Optimal risk and dividend control problem with fixed costs and salvage value: Variance premium principle. Title. Yao, D; Yang, H; Wang, R

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Optimal risk and dividend control problem with fixed costs and salvage value: Variance premium principle. Title. Yao, D; Yang, H; Wang, R"

Transcription

1 Title Optimal risk and dividend control problem with fixed costs and salvage value: Variance premium principle Author(s Yao, D; Yang, H; Wang, R Citation Economic Modelling, 214, v. 37, p Issued Date 214 URL Rights NOTICE: this is the author s version of a work that was accepted for publication in Economic Modelling. Changes resulting from the publishing process, such as peer review, editing, corrections, structural formatting, and other quality control mechanisms may not be reflected in this document. Changes may have been made to this work since it was submitted for publication. A definitive version was subsequently published in Economic Modelling, 214, v. 37, p DOI: 1.116/j.econmod ; This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4. International License.

2 Optimal risk and dividend control problem with fixed costs and salvage value: Variance premium principle Dingjun Yao a, Hailiang Yang b,, Rongming Wang c a School of Finance, Nanjing University of Finance and Economics, Nanjing 2123, PR China b Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science, The University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong, PR China c School of Finance and Statistics, East China Normal University, Shanghai 2241, PR China Abstract In this paper we study the combined optimal dividend, capital injection and reinsurance problems in a dynamic setting. The reinsurance premium is assumed to be calculated via the variance principle instead of the expected value principle. The proportional and fixed transaction costs and the salvage value at bankruptcy are included in the model. In both cases of unrestricted dividend rate and restricted dividend rate, we obtain the closed-form solutions of the value function and the optimal joint strategies, which depend on the transaction costs and the profitability in future. Keywords: Dividend payment, Capital injection, Proportional reinsurance, Variance principle, Fixed costs, Salvage value. 1. Introduction The classical optimal dividend problem for an insurance company consists in finding a dividend payment strategy that maximizes the total expected discounted dividends until the bankruptcy time. Much research on this issue has been carried out for various surplus process models. See, Asmussen and Taksar (1997, Gerber and Shiu (26, Avram et al. (27, Belhaj (21, Azcue and Muler (212. Capital injection is one possible way to help the manager to run the business. The company sometimes needs to raise new capitals from the market in order to continue the business. Some papers assume that the company can survive forever with forced capital injections. The expected cumulative discounted dividends minus the expected discounted costs of capital injections can be regarded as the company s value, the management seeks to find the join optimal dividend payment and capital injection strategies that maximize this value. There are many papers on this topic. For instance, Sethi and Taksar (22, Avram et al. (27, Kulenko and Schmidli (28 and Yao et al. (211. However, capital injection is not always profitable when the company is facing the financial difficulty. Lφkka and Zervos (28 study the combined optimal dividend and capital injection problem by taking into account the possibility of bankruptcy. The optimal strategy happens to be either a dividend barrier strategy without capital injections, or another dividend barrier strategy with forced injections when surplus is null to prevent bankruptcy, which depends on the parameters of risk model. By adopting their technique, some extended results are obtained in other risk models. See, He and Liang (28, Dai et al. (21 and Yao et al. (21. Reinsurance is an effective tool for insurance companies to control the risk exposure. Due to its practical importance and theoretical value, some researchers begin to pay attention to the combined dividend and reinsurance problem. Some literature on this issue includes Asmussen and Taksar (1997, Choulli et al. (23, Hφgaard and Taksar (24, Cadenillas et al. (26, Meng and Siu (211 and Peng et al. (212. As we can see, in these literature, the expected value principle is commonly used as the reinsurance premium principle due to its simplicity and popularity in practice. Although the variance principle is another important premium principle, very few papers consider using it for risk control in a dynamic setting. Zhou and Yuen (212 first study the optimal dividend and capital injection problem with reinsurance under the variance premium principle. Depending on whether there exist restrictions on dividend rates, they provide the optimal joint strategies in two different cases, the proportional costs for capital injections are also considered. In this paper, we continue studying the optimal dividend, capital injection and reinsurance problem with variance premium principle in a Corresponding author. Tel: ; fax: addresses: yaodingjun@com.cn (Dingjun Yao, hlyang@hku.hk (Hailiang Yang, rmwang@stat.ecnu.edu.cn (Rongming Wang Preprint submitted to Economic Modelling October 18, 213

3 dynamic setting. Comparing with the work Zhou and Yuen (212, we add the fixed costs for capital injections and a salvage value at the time of bankruptcy in our model. In real financial market, transaction cost is an unavoidable issue, especially, the fixed cost (for example, advisory and consulting fees can generate some difficult impulse control problems. See, for example, Paulsen (28, Bai et al. (21, Meng and Siu (211 and Yao et al. (211. The salvage value of the insurer can be explained as an insurer s brand name or agency network. As we know, very little work considers optimal dividend strategies under a salvage (or penalty for bankruptcy. A few examples are Taksar (2, Gerber et al. (26, Thonhauser and Albrecher (27, Loeffen and Renaud (21 and Liang and Young (212. By including the fixed costs and salvage value, our model is more realistic. Under some new objective functions, we present the associated optimal joint dividend, capital injection and reinsurance strategies. We show, under our model, that the decision to declare bankruptcy or to collect new capitals depends on the model parameters, which is consistent with the results and idea in Lφkka and Zervos (28. The outline of this paper is as follows. In Section 2, we introduce the framework of this paper and formulate two general optimization problems concerning with dividend payments, capital injections and reinsurance under the variance premium principle. In Section 3, we consider two suboptimal problems in the cases of unrestricted and restricted rates of dividend payments with forced capital injections. In Section 4, a similar study is carried out for two suboptimal problems without considering capital injections. Finally, by comparing the solutions of suboptimal problems, we identify the closed-form solutions to the general optimal problems in Section 5, which depend on the relationships among the parameters of risk model. 2. Model formulation and the optimal control problem We first introduce the framework of this paper. Let (Ω, F, P be a probability space with the filtration F t } satisfying the usual conditions. We first present the classical insurance risk model of an insurance company, which means the surplus of an insurance company can be modeled by N t U t = x + ct Y n, where x is the initial surplus, c is the premium rate, N t is a Poisson process with constant intensity λ, random variables Y n s are positive i.i.d. claims with finite mean µ 1 and finite second moment µ 2 2. A reinsurance contract can be represented by a measurable functional R( defined on the space composed of all positive random variables such that R(Y Y. Under reinsurance R, a positive risk Y is decomposed into two parts, namely R(Y and Y R(Y, where R(Y is retained by the insurer and Y R(Y is ceded to the reinsurer. Suppose that reinsurance R is taken for each claim. Then the total ceded risk up to time t is given by N t (Y n R(Y n, and the aggregate reinsurance premium under the variance principle takes the form ( N t E (Y n R(Y n ( N t + θd (Y n R(Y n = λ [ (µ 1 E(R(Y 1 + θe((y 1 R(Y 1 2] t, where E and D stand for expectation and variance, respectively, and θ > is a loading associated with the variance of ceded risk. Then the premium process in the presence of reinsurance R can be written as U R t N t = x + (c c R t R(Y n, (2.1 where c R = λ[(µ 1 E(R(Y + θe((y R(Y 2 ] represents the reinsurance premium rate associated with R. Here we assume that the reinsurance market is frictionless. This means that the reinsurance premium rate is equal to the premium rate c = λ(µ 1 + θµ 2 2 if the whole risk is ceded to the reinsurer. We approximate the model (2.1 by a pure diffusion model Xt R, t } with the same drift and volatility. Specifically, Xt R satisfies the following stochastic differential equation X R t = x + t θλ(µ 2 2 E(Y 1 R(Y 1 2 ds + t λe((r(y1 2 db s, (2.2 with X R = x, where B t, t } is a standard Brownian motion, adapted to the filtration Ft B := σb s ; s t}. From now on, R is assumed to be a proportional reinsurance policy with R(y = (1 ay. Then we represent 2

4 (2.2 as with X a = x. t t Xt a = x + (1 a 2 θλµ 2 2 ds + (1 a λµ 2 db s, (2.3 Suppose that the proportion a can be adjusted dynamically to control the risk exposure. Denote L t as the cumulative amount of dividends paid from time to time t. The capital injection process G t = I τ n t}η n } is described by a sequence of increasing stopping times τ n, n = 1, 2, } and a sequence of random variables η n, n = 1, 2, }, which represent the times and the sizes of capital injections, respectively. A control strategy is described by = (a ; L ; G = (a ; L ; τ1, τ n, ; η 1,, η n,. The controlled surplus process associated with is given by X t = x + t (1 (a s 2 θλµ 2 2ds + t (1 a s λµ 2 db s L t + I τ n t}ηn. (2.4 Definition 2.1. A strategy = (a ; L ; G is said to be admissible if (i The ceded proportion a = a t is an FB t -adapted process with a t 1 for all t. (ii L t } is an increasing, Ft B -adapted càdlàg process with L =, and satisfies that L t = L t L t Xt for all t. (iii τn } is a sequence of stopping times w.r.t. FB t, and τ 1 < < τ n <, a.s.. (iv ηn, n = 1, 2, is measurable w.r.t. Fτ B. n (v P( lim < T =, T >. n τ n The class of admissible strategies is denoted by Π. For each strategy Π, the bankruptcy time of the controlled process Xt is defined as τ = inft : Xt < }, which is an Ft B -stopping time. Note that the bankruptcy time could be infinite. Problem 2.1. We define the company s value by the performance function V (x,, which is the expected sum of discounted salvage and the discounted dividends less the expected discounted costs of capital injections until bankruptcy V (x, = E x( τ β 1 e δs dl s e δτ n (β2 ηn + KI τn τ } + Pe δτ. (2.5 E x denotes the expectation conditional on X = x, and δ > is the discount rate. We regard P as the salvage value of the insurer; for example, an insurer s brand name or agency network which might be of value to a potential buyer of the insurer. We assume that the shareholders need to pay β 2 η + K to meet the capital injection of η. β 2 > 1 measures the proportional costs, K > is the fixed costs. Proportional costs on dividends transaction are taken into account through the value of β 1, with < β 1 1 representing the net proportion of leakages from the surplus received by shareholders after transaction costs have been paid. We are interested in finding the value function and the associated optimal strategy such that V (x = V (x,. V (x = maxv (x, (2.6 Π Remark 2.1. The case of P < is out of consideration in this paper. Since the surplus can keep nonnegative by ceding the whole risk to the reinsurer, so V ( follows from the optimality of V (x and the case of V ( = P < is impossible. Furthermore, if we suppose that the dividend rate l t at time t is bounded by some dividend ceiling M >, then the cumulated dividend process L t, t } satisfies L t = t l sds with l s M. Definition 2.2. A strategy = (a ; L ; G is said to be admissible if (i The ceded proportion a = a t is an F B t -adapted process with a t 1 for all t. 3

5 (ii L t, t } is an increasing, Ft B -adapted càdlàg process satisfying that L = and L t = t l s ds with l s M. (iiii τn } is a sequence of stopping times w.r.t. FB t, and τ 1 < < τ n <, a.s.. (iv η n, n = 1, 2, is measurable w.r.t. Fτ B. n (v P( lim τ n < T =, T >. n The class of admissible strategies is denoted by Π. For each strategy Π, the bankruptcy time of the controlled process X t is defined as τ = inft : X t < }, which is an F B t -stopping time. Problem 2.2. Parallel to Problem 2.1, when a ceiling M > is imposed on the dividend rate, we define the following performance function V (x, = E x( τ β 1 e δs l s ds e δτ n η (β2 n + KI τ n τ } + Pe δτ. (2.7 Correspondingly, we want to find the value function V (x = maxv (x,, (2.8 Π and the associated optimal strategy Π such that V (x = V (x,. Apparently, the function V (x is bounded above by β 1 M/δ + P. To develop our result, for any function ω(x C 2, we define the capital injection operator M by and the operator A a with a 1 by Mω(x = max y ω(x + y β 2y K}, (2.9 A a ω(x = 1 2 (1 a2 λµ 2 2ω (x + (1 a 2 θλµ 2 2ω (x δω(x. (2.1 For future use, we cite the following lemma from Zhou and Yuen (212, which can be proved by straightforward calculations. Lemma 2.1. Let a(x = (ξ + a(e 2θx ξ, x such that a( 1. Suppose that H(x satisfies ( H y 2θa(z (x = exp x 1 a(z dz, with (1 a(h ( = 2θξH( for some ξ and y > x. Then, we have where H(x = A(y ( ξ + 1 ξ 2θξ ξ + a( e2θx 1 A(y = (ξ + a(y ξ (1 a(y ξ. 3. The solution to the problem that does not allow for bankruptcy In this section we require that the company survives forever by forced capital injections. This optimization problem is studied in two cases depending on whether there exist restrictions on dividend rates. 4

6 3.1. Unrestricted dividends In this subsection, we derive closed-form solutions for the value function and the optimal strategy in the case that no restriction is imposed on the dividend rate. Denote r = (a r ; L r ; G r Π as the controlled process such that the company never goes bankrupt. For each admissible strategy r, the performance function becomes V (x, r = E x( β 1 The objective is to find the value function e δs dl r s e r δτn (β2 ηn r + KI τn r < }. (3.1 V r (x = max r Π V (x, r, (3.2 and the associated optimal strategy r = (a r ; L r ; G r Π such that Vr (x = V (x, r. We assume that all value functions appearing in this paper are sufficiently smooth and regular. With reference to the theory of optimal control, V r (x should satisfy the HJB equation and the boundary condition as follows max } r (x, MV r(x V r (x max V r (x}, β 1 V a 1 =, (3.3 maxmv r ( V r (, V r (} =. (3.4 Then, we suppose the function V r is concave. Because the time value of money, we conjecture that the optimal timing of capital injection should only come at the moments when the surplus process hits the barrier, mathematically, the equation MV r (x = V r (x has at most one solution at x =, the inequality MV r (x < V r (x holds strictly for x >. Actually, when the surplus reaches, we have two ways to avoid bankruptcy: One way is to inject new capitals, the surplus jumps to some appropriate level η > immediately, if this choice is optimal, then corresponding boundary condition is MV r ( = V r ( = V r (η β 2 η K and V r (. By the definition of operator M, it follows that η = infx : V r(x = β 2 }. We can construct an injection strategy G r by letting τ r 1 = inft : X r t = }, (3.5 τ r n = inft > τ r n 1 : X r t = }, n = 2, 3,, (3.6 η r n η, n = 1, 2, 3,. (3.7 The other way of preventing bankruptcy is to cede the whole risk to the reinsurer and keep the surplus stay at the point forever, the capital injection never occurs. If this choice is optimal, the corresponding boundary condition is V r ( = and MV r ( < V r (. Correspondingly, G r. (3.8 In addition, if we further assume that V r (x is concave and there exists some number b r = infx : V r(x = β 1 }, then the optimal dividend strategy should be a barrier strategy with the barrier b r. Mathematically, L r t satisfies L r t = (x b r + + t I X r s In the region (, b r, the optimal ceded proportion a r should satisfy r =b r }dl s. (3.9 max A a V r (x} = A a r V r (x =. (3.1 a 1 The optimality of strategy r = (a r ; L r ; G r will be confirmed later. Theorem 3.1. Let g(x be a twice continuously differentiable, increasing and concave solution of equations (3.3 and (3.4, then we have the following statements: 5

7 (i For each r Π, it follows thatg(x V (x, r. So g(x V r (x for all x. (ii If there exists some strategy r = (a r ; L r ; G r such that g(x = V (x, r, then g(x = V r (x and r is optimal. Proof. The proof of (i is similar to Appendix A, it is omitted here. The result of (ii automatically holds due to the optimality of V r (x. Next, we present the following lemma, which plays a key role in finding the value function and associated optimal strategies. Lemma 3.1. Let â [, 1] be the unique solution of the following equation, where ξ is a positive number. For each a [â, 1] and b r = 1 2θ β 1 ξ ξ 1 ( ξ = β 2, (3.11 ξ + â ξ + â a ln(1 + ξ, define a function ( Φ a (x := β 1 ξ ξ 1 e2θx ξ+a ξ+a e 2θx 1 >, < x b r. (3.12 Then there is a unique η (, b r such that Φ a (η = β 2. Furthermore, I(a := η(a is an increasing function in a with the range [, I(1]. Proof. Observing that the function Φ a (x has some useful properties: (i The function Φ a (x is decreasing in x since (ii Φ a (b r = β 1 and (Φ a (x β 2 dx, a [â, 1], (3.13 Φ a (x = 2θβ 1 ξ 1 e 2θx ( ξ e 2θx ξe 2θx (ξ + a 1 ξ + a ξ + a (ξ + 1e 2θx <. (3.14 (ξ + a Φ a ( = β 1 ξ ξ 1 ( ξ (3.15 ξ + a ξ + a (iii For each fixed x b r, Φ a (x can be viewed as an increasing function of a. Especially, lim Φ a ( = +. (3.16 a 1 (iv Obviously, (3.11 can be written as Φâ ( = β 2. Based on above analysis, we conclude that there exists a unique solution η(a [, b r to equation Φ a (η = β 2 if a [â, 1]. More importantly, η(a is an increasing function of a. The minimum η min = η(â = and the maximum η max = η(1 < b r is uniquely determined by Φ 1 (η(1 = β 1 ξ ξ e2θη(1 ξ + 1 ( 1 e 2θη(1 1 = β 2. (3.17 Thereby, together with (iii, I(a is non-negative and increasing on (â, 1]. It is easy to verify that I(â = and I(1 = Thereby, I(a [, I(1] for a [â, 1]. η(1 (Φ 1 (x β 2 dx β 1 2θξ. (3.18 Theorem 3.2. The value function V r (x coincides with β 1 (x b r + β1 2θξ, x b r g(x =, ξ β 1 1 ( 2θ ξ ξ+a r ( e2θx 1, x b r, (3.19 6

8 where b r = 1 2θ ln ( 1 + a r ( ξ. Correspondingly, the optimal dividend strategy L r satisfies L r t = (x b r + + t I X r s r =b r }dl s. (3.2 The optimal ceded proportion a r coincides with a r (x =, x > b r, (ξ + a r (e 2θx ξ, x b r, (3.21 which solves (3.1. The value of a r ( and the injection strategy G r can be determined as follows: (i In the case of < K I(1, a r ( = a (â, 1] is the unique solution of I(a = K. The optimal injection strategy G r is described by (3.5-(3.7, the value of η can be obtained by (3.32 and (3.33. It means the surplus immediately jumps to η once it reaches by injecting capitals. In this case, it follows that Mg( = g( and g(. (ii In the case of K I(1, the initial value is a r ( = 1, and the injection strategy G r t in (3.8 is optimal. Namely, the capital injection never occurs. When the surplus reaches, the company cedes the whole business to the reinsurer and keeps the surplus stay at the point forever. In this case, Mg( g( and g( =. Proof. We try to find a concave solution of (3.3 and (3.4 with a switch point b r such that g (b r = β 1. We conjecture that g (x β 1 holds for all x b r, which yields g(x = β 1 (x b r + g(b r. (3.22 Moreover the concavity implies that g (x β 1 for x b r, to satisfy (3.3, it must have max a 1 A a g(x} =, x b r, (3.23 specifically, 1 max a 1 2 (1 a2 λµ 2 2 g (x + (1 a 2 θλµ 2 2 g (x δg(x} =. (3.24 Taking derivative with respect to a and setting the derivative equal to zero yield where a r (x is the maximizer in (3.24. Plugging (3.25 in (3.24 yields g (x g (x = 2θ a r (x 1 a r(x, (3.25 (1 a r (xg (x = 2θξg(x, (3.26 with ξ = δ/(2λ(θµ 2 2 >. Taking derivative with respect to x on both sides of (3.26 and using (3.25, we obtain Note that we have a r (x = with a r (x = (ξ + a r (e 2θx ξ. (3.27 x = 1 2θ ln ( For x x, it follows that from (3.26 that with g (x = k and 1 + a r ( ξ ( g x 2θa r (z (x = k exp x 1 a r(z dz. (3.28 (3.29 g (x = 2θk a r (x 1 a r(x g (x =, (3.3 7

9 the constant k needs to be determined. Applying Lemma 2.1 to (3.26 and (3.29 yields g(x = 1 ( 1 2θ kξ ξ + 1 ξ + a r( e2θx 1 ξ 1+ξ, x x, (3.31 with g(x = k/(2θξ. We conjecture that there is only one common switch level for the optimal reinsurance and dividend strategies, i.e., x = b r. Then it follows that k = g (x = g (b r = β 1. By the way, we can deduce that g(b r = β1 2θξ. The unknown value of a r ( and the optimal injection process G r can be determined in different cases: (i In the case of < K I(1, we conjecture that Mg( = g( holds. It requires that there exist some a r ( [, 1] and η (a r ( > such that (3.33 can be rewritten as K = η (g (x β 2 dx = g (η = β 2, (3.32 g( = g(η β 2 η K = Mg(. (3.33 η (a r ( (Φ a r ( (x β 2dx = I(a r (. (3.34 Recalling Lemma 3.1, we know that a r ( (â, 1] and η exist if < K I(1. A straightforward calculation can verify that g(x is indeed a twice continuously differentiable, increasing and concave function. Now, according to Theorem 3.1, we are in the position to verify that g(x in (3.19 satisfies (3.3 and (3.4. From the construction of g(x, we know that g (x = β 1 for x b r and max A a g(x} = for a 1 x b r. In addition, from the expression of g(x for x b r we have max A a g(x} = max (1 a 2 θλµ 2 2 β 1 δ[β 1 (x b r + β } 1 a 1 a 1 2θξ ] = θλµ 2 2 β 1 δ[β 1 (x b r + β 1 2θξ ] = δβ 1 (x b r (3.35 and, for x b r, the property g (x β 1 follows from the conditions g (b r = β 1 and g (x. Moreover, g( = Mg( and g( are obvious. Hence, g(x in (3.19 satisfies HJB equation (3.3 and (3.4. Finally, the optimality of r can be verified by Appendix B. According to Theorem 3.1, the statements are proved. (ii In the case of K I(1, (3.19-(3.21 can also be obtained. However, the number η satisfying (3.32 and (3.33 does not exist and Mg( < g(, which suggests that G r. To satisfy (3.4, it must be true that g( = and a r ( = 1. By repeating the same verification process as that in (i, we can prove that g(x = V r (x = V (x, r. Remark 3.1. Theorem 3.2 suggests that the company should give up to raise new capitals from market if the fixed cost K is larger than I(1. It can be viewed as the maximal fixed cost for injections that the company would pay. Observe from (3.12 and (3.18, I(1 becomes larger when the cost factor for injections β 2 decreases or the cost factor for dividends β 1 increases. These results agree with our intuition Restricted dividends In this subsection, we derive explicit solutions for the value function and the optimal strategy when a ceiling M > is imposed on the dividend rate. Denote r Π as the control strategy such that the company never goes bankrupt. The performance function associated with r takes the form of V (x, r = E x( β 1 We are interesting in the value function as δs e l r s ds e r δτn (β2 η r n + KI τ r n < }. (3.36 V r (x = max V (x, r, (3.37 r Π 8

10 and the optimal strategy r = (a r ; L r ; G r Π, where V r (x = V (x, r. With reference to the theory of optimal control, V r (x should satisfy the HJB equation and the boundary condition as follows max max A āv } r (x + l(β 1 V r(x}, MV r (x V r (x =, (3.38 ā 1, l M maxmv r ( V r (, V r (} =. (3.39 Similar to the analysis in Subsection 3.1, we assume that V r (x is concave and the equation MV r (x = V r (x has at most one solution at x =, the inequality MV r (x < V r (x holds strictly for x >. When the surplus reaches, we have two ways to avoid bankruptcy: One way is to inject new capitals, the surplus jumps to some appropriate level η > immediately, if this choice is optimal, then the corresponding boundary condition is MV r ( = V r ( = V r ( η β 2 η K and V r (. By the definition of operator M, it follows that η = infx : V r (x = β 2}. We can construct an injection strategy G r by letting τ r 1 = inft : X r t = }, (3.4 τ r n = inft > τ r n 1 : X r t = }, n = 2, 3,, (3.41 η r n η, n = 1, 2, 3,. (3.42 The other way of preventing bankruptcy is to cede the whole business to the reinsurer and keep the surplus stay at the point forever, the capital injection never occurs. If this choice is optimal, the boundary condition becomes V r ( = and MV r ( < V r (. Correspondingly, G r t. (3.43 If we further assume that V r (x is concave and there exists some number b r = infx : V r(x = β 1 }, then the threshold dividend strategy L r with the following dividend rate M, x > l r = l r (x = b r,, x b r, (3.44 is optimal. The optimal ceded proportion strategy a r should satisfy max A āv r (x = A a r V r (x =, x b r. (3.45 ā 1 However, in the region [ b r,, the optimal ceded proportion is expected to be some constant ā [, a r (]. The optimality of strategy r = (a r ; L r ; G r will be established later. Theorem 3.3. Let w(x be a twice continuously differentiable, increasing and concave solution to (3.38 and (3.39. Then, we have the following statements: (i For each r Π, it follows that w(x V (x, r. So w(x V r (x for all x. (ii If there exists some strategy r = (a r ; L r ; G r such that w(x = V (x, r, then w(x = V r (x and r is optimal. Proof. The proof of (i is similar to Appendix A, it is omitted here. The result of (ii comes from the optimality of V r (x. Analogous to Lemma 3.1, we state the following lemma for future reference, its proof is omitted because it is quite similar to the proof of Lemma 3.1. Lemma 3.2. Let ã [, 1] be the unique solution of the following equation, A ( ξ = β 2, (3.46 ξ + ã ξ + ã 9

11 with some A = β 1 (ξ + ā ξ (1 ā 1 and ā. For any number ā [ã, 1] and b r = 1 2θ a function ln( ξ+ā ξ+ā, define ( Ψā (x := A e2θx ξ e 2θx 1 >, x ξ + ā ξ + ā b r. (3.47 Then there is a unique η [, b r such that Ψā ( η = β 2. Furthermore, Ī(ā = η(ā (Ψā (x β 2 dx, ā [ã, 1], (3.48 is an increasing function in ā with the range [, Ī(1]. In addition, it is not difficult to show that Ī(ã = and Ī(1 β 1(1 ā. (3.49 2θξ Theorem 3.4. If the dividend rate is bounded by < M <, then the value function V r (x coincides with β 1M δ + β1 eγ(x b r γ, x > b r w(x = (, ξ A 2θξ ξ+a r ( e2θx 1, x b (3.5 r, ( where A = β 1 (ξ + ā ξ (1 ā 1, b r = 1 2θ ln ξ+a r ( ξ+ā, γ < and ā [, 1] are unique roots of (3.59 and (3.6, respectively. The threshold dividend strategy L r defined by l r in (3.44 is optimal. The optimal ceded proportion a r takes the form as ā, x > b a r (x = r, (ξ + a r (e 2θx ξ, < x b (3.51 r. The value of a r ( and injection strategy G r is given according to two different cases: (i In the case of < K Ī(1, the initial value a r ( = ā [, 1] is the unique solution of Ī(ā = K. The injection strategy G r is described by (3.4-(3.42, in which the value of η will be given in (3.62 and (3.63. It means the surplus immediately jumps to η once it reaches by injecting capital. In this case, it follows that Mw( = w( and w(. (ii In the case of K Ī(1, the ceded proportion described by (3.51 with the initial value a r ( = 1 is optimal. However, the optimal strategy of capital injection is (3.43, namely, the capital injection never occurs. Whenever the surplus reaches, one lets the ceded proportion of risk be a r ( = 1 and keeps the surplus stay at the point forever. In this case, Mw( w( and w( =. Proof. We try to find a concave solution w(x of (3.38 with a switch level b r > such that w ( b r = β 1. Then we have w (x β 1 for x b r, so max A āw(x + l(β 1 w (x} = max A āw(x} =, x b r, (3.52 ā 1, l M ā 1 specifically, 1 max ā 1 2 (1 ā2 λµ 2 2w (x + (1 ā 2 θλµ 2 2w (x δw(x} =, x b r. (3.53 Following the same method as that in Theorem 3.2, we provide the candidate solution to (3.53 w(x = A ( 2θξ with optimal ceded proportion a r (x as ξ + 1 ξ + a r( e2θx 1 ξ 1+ξ, x b r, (3.54 a r (x = (ξ + a r (e 2θx ξ, x b r. (3.55 1

12 Applying the condition w( b r = β 1 to (3.54 yields A = (ξ +ā ξ (1 ā 1. For x > b r, it has w (x < β 1, we conjecture the following equation holds with some constant ā 1, or equivalently, max A āw(x + l(β 1 w (x} = A ā w(x + M(β 1 w (x =, ā 1, l M 1 2 (1 ā 2 λµ 2 2w (x + [(1 ā 2 θλµ 2 2 M]w (x δw(x + β 1 M =. (3.56 Recalling that w(x should be bounded and w ( b r = β 1, then w(x = β 1M δ + β 1 γ eγ(x b r, (3.57 where γ is the negative root of the equation To match the continuous condition it requires that 1 2 (1 ā 2 λµ 2 2γ 2 + [(1 ā 2 θλµ 2 2 M]γ δ =. (3.58 w ( b r w ( b r = w ( b r + w ( b r +, 2θā = γ. ( ā Then, by substituting (3.59 into (3.58, we see that < ā < 1 is the unique positive root of following equation in a In addition, the continuity of a r (x at point b r shows a 2 + (ξ 1 + 2Mθξ a ξ =. (3.6 δ (ξ + a r (e 2θ b r ξ = ā (3.61 which yields b r = 1 2θ ln ( ξ+a r ( ξ+ā. The unknown value of a r ( and the optimal injection strategy G r can be determined as follows: (i Relying on Lemma 3.2 and the fact that w (x = Ψ a r ((x, when < K Ī(1 there exists a unique value η such that w ( η = β 2, (3.62 w( = w( η β 2 η K = Mw(. (3.63 a r ( = ā is the unique solution of Ī(ā = K. Finally, a straightforward calculation can verify that w(x is indeed a twice continuously differentiable, increasing and concave solution of (3.38 and (3.39, moreover, w(x = V (x, r can be proved as that in Appendix B. According to Theorem 3.3, the results are proved. (ii In the case of K Ī(1, by repeating the same discussion as above, V r(x, a r and L r can also be given by (3.5, (3.51 and (3.44 respectively, apart from different initial value of a r (. In this case, η satisfying (3.62 and (3.63 does not exist, i.e., M w( < w(. Thus the optimal capital injection process is G r t. The capital injection never occurs. To satisfy (3.39, the condition w( = is required, which yields a r ( = 1. Whenever the surplus reaches, let the ceded proportion of risk be a r ( = 1 and keep the surplus stay at the point forever. Finally, w(x is indeed a twice continuously differentiable, increasing and concave solution of (3.38 and 11

13 (3.39. Similar to Appendix B, w(x = V r (x = V (x, r can also be proved. Remark 3.2. Parallel to Remark 3.1, Theorem 3.4 suggests that the company should give up to raise new capitals from market if the fixed cost K is larger than Ī(1. It can be viewed as the maximal fixed cost for injections that the company would afford. Notice, from (3.47 and (3.48, that Ī(1 becomes larger as the cost factor for injection β 2 decreases or the cost factor for dividend β 1 increases. These results are consistent with our intuition. 4. The solution to the problem without capital injection 4.1. Unrestricted dividends In this subsection, we consider the classical optimal dividend problem of maximizing the expected total discounted dividends under a salvage for bankruptcy and the dividend rate is not restricted. Let p = (a p ; L p ; Π stand for the control process in which capital injection is not allowed. Then the performance function associated with p is defined by V (x, p = E x( τ p β 1 Correspondingly, the value function is defined by e δs dl p s + Pe δτ p. (4.1 V p (x = max p Π V (x, p. (4.2 The associated optimal strategy is p = (a p ; L p ; such that Vp (x = V (x, p needs to be determined. From the optimal control theory, V p (x should satisfy the following HJB equation } max max A a V p (x, β 1 V p (x = (4.3 a 1 with the boundary condition V p ( = P. (4.4 Theorem 4.1. Let f(x be a twice continuously differentiable, increasing and concave solution of equations (4.3 and (4.4, then we have the following statements: (i For each p Π, we have g(x V (x, p. So f(x V p (x for all x. (ii If there exists some strategy p = (a p ; L p ; such that f(x = V (x, p, then f(x = V p (x and p is optimal. Proof. The proof of (i is similar to Appendix A, it is omitted here. The result of (ii comes from the optimality of V p (x. Theorem 4.2. The value function V p (x and the associated optimal strategy p = (a p ; L p ; are given according to different cases: (i In the case where P [, β1 2θξ ], then V p(x coincides with β 1 (x b p + β1 2θξ, x b p f(x =, ξ β 1 1 ( (4.5 2θ ξ ξ+a p( e2θx 1, x b p, with a p ( given by (4.8 and b p = 1 2θ ln(1 + p( a ξ. Correspondingly, L p is a barrier dividend strategy with level b p satisfying L p t = (x b p + + t I X p s The optimal ceded proportion a p is given by a p (x =, x b p, (ξ + a p (e 2θx ξ, x b p, p =b p }dl s. (4.6 (4.7 12

14 where a p ( [, 1] is the unique root of the following equation β ( 1 1 2θ ξ ξ + 1 ξ + a p ( 1 (ii In the case where P [ β1 2θξ,, then V p(x equals to ξ = P. (4.8 f(x = β 1 x + P. (4.9 The associated optimal strategy is to distribute all surplus as dividends (by letting b p = in (4.6 and declare bankruptcy at once (by letting a p ( < 1. Proof. (i Note that V p (x and V r (x satisfy the same HJB equation but with different boundary conditions. With the same argument, we can obtain the expressions of f(x, a p (x and L p t. The boundary condition f( = P (which is the same as equation (4.8 gives the value of a p ( [ã, 1]. In the case where P [, β1 2θξ ], we know that a p ( exists. Obviously, it is not difficult to verify that f(x is indeed a twice continuously differentiable, increasing and concave solution of (4.3 and (4.4, and the optimality of p can also be established as that in Appendix B. All conditions in Theorem 4.1 are satisfied. (ii In the case where P [ β1 2θξ,, (4.8 has no solution for a p (. We conclude that f(x = β1 x + P, x solves (4.3 and (4.4 now, because max A a f(x} = max (1 a 1 a 1 a2 θλµ 2 2 β 1 δ(β 1 x + P} = θλµ 2 2β 1 δ(β 1 x + P = δ(p β 1 2θξ δβ 1x (4.1 and f (x β 1 on [,. Furthermore, we define a control strategy p by letting the b p = in (4.6 and a p ( < 1, then f(x = V (x, p follows. The statement of (ii is true according to Theorem 4.1. Remark 4.1. It is interesting to see V p (x = f(x behaves differently depending on the relationship between P and β1 2θξ. In fact, β 1 2θξ = β 1λθµ 2 2 /δ is the present value of a perpetuity with discount rate δ and rate of income β 1 λθµ 2 2, which is the expected rate of profit under the strategy of full retention. Therefore, when salvage value is greater than the present value of this perpetuity, then it is optimal for the insurer to declare bankruptcy and claim the salvage value. This strategy is called take-the-money-and-run by Loeffen and Renaud (21, Theorem 1.1 and Liang and Young (212, Remark Restricted dividends In this subsection, we consider the optimal classical dividend problem where a ceiling M > is imposed on the dividend rate. Let p = (a p ; L p ; Π stand for the control process in which capital injection is not allowed. The performance function associated with p is defined by We focus on finding the value function V (x, p = E x( τ p β 1 δs e l p s ds + Pe δτ p. (4.11 V p (x = max V (x, p (4.12 p Π and the optimal strategy p = (a p ; L p ; Π such that V p (x = V (x, p. From the stochastic control theory, V p (x should satisfy the following HJB equation and the boundary condition max A āv p (x + l(β 1 V p(x} = (4.13 ā 1, l M V p ( = P. (

15 Theorem 4.3. Let h(x be a twice continuously differentiable, increasing and concave solution of (4.13 and (4.14, then we have the following statements: (i For each p Π, we have h(x V (x, p. So h(x V p (x for all x. (ii If there exists some strategy p = (a p ; L p ; such that h(x = V (x, p, then h(x = V p (x and p is optimal. Proof. The proof of (i is similar to Appendix A, it is omitted here. The result of (ii is obvious. Theorem 4.4. The value function V p (x and the associated optimal strategy p = (a p ; L p ; are given according to different cases: (i In the case where P [, β1(1 ā 2θξ ], then V p (x coincides with β 1M δ + β1 eγ(x b p γ, x > b p, h(x = ( ξ A 2θξ ξ+a p ( e2θx 1, x b p, (4.15 where A = β 1 (ξ + ā ξ (1 ā 1, b p = 1 2θ ln ( ξ+a p( ξ+ā and a p (, ā, γ are roots of (4.18, (4.19 and (4.25, respectively. The optimal dividend strategy L p is defined by the following dividend rate M, x > l p = l p (x = b p,, x b p. (4.16 The optimal ceded proportion a p is given by a p (x = ā, x > b p, (ξ + a p (e 2θx ξ, < x b p. (4.17 Here a p ( (, 1 is the unique solution of the following equation A ( 2θξ ā (, 1 is the positive root of the equation ( a 2 + (ii In the case where P [ β1(1 ā 2θξ,, then ξ + 1 ξ + a p ( 1 ξ 1 + 2Mθξ δ h(x = β 1M δ ξ = P, (4.18 a ξ =. ( (P β 1M e γx. (4.2 δ The associated optimal strategy L p and a p can also be described by (4.16 and (4.17 but with b p =. Proof. (i The value functions V p (x and V p (x satisfy the same HJB equation but with different boundary conditions at x =. So (4.15-(4.17 can be obtained similarly. The value of a p ( is determined by h( = P, which is the same as equation (4.18. Note that a p ( must be larger than the fixed number ā, the value of the left hand side of (4.18 varies in the region [, β1(1 ā 2θξ ], the solution for a p ( exists in this case. Finally, we can establish that h(x is indeed a twice continuously differentiable, increasing and concave solution of (4.13 and (4.14, and h(x = V p (x = V (x, p, the verification process is omitted. (ii Let us consider the opposite case with P [ β1(1 ā 2θξ,. We conjecture that h (x β 1 for all x. Then max A āh(x } + l(β 1 h (x = max A āh(x } + M(β 1 h (x, (4.21 ā 1, l M ā 1 specifically, 1 max ā 1 2 (1 ā2 λµ 2 2h (x + ((1 ā 2 θλµ 2 2 Mh (x δh(x + β 1 M} =. (

16 Taking derivative with respect to ā on the left hand side of (4.22 yields h (x 2θa h (x = p (x, ( a p (x where a p (x is the maximizer in (4.22. However, we guess that a p (x ā is a constant, then the value function takes the form with h(x = C + De γx (4.24 γ = 2θā 1 ā. (4.25 By plugging (4.24 into (4.22, we deduce that C = β1m δ, and < ā < 1 is given by (4.19. Then D = P β1m δ can also be obtained by the boundary condition h( = P. We still need to verify the condition h (x β 1 for all x, equivalently, h ( = Dγ β 1 P β 1 γ + β 1M δ = β 1(1 ā 2θā + β 1M δ = β 1(1 ā 2θξ (4.26 where the last step follows from (4.19. It is easy to verify that h(x is indeed a twice continuously differentiable, increasing and concave solution of (4.13 and (4.14, the optimality of p can be established by the same way as that in Appendix B. Remark 4.2. All results obtained in Subsections 3.2 and 4.2 are compatible with those in Subsection 3.1 and Subsection 4.1, respectively, when the dividend ceiling M goes to infinity. That is, the optimal control problem without dividend restrictions can be seen as the limiting optimal control problem with bounded dividend rate. 5. The solution to the general optimal problems Now, based on the analysis in sections above, we can address the problem of maximizing the performance function over all admissible strategies. The two general optimal control problems raised in Section 2 can be solved completely Unrestricted dividends In this subsection, we would deal with Problem 2.1 in general case. According to the stochastic control theory, V (x should satisfy the following HJB equation } max max A a V (x, β 1 V (x, MV (x V (x =, (5.1 a 1 with boundary condition maxmv ( V (, P V (} =. (5.2 Theorem 5.1. Let v(x be a twice continuously differentiable, increasing and concave solution of equations (5.1 and (5.2, then we have the following statements: (i For each Π we have v(x V (x,. So v(x V (x for all x. (ii If there exists some strategy = (a ; L ; G such that v(x = V (x,, then v(x = V (x and is optimal. Proof. See the proof process in Appendix A. Next, let us give two lemmas, which show the relationships between parameters and signs of some important quantities. For convenience, denote ˆP := β ( 1 1 2θ ξ ξ + 1 ξ 1 ξ + â (5.3 15

17 which proves to be a critical level later. By the way, ˆP takes value on [, β1 2θξ ] since â [, 1]. Lemma 5.1. The signs of Mg( g( and P g( can be determined as follows: (i In the case where < K I(1, P ˆP and a r ( a p (, it follows that Mg( g( = and P g(. (ii In the case where < K I(1, P ˆP and a r ( > a p (, it follows that Mg( g( = and P g( >. (iii In the case where < K I(1, P > ˆP, it follows that Mg( g( = and P g( >. (iv In the case where K > I(1, it follows that Mg( g( <. Proof. (i Theorem 3.2 shows that Mg( g( = holds with some a r ( (â, 1] when < K I(1. Furthermore, by observing the structures of (4.8 and (5.3, we know that the condition P ˆP leads to a p ( â, which makes the inequality a r ( a p ( possible. So P g( holds if a r ( a p (. (ii In this case, the equality Mg( g( = still holds. Similar to the analysis in (i, the condition a r ( > a p ( leads to P g( >. (iii In this case, the equality Mg( g( = still holds. In addition, for the case of ˆP < P β 1 2θξ, it follows that a p ( < â < a r (, which leads to P g( >. For the case of P β 1 2θξ g( < g(b r = β1 2θξ P since the function g(x is increasing. (iv Obviously, (iv is a direct result of Theorem 3.2., we have Lemma 5.2. The property of P f( = is known. Moreover, we can derive the sign of Mf( f( according to the following cases: (i In the case where < K I(1, P ˆP and a p ( a r (, it follows that Mf( f(. (ii In the case where < K I(1, P ˆP and a p ( < a r (, it follows that Mf( f( <. (iii In the case where < K I(1, P > ˆP, it follows that Mf( f( <. (iv In the case where K > I(1, it follows that Mf( f( <. Proof. (i Observing the structures of (4.8 and (5.3, the condition P ˆP implies that a p ( â. Lemma 3.1 suggests that there exists some number ζ < b p with f (ζ = Φ a p ( (ζ = β 2. Then, it follows that f (x β 2 on (, ζ] and f (x β 2 < on (ζ, since f(x is concave. Consequently, Mf( f( = max f(y β 2y K f(} y y } = max (f (x β 2 dx K = y ζ (f (x β 2 dx K = I(a p ( K The above inequality follows from a p ( a r (. (ii Similar to the analysis in (i, the condition a p ( < a r ( leads to I(a r ( K =. (5.4 Mf( f( = I(a p ( K < I(a r ( K =. (5.5 (iii In the case of P > ˆP, the number a p ( [â, 1] does not exist, we can not find the number ζ > such that f (ζ = Φ a p ( (ζ = β 2. It implies that f (x < β 2 holds for all x since f(x is concave. Thereby, Mf( f( = max f(y β 2y K f(} y y } = max (f (x β 2 dx K <. (5.6 y (iv From the above analysis we know the value of Mf( f( can not exceed I(1 K, no matter the number ζ > with f (ζ = β 2 exists or not. So Mf( f( < follows. Consequently, by comparing two different suboptimal models in Subsection 3.1 and Subsection 4.1, we 16

18 can address the problem of maximizing the performance function V (x, over all admissible strategies. Theorem 5.2. Let g(x be the solution appearing in Theorem 3.2, and let f(x be the solution appearing in Theorem 4.2. Then we can solve Problem 2.1 as follows: Case 1. In the case where Mg( g( = and P g(, or equivalently, the following condition holds, (i < K I(1, P ˆP and a r ( a p (, then V (x = V r (x = g(x and coincides with r = (a r ; L r ; G r appearing in Theorem 3.2. Case 2. In the case where Mf( f( and P f( =, or equivalently, one of the following conditions holds, (ii < K I(1, P ˆP and a r ( > a p (; (iii < K I(1 and P > ˆP; (iv K I(1, then V (x = V p (x = f(x and coincides with p = (a p ; L p ; G p appearing in Theorem 4.2. Proof. See the proof process in Appendix B Restricted dividends In this subsection, we would solve Problem 2.2 in general case. According to the stochastic control theory, V (x should satisfy the following HJB equation max max A āv } (x + l(β 1 V (x}, MV (x V (x = (5.7 ā 1, l M with boundary condition maxmv ( V (, P V (} =. (5.8 Theorem 5.3. Let u(x be a twice continuously differentiable, increasing and concave solution of equations (5.7 and (5.8, then we have the following statements: (i For each Π, it follows that u(x V (x,. So u(x V (x for all x. (ii If there exists some strategy = (a ; L ; G such that u(x = V (x,, then u(x = V (x and is optimal. Proof. Repeating a similar proof procedure as that in Appendix A, the results can be proved. Similar to the discussion in Subsection 5.1, let us give following two lemmas, but the proofs are omitted. To facilitate the expression, we denote that P := A ( ξ + 1 ξ 1 2θξ ξ + ã (5.9 which is also a critical level. By the way, P takes value on [, β1(1 ā 2θξ ] since ã [, 1]. Lemma 5.3. The signs of Mw( w( and P w( can be determined as follows. (i In the case where < K Ī(1, P P and a r ( a p (, it has Mw( w( = and P w(. (ii In the case where < K Ī(1, P P and a r ( > a p (, it has Mw( w( = and P w( >. (iii In the case where < K Ī(1, P > P, it has Mw( w( = and P w( >. (iv In the case where K > Ī(1, it has Mw( w( <. Lemma 5.4. The signs of Mh( h( and P h( can be determined as follows. (i In the case where < K Ī(1, P P and a p ( a r (, it has Mh( h( and P h( =. (ii In the case where < K Ī(1, P P and a p ( < a r (, it has Mh( h( < and P h( =. (iii In the case where < K Ī(1, P > P, it has Mh( h( < and P h( =. (iv In the case where K > Ī(1, it has Mh( h( < and P h( =. Next, by comparing results in Subsection 3.2 and Subsection 4.2, we will identify Problem 2.2 of maximizing the performance function V (x, over all admissible strategies. 17

19 Theorem 5.4. Let w(x be the solution appearing in Theorem 3.4, and let h(x be the solution appearing in Theorem 4.4. Then the Problem 2.2 can be solved according to different cases: Case 1. In the case where Mw( w( = and P w(, i.e., the following condition holds, (i < K Ī(1, P P and a r ( a p (, then V (x = V r (x = w(x and coincides with r = (a r ; L r ; G r appearing in Theorem 3.4. Case 2. In the case where Mh( h( < and P h( =, i.e., one of the following conditions holds, (ii < K Ī(1, P P and a p ( < a r (; (iii < K Ī(1, P > P; (iv K > Ī(1, then V (x = V p (x = h(x and coincides with p = (a p ; L p ; G p appearing in Theorem 4.4. Proof. Repeating a similar proof procedure as that in Appendix B, the results can be verified. Remark 5.1. Zhou and Yuen (212 have explored the optimal dividend, capital injection and reinsurance problem in the special case with P = K =. All results there can be viewed as limiting forms of ours as P and K. Due to the existence of the fixed cost and the salvage value, to inject capital is not always optimal when K > or P > in our model. The decision to inject new capitals or to declare bankruptcy depends on the costs of injections and the profitability in future. Appendix A. Proofs of Theorem 5.1 For each given strategy = (a ; L ; G Π, define Λ L = s : L s L s }, Λ G = s : G s G s } = τ1, τ2,, τn, }. Let ˆL t = (L s Λ L,s t s L s be the discontinuous part of L t and L t = L t ˆL t be the continuous part of L t. Similarly, Ĝ t and G t stand for the discontinuous and continuous parts of G t respectively. Then, applying the generalized Itô formula, we derive that e δ(t τ v(xt τ v(x = t τ + e δs L a v(x s ds + t τ e δs v (X s d G s + t τ (1 a t τ λµ 2 e δs v (Xs db s s Λ G Λ L,s t τ e δs e δs v (X s d L s ( v(xs v(xs. (A.1 The last term on the right hand side can be written as ( v(xs v(xs s Λ G Λ L,s t τ e δs = s Λ L,s t τ e δs ( v(xs v(xs + s Λ L,s t τ e δs β 1 (L s L s + s Λ G,s t τ e δs ( v(xs v(xs e δτ n (β2 ξn + KI τn t τ } (A.2 where the inequality is due to that v(x satisfies the HJB equation (5.1 with v (x β 1 and Mv(x v(x. Moreover, in view of (5.1, the first term on the right hand side of (A.1 is non-positive. So substituting (A.2 into (A.1, we obtain e δ(t τ v(x t τ t τ v(x + (1 a t τ λµ 2 e δs v (Xs db s β 1 e δs dl s + e δτ n (β2 ξn + KI τn t τ }. (A.3 18

20 Since v(x is an increasing function and v( P, we have e δ(t τ P v(x + + t τ (1 a t τ λµ 2 e δs v (Xs db s β 1 e δτ n (β2 ξn + KI τn t τ }. e δs dl s (A.4 The stochastic integral with respect to the Brownian motion in (A.4 is a uniformly integrable martingale, if v (x is bounded. Taking expectation and limit on both sides of (A.4 yields v(x E x( τ β 1 e δs dl s e δτ n (β2 ηn + KI τ n τ } + Pe δτ = V (x,. (A.5 Consequently, v(x V (x by (2.6. Applying the method in Cadenillas et al. (26, we can also prove above results when v (x is unbounded by modifying above proof process, it is omitted here. B. Proofs of Theorem 5.2 (1 If P g( and Mg( = g(, then g(x satisfies conditions of Theorem 5.1, g(x V (x. Since L a r g(x r t = for X r t b r, one has t τ r Furthermore, (3.5-(3.7 and (3.9 indicate that e δs( g(x r s g(x r s s Λ r G Λ r L,s t τ r = = s Λ r L,s t τ r s Λ r L,s t τ r t τ r e δs L a r g(x r s ds = e δs L a r g(x r s I X r s b r }ds =. (B.1 e δs( g(x r s g(x r s I X r s =b r } + e δs β 1 (L r s L r s + r e δτ n s Λ r G,s t τ r (β 2 ξ r n e δs( g(x r s g(x r s I X r s =} + KI τ r n t τ r }. (B.2 Replacing, τ, v by r, τ r =, g in Itô formula (A.1 and taking expectations, we have g(x = E x [e δt g(x r t ] + E x( β 1 t e δs dl r s r e δτ n (β 2 ξ r n Letting t, the first term on the right hand side vanishes, then we obtain g(x = E x( β 1 e δs dl r s e δτ r n (β 2 ξ r n + KI τ r n < } + KI τ r. (B.3 n t} = V (x, r, (B.4 which, together with g(x V (x, establishes that g(x = V (x = V (x, r, and r strategy. is the associated optimal (2 If P f( = and Mf( f(, then f(x satisfies conditions of Theorem 5.1, so f(x V (x. Since L a p f(x p t = for X p t b p, one has t τ p e δs L a p f(x p s ds = t τ p e δs L a p f(x p s I X p =. (B.5 s b p }ds 19

21 Moreover, under the strategy p = (a p ; L p ; Π, the capital injection never occurs, Λ p G is a null set. Thereby, together with (4.6, it follows that s Λ p G Λ p L,s t τ p e δs( f(x p s f(x p s = = s Λ p L,s t τ p s Λ p L,s t τ p e δs( f(x p s f(x p s I X p s =b p } β 1 e δs( L p s L p s. (B.6 Replacing, τ, v by p, τ p, f, respectively, in Itô formula (A.1 and taking expectations, we have Letting t yields f(x = E x( t τ p β 1 e δs dl p s + f(x p p t τ e δ(t τ. p (B.7 f(x = E x( τ p β 1 e δs dl p s + Pe δτ p = V (x, p, (B.8 which, together with f(x V (x, confirms that f(x = V (x = V (x, p, and p is the associated optimal strategy. Acknowledgments This work was supported by the Research Grants Council of the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region, China (project No. HKU 76611P, National Natural Science Foundation of China(111125,112315, , Doctoral Program Foundation of the Ministry of Education of China ( , The Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities, A Project Funded by the Priority Academic Program Development of Jiangsu Higher Education Institutions. References [1] Asmussen, S. and Taksar, M., Controlled diffusion models for optimal dividend pay-out. Ins.: Mathematics Econ. 2(1, [2] Avram, F., Palmowski, Z. and Pistorius, M. R., 27. On the optimal dividend problem for a spectrally negative Lévy process. Ann. Appl. Probab. 17(1, [3] Azcue, P. and Muler, N., 212. Optimal dividend policies for compound Poisson processes: The case of bounded dividend rates. Ins.: Mathematics Econ. 51(1, [4] Bai, L., Guo, J. and Zhang, H., 21. Optimal excess-of-loss reinsurance and dividend payments with both transaction costs and taxes. Quant. Financ. 1(1, [5] Belhaj, M., 21. Optimal dividend payments when cash reserves follow a jump-diffusion process. Math. Financ. 2(2, [6] Cadenillas, A., Choulli, T., Taksar, M. and Zhang, L., 26. Classical and impulse stochastic control for the optimization of the dividend and risk policies of an insurance firm. Math. Financ. 16(1, [7] Choulli, T., Taksar, M. and Zhou, X.Y., 23. A diffusion model for optimal dividend distribution for a company with constraints on risk control. SIAM J. Control. Optim. 41(6, [8] Dai, H., Liu, Z. and Luan, N., 21. Optimal dividend strategies in a dual model with capital injections. Math. Method. Oper. Res. 72(1, [9] Gerber, H.U. and Shiu, E.S.W., 26. On optimal dividends strategies in the compound poisson model. N. Amer. Actuarial J. 1(2, [1] Gerber, H.U., Lin, X. S. and Yang, H., 26. A note on the dividends-penalty identity and the optimal dividend barrier. ASTIN Bull. 36(2, [11] He, L. and Liang, Z.X., 29. Optimal financing and dividend control of the insurance company with fixed and proportional transaction costs. Ins.: Mathematics Econ. 42(3, [12] Hφgaard, B. and Taksar, M., 24. Optimal dynamic portfolio selection for a corporation with controllable risk and dividend distribution policy. Quant. Financ. 9(2, [13] Kulenko, N. and Schmidli, H., 28. Optimal dividend strategies in a Cramér-Lundberg model with capital injections. Ins.: Mathematics Econ. 43(2, [14] Liang, Z. and Young, V.R., 212. Dividends and reinsurance under a penalty for ruin. Ins.: Mathematics Econ. 5(3, [15] Loeffen, R.L. and Renaud, J.F., 21. De Finetti s optimal dividends problem with an affine penalty function at ruin. Ins.: Mathematics Econ. 46(1, [16] Lφkka, A. and Zervos, M., 28. Optimal dividend and issuance of equity policies in the presence of proportional costs. Ins.: Mathematics Econ. 42(3, [17] Meng, H. and Siu, T., 211. On optimal reinsurance, dividend and reinvestment strategies. Econ. Model. 28, [18] Paulsen, J., 28. Optimal dividend payments and reinvestments of diffusion processes with both fixed and proportional costs. SIAM J. Control. Optim. 47(5, [19] Peng, X., Chen, M. and Guo, J., 212. Optimal dividend and equity issuance problem with proportional and fixed transaction costs. Ins.: Mathematics Econ. 51(3, [2] Sethi, S.P. and Taksar, M., 22. Optimal financing of a corporation subject to random returns. Math. Financ. 12,

ON MAXIMIZING DIVIDENDS WITH INVESTMENT AND REINSURANCE

ON MAXIMIZING DIVIDENDS WITH INVESTMENT AND REINSURANCE ON MAXIMIZING DIVIDENDS WITH INVESTMENT AND REINSURANCE George S. Ongkeko, Jr. a, Ricardo C.H. Del Rosario b, Maritina T. Castillo c a Insular Life of the Philippines, Makati City 0725, Philippines b Department

More information

Optimal Dividend Policy of A Large Insurance Company with Solvency Constraints. Zongxia Liang

Optimal Dividend Policy of A Large Insurance Company with Solvency Constraints. Zongxia Liang Optimal Dividend Policy of A Large Insurance Company with Solvency Constraints Zongxia Liang Department of Mathematical Sciences Tsinghua University, Beijing 100084, China zliang@math.tsinghua.edu.cn Joint

More information

Dividend problem for a general Lévy insurance risk process

Dividend problem for a general Lévy insurance risk process Dividend problem for a general Lévy insurance risk process Zbigniew Palmowski Joint work with F. Avram, I. Czarna, A. Kyprianou, M. Pistorius Croatian Quants Day, Zagreb Economic point of view 2 The word

More information

Dividend Strategies for Insurance risk models

Dividend Strategies for Insurance risk models 1 Introduction Based on different objectives, various insurance risk models with adaptive polices have been proposed, such as dividend model, tax model, model with credibility premium, and so on. In this

More information

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance Alexander Cox Jiajie Wang University of Bath Bachelier 21, Toronto Financial Setting Option priced on an underlying asset S t Dynamics of S t unspecified,

More information

Deterministic Income under a Stochastic Interest Rate

Deterministic Income under a Stochastic Interest Rate Deterministic Income under a Stochastic Interest Rate Julia Eisenberg, TU Vienna Scientic Day, 1 Agenda 1 Classical Problem: Maximizing Discounted Dividends in a Brownian Risk Model 2 Maximizing Discounted

More information

Dividend Problems in Insurance: From de Finetti to Today

Dividend Problems in Insurance: From de Finetti to Today Dividend Problems in Insurance: From de Finetti to Today Nicole Bäuerle based on joint works with A. Jaśkiewicz Strasbourg, September 2014 Outline Generic Dividend Problem Motivation Basic Models and Results

More information

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection Hans U. Gerber and Gérard Pafumi Switzerland Abstract In the first part of the paper the surplus of a company is modelled by a Wiener process.

More information

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk Portfolio optimization problem with default risk M.Mazidi, A. Delavarkhalafi, A.Mokhtari mazidi.3635@gmail.com delavarkh@yazduni.ac.ir ahmokhtari20@gmail.com Faculty of Mathematics, Yazd University, P.O.

More information

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION SILAS A. IHEDIOHA 1, BRIGHT O. OSU 2 1 Department of Mathematics, Plateau State University, Bokkos, P. M. B. 2012, Jos,

More information

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 2014 MERTON PORTFOLIO PROBLEM WITH ONE INDIVISIBLE ASSET JAKUB TRYBU LA arxiv:143.3223v1 [q-fin.pm] 13 Mar 214 Abstract. In this paper we consider a modification of the classical Merton portfolio optimization

More information

A discretionary stopping problem with applications to the optimal timing of investment decisions.

A discretionary stopping problem with applications to the optimal timing of investment decisions. A discretionary stopping problem with applications to the optimal timing of investment decisions. Timothy Johnson Department of Mathematics King s College London The Strand London WC2R 2LS, UK Tuesday,

More information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Course: Setter: M5MF6 Dr Antoine Jacquier MSc EXAMINATIONS IN MATHEMATICS AND FINANCE DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS April 2016 M5MF6 Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing Setter s signature...........................................

More information

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model

Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model Pricing Exotic Options Under a Higher-order Hidden Markov Model Wai-Ki Ching Tak-Kuen Siu Li-min Li 26 Jan. 2007 Abstract In this paper, we consider the pricing of exotic options when the price dynamic

More information

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model MATHEMATICAL COMMUNICATIONS 231 Math. Commun. 18(2013, 231 239 The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model Tatjana Slijepčević-Manger 1, 1 Faculty of Civil Engineering, University

More information

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products June 2016 2 Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products Jungmin Choi Department of Mathematics East Carolina University Abstract In this study, a hybrid

More information

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Fuzzy Optim Decis Making 217 16:221 234 DOI 117/s17-16-9246-8 No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate Xiaoyu Ji 1 Hua Ke 2 Published online: 17 May 216 Springer

More information

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies Jan Večeř, Columbia University, Department of Statistics, Mingxin Xu, Carnegie Mellon University, Department of Mathematical Sciences, Olympia

More information

Lecture 1: Lévy processes

Lecture 1: Lévy processes Lecture 1: Lévy processes A. E. Kyprianou Department of Mathematical Sciences, University of Bath 1/ 22 Lévy processes 2/ 22 Lévy processes A process X = {X t : t 0} defined on a probability space (Ω,

More information

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Theory of Option Pricing 2 2. Black-Scholes PDE Method 4 3. Martingale method 4 4. Monte Carlo methods 5 4.1. Method of antithetic variances 5

More information

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching

Option Pricing under Delay Geometric Brownian Motion with Regime Switching Science Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics 2016; 4(6): 263-268 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/sjams doi: 10.11648/j.sjams.20160406.13 ISSN: 2376-9491 (Print); ISSN: 2376-9513 (Online)

More information

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models

Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models Stock Loan Valuation Under Brownian-Motion Based and Markov Chain Stock Models David Prager 1 1 Associate Professor of Mathematics Anderson University (SC) Based on joint work with Professor Qing Zhang,

More information

Optimal retention for a stop-loss reinsurance with incomplete information

Optimal retention for a stop-loss reinsurance with incomplete information Optimal retention for a stop-loss reinsurance with incomplete information Xiang Hu 1 Hailiang Yang 2 Lianzeng Zhang 3 1,3 Department of Risk Management and Insurance, Nankai University Weijin Road, Tianjin,

More information

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval A. N. Shiryaev M. V. Zhitlukhin arxiv:1212.379v1 [math.st] 15 Dec 212 December 18, 212 Abstract We consider optimal

More information

Optimal Allocation of Policy Limits and Deductibles

Optimal Allocation of Policy Limits and Deductibles Optimal Allocation of Policy Limits and Deductibles Ka Chun Cheung Email: kccheung@math.ucalgary.ca Tel: +1-403-2108697 Fax: +1-403-2825150 Department of Mathematics and Statistics, University of Calgary,

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2016 M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market Models 1 / 87 General Single-Period

More information

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments

Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments Pricing in markets modeled by general processes with independent increments Tom Hurd Financial Mathematics at McMaster www.phimac.org Thanks to Tahir Choulli and Shui Feng Financial Mathematics Seminar

More information

Optimal Time for Acquisition of a company in the diffusion model

Optimal Time for Acquisition of a company in the diffusion model Optimal Time for Acquisition of a company in the diffusion model Nora Muler nmuler@utdt.edu Universidad Torcuato Di Tella Coauthor: Pablo Azcue Universidad Torcuato Di Tella. Buenos Aires, Argentina. Samos.

More information

Multi-period mean variance asset allocation: Is it bad to win the lottery?

Multi-period mean variance asset allocation: Is it bad to win the lottery? Multi-period mean variance asset allocation: Is it bad to win the lottery? Peter Forsyth 1 D.M. Dang 1 1 Cheriton School of Computer Science University of Waterloo Guangzhou, July 28, 2014 1 / 29 The Basic

More information

A Continuity Correction under Jump-Diffusion Models with Applications in Finance

A Continuity Correction under Jump-Diffusion Models with Applications in Finance A Continuity Correction under Jump-Diffusion Models with Applications in Finance Cheng-Der Fuh 1, Sheng-Feng Luo 2 and Ju-Fang Yen 3 1 Institute of Statistical Science, Academia Sinica, and Graduate Institute

More information

The stochastic calculus

The stochastic calculus Gdansk A schedule of the lecture Stochastic differential equations Ito calculus, Ito process Ornstein - Uhlenbeck (OU) process Heston model Stopping time for OU process Stochastic differential equations

More information

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS MATH307/37 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS School of Mathematics and Statistics Semester, 04 Tutorial problems should be used to test your mathematical skills and understanding of the lecture material.

More information

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes International Journal of Mathematical Analysis Vol. 9, 215, no. 16, 787-791 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/1.12988/ijma.215.411358 Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

More information

The value of foresight

The value of foresight Philip Ernst Department of Statistics, Rice University Support from NSF-DMS-1811936 (co-pi F. Viens) and ONR-N00014-18-1-2192 gratefully acknowledged. IMA Financial and Economic Applications June 11, 2018

More information

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods Finite difference and finite element methods Lecture 4 Outline Black-Scholes equation From expectation to PDE Goal: compute the value of European option with payoff g which is the conditional expectation

More information

Optimal reinsurance for variance related premium calculation principles

Optimal reinsurance for variance related premium calculation principles Optimal reinsurance for variance related premium calculation principles Guerra, M. and Centeno, M.L. CEOC and ISEG, TULisbon CEMAPRE, ISEG, TULisbon ASTIN 2007 Guerra and Centeno (ISEG, TULisbon) Optimal

More information

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Fuzzy Optim Decis Making manuscript No (will be inserted by the editor) A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model Kai Yao Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Stock model is used to describe

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL YOUNGGEUN YOO Abstract. Ito s lemma is often used in Ito calculus to find the differentials of a stochastic process that depends on time. This paper will introduce

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Liquidation of a Large Block of Stock

Liquidation of a Large Block of Stock Liquidation of a Large Block of Stock M. Pemy Q. Zhang G. Yin September 21, 2006 Abstract In the financial engineering literature, stock-selling rules are mainly concerned with liquidation of the security

More information

Volatility. Roberto Renò. 2 March 2010 / Scuola Normale Superiore. Dipartimento di Economia Politica Università di Siena

Volatility. Roberto Renò. 2 March 2010 / Scuola Normale Superiore. Dipartimento di Economia Politica Università di Siena Dipartimento di Economia Politica Università di Siena 2 March 2010 / Scuola Normale Superiore What is? The definition of volatility may vary wildly around the idea of the standard deviation of price movements

More information

Discounted Optimal Stopping for Maxima of some Jump-Diffusion Processes

Discounted Optimal Stopping for Maxima of some Jump-Diffusion Processes SFB 649 Discussion Paper 2006-059 Discounted Optimal Stopping for Maxima of some Jump-Diffusion Processes Pavel V. Gapeev* * Weierstrass Institute for Applied Analysis and Stochastics, Berlin, Germany

More information

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns Peter Carr NYU CBOE Conference on Derivatives and Volatility, Chicago, Nov. 10, 2017 Peter Carr (NYU) Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns 11/10/2017 1 / 33 Interest Rates

More information

Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps

Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps Estimation of Value at Risk and ruin probability for diffusion processes with jumps Begoña Fernández Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México joint work with Laurent Denis and Ana Meda PASI, May 21 Begoña

More information

Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund

Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund Alexander M. G. Cox Sam M. Kinsley University of Bath Recent Advances in Financial Mathematics, Paris, 10th January, 2017 A. M. G. Cox, S.

More information

MARGIN CALL STOCK LOANS

MARGIN CALL STOCK LOANS MARGIN CALL STOCK LOANS ERIK EKSTRÖM AND HENRIK WANNTORP Abstract. We study margin call stock loans, i.e. loans in which a stock acts as collateral, and the borrower is obliged to pay back parts of the

More information

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models Beatrice Acciaio the London School of Economics and Political Science (based on a joint work with C. Fontana and

More information

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS. MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS May/June 2006 Time allowed: 2 HOURS. Examiner: Dr N.P. Byott This is a CLOSED

More information

Minimizing the ruin probability through capital injections

Minimizing the ruin probability through capital injections Minimizing the ruin probability through capital injections Ciyu Nie, David C M Dickson and Shuanming Li Abstract We consider an insurer who has a fixed amount of funds allocated as the initial surplus

More information

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations Martin Haugh Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University Email: martin.b.haugh@gmail.com

More information

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models Alexander Cox 1 Jiajie Wang 2 1 University of Bath 2 Università di Roma La Sapienza Advances in Financial Mathematics, 9th January,

More information

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Jan Obłój j.obloj@imperial.ac.uk based on joint works with L. Carraro, N. El Karoui, A. Meziou and M. Yor Swiss Probability Seminar, 5 Dec 2007 Are the Azéma-Yor

More information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Exponential utility maximization under partial information Exponential utility maximization under partial information Marina Santacroce Politecnico di Torino Joint work with M. Mania AMaMeF 5-1 May, 28 Pitesti, May 1th, 28 Outline Expected utility maximization

More information

THE NUMBER OF UNARY CLONES CONTAINING THE PERMUTATIONS ON AN INFINITE SET

THE NUMBER OF UNARY CLONES CONTAINING THE PERMUTATIONS ON AN INFINITE SET THE NUMBER OF UNARY CLONES CONTAINING THE PERMUTATIONS ON AN INFINITE SET MICHAEL PINSKER Abstract. We calculate the number of unary clones (submonoids of the full transformation monoid) containing the

More information

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model A Quasi-Likelihood Approach Ziliang Li University of Maryland, College Park GEE RIT, Spring 28 Outline 1 Model Review The Big Model in Mind: Signal + Noise

More information

13.3 A Stochastic Production Planning Model

13.3 A Stochastic Production Planning Model 13.3. A Stochastic Production Planning Model 347 From (13.9), we can formally write (dx t ) = f (dt) + G (dz t ) + fgdz t dt, (13.3) dx t dt = f(dt) + Gdz t dt. (13.33) The exact meaning of these expressions

More information

Research Article Portfolio Selection with Subsistence Consumption Constraints and CARA Utility

Research Article Portfolio Selection with Subsistence Consumption Constraints and CARA Utility Mathematical Problems in Engineering Volume 14, Article ID 153793, 6 pages http://dx.doi.org/1.1155/14/153793 Research Article Portfolio Selection with Subsistence Consumption Constraints and CARA Utility

More information

Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control

Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Optimal Securitization via Impulse Control Rüdiger Frey (joint work with Roland C. Seydel) Mathematisches Institut Universität Leipzig and MPI MIS Leipzig Bachelier Finance Society, June 21 (1) Optimal

More information

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable?

Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Are the Azéma-Yor processes truly remarkable? Jan Obłój j.obloj@imperial.ac.uk based on joint works with L. Carraro, N. El Karoui, A. Meziou and M. Yor Welsh Probability Seminar, 17 Jan 28 Are the Azéma-Yor

More information

Term Structure of Credit Spreads of A Firm When Its Underlying Assets are Discontinuous

Term Structure of Credit Spreads of A Firm When Its Underlying Assets are Discontinuous www.sbm.itb.ac.id/ajtm The Asian Journal of Technology Management Vol. 3 No. 2 (2010) 69-73 Term Structure of Credit Spreads of A Firm When Its Underlying Assets are Discontinuous Budhi Arta Surya *1 1

More information

Liquidity and Risk Management

Liquidity and Risk Management Liquidity and Risk Management By Nicolae Gârleanu and Lasse Heje Pedersen Risk management plays a central role in institutional investors allocation of capital to trading. For instance, a risk manager

More information

1 Rare event simulation and importance sampling

1 Rare event simulation and importance sampling Copyright c 2007 by Karl Sigman 1 Rare event simulation and importance sampling Suppose we wish to use Monte Carlo simulation to estimate a probability p = P (A) when the event A is rare (e.g., when p

More information

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment Goal: Endogenize firm characteristics and risk. Value/growth Size Leverage New issues,... This lecture: q theory of investment Irreversible investment and real

More information

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms Bernard Bercu Bordeaux University, France IFCAM Summer School Bangalore, India, July 2015 Bernard Bercu Asymptotic results for discrete

More information

Lecture 23: April 10

Lecture 23: April 10 CS271 Randomness & Computation Spring 2018 Instructor: Alistair Sinclair Lecture 23: April 10 Disclaimer: These notes have not been subjected to the usual scrutiny accorded to formal publications. They

More information

Portfolio Optimization Under Fixed Transaction Costs

Portfolio Optimization Under Fixed Transaction Costs Portfolio Optimization Under Fixed Transaction Costs Gennady Shaikhet supervised by Dr. Gady Zohar The model Market with two securities: b(t) - bond without interest rate p(t) - stock, an Ito process db(t)

More information

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Model-independent bounds for Asian options Model-independent bounds for Asian options A dynamic programming approach Alexander M. G. Cox 1 Sigrid Källblad 2 1 University of Bath 2 CMAP, École Polytechnique University of Michigan, 2nd December,

More information

Department of Social Systems and Management. Discussion Paper Series

Department of Social Systems and Management. Discussion Paper Series Department of Social Systems and Management Discussion Paper Series No.1252 Application of Collateralized Debt Obligation Approach for Managing Inventory Risk in Classical Newsboy Problem by Rina Isogai,

More information

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s An Informal Introduction Olav Kallenberg Graduate Student Seminar, April 18, 2012 1 / 33 2 / 33 Simple recursion: Deterministic system, discrete time x n+1 = f (x

More information

VALUATION OF FLEXIBLE INSURANCE CONTRACTS

VALUATION OF FLEXIBLE INSURANCE CONTRACTS Teor Imov r.tamatem.statist. Theor. Probability and Math. Statist. Vip. 73, 005 No. 73, 006, Pages 109 115 S 0094-90000700685-0 Article electronically published on January 17, 007 UDC 519.1 VALUATION OF

More information

Online Appendices to Financing Asset Sales and Business Cycles

Online Appendices to Financing Asset Sales and Business Cycles Online Appendices to Financing Asset Sales usiness Cycles Marc Arnold Dirk Hackbarth Tatjana Xenia Puhan August 22, 2017 University of St. allen, Unterer raben 21, 9000 St. allen, Switzerl. Telephone:

More information

Hedging under Arbitrage

Hedging under Arbitrage Hedging under Arbitrage Johannes Ruf Columbia University, Department of Statistics Modeling and Managing Financial Risks January 12, 2011 Motivation Given: a frictionless market of stocks with continuous

More information

Finite Additivity in Dubins-Savage Gambling and Stochastic Games. Bill Sudderth University of Minnesota

Finite Additivity in Dubins-Savage Gambling and Stochastic Games. Bill Sudderth University of Minnesota Finite Additivity in Dubins-Savage Gambling and Stochastic Games Bill Sudderth University of Minnesota This talk is based on joint work with Lester Dubins, David Heath, Ashok Maitra, and Roger Purves.

More information

Asymptotic Theory for Renewal Based High-Frequency Volatility Estimation

Asymptotic Theory for Renewal Based High-Frequency Volatility Estimation Asymptotic Theory for Renewal Based High-Frequency Volatility Estimation Yifan Li 1,2 Ingmar Nolte 1 Sandra Nolte 1 1 Lancaster University 2 University of Manchester 4th Konstanz - Lancaster Workshop on

More information

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel) All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel) First Name: Waterloo, April 2013. Last Name: UW ID #:

More information

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017 VALUATION OF EQUITY WARRANTS FOR UNCERTAIN FINANCIAL MARKET FOAD SHOKROLLAHI arxiv:17118356v2 [q-finpr] 23 Nov 217 Department of Mathematics and Statistics, University of Vaasa, PO Box 7, FIN-6511 Vaasa,

More information

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications Albert Cohen Actuarial Science Program Department of Mathematics Department of Statistics and Probability albert@math.msu.edu August 29, 2018 Outline

More information

Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property

Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property Replication under Price Impact and Martingale Representation Property Dmitry Kramkov joint work with Sergio Pulido (Évry, Paris) Carnegie Mellon University Workshop on Equilibrium Theory, Carnegie Mellon,

More information

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View An Introduction to Point Processes from a Martingale Point of View Tomas Björk KTH, 211 Preliminary, incomplete, and probably with lots of typos 2 Contents I The Mathematics of Counting Processes 5 1 Counting

More information

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH 2010 Tomas Björk Tomas Björk, 2010 Contents 1. Mathematics recap. (Ch 10-12) 2. Recap of the martingale approach. (Ch 10-12) 3. Change of numeraire. (Ch 26) Björk,T. Arbitrage

More information

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics Chapter 12 American Put Option Recall that the American option has strike K and maturity T and gives the holder the right to exercise at any time in [0, T ]. The American option is not straightforward

More information

A Simple Method for Solving Multiperiod Mean-Variance Asset-Liability Management Problem

A Simple Method for Solving Multiperiod Mean-Variance Asset-Liability Management Problem Available online at wwwsciencedirectcom Procedia Engineering 3 () 387 39 Power Electronics and Engineering Application A Simple Method for Solving Multiperiod Mean-Variance Asset-Liability Management Problem

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation 3.1 Itô Integral 3.1.1 Convergence in the Mean and Stieltjes Integral Definition 3.1 (Convergence in the Mean) A sequence {X n } n ln of random

More information

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach Zorana Grbac Department of Math. Stochastics, University of Freiburg Joint work with Ernst Eberlein Croatian Quants Day University of Zagreb, 9th

More information

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Harold L. Cole and Narayana Kocherlakota Working Paper 604 September 2000 Cole: U.C.L.A. and Federal Reserve

More information

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel) AFFI, Lyon, May 2013. Carole Bernard All Investors are

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.7J Fall 213 Lecture 19 11/2/213 Applications of Ito calculus to finance Content. 1. Trading strategies 2. Black-Scholes option pricing formula 1 Security

More information

Optimal rebalancing of portfolios with transaction costs assuming constant risk aversion

Optimal rebalancing of portfolios with transaction costs assuming constant risk aversion Optimal rebalancing of portfolios with transaction costs assuming constant risk aversion Lars Holden PhD, Managing director t: +47 22852672 Norwegian Computing Center, P. O. Box 114 Blindern, NO 0314 Oslo,

More information

Forward Dynamic Utility

Forward Dynamic Utility Forward Dynamic Utility El Karoui Nicole & M RAD Mohamed UnivParis VI / École Polytechnique,CMAP elkaroui@cmapx.polytechnique.fr with the financial support of the "Fondation du Risque" and the Fédération

More information

Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers

Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers Risk Measures and Optimal Risk Transfers Université de Lyon 1, ISFA April 23 2014 Tlemcen - CIMPA Research School Motivations Study of optimal risk transfer structures, Natural question in Reinsurance.

More information

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling Prof. S. Jaimungal, Department of Statistics, University of Toronto 2004 Arrow-Debreu Securities 2004 Prof. S. Jaimungal 2 Consider a simple one-period economy

More information

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED SIMON ELLERSGAARD NIELSEN Abstract. We consider the nitty gritty of the martingale approach to option pricing. These notes are largely based upon Björk s Arbitrage Theory

More information

Online Supplement: Price Commitments with Strategic Consumers: Why it can be Optimal to Discount More Frequently...Than Optimal

Online Supplement: Price Commitments with Strategic Consumers: Why it can be Optimal to Discount More Frequently...Than Optimal Online Supplement: Price Commitments with Strategic Consumers: Why it can be Optimal to Discount More Frequently...Than Optimal A Proofs Proof of Lemma 1. Under the no commitment policy, the indifferent

More information

An Explicit Example of a Shadow Price Process with Stochastic Investment Opportunity Set

An Explicit Example of a Shadow Price Process with Stochastic Investment Opportunity Set An Explicit Example of a Shadow Price Process with Stochastic Investment Opportunity Set Christoph Czichowsky Faculty of Mathematics University of Vienna SIAM FM 12 New Developments in Optimal Portfolio

More information

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University November 2007 Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin 1 Performance measurement of investment strategies 2 Market

More information

X i = 124 MARTINGALES

X i = 124 MARTINGALES 124 MARTINGALES 5.4. Optimal Sampling Theorem (OST). First I stated it a little vaguely: Theorem 5.12. Suppose that (1) T is a stopping time (2) M n is a martingale wrt the filtration F n (3) certain other

More information

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Model-independent bounds for Asian options Model-independent bounds for Asian options A dynamic programming approach Alexander M. G. Cox 1 Sigrid Källblad 2 1 University of Bath 2 CMAP, École Polytechnique 7th General AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference

More information

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options Chapter 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options A derivative is a financial instrument whose value depends on the values of other, more basic underlying variables

More information

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford. Tangent Lévy Models Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford June 24, 2010 6th World Congress of the Bachelier Finance Society Sergey

More information