sources of Lifetime Inequality Sources of Lifetime Inequality Mark Huggett, Gustavo Ventura and Amir Yaron July 24, 2006 Abstract Is lifetime inequality mainly due to differences across people established early in life or to differences

More information

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity Ctirad Slavík, CERGE-EI, Prague (with Hakki Yazici, Sabanci University and Özlem Kina, EUI) January 4, 2019 ASSA in Atlanta 1 / 31 Motivation Optimal

More information

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg * Eric Sims University of Notre Dame & NBER Jonathan Wolff Miami University May 31, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the properties of the fiscal

More information

Identifying Long-Run Risks: A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach

Identifying Long-Run Risks: A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach Identifying : A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach Frank Schorfheide University of Pennsylvania CEPR and NBER Dongho Song University of Pennsylvania Amir Yaron University of Pennsylvania NBER February 12,

More information

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective Vipin Arora Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Junsang Lee U.S. EIA Deakin Univ. SKKU December 16, 2013 GRIPS Junsang Lee (SKKU) Oil Price Dynamics in

More information

Key Moments in the Rouwenhorst Method

Key Moments in the Rouwenhorst Method Key Moments in the Rouwenhorst Method Damba Lkhagvasuren Concordia University CIREQ September 14, 2012 Abstract This note characterizes the underlying structure of the autoregressive process generated

More information

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Monetary Economics Final Exam 316-466 Monetary Economics Final Exam 1. Flexible-price monetary economics (90 marks). Consider a stochastic flexibleprice money in the utility function model. Time is discrete and denoted t =0, 1,...

More information

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan Minchung Hsu Pei-Ju Liao GRIPS Academia Sinica October 15, 2010 Abstract This paper aims to discover the impacts

More information

Aggregate Implications of Indivisible Labor, Incomplete Markets, and Labor Market Frictions

Aggregate Implications of Indivisible Labor, Incomplete Markets, and Labor Market Frictions Aggregate Implications of Indivisible Labor, Incomplete Markets, and Labor Market Frictions Per Krusell Toshihiko Mukoyama Richard Rogerson Ayşegül Şahin October 2007 Abstract This paper analyzes a model

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions By DAVID BERGER AND JOSEPH VAVRA How big are government spending multipliers? A recent litererature has argued that while

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

Centro de Altísimos Estudios Ríos Pérez. Pricing Risk in Economies with Heterogenous Agents and Incomplete Markets. Josep Pijoan-Mas CAERP

Centro de Altísimos Estudios Ríos Pérez. Pricing Risk in Economies with Heterogenous Agents and Incomplete Markets. Josep Pijoan-Mas CAERP Centro de Altísimos Estudios Ríos Pérez Pricing Risk in Economies with Heterogenous Agents and Incomplete Markets Josep Pijoan-Mas CAERP Documento de Trabajo #3 Working Paper #3 Pricing Risk in Economies

More information

Homework #4. Due back: Beginning of class, Friday 5pm, December 11, 2009.

Homework #4. Due back: Beginning of class, Friday 5pm, December 11, 2009. Fatih Guvenen University of Minnesota Homework #4 Due back: Beginning of class, Friday 5pm, December 11, 2009. Questions indicated by a star are required for everybody who attends the class. You can use

More information

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing I. The Consumption - Portfolio Choice Problem We have studied the portfolio choice problem of an individual

More information

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013 Comprehensive Exam August 19, 2013 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question. Good luck! 1 1 Menu

More information

Discussion of Do taxes explain European employment? Indivisible labor, human capital, lotteries and savings, by Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas Sargent

Discussion of Do taxes explain European employment? Indivisible labor, human capital, lotteries and savings, by Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas Sargent Discussion of Do taxes explain European employment? Indivisible labor, human capital, lotteries and savings, by Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas Sargent Olivier Blanchard July 2006 There are two ways to read

More information

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World Kenichi Ueda* *The University of Tokyo PRI-ADBI Joint Workshop January 13, 2017 The views are those of the author and should not be attributed

More information

The Heterogeneous State of Modern Macroeconomics: A Reply to Solow

The Heterogeneous State of Modern Macroeconomics: A Reply to Solow Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 399 October 2007 The Heterogeneous State of Modern Macroeconomics: A Reply to Solow V. V. Chari University of Minnesota and Federal

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 Section 1. Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1 2013 North American Summer Meeting Ralph Lütticke 13.06.2013 1 Joint-work with Christian Bayer, Lien Pham, and Volker Tjaden 1 / 30 Research

More information

An Open Letter to Professors Heckman and Prescott

An Open Letter to Professors Heckman and Prescott An Open Letter to Professors Heckman and Prescott Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas J. Sargent July 19, 2014 You both use pertinent data to draw quantitative inferences about dynamic stochastic models of individuals

More information

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation Joachim Hubmer, Per Krusell, and Tony Smith Yale, IIES, and Yale March 2016 Evolution of top wealth inequality

More information

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions Daniel Wills 1 Gustavo Camilo 2 1 Universidad de los Andes 2 Cornerstone November 11, 2017 NTA 2017 Conference Corporate income is often taxed at different sources

More information

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014 External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory Ali Shourideh Wharton Ariel Zetlin-Jones CMU - Tepper November 7, 2014 Introduction Question: How

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009 Instructions: Read the questions carefully and make sure to show your work. You

More information

The Return to Capital and the Business Cycle

The Return to Capital and the Business Cycle The Return to Capital and the Business Cycle Paul Gomme Concordia University paul.gomme@concordia.ca Peter Rupert Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland peter.c.rupert@clev.frb.org B. Ravikumar University of

More information

1 Roy model: Chiswick (1978) and Borjas (1987)

1 Roy model: Chiswick (1978) and Borjas (1987) 14.662, Spring 2015: Problem Set 3 Due Wednesday 22 April (before class) Heidi L. Williams TA: Peter Hull 1 Roy model: Chiswick (1978) and Borjas (1987) Chiswick (1978) is interested in estimating regressions

More information

Macroeconomic Implications of Tax Cuts for the Top Income Groups:

Macroeconomic Implications of Tax Cuts for the Top Income Groups: Macroeconomic Implications of Tax Cuts for the Top Income Groups: 1960-2010 Barış Kaymak Université de Montréal and CIREQ Markus Poschke McGill University and CIREQ Preliminary and Incomplete Please do

More information

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints The University of Hong Kong From the SelectedWorks of Yulei Luo 00 Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints Yulei Luo, The University of Hong Kong Eric Young, University of Virginia Available

More information

Topics in Macroeconomics

Topics in Macroeconomics Topics in Macroeconomics Volume 5, Issue 1 2005 Article 15 Income and Wealth Distributions Along the Business Cycle: Implications from the Neoclassical Growth Model Lilia Maliar Serguei Maliar Juan Mora

More information

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis A. Buss B. Dumas R. Uppal G. Vilkov INSEAD INSEAD, CEPR, NBER Edhec, CEPR Goethe U. Frankfurt

More information

Part 3: Value, Investment, and SEO Puzzles

Part 3: Value, Investment, and SEO Puzzles Part 3: Value, Investment, and SEO Puzzles Model of Zhang, L., 2005, The Value Premium, JF. Discrete time Operating leverage Asymmetric quadratic adjustment costs Counter-cyclical price of risk Algorithm

More information

Appendix: Net Exports, Consumption Volatility and International Business Cycle Models.

Appendix: Net Exports, Consumption Volatility and International Business Cycle Models. Appendix: Net Exports, Consumption Volatility and International Business Cycle Models. Andrea Raffo Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City February 2007 Abstract This Appendix studies the implications of

More information

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge By Patrick Kehoe, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Elena Pastorino This paper is motivated by the strong correlation between changes in household debt and employment across regions

More information

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy George Alogoskoufis* Athens University of Economics and Business September 2012 Abstract This paper examines

More information

Is the Affordable Care Act s Individual Mandate a Certified Job-Killer?

Is the Affordable Care Act s Individual Mandate a Certified Job-Killer? Is the Affordable Care Act s Individual Mandate a Certified Job-Killer? Cory Stern Macalester College May 8, 216 Abstract: Opponents of the Affordable Care Act argue that its individual mandate component

More information

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports Alexandre Dmitriev University of New South Wales Ivan Roberts Reserve Bank of Australia and University of New South Wales February 2, 2011 Abstract Two-country,

More information

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance

Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Macro II Chapter 5 Macro and Finance 1 Chapter 5 Macroeconomics and Finance Main references : - L. Ljundqvist and T. Sargent, Chapter 7 - Mehra and Prescott 1985 JME paper - Jerman 1998 JME paper - J.

More information

The Return to Capital and the Business Cycle

The Return to Capital and the Business Cycle The Return to Capital and the Business Cycle Paul Gomme Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland paul.a.gomme@clev.frb.org Peter Rupert Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland peter.c.rupert@clev.frb.org B. Ravikumar

More information

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings James MacGee University of Western Ontario Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Jie Zhou Nanyang Technological University March 26, 2009 Abstract

More information

Optimal Life-Cycle Investing with Flexible Labor Supply: A Welfare Analysis of Default Investment Choices in Defined-Contribution Pension Plans

Optimal Life-Cycle Investing with Flexible Labor Supply: A Welfare Analysis of Default Investment Choices in Defined-Contribution Pension Plans Optimal Life-Cycle Investing with Flexible Labor Supply: A Welfare Analysis of Default Investment Choices in Defined-Contribution Pension Plans Francisco J. Gomes, Laurence J. Kotlikoff and Luis M. Viceira

More information

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? DOI 0.007/s064-006-9073-z ORIGINAL PAPER Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function? Jules H. van Binsbergen Michael W. Brandt Received:

More information

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 7b

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 7b 316-406 ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 7b Chris Edmond hcpedmond@unimelb.edu.aui Aiyagari s model Arguably the most popular example of a simple incomplete markets model is due to Rao Aiyagari (1994,

More information

Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data

Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data by Peter A Groothuis Professor Appalachian State University Boone, NC and James Richard Hill Professor Central Michigan University

More information

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico Thomas F. Cooley New York University Vincenzo Quadrini Duke University and CEPR May 2, 2000 Abstract This paper develops a two-country monetary

More information

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl) University of California, Davis Date: September 1, 2011 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Macroeconomics Reading Time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Directions: Answer all

More information