Bank Bailouts and Market Discipline: How Bailout Expectations Changed During the Financial Crisis

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Bank Bailouts and Market Discipline: How Bailout Expectations Changed During the Financial Crisis"

Transcription

1 Bank Bailouts and Market Discipline: How Bailout Expectations Changed During the Financial Crisis Florian Hett Alexander Schmidt August 2013 Abstract We show that market discipline, defined as the extent to which firm specific risk characteristics are reflected in market prices, eroded during the recent financial crisis in We design a novel test of changes in market discipline based on the relation between firm specific risk characteristics and debt-to-equity hedge ratios. We find that market discipline already weakened after the rescue of Bear Stearns before disappearing almost entirely after the failure of Lehman Brothers. The effect is stronger for investment banks and large financial institutions, while there is no comparable effect for non-financial firms. Keywords: Bailout, Implicit Guarantees, Too-Big-To-Fail, Market Discipline JEL: G14, G21, G28, H81 University of Mainz and GSEFM, florian.hett@uni-mainz.de. Goethe University Frankfurt and GSEFM, alexander.schmidt@hof.uni-frankfurt.de. A previous version of this paper circulated under the title Do Bank Bailouts Hurt Market Discipline? Evidence from the Financial Crisis. We thank Lammertjan Dam, Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln, Charles Goodhart, Martin Hellwig, Holger Kraft, Christian Schlag, Isabel Schnabel, Hans-Werner Sinn, Christoph Trebesch, Grigory Vilkov and the participants of the Spring Meeting of Young Economists, the Annual Meeting of the German Economic Association (VfS), the Annual Meeting of the European Economic Association (EEA), the Annual Meeting of the German Finance Association (DGF) and the second workshop of the DFG priority programme We are further grateful for valuable comments in the Brown Bag seminars in Mainz, Frankfurt and Mannheim, the economics workshops at the Universities of Halle, Mainz and Tuebingen, and the seminars at the CESifo in Munich and the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods in Bonn. We gratefully acknowledge financial support by the DFG Priority Program 1578 Financial Market Imperfections and Macroeconomic Performance (Hett), and by the Deutsche Boerse AG and the Center of Excellence Sustainable Architecture for Finance in Europe (SAFE) (Schmidt). 1

2 1 Introduction Public interventions in the financial sector during the recent financial crisis have been discussed controversially. A major concern has been the fear of a decline in market discipline: market participants may react to interventions by adjusting their expectations about the likelihood of future bailouts of distressed financial institutions. This would weaken market participants incentives to monitor and control banks risk-taking, which in turn increases the probability of future crises. Hence, whether a troubled bank should be supported also depends on the question how strongly market participants adjust their expectations after public interventions. In this paper, we test how major events during the crisis affected market discipline for large US financial institutions. In particular, we analyze the effect of the bailout of Bear Stearns in March 2008 and the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers and subsequent events in October We define market discipline as a situation in which changes of security prices reflect the riskiness of the underlying firm. Market participants ultimately care about actual cash flows resulting from their claims. Thus, the extent to which they incorporate individual bank risk into market prices depends on how strongly bank risk affects these cash flows. However, government interventions typically change the relation between individual bank risk and investors claims, for example by guaranteeing debt in order to prevent bankruptcy. Thus, if rational investors perceive the probability of future support by the government to increase, this should lead to a reduction of the sensitivity of market prices to bank risk. In order to measure changes in the degree of market discipline, we develop a novel model-free test that exploits the asymmetric treatment of debt and equity holders during public bailouts. The fundamental idea of our test approach is that bailouts change the structural link between CDS and equity returns and affect the sensitivity of the debt-to-equity hedge ratio to firm specific risk characteristics. We find that market discipline eroded during 2008, which can be linked to the events surrounding the failure of Lehman Brothers as well as the rescue of Bear Stearns. The failures of these investment banks provide two particularly interesting events in order to analyze the relation between government interventions and market discipline. During the bailout of Bear Stearns in March 2008, the Federal Reserve supported J.P. Morgan in acquiring Bear Stearns by guaranteeing creditors claims worth of $30 billion. Although 2

3 the notion of Too-big-to-fail (TBTF) was widely recognized prior to March , Bear Stearns was the first case where the TBTF doctrine was applied to a large investment bank. 2 Thus, it seems reasonable to assume that market participants perceived this as an increase in the likelihood of future support measures in case of bank distress. Accordingly, we would expect market discipline to decline in the period after March Furthermore, we analyze the failure of Lehman Brothers in September 2008, including actions taken during the subsequent financial turmoil, e. g. the bailout of AIG and the introduction of TARP and other worldwide financial sector rescue packages. For this series of events, it is not clear a priori what the overall effect on market discipline might be. One might interpret the failure of a large investment bank like Lehman Brothers as the inverse event to the rescue of Bear Stearns. Accordingly, one could expect an increase in market discipline, reflecting declining expectations of future bailouts. However, the magnitude of the financial turmoil following the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy has been unexpected by market participants as well as policy makers. One can thus interpret the Lehman default as revealing the actual costs of letting systemically important institutions fail. As these costs turned out to be substantially higher than expected, this might have convinced the market that policy makers will not allow comparable events to ever take place again. As a result, the perceived likelihood of future support measures might have increased even further. Actions taken in the aftermath of the Lehman failure support this interpretation: The bailout of AIG as well as the introduction of TARP oppose the view, that governmental support for financial institutions would be less likely in the future. Given the opposing nature of these events, it remains an empirical question whether the net effect on market discipline has been positive or negative. Our analysis shows that the rescue of Bear Stearns was followed by a reduction in market discipline: The sensitivity of the hedge ratio 3 to bank specific risk characteristics weakens after March 2008 for investment banks and large financial institutions. With respect to the Lehman failure and subsequent events, we find that the pre-crisis level of market discipline has not been re-established. In fact, compared to the period after the rescue of Bear Stearns, 1 O Hara and Shaw (1990) provide early evidence, that market participants care about TBTF. Stern and Feldman (2004) stress the fundamental role TBTF plays for financial regulation. 2 In 1998, the hedge fund Long Term Capital Management was bailed out. However, in that case the FED only acted as a coordinator among other banks and did not put up public money. 3 The hedge ratio is defined as the ratio of the first derivatives of debt and equity with respect to the firm value. See section 2 for details. 3

4 market discipline declined even further, rendering debt-to-equity hedge ratios insensitive to all risk characteristics. Analyzing the heterogeneity of the effects, we find that the decline in market discipline is more pronounced for the largest banks and for investment banks. Furthermore, we conduct the same kind of analysis for a broad set of non-financial firms. In contrast to financial institutions, we find that debt-to-equity hedge ratios remain sensitive to underlying risk characteristics throughout the whole sample for non-financial companies. This rules out the possibility that our results for the financial sector just capture a general change in the market environment. Overall, our results indicate that letting Lehman Brothers fail was not sufficient to convince market participants that the probability of future bailouts had decreased. Apparently, the subsequent turmoil including the respective actions taken by policy makers 4 strengthened the belief in future support to the financial sector. In summary, our results cast a damning light on the behavior of policy makers during the crisis. A main motivation for letting Lehman Brothers fail was to re-establish market discipline. 5 Our results suggests that policy measures taken have not been successful in reaching this goal. In general, our paper adds to the empirical literature analyzing market discipline. From a theoretical point of view, market discipline as a regulatory tool has been advocated by, amongst others, Calomiris and Kahn (1991) and Calomiris (1999). Flannery (2001), Bliss and Flannery (2001) as well as Hellwig (2005) discuss the ambiguous use of the term in the literature and provide a structured view on what should and what should not be called market discipline. As Bliss and Flannery (2001) point out, market discipline consists of two distinct components: First, monitoring refers to market prices reflecting the condition of a bank, most importantly its probability of default. However, the mere fact that information about bank behavior can be extracted from market prices does not yet imply a disciplining function of the market. Second, influence describes how this market information translates into incentives for bank managers to adhere to a proper risk behavior. By analyzing how the riskiness of banks is reflected in its different securities, our paper relates to the first category in this classification. Avery et al. (1988) and Gorton and Santomero (1990) are early studies analyzing the mon- 4 See Panetta et al. (2009) for an overview of the measures. 5 Sorkin (2011) describes discussions and lines of reasoning during this period, indicating that this has indeed been the main motivation, especially put forward by several senate members in the US. 4

5 itoring function of market discipline. They reject the notion that yield spreads reflect individual bank risk. In a more recent study, Krishnan et al. (2005) confirm this result by analyzing spreads adjusted to liquidity and market characteristics. By contrast, Flannery and Sorescu (1996), Hannan and Hanweck (1988), Hancock and Kwast (2001), Jagtiani et al. (2002), Morgan and Stiroh (2001), Sironi (2003) and Gropp et al. (2006) find significant relations between debt spreads and bank risks. 6 In the literature on sovereign risk, the paper by Dell Ariccia et al. (2006) shows how changes in bailout expectations affect the pricing of risk. All the aforementioned papers deal with the reaction of market prices to individual risk, i. e. testing the functioning of monitoring. Another strand of the literature looks at the interaction of implicit or explicit guarantees and banks risk-taking, thereby testing the influence channel of market discipline. These papers argue that such guarantees weaken market discipline, which in turn leads to excessive risk taking by banks. Papers in this area are Keeley (1990), Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache (2002), Gropp and Vesala (2004), Gropp et al. (2011), and Dam and Koetter (2012). Overall, the literature confirms the link between banks risk-taking and the strength of explicit or implicit guarantees. A paper similar in spirit to ours is that by Schweikhard and Tsesmelidakis (2012). They compare equity-implied CDS spreads to actual market prices and ascribe the wedge between the two to bailout expectations. In line with our results, they find that during and after the crisis this wedge increased, reflecting an increase in perceived bailout probabilities. However, in order to derive their results they have to rely on a correct calibration of a specific firm value model. By contrast, our approach is independent of any specific modeling assumption and mainly draws upon the general insight that the hedge ratio can be approximated by a function of risk characteristics (see for instance Campello et al. (2008), even though their ultimate research aim is different). Considering the aim of the test to compare pricing relations during crisis times, this robustness of our methodology to changes in underlying structural parameters is particularly beneficial. 6 Flannery (1998) provides an extensive survey on the early evidence in this literature strand. 5

6 2 Theory Market discipline requires market prices to mirror individual company risk: In a regime of perfect market discipline investors demand a fairly-priced risk premium in order to provide funds. If market prices of debt and equity reflect refinancing costs of banks, the sensitivity of market prices to individual bank risk incentivizes banks to adhere to proper risk behavior. In this paper we restrict the analysis to the monitoring function, i. e. we test to what extent market prices actually reflect individual bank risk. Thus, our first step is to derive a relation between market prices and individual bank risk that holds in the presence of market discipline, i. e. defines a regime of market discipline. In a second step, we show that this relation weakens if market participants perceive a higher probability of bank bailouts in the future. When constructing a test for changes in market discipline, it is crucial to impose as few assumptions about structural relations between market prices as possible. As we aim to analyze a period of high financial distress, we want to base the analysis only on relations that are unlikely to change fundamentally even in times of crises. Thus, in order to derive a relation between market prices and individual bank risk, we start from only two general assumptions. First, we make use of a fundamental insight from a parsimonious firm value model. In particular, we rely on the fact that the CDS to equity semi-elasticity is fundamentally driven by the unobservable ratio of the first derivatives of debt and equity with respect to the firm value, also known as the debt-to-equity hedge ratio (HR). While the true functional form of the hedge ratio is unknown and highly model-dependent, it is straightforward to show that the hedge ratio unambiguously increases in absolute value for declining firm values and increases in a firm s risk. Second, we draw upon the fact that public bailouts favor debt over equity holders. Introducing a discrete bailout probability P B for bondholders only, we show that the new hedge ratio HR in the presence of possible bailouts is equal to the product of the old hedge ratio HR and the non-bailout probability (1 P B). Given these two insights, we estimate the hedge ratio as a function of company specific risk characteristics in a control period before the crisis and evaluate how this relation changes during the crisis as a consequence of government actions. As outlined above, we draw upon the fundamental insights of the structural firm value approach, which was pioneered by Merton (1974). It states that the prices of equity E t and debt D t can be interpreted as derivatives on the fundamental firm value V t and thus can be 6

7 valued using option pricing theory, i. e. V t = E t + D t (1) E t = f(v t ) (2) D t = g(v t ) (3) In particular, equity can be seen as a call option on the firm value with a strike price equal to the face value of debt. Accordingly, debt is equivalent to a risk-free investment plus a short put option on the firm value. Furthermore, the credit spread CS t for the risky bond can be written as CS t = 1 T log(d t B t ) = 1 T log(d t) r f (4) with r f being the yield of a risk-free zero coupon bond B t, where both D t and B t refer to a risky and risk-free bond with the same notional and the same time to maturity T. Following the firm value approach, changes in the value of equity and debt (and hence the credit spread) are both driven by the same changes in the underlying firm value and should therefore be structurally linked. In particular, after some re-arranging the semi-elasticity of credit spread changes to equity returns β CS,E can be written as β CS,E = CS E E = 1 T = CS D D V V E E = 1 D V E T D E V E D V = 1 D E V T ( 1 1) HR (5) L with the market leverage L being defined as the ratio of the debt to firm value, i. e. L = D/V. The semi-elasticity itself depends on the time to maturity, leverage as well as the ratio of two non-observable inputs, i. e. the derivatives of debt and equity with respect to the firm value. As the time to maturity and leverage can be proxied by market data reasonably well, our focus is on the theoretical behaviour of this hedge ratio. In particular, we derive how the hedge ratio changes if the firm value and the fundamental risk of a company changes. For that, we need to take a look at the first derivative of the hedge ratio with respect to the firm value: 7

8 HR V = DV E V V = D V V E V D V E V V E 2 V = D V V (1 D V ) + D V D V V E 2 V = D V V E 2 V < 0 (6) as D V V < 0. Equation (6) shows that the hedge ratio unambiguously declines in the firm value. Note that this insight is most general and in particular does not rely on any particular modelling assumption such as the form of the firm value process (e. g. diffusion and/or jump process) or the default trigger (default only at maturity or exogenous or endogenous default barrier). Still, the question remains how to measure the unobservable hedge ratio. Schaefer and Strebulaev (2008) estimate the hedge ratio based on a simple Merton model and show that their estimated hedge ratio can successfully explain the comovement between stock and bond prices for non-financial firms. When applied to financial companies however, there are several drawbacks of calculating the hedge ratio directly from any particular firm value model. First of all, banks are highly leveraged firms with low implied asset volatilities. A simple Merton model as well as most of its diffusion-only extensions (e. g. Black and Cox, 1976) cannot be reasonably calibrated to capture this. Most of the time, traditional firm value models imply a flat zero default probability and hence a zero credit spread even for longer time horizons. Modelling positive credit spread levels requires additional uncertainty about the distance to default, for instance by introducing jumps (Zhou, 2001) or a nonobservable default barrier (Finger et al., 2002), but even then it appears to be difficult to calibrate those models for reasonable parameter values. Even by introducing additional uncertainty, those extensions still inherit a feature of classical firm value models that misses out on the special characteristics of financial institutions. In classical firm value models, a company only defaults if its asset value drops below a certain critical threshold. This in turn implies that the entire risk of a company is measurable via its distance to default. 7 While this might be a reasonable assumption for non-financial firms, it entirely ignores the funding risks of banks. As outlined in the theoretical literature on bank runs started by 7 The distance to default is usually interpreted as the number of asset value standard deviations the firm value exceeds the critical default barrier. 8

9 Diamond and Dybvig (1983) and as witnessed in the recent financial crisis, an omnipresent risk for financial firms with illiquid assets is the inability to fund those assets, even when the overall financial status is relatively solid. That is, banks are severely prone to default due to liquidity and funding problems, a feature which lies outside the theoretical firm value approach. While asset values and funding problems are often interrelated, they represent two distinct risks and should therefore be treated separately. As a consequence, we refrain from using theoretical model-dependent hedge ratios as these models do not feature some of the main sources of risk for financial companies. Instead we base our analysis on a more fundamental insight from general option pricing theory. As the hedge ratio is the ratio of the first derivatives of two options on the firm value with the same strike price, it depends on the moneyness of the underlying options and hence on the riskiness of the firm itself. Intuitively, when the firm is very healthy, the risk of bankruptcy is very low and changes in the firm value mainly affect the residual claim, i. e. the stock price. The hedge ratio thus becomes very small for low risk companies. If, however, the firm value is very low and the company is very likely to default, small changes in firm value strongly affect the value of bonds but to a lesser extent the value of equity, i. e. D V (E V ) strongly increases (decreases) relative to the low risk case. Hence, the hedge ratio increases when the firm value declines. A similar intuition applies to other characteristics, for instance asset volatility, which affect a firm s risk profile. As a consequence, the hedge ratio generally increases in a company s risk exposure. We assume a simple linear relation between the hedge ratio and the company risk characteristics X, i. e. k HR i,t = α 0 + α j X j i,t, (7) which is very similar to the approach taken by Campello et al. (2008) who estimate the debtto-equity sensitivity as a function of leverage, stock volatility and interest rates. 8 Combining equations (5) and (7) yields the following relation between CDS changes and equity returns: j=1 CDS i,t = (α 0 + k j=1 α j X j i,t ) ( 1 T )( 1 L t 1) E i,t E i,t (8) 8 See Appendix C for a further discussion of the restrictiveness of the linearity assumption. 9

10 Equation (8) thus represents a fundamental relation between market prices and individual bank risk that defines the regime of market discipline. From Equation (7) we see that the hedge ratio is increasing in individual bank risk as long as α j > 0 j. We now derive how the relation between the hedge ratio and individual bank risks changes when there is a non-zero bailout probability P B for bondholders only. The assumption that only bondholders but not stockholders will be bailed out is motivated by the fact that bailing-out financial institutions aims at avoiding a market-wide collapse of the financial system. To achieve this, it is necessary to prevent a bank from bankruptcy, which can be achieved via guaranteeing or actually repaying debt obligations, but does not require to compensate equity holders in addition. 9 Hence we adjust the general firm value model by including the possibility of a public bailout in the following way. The new firm value V is the sum of the fundamental firm value V and the expected value of the government payment which recovers the defaulted debt to treasury 10 with a probability P B, i. e. V t = V t + P B GovGuarantee t = D t + E t (9) GovGuarantee t = E Q (e r f (τ t) (B τ V τ ) + 1(τ T )) (10) τ is thereby the timing of the first default after t and P B is assumed to be independent of the fundamental firm value. Because the bailout payment is only made when the company is already in default and the full firm value is transferred to the debt holders, the equity holders remain unaffected by the potential bailout. E t = E t (11) D t = (1 P B)D t + P B B t > D t (12) 9 For example over the weekend of the Bear Stearns rescue, the 5 year CDS rate on Bear Stearns improved by over 350 bps but the stock price plummeted by 90% as a direct response to the bailout. The Economist (2008) notes that the real value of the bank probably actually substantially exceeded the acquisition price shareholders received. This would imply that shareholders did not only not benefit from the bailout but even suffered from it. 10 The assumption of recovery to treasury is made for analytical convenience but can be easily adjusted without changing the underlying rationale. 10

11 This in turn implies for the partial derivatives with respect to the firm value E V = E V, D V = (1 P B)D V (13) such that in the presence of an exogenous bailout probability the new hedge ratio HR adjusts to HR = (1 P B) D V E V < HR. (14) Of course, one can argue that the effects of public interventions went beyond the securing of individual companies bond repayments. In particular, actual government bailouts involved equity injections and had a stabilizing effect on the market as a whole. In addition, equity holders should also benefit from improved refinancing conditions due to increased bailout expectations. The important point to note is that all these effects do not affect the fundamental relation between hedge ratios and risk characteristics. In our framework, such indirect effects of public interventions already enter via a change of the fundamental firm value. Equations (14) and (7) now imply that HR X j = (1 P B) α j < HR X j, (15) and therefore HR X j P B = α j < 0, (16) i. e. that the sensitivity of the hedge ratio to individual risk is declining in the bailout probability. This relation is the fundamental link between bailout expectations and market discipline that we will base our analysis on. Equation (16) states that a higher perceived bailout probability weakens the marginal effect of risk on the hedge ratio. Put differently, changes in bailout expectations affect the link between individual bank risks and market prices. This link is an important prerequisite for market discipline to work: Only if market prices correctly reflect changes in banks individual risks, banks have an incentive to manage their risks accordingly. Equation (16) thus builds the theoretical framework how to analyze perceived bailout expectations and the implied decline in market discipline: One can test for changes 11

12 in bailout expectations by testing for structural declines in the relation between bank risks and hedge ratios. Following those theoretical considerations, the empirical implementation of this test is straightforward. To capture the relation between the hedge ratio and individual risks we employ the following baseline estimation equation: CDS i,t = c + (α 0 + α j X j i,t ) ( 1 T )( 1 L t 1) r E,i,t + ɛ i,t = c + β 1 r AE,i,t + β 2 X j i,t r AE,i,t + ɛ i,t (17) where r E,i,t is the percentage equity return of company i and the adjusted equity return r AE,i,t being defined as: r AE,i,t = 1 T ( 1 L t 1) r E,i,t (18) Equation (17) explicitly allows for the hedge ratio to depend on the current level of company risks. Equation (16) now states a higher perceived bailout probability implies a lower HR sensitivity to fundamental company risks. This implies that testing for changes in perceived bailout probabilities corresponds to testing for changes in β 2. Accordingly, we interact Equation (17) with dummy variables reflecting the different time periods of interest. Finally, we compare coefficients over time where significant differences can be contributed to changes in market discipline. 3 Hypotheses As the previous section has shown, our empirical strategy provides a rigorous test of changes in market discipline: Changes in the perceived probability of bailouts are reflected in changes in the sensitivity of the hedge ratio to individual bank risk. This sensitivity is captured by β 2 in the regression equation (17). To assess the change of the degree of market discipline, we first estimate equation (17) in a control period, prior to any events of interest. First, this 12

13 serves as a check of the reliability of our approach: Assuming that there has been at least some degree of market discipline prior to the rescue of Bear Stearns, we should observe a significant influence of individual bank risks on the hedge ratio. Second, those estimates can be interpreted as a benchmark level of market discipline, which then serves as a comparison for the strength of the relation after our events of interest. Hypothesis 1: In the period after the rescue of Bear Stearns, β 2 is significantly lower in absolute terms than in the control period. The first event of interest is the bailout of Bear Stearns in March The Federal Reserve supported J.P. Morgan in acquiring Bear Stearns by guaranteeing creditors claims worth of $30 billion. Of course, already prior to this event banks had been supported by the government, giving rise to the notion of Too-Big-To-Fail. Nevertheless, the event can be assumed to have a high informational value, as it was the first time that an investment bank was explicitly supported by the government. As a result, market participants should subsequently have adjusted their expectations about the likelihood of future bailouts upwards, resulting in a lower degree of market discipline. The second event we analyze is actually a series of incidences starting with the failure of Lehman Brothers in September 2008 and additionally includes the bailout of AIG and the introduction of TARP as well as other worldwide financial sector rescue packages. Given the short time spans between these events, it is not possible to robustly distinguish their isolated effects on market discipline and we rather test their joint effect. Given this multiplicity of events as well as the fact that for some of them the effects on market discipline are not a priori clear, there are different possible results to expect: Hypothesis 2a: In the period after the failure of Lehman Brothers, β 2 is significantly larger in absolute value compared to the period between Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. First, one might expect that the failure of Lehman Brothers led to a re-establishment of market discipline. Contrary to the Bear Stearns bailout, Lehman Brothers was not supported. Accordingly, these two events should have opposing effects on future bailout expectations and market discipline. Hypothesis 2b: In the period after the failure of Lehman Brothers, β 2 is signifi- 13

14 cantly lower or equal in absolute value compared to the control period. However, the failure of Lehman Brothers was not an isolated incident but rather the starting point of a series of events, most importantly the bailout of AIG and the introduction of TARP. Both events oppose the view that governmental support for financial institutions had become less likely in the future. In addition, the magnitude of the financial turmoil following the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy might have convinced the market that policy makers would not allow comparable events to take place ever again. This might have increased the perceived likelihood of future support measures even further. Overall, this could have led to a further decline in market discipline, overshadowing the potential signal sent out by the non-intervention in the Lehman filing. As a result, market discipline might be even lower than prior to Bear Stearns or at least not back to its level in the control period. Hypothesis 3: The effects on market discipline are particularly pronounced for large financial institutions. It is unlikely that the effects on market discipline were homogeneous across all financial institutions. As already noted above, the rationale to prevent banks from failure is to avoid a complete breakdown of the financial system. However, the systemic risk of any particular bank should depend on its characteristics. Thus, a common belief is that the failure of larger banks represents a bigger threat to the stability of the economy than the collapse of a small bank, a notion typically captured by the expression Too-Big-To-Fail. 11 As a result, the changes in the degree of market discipline should depend on its size: For large banks there should be a stronger effect than for small banks. Hypothesis 4: The effects on market discipline are particularly pronounced for investment banks. A further important characteristic is an institution s business model. As investment banks have been at the focus of the crisis, the effects should be stronger for investment banks than for other institutions. As a result, we should observe a particular strong effect for the remaining investment banks. In particular, this should hold true for the time period immediately after Bear Stearns rescue, as this was the first time that an investment bank 11 Admittedly, size is typically not regarded as the only determinant of systemic importance of financial institutions (see for instance Acharya et al., 2010; Adrian and Brunnermeier, 2011; Barth and Schnabel, 2013). However, it seems uncontroversial to assume that a larger bank is ceteris paribus more systemic important than a smaller bank. 14

15 received public support. Hypothesis 5: The effects on market discipline for non-financial firms are less pronounced. Given that the majority of governmental interventions in the period of interest concerns financial institutions, we expect that non-financial firms are less affected with respect to changes in market discipline. Thus, if the sensitivity of the hedge ratio to firm specific risk weakens for non-financial firms to the same extent as for financial institutions, it might be that our test simply picks up changes in pricing structures not necessarily related to changes in bailout expectations. Hence, the analysis of the non-financial sector also serves as a robustness check and can thus be interpreted in the spirit of a placebo treatment. 4 Risk proxies and data summary 4.1 Measuring individual bank risks In order to cover the various risks for financial institutions, we employ several risk measures. Equity volatility can be identified as a key variable for asset value risk. In addition we calculate an liquidity and funding risk measure and an option-implied skewness measure to capture default risk implied in equity markets Asset value risk Classical firm value models emphasize the importance of leverage and asset volatility as the main determinants of credit risk. Gorton and Santomero (1990) use the framework proposed by Black and Cox (1976) in order to test whether implied asset volatilities of junior bank debt are related to other credit risk proxies but find no significant relation. By contrast, Flannery and Sorescu (1996) and Balasubramnian and Cyree (2011) find that junior bank debt yield spreads were sensitive to variables such as leverage and stock volatility. This was particularly true for time periods when financial companies were not perceived to be too-big-too-fail. Their results remain robust to the addition of other conventional balance sheet risk characteristics such as loan composition and performance. In our setup, we prefer 15

16 forward-looking option-implied volatilities to historical volatilities as these should employ more information about associated future risks. Thus, we proxy asset value risk by using 1y at-the-money (ATM) call option volatilities Liquidity and funding risk As financial institutions are refinancing a large portion of their debt by rolling over of shortterm debt, they are subject to potential liquidity and funding shortages. In order to control for this important risk source, we compute the average spread of Financial Commercial Paper (FCP) to Non-Financial Commercial Paper (NFCP) with a remaining time to maturity of one month. As the FCP-spread is based on a broad range of commercial paper, it should largely mirror the relative ease and difficulty of financial institutions to acquire short-term funding. Nevertheless, not all financial institutions rely on short-term funding to the same extent, so that funding risk might be very different for individual firms. In order to account for this heterogeneity, we interact the spread with the company specific ratio of short- and long-term debt, i. e. F CP funding i,t = (F CP t NF CP t ) ST D i,t LT D i,t (19) Short-term debt (STD) is thereby defined as current debt maturing within one year. It does not include deposits, as the yield spreads mainly apply to wholesale funding Option-implied skewness Recent contributions to the empirical asset pricing literature have shown that option surfaces contain information about the implied distribution of future stock returns. Various measures of idiosyncratic implied skewness have been successfully used in order to establish the link between skewness and stock returns. For instance Yan (2011) examines the steepness of the implied volatility curve for short ATM options as a proxy for the average jump size and finds that stocks with higher slopes underperform. Rehman and Vilkov (2012) use the model-free implied skewness measure from Bakshi et al. (2003) and find that stocks with a more negatively skewed return distribution perform significantly worse in the future. A similar finding was made by Xing et al. (2010), who employ the difference between OTM 16

17 and ATM option volatilities as an indicator of implied skewness. While Rehman and Vilkov (2012) find that the return differences stem from stock over- and undervaluations relative to their industry peers, Xing et al. (2010) show that the most negatively skewed stocks experience the worst earnings shocks in the next quarter. While these papers differ with respect to the presumed sources of risk, they stress the importance of option-implied information for the riskiness of a firm and the implied default probability, as any default comes along with large negative stock returns. The riskier a company and the more likely it is to default on its debt, the higher should be the implied probabilities of very large negative stock returns, especially relative to large positive returns. As our particular interest lies in the distribution of very large negative stock returns and due to its computational simplicity, we follow Xing et al. (2010) by calculating our skewness measure as the difference between the 1y implied volatilities of OTM put and ATM calls with stock deltas of 0.2 and 0.5 respectively: skewness t,i = vol OT M P ut vol AT M Call (20) The higher the skewness measure, the more likely are very large negative stock returns relative to very positive ones, which we interpret as a signal for higher implied default risk Leverage Besides asset volatility, leverage is one of the key determinants of a company s risk profile and an integral part of any reasonable firm value model. Nevertheless, in our baseline estimation (17) the inclusion of leverage as a separate risk characteristic turns out out to be problematic as leverage already enters the regression equation via the calculated adjusted stock return r AE,i,t. This leaves the information content on a possible β Leverage -coefficient highly questionable in the base case. Yet, we do not question the overall importance of leverage for company risks and hedge ratios. In the robustness analysis of Section 6, we therefore repeat our regression analysis using unadjusted equity returns r E,i,t on the righthand side of regression (17) and include leverage as an additional risk characteristic. Its inclusion in the baseline estimation is further complicated by the fact that theoretical firm value models suggest a possible non-linear leverage effect on the hedge ratio, especially when leverage is measured as L = D/(D + E). The non-linearity problem, however, is 17

18 mitigated when leverage is measured as L = D/E (see Appendix C). Given the latter leverage definition, halfing the equity value doubles the leverage proxy regardless of the size of the debt value. Thus, for the risk characteristic analysis, we prefer to define leverage as the ratio of debt to equity value. In the regression with unadjusted returns, the estimated coefficients are determined by the overall debt-to-equity sensitivity rather than the hedge ratio. While strictly speaking Section 2 only derives the theoretical link between hedge ratios and risk characteristics, the empirical results by Campello et al. (2008) suggest a similar relation for the debt-to-equity sensitivity. 4.2 Construction of the data set We rely on a data set constructed from different sources. For the period from January to September , it contains information on 31 of the largest US financial institutions. Starting from the 50 largest US financial institutions by market capitalization in 2007, we eliminate all companies for which no time series of CDS and option quotes are available. We also drop the government sponsored enterprises Fanny Mae, Freddy Mac, and Sally Mae. Daily equity prices and CDS quotes are obtained from CRSP and Thomson Datastream, equity option quotes from Optionmetrics, interest rate data from the Federal Reserve Bank and quarterly balance sheet information from Compustat. Regarding data cleansing, we ignore daily observations where market information on either the change in CDS level or the equity return for a given institution is not available. Furthermore, we omit observations where the CDS level did not change at all or by more than 100 basis points in absolute value relative to the day before. As some of the CDS time series show signs of illiquidity and lack of trading activity, these omissions take care of CDS quotes that are not updated on a daily basis. We delete all observations for credit spreads of more than 2000bps as we expect very low liquidity in CDS markets for extremely distressed companies. In addition, we ignore all observations for Bear Stearns, Merrill Lynch, Wachovia, Lehman Brothers, Washington Mutual and CIT after their announced take-overs or bankruptcies in Finally, we winsorize all included variables at the 1% level. As there is a well-known phenomenon of excess correlation in times of extreme market distress, our findings could be substantially biased during the heights of the turmoil. To avoid this, we exclude all observations from March 2008 and September 2008, i. e. those 18

19 months in which our main events took place. Thereby we also circumvent the problem of precisely defining the point in time at which new information about bailouts entered the market and thus the actual cutoff dates for our periods of interest. Numbers from the quarterly or (semi-)annual reports are used from the day of their announcements onwards. Those adjustments leave us with a total of 8,760 observations over the whole sample, with 6,064 observations falling into the control period, 548 observations in the period after Bear Stearns and 2,148 observations after September As can be seen from Table 1, average variable values differ substantially between the subperiods. 12 The average CDS spread increases from 46 bps in the control period to 218 bps and 299 bps after the Bear Stears and Lehman Brothers collapses, indicating a strong increase in the market perception of risks in the financial sector. The higher risk can also be seen from our risk proxies where implied volatilities and skewness as well as funding spreads strongly increase after Bear Stearns relative to the control period. 13 Figures 1 and 2 depict the evolution of the risk characteristics we consider in our analysis. Until the first half of 2007, they remain relatively stable. With the beginning of the crisis in second half of 2007, however, our risk proxies mirror developments in the financial markets, with implied volatility and skewness almost doubling and the funding risk measure rising from 0.04 to After equity valuations for financial companies had reached their maxima in mid-2007, declining stock prices lowered equity buffers and increased effective leverage, a trend that continued until mid After the bailout of Bear Stearns, the following short recovery is only of temporary nature as concerns regarding the health of the whole financial system drive volatility and skewness proxies further up and reach all time highs after the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers. After staying at elevated levels for the rest of the year, the subsequent declines of the risk measure do not take place prior to early or mid The minimum and maximum values are very similar across all subperiods due to the 1% winsorization of all variables. 13 Following the definition of the skewness indicator a higher positive value implies a more pronounced negatively skewed distribution. 19

20 5 Results Table 2 reports the results from the baseline specification using weekly data. Note that as the relation between CDS changes and adjusted stock returns should be negative, a more negative coefficient reflects a stronger sensitivity of the hedge ratio to risk, i. e. a stronger degree of market discipline. We see that in the control period the hedge ratio systematically varies with all included risk characteristics, as the interactions of adjusted stock returns with skewness, implied volatility, and funding risk are each negative and statistically highly significant. This finding is in line with the prediction from the theoretical firm value model. Hence, we can confidently conclude that in the control period at least some degree of market discipline was in place. Note that our methodology is not able to identify a regime of perfect market discipline. Changes in the coefficient estimates only indicate relative changes over time. However, bailout certainty and the absolute absence of market discipline would empirically correspond to a total insensitivity of the hedge ratio to individual risk characteristics. Hence, the significance of the coefficients of the individual risk characteristics reflects the existence of some market discipline, and a structural decline of this relation a weakening in market discipline. Regarding Hypothesis 1, namely the effect of the bailout of Bear Stearns on market discipline, we see that the sensitivity of the hedge ratio to skewness as well as to funding risk decreases. However, as these changes are not statistically significant we cannot conclude that market discipline decreased significantly after the rescue of Bear Stearns - at least not for the total sample of financial institutions included in our data set. Regarding the two opposing hypotheses about the post Lehman effects, our results are strongly in favor of Hypothesis 2b, i. e. that market discipline declined after the autumn of First, the point estimates of the interactions are quantitatively smaller in absolute values than in both subperiods prior to the Lehman collapse. Second, looking at the coefficients of the individual risk factors, we see that they are only marginally significant or not at all. In turn, this result implies that we cannot reject the hypothesis of the complete absence of market discipline anymore. Formal equality tests for the risk sensitivity coefficient reject the null hypothesis in all post-lehman test setups (see bottom of Table 3). This confirms the finding that market discipline decreased significantly after September

21 We now turn to Hypotheses 3 and 4 that take a closer look at the heterogeneity of the effects on market discipline. First, Table 3 reports the results for the subsample of financial institutions whose asset value is above the sample median, i. e. that can be regarded as relatively large. 14 Again, we find that the sensitivity of the hedge ratio to individual risk characteristics is statistically significant in the control period, confirming the existence of market discipline. Yet, in contrast to the earlier results based on the full sample, we now observe a stronger drop of market discipline with respect to skewness and implied volatility already after March Here, the influence of skewness and implied volatility on the hedge ratio turns statistically insignificant after the rescue of Bear Stearns. However, the changes in these sensitivities are still not statistically significant across all specifications. Analyzing the period after the Lehman default, the results resemble those from the full sample: The hedge ratio is entirely insensitive to individual bank risk characteristics and the difference to the control period is statistically highly significant. Overall, those results provide some support for Hypothesis 3: The effect on market discipline is particularly strong for large banks, as we see a decline in market discipline already as a reaction to the Bear Stearns rescue. After the Lehman bankruptcy, market discipline has disappeared entirely, as was the case in the total sample. Table 4 reports the estimation results for the subsample of investment banks. The findings allow us to analyze Hypothesis 4, i. e. whether the effect on market discipline was particularly pronounced for those institutions. 15 Again, as in all previous specifications, in the control period the hedge ratio depends on the banks individual risk characteristics. This relation between hedge ratios and risks entirely collapses after March 2008 for skewness and implied volatility, as those variables turn statistically insignificant. The differences in sensitivities between the periods are also highly significant. While this indicates a strong drop in market discipline after Bear Stearns already, the sensitivity of the hedge ratio to funding risk only drops significantly after the Lehman default. Overall, those results are in line with Hypothesis 4, suggesting that the decline in market discipline was particularly severe for investment banks in the sense that it took place already after Bear Stearns. With respect to Hypothesis 5, Table 7 reports the estimation results for the sample of non-financial firms. As short-term funding risks are specific to financial institutions, we 14 See Appendix D for the list of institutions classified as large. 15 See Appendix D for the list of institutions classified as investment banks. 21

22 focus on the volatility and skewness effects for the non-financial firms. Even though the coefficient estimates decline to some extent over time, we find them to be negative and strongly significant in every subperiod. As a result, we can confidently conclude that there are no comparable effects for non-financial firms to those reported for financial institutions. This finding further confirms the interpretation of our main results. With no similar effects for non-financial companies, the change in the hedge ratio risk sensitivity is specific to financial institutions and strengthens the argument for a decline in market discipline due to higher bailout expectations. To summarize, we find a significant relation between the hedge ratio and individual risk characteristics in the control period in all specifications. This is in line with the finding by Campello et al. (2008) and confirms the existence of market discipline prior to the rescue of Bear Stearns. Another robust finding across all specifications is the decline in market discipline after the failure of Lehman Brothers, as we observe significant drops in the coefficients of the risk characteristics. Yet, the results are heterogeneous with respect to the Bear Stearns rescue: Here, we only find significant declines in the two subsamples of large institutions and investment banks, while there are no significant differences in the baseline specification. 6 Robustness analysis In addition, we perform a series of robustness checks along various dimensions: First, previous results were all based on weekly averages of all included variables. To address the potential concern that the drop in the sensitivity of the hedge ratio to individual risk characteristics is just a result of too much noise in the data, we perform the same analysis using monthly averages. With monthly data we trade off the benefits of a higher number of observations against the benefit of a reduction of noise in the data, such that the analysis is based on more stable relations. Second, as outlined in Section we repeat our estimation procedure using unadjusted equity returns and leverage as an additional risk characteristic. The results when using monthly instead of weekly averages can be found in Table 5. Overall, the results are in line with the baseline specification of Table 2, with the only difference being that the funding risk measure is insignificant in the control period. Apart from that, the 22

23 results of Table 5 confirm the earlier findings. In particular, the coefficients of all risk proxies are still negative and significant after the Bear Stearns rescue but strongly decline after October The regression results from the unadjusted equity return data can be found in Table 6. Again, the coefficients of the risk proxies are negative in all control periods and highly significant with only one exception. For the skewness, implied volatility and funding risk proxies, the coefficients become notably smaller and turn insignificant already after the Bear Stearns rescue. Of particular interest, however, are the results from the last row columns of Table 6, as we could not include the leverage risk proxy in the baseline regression (17). In contrast to Campello et al. (2008), we find a significant influence of the leverage proxy on the debt-to-equity sensitivity, at least in the control period. In addition, we find that the leverage factor remains negative after March 2008 and the difference to the control period being insignificant. Only after the Lehman default, the leverage proxy turns insignificant as well. Finally, we repeat our analysis using the (quasi-) market value leverage instead of values in order to calculate the adjusted stock returns. As the results are qualitatively and quantitatively similar to the ones in Table 2, we refrain from reporting them separately. 7 Conclusion In this paper, we develop a novel test for changes in the degree of market discipline that stem from changes in the perceived probability of future bailouts. We apply this method to analyze the strength of market discipline during the recent financial crisis. A particular advantage of our methodology is its robustness to specific assumptions about the underlying firm value model. Instead we exploit the sensitivity of the hedge ratio to changes in firm specific risk characteristics - a relation that already follows from a parsimonious firm value model. We find that overall market discipline significantly weakened for all financial institutions after September 2008, i. e. after the events surrounding and following the failure of Lehman Brothers. This result is robust across all specifications. We find the effects to be more pronounced for the subsamples of large financial institutions and investment banks. In 23

24 particular, some of the loss in market discipline took place already after the rescue of Bear Stearns in March 2008 for those institutions. Furthermore, we find no comparable effects for non-financial firms. This adds further confidence that the declining sensitivity of the hedge ratio to individual risk characteristics for financial institutions can indeed be attributed to the change in perceived bailout probabilities. Our results cast additional doubt on the decision to let Lehman Brothers fail. Given that the hope to re-establish market discipline was an important reason for the non-intervention, the further deterioration of market discipline in the aftermath of September 2008 indicates that this goal has not been accomplished. In addition, the nature of the heterogeneity of the effect suggests that market participants in fact adjust expectations about future bailout probabilities in a sophisticated manner: After the rescue of Bear Stearns market participants altered their bailout expectations only for investment banks. This can be rationalized as Bear Stearns had been the first investment bank to be bailed out by the government. Thus, the event should have mattered more for remaining investment banks compared to other financial institutions. Only after the Lehman bankruptcy and the broad government interventions across the whole financial sector (like TARP, for example) market discipline vanishes across the entire sample. Overall, we find strong evidence that market participants rationally adjust their bailout expectations in response to government interventions. Given these findings, policymakers should take into account the potential effects on market discipline when deciding about public bailouts in future crises. References Acharya, V. V., L. H. Pedersen, T. Philippon, and M. P. Richardson (2010). Measuring systemic risk. Working Paper 10-02, FRB of Cleveland. Adrian, T. and M. Brunnermeier (2011). CoVaR. NBER Working Paper Avery, R., T. Belton, and M. Goldberg (1988). Market discipline in regulating bank risk: New evidence from the capital markets. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 20 (4),

25 Bakshi, G., N. Kapadia, and D. Madan (2003). Stock return characteristics, skew laws, and the differential pricing of individual equity options. Review of Financial Studies 16 (1), Balasubramnian, B. and K. B. Cyree (2011). Market discipline of banks: Why are yield spreads on bank-issued subordinated notes and debentures not sensitive to bank risks? Journal of Banking and Finance 35 (1), Barth, A. and I. Schnabel (2013). Why banks are not too big to fail - evidence from the CDS market. Economic Policy 28 (74), Black, F. and J. Cox (1976). Valuing corporate securities: Some effects of bond indenture provisions. Journal of Finance 31 (2), Bliss, R. and M. Flannery (2001). Market discipline in the governance of U.S. bank holding companies: Monitoring versus influencing. In Prudential Supervision: What Works and What Doesn t, NBER Chapters, pp National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. Calomiris, C. (1999). Building an incentive-compatible safety net. Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (10), Calomiris, C. and C. Kahn (1991). The role of demandable debt in structuring optimal banking arrangements. American Economic Review 81 (3), Campello, M., L. Chen, and L. Zhang (2008). Expected returns, yield spreads, and asset pricing tests. Review of Financial Studies 21 (3), Dam, L. and M. Koetter (2012). Bank bailouts and moral hazard: Evidence from Germany. Review of Financial Studies 25 (8), Dell Ariccia, G., I. Schnabel, and J. Zettelmeyer (2006). How do official bailouts affect the risk of investing in emerging markets? Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 38 (7), Demirguc-Kunt, A. and E. Detragiache (2002). Does deposit insurance increase banking system stability? an empirical investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics 49 (7),

26 Diamond, D. W. and P. H. Dybvig (1983). Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. Journal of Political Economy 91 (3), Finger, C., V. Finkelstein, J. Lardy, G. Pan, T. Ta, and J. Tierney (2002). Credit grades technical document. Risk metrics group working paper. Flannery, M. (1998). Using market information in prudential bank supervision: A review of the U.S. empirical evidenc. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 30 (3), Flannery, M. (2001). The faces of market discipline. Journal of Financial Services Research 20 (2), Flannery, M. and S. Sorescu (1996). Evidence of bank market discipline in subordinated debenture yields: Journal of Finance 51 (4), Gorton, G. and A. Santomero (1990). Market discipline and bank subordinated debt. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 22 (1), Gropp, R., H. Hakenes, and I. Schnabel (2011). Competition, risk-shifting, and public bailout policies. Review of Financial Studies 24 (6), Gropp, R. and J. Vesala (2004). Deposit insurance, moral hazard and market monitoring. Review of Finance 8 (4), Gropp, R., J. Vesala, and G. Vulpes (2006). Equity and bond market signals as leading indicators of bank fragility. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 38 (2), Hancock, D. and M. Kwast (2001). Using subordinated debt to monitor bank holding companies: Is it feasible? Journal of Financial Services Research 20 (2-3), Hannan, T. and G. Hanweck (1988). Bank insolvency risk and the market for large certificates of deposit. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 20 (2), Hellwig, M. (2005). Market discipline, information processing, and corporate governance. Working Paper Series of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods 2005/19, Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods. 26

27 Jagtiani, J., G. Kaufman, and C. Lemieux (2002). The effect of credit risk on bank and bank holding company bond yields: Evidence from the post-fdicia period. Journal of Financial Research 25 (4), Keeley, M. (1990). Deposit insurance, risk, and market power in banking. American Economic Review 80 (5), Krishnan, C., P. Ritchken, and J. Thomson (2005). Monitoring and controlling bank risk: Does risky debt help? Journal of Finance 60 (1), Merton, R. (1974). On the pricing of corporate debt: The risk structure of interest rates. Journal of Finance 29 (2), Morgan, D. and K. Stiroh (2001). Market discipline of banks: The asset test. Journal of Financial Services Research 20 (2), O Hara, M. and W. Shaw (1990). Deposit insurance and wealth effects: The value of being too big to fail. The Journal of Finance 45 (5), Panetta, F., T. Faeh, G. Grande, C. Ho, M. King, A. Levy, F. Signoretti, M. Taboga, and A. Zaghini (2009). An assessment of financial sector rescue programmes. Questioni di Economia e Finanza (Occasional Papers) 47, Bank of Italy, Economic Research and International Relations Area. Rehman, Z. and G. Vilkov (2012). sources. mimeo. Risk-neutral skewness: Return predictability and its Schaefer, S. and I. Strebulaev (2008). Structural models of credit risk are useful: Evidence from hedge ratios on corporate bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 90 (1), Schweikhard, F. and Z. Tsesmelidakis (2012). The impact of government interventions on CDS and equity markets. Available at ssrn: Sironi, A. (2003). Testing for market discipline in the european banking industry: Evidence from subordinated debt issues. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 35 (3), Sorkin, A. (2011). Too big to fail: the inside story of how Wall Street and Washington fought to save the financial system - and themselves. Viking, New York. 27

28 Stern, G. and R. Feldman (2004). Too big to fail: The hazards of bank bailouts. The Brookings Institute, Washington. The Economist (2008). The $2 bail-out. Print edition, mar 22nd. Xing, Y., X. Zhang, and R. Zhao (2010). What does the individual option volatility smirk tell us about future equity returns? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 45 (3), Yan, S. (2011). Jump risk, stock returns, and slope of implied volatility smile. Journal of Financial Economics 99 (1), Zhou, C. (2001). The term structure of credit spreads with jump risk. Journal of Banking and Finance 25 (11),

29 8 Appendix A: Tables 29

30 Variable Obs Mean Median Std. Dev. Min Max Min Win Max Win Full Sample CDS 8, CDS change 8, Stock return 8, adjusted stock return 8, Asset size (in bn) 7, Book leverage 8, Short-long-funding 8, FCP-NFCP spread 8, Fundingrisk 8, Implied volatility 8, Skewness 8, Control Period CDS 6, CDS change 6, Stock return 6, adjusted stock return 6, Asset size (in bn) 5, Book leverage 6, Short-long-funding 5, FCP-NFCP spread 6, Fundingrisk 5, Implied volatility 6, Skewness 6, After Bear Stearns, before Lehman Brothers CDS CDS change Stock return adjusted stock return Asset size (in bn) Book leverage Short-long-funding FCP-NFCP spread Fundingrisk Implied volatility Skewness After Lehman Brothers CDS 2, CDS change 2, Stock return 2, adjusted stock return 2, Asset size (in bn) 1, Book leverage 2, Short-long-funding 1, FCP-NFCP spread 2, Fundingrisk 1, Implied volatility 2, Skewness 2, Table 1: Summary statistics. Above are the summary statistics for weekly data for the total sample of financial institutions as well as for each subsample: The period prior to the rescue of Bear Stearns (control period), the period between the rescue of Bear Stearns and the failure of Lehman Brothers, and the period after the failure of Lehman Brothers. Variables used in the final regressions are winsorized at the 1% level. For winsorized variables, the columns Min Win and Max Win refer to minimum and maximum values before winsorizing. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the text. 30

31 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) CDS CDS CDS CDS CDS CDS D C r AE 259.2*** 253.7*** 696.2** 687.0** (46.11) (46.56) (293.5) (301.0) (63.52) (62.23) D BS r AE ** 919.5** (248.6) (247.1) (343.8) (340.8) (226.8) (226.0) D LEH r AE *** *** (173.6) (174.4) (163.9) (163.4) (117.6) (118.3) D C r AE Skewness -10,267*** -10,068*** (1,277) (1,307) D BS r AE Skewness -9,247*** -9,279*** (1,948) (1,943) D LEH r AE Skewness -2,174-2,176 (1,358) (1,366) D C r AE Implied V ol -3,277*** -3,237** (1,176) (1,208) D BS r AE Implied V ol -3,489*** -3,505*** (633.0) (626.7) D LEH r AE Implied V ol * * (344.0) (345.3) D C r AE F unding Risk -7,644*** -7,661*** (2,768) (2,776) D BS r AE F unding Risk -5,574** -5,574** (2,316) (2,315) D LEH r AE F unding Risk -1,265-1,268 (766.4) (765.5) Bank fixed effects yes no yes no yes no Observations 8,756 8,756 8,756 8,756 8,134 8,134 R-squared Number of banks Period 0 = Period Period 0 = Period Period 1 = Period Table 2: Regression results for full sample. Above are the results from regression (17) for the full sample of financial institutions, using weekly return data and skewness, implied volatility and funding risk as the main risk proxies. r AE is the adjusted equity return according to Equation (18) and using book leverage values. D C, D BS and D LEH are dummy variables that are one before March 2008, between March and September 2008 and after September 2008, respectively, and zero otherwise. Standard errors clustered at the bank level are given in parentheses. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. Period 0 = Period 1 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period between Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. Period 0 = Period 2 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period after Lehman Brothers. Period 1 = Period 2 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period between Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the text. 31

32 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) CDS CDS CDS CDS CDS CDS D C r AE 750.0** 744.1** 2,039** 2,030** *** *** (320.7) (323.1) (692.9) (688.3) (117.6) (117.8) D BS r AE * * (657.3) (660.3) (1,618) (1,615) (379.4) (378.8) D LEH r AE -1,174* -1,165* -2,135** -2,157** -1,797*** -1,798*** (611.0) (622.7) (919.2) (929.4) (410.9) (411.5) D C r AE Skewness -33,794*** -33,710*** (7,158) (7,220) D BS r AE Skewness -14,887-14,689 (8,575) (8,575) D LEH r AE Skewness -3,977-4,047 (3,884) (3,968) D C r AE Implied V ol -11,465*** -11,435*** (3,397) (3,378) D BS r AE Implied V ol -2,578-2,602 (3,236) (3,233) D LEH r AE Implied V ol (1,321) (1,336) D C r AE F unding Risk -6,466** -6,482** (2,489) (2,495) D BS r AE F unding Risk -4,886* -4,887* (2,310) (2,305) D LEH r AE F unding Risk (901.8) (899.7) Bank fixed effects yes no yes no yes no Observations 4,610 4,610 4,610 4,610 4,432 4,432 R-squared Number of banks Period 0 = Period Period 0 = Period Period 1 = Period Table 3: Regression results for largest financial Institutions. Above are the results from regression (17) for the largest financial institutions, using weekly return data and skewness, implied volatility and funding risk as the main risk proxies. The relevant size classification of the financial institutions can be found in Table 8 in Appendix D. r AE is the adjusted equity return according to Equation (18) and using book leverage values. D C, D BS and D LEH are dummy variables that are one before March 2008, between March and September 2008 and after September 2008, respectively, and zero otherwise. Standard errors clustered at the bank level are given in parentheses. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. Period 0 = Period 1 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period between Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. Period 0 = Period 2 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period after Lehman Brothers. Period 1 = Period 2 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period between Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the text. 32

33 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) CDS CDS CDS CDS CDS CDS D C r AE 5,254*** 5,394*** 8,660*** 8,805*** -1,768*** -1,732*** (690.0) (722.6) (864.1) (924.2) (143.2) (143.4) D BS r AE -5,293-5,421-8,585** -8,601** (4,128) (4,084) (2,168) (2,197) (1,235) (1,326) D LEH r AE -3,573*** -3,579*** -5,604*** -5,602*** -4,291*** -4,272*** (335.8) (343.7) (162.8) (168.5) (16.34) (31.57) D C r AE Skewness -147,100*** -149,407*** (10,794) (11,408) D BS r AE Skewness -8,431-7,398 (27,281) (26,984) D LEH r AE Skewness 3,686 3,744 (2,301) (2,198) D C r AE Implied V ol -40,882*** -41,354*** (3,166) (3,439) D BS r AE Implied V ol 3,877 3,897 (2,742) (2,784) D LEH r AE Implied V ol 4,334** 4,323** (1,018) (1,017) D C r AE F unding Risk -6,934** -7,050** (1,332) (1,275) D BS r AE F unding Risk -9,233*** -8,906*** (347.6) (468.9) D LEH r AE F unding Risk 2,375 2,345 (1,091) (1,117) Bank fixed effects yes no yes no yes no Observations 1,144 1,144 1,144 1,144 1,141 1,141 R-squared Number of banks Period 0 = Period Period 0 = Period Period 1 = Period Table 4: Regression results for investment banks. Above are the results from regression (17) for the largest financial institutions, using weekly return data and skewness, implied volatility and funding risk as the main risk proxies. The relevant business type classification of the financial institutions can be found in Table 8 in Appendix D. r AE is the adjusted equity return according to Equation (18) and using book leverage values. D C, D BS and D LEH are dummy variables that are one before March 2008, between March and September 2008 and after September 2008, respectively, and zero otherwise. Standard errors clustered at the bank level are given in parentheses. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. Period 0 = Period 1 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period between Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. Period 0 = Period 2 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period after Lehman Brothers. Period 1 = Period 2 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period between Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the text. 33

34 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) CDS CDS CDS CDS CDS CDS D C r AE 479.6*** 477.5*** 949.3*** 955.8*** (36.72) (31.46) (68.45) (80.00) (95.33) (87.21) D BS r AE ,259** 1,286** (370.3) (367.4) (509.2) (510.0) (308.6) (307.6) D LEH r AE *** *** (370.2) (364.3) (312.5) (306.2) (137.5) (135.8) D C r AE Skewness -16,961*** -16,526*** (809.3) (937.0) D BS r AE Skewness -11,572*** -11,835*** (2,917) (2,849) D LEH r AE Skewness -1,436-1,420 (3,171) (3,105) D C r AE Implied V ol -4,455*** -4,425*** (285.9) (342.0) D BS r AE Implied V ol -3,919*** -3,961*** (893.9) (881.8) D LEH r AE Implied V ol -1,251* -1,232* (617.3) (608.2) D C r AE F unding Risk -4,231-3,647 (3,289) (3,260) D BS r AE F unding Risk -5,612* -5,730* (3,116) (3,154) D LEH r AE F unding Risk -2,215-2,265 (1,370) (1,341) Bank fixed effects yes no yes no yes no Observations 2,088 2,088 2,088 2,088 1,966 1,966 R-squared Number of banks Period 0 = Period Period 0 = Period Period 1 = Period Table 5: Regression results for full sample and monthly returns. Above are the results from regression (17) for the full sample of financial institutions, using monthly return data and skewness, implied volatility and funding risk as the main risk proxies. r AE is the adjusted equity return according to Equation (18) and using book leverage values. D C, D BS and D LEH are dummy variables that are one before March 2008, between March and September 2008 and after September 2008, respectively, and zero otherwise. Standard errors clustered at the bank level are given in parentheses. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. Period 0 = Period 1 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period between Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. Period 0 = Period 2 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period after Lehman Brothers. Period 1 = Period 2 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period between Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the text. 34

35 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) CDS CDS CDS CDS CDS CDS CDS CDS D C r AE ** 85.21** *** *** *** *** (14.44) (15.10) (38.57) (40.99) (16.54) (16.70) (17.00) (16.63) D BS r AE *** *** * * *** *** *** *** (38.75) (39.68) (48.91) (48.70) (28.50) (28.68) (31.62) (31.84) D LEH r AE *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** (49.43) (50.22) (53.39) (53.73) (20.59) (20.62) (27.63) (27.70) D C r AE Skewness -1,734*** -1,699*** (245.1) (258.9) D BS r AE Skewness * * (304.3) (311.6) D LEH r AE Skewness (321.4) (326.1) D C r AE Implied V ol *** *** (141.7) (151.2) D BS r AE Implied V ol ** ** (75.19) (74.74) D LEH r AE Implied V ol (79.84) (80.28) D C r AE F unding Risk (83.13) (84.47) D BS r AE F unding Risk (62.34) (62.78) D LEH r AE F unding Risk (65.61) (65.48) D C r E Leverage *** *** (1.779) (1.779) D BS r E Leverage ** ** (1.554) (1.589) D LEH r E Leverage (1.516) (1.521) Bank fixed effects yes no yes no yes no yes no Observations 8,756 8,756 8,756 8,756 8,134 8,134 8,760 8,760 R-squared Number of banks Period 0 = Period Period 0 = Period Period 1 = Period Table 6: Regression results for unadjusted returns. Above are the regression results, using weekly unadjusted return data and skewness, implied volatility, funding risk and leverage as the main risk proxies. r E is the unadjusted equity return and leverage is defined as L = D/E. D C, D BS and D LEH are dummy variables that are one before March 2008, between March and September 2008 and after September 2008, respectively, and zero otherwise. Standard errors clustered at the bank level are given in parentheses. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. Period 0 = Period 1 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period between Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. Period 0 = Period 2 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period after Lehman Brothers. Period 1 = Period 2 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period between Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the text. 35

36 (1) (2) (3) (4) CDS CDS CDS CDS D C r AE 48.11*** 48.81*** 196.2*** 197.6*** (13.82) (13.91) (21.95) (21.98) D BS r AE ** ** (29.10) (29.05) (40.52) (40.46) D LEH r AE ** ** 90.45*** 91.08*** (36.62) (36.52) (29.89) (29.86) D C r AE Skewness -2,459*** -2,464*** (357.8) (362.2) D BS r AE Skewness -2,300*** -2,293*** (328.2) (325.6) D LEH r AE Skewness -1,343*** -1,328*** (356.4) (355.5) D C r AE Implied V ol *** *** (79.66) (79.93) D BS r AE Implied V ol *** *** (85.08) (85.06) D LEH r AE Implied V ol *** *** (71.30) (71.25) Firm fixed effects yes no yes no Observations 25,294 25,294 25,294 25,294 R-squared Number of firms Period 0 = Period Period 0 = Period Period 1 = Period Table 7: Regression results for non-financial firms. Above are the results from regression (17) for the full sample of non-financial institutions, using weekly return data and skewness and implied volatility as the main risk proxies. r AE is the adjusted equity return according to Equation (18) and using book leverage values. D C, D BS and D LEH are dummy variables that are one before March 2008, between March and September 2008 and after September 2008, respectively, and zero otherwise. Standard errors clustered at the firm level are given in parentheses. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. Period 0 = Period 1 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period between Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. Period 0 = Period 2 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period after Lehman Brothers. Period 1 = Period 2 refers to the p-value of a test on the equality of the coefficient of the interaction of the respective risk characteristic with adjusted equity returns in the control period and the period between Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. Detailed variable descriptions are given in the text. 36

37 9 Appendix B: Figures (Implied volatility) (Skewness) Figure 1: Time series evolution of implied volatility and skewness proxies. Above graphs depict the time series evolution of the company specific implied volatility and skewness proxies for the full sample of financial institutions. The vertical dashed lines mark the rescue of Bear Stearns and the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers. 37

38 (F unding risk) (Leverage) Figure 2: Time series evolution of funding risk and leverage proxies. Above graphs depict the time series evolution of the company specific funding risk and leverage proxies for the full sample of financial institutions. Leverage is defined as L = D/(D + E). The vertical dashed lines mark the rescue of Bear Stearns and the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers. 38

39 10 Appendix C: Discussion of the linearity of the hedge ratio in risk Assuming a linear functional form is a restriction by itself and comes at a potential cost. The cost however is limited if standard firm value models imply a close to linear relation as well. In order to visualize the effect for two main risk proxies, volatility and leverage, we use a market standard model from Finger et al. (2002) in order to derive theoretical debt-toequity sensitivities and hedge ratios for a set of realistic market parameter, as experienced during the crisis. Figures 3 and 4 depict the credit spread-to-equity semi-elasticity (beta) and the debt-to-equity hedge ratio for various values of the stock volatility and two different definitions of leverage (L = D and D+E L = D ). The figure inputs are based on the same E balance sheet data for J.P. Morgan Chase and calibrated to match the CDS level for June 2007, right before the onset of the financial crisis. 16 As can be seen in all four figures, the beta and the hedge ratio are approximately linear in the stock volatility regardless of the leverage definition. Scrutinizing the two different leverage definitions, the beta and the hedge ratio are rather non-linear in L. By contrast, the beta function is much less concave in L while the hedge ratio is almost linear in L. Thus, at least for the stock volatility and the leverage definition L = D/E the cost of the linearity assumption seems small relative to the possible gains of including non-traditional risk proxies. Those risk proxies enable us to include factors which are beyond the scope of traditional firm value models such as funding and liquidity proxies or option-implied information about future return distributions. 16 In order to ease comparability, the assumed exogenous parameters are the same as in Schweikhard and Tsesmelidakis (2012). Our CDS level calibration for June 2007 yields a mean recovery rate of L = 0.08 which is comparable in size with the estimated pre-crisis level of 0.03 estimated by Schweikhard and Tsesmelidakis (2012). 39

40 Figure 3: Illustration of theoretical credit spread semi-elasticities. Above are the theoretical credit spread semi-elasticities as functions of stock volatility and two different definitions of leverage, derived from Finger et al. (2002). On the left, leverage is defined as L = D/(D + E), while on the right leverage is defined as L = D/E. The fundamental leverage and the other firm characteristics are the same in both figures. The model is calibrated using data for J.P. Morgan Chase in June Figure 4: Illustration of theoretical hedge ratios. Above are the theoretical hedge ratios as functions of stock volatility and two different definitions of leverage, derived from Finger et al. (2002). On the left, leverage is defined as L = D/(D + E), while on the right leverage is defined as L = D/E. The fundamental leverage and the other firm characteristics are the same in both figures. The model is calibrated using data for J.P. Morgan Chase in June

Bank Rescues and Bailout Expectations: The Erosion of Market Discipline During the Financial Crisis

Bank Rescues and Bailout Expectations: The Erosion of Market Discipline During the Financial Crisis Bank Rescues and Bailout Expectations: The Erosion of Market Discipline During the Financial Crisis Florian Hett Goethe University Frankfurt Alexander Schmidt Deutsche Bundesbank & Goethe University Frankfurt

More information

The End of Market Discipline? Investor Expectations of Implicit State Guarantees

The End of Market Discipline? Investor Expectations of Implicit State Guarantees The Investor Expectations of Implicit State Guarantees Viral Acharya New York University World Bank, Virginia Tech A. Joseph Warburton Syracuse University Motivation Federal Reserve Chairman Bernanke (2013):

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Validation of Nasdaq Clearing Models

Validation of Nasdaq Clearing Models Model Validation Validation of Nasdaq Clearing Models Summary of findings swissquant Group Kuttelgasse 7 CH-8001 Zürich Classification: Public Distribution: swissquant Group, Nasdaq Clearing October 20,

More information

The Role of Industry Affiliation in the Underpricing of U.S. IPOs

The Role of Industry Affiliation in the Underpricing of U.S. IPOs The Role of Industry Affiliation in the Underpricing of U.S. IPOs Bryan Henrick ABSTRACT: Haverford College Department of Economics Spring 2012 This paper examines the significance of a firm s industry

More information

How Curb Risk In Wall Street. Luigi Zingales. University of Chicago

How Curb Risk In Wall Street. Luigi Zingales. University of Chicago How Curb Risk In Wall Street Luigi Zingales University of Chicago Banks Instability Banks are engaged in a transformation of maturity: borrow short term lend long term This transformation is socially valuable

More information

Implicit guarantees and market discipline: Has anything changed over the financial crisis?

Implicit guarantees and market discipline: Has anything changed over the financial crisis? Implicit guarantees and market discipline: Has anything changed over the financial crisis? Andreas Barth Johannes Gutenberg University Mainz und GSEFM Isabel Schnabel Johannes Gutenberg University Mainz,

More information

Capital structure and the financial crisis

Capital structure and the financial crisis Capital structure and the financial crisis Richard H. Fosberg William Paterson University Journal of Finance and Accountancy Abstract The financial crisis on the late 2000s had a major impact on the financial

More information

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender *

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender * COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY Adi Brender * 1 Key analytical issues for policy choice and design A basic question facing policy makers at the outset of a crisis

More information

THE NEW EURO AREA YIELD CURVES

THE NEW EURO AREA YIELD CURVES THE NEW EURO AREA YIELD CURVES Yield describe the relationship between the residual maturity of fi nancial instruments and their associated interest rates. This article describes the various ways of presenting

More information

Bachelor Thesis Finance

Bachelor Thesis Finance Bachelor Thesis Finance What is the influence of the FED and ECB announcements in recent years on the eurodollar exchange rate and does the state of the economy affect this influence? Lieke van der Horst

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* Sónia Costa** Luísa Farinha** 133 Abstract The analysis of the Portuguese households

More information

Government interventions - restoring or destructing financial stability in the long-run?

Government interventions - restoring or destructing financial stability in the long-run? Government interventions - restoring or destructing financial stability in the long-run? Aneta Hryckiewicz* University of Frankfurt and Kozminski University January 2, 2012 Abstract: Recent government

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin June 15, 2008 Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin Abstract The trade effect of the euro is typically

More information

US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies

US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies Nathan Foley-Fisher Bernardo Guimaraes August 2009 Abstract We empirically analyse the appropriateness of indexing emerging market sovereign

More information

HOW HAS CDO MARKET PRICING CHANGED DURING THE TURMOIL? EVIDENCE FROM CDS INDEX TRANCHES

HOW HAS CDO MARKET PRICING CHANGED DURING THE TURMOIL? EVIDENCE FROM CDS INDEX TRANCHES C HOW HAS CDO MARKET PRICING CHANGED DURING THE TURMOIL? EVIDENCE FROM CDS INDEX TRANCHES The general repricing of credit risk which started in summer 7 has highlighted signifi cant problems in the valuation

More information

Sebastian C. Moenninghoff, WHU Steven Ongena, University of Zurich, SFI, Bangor University & CEPR Axel Wieandt, WHU

Sebastian C. Moenninghoff, WHU Steven Ongena, University of Zurich, SFI, Bangor University & CEPR Axel Wieandt, WHU THE PERENNIAL CHALLENGE TO COUNTER TOO-BIG-TO-FAIL IN BANKING: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM THE NEW INTERNATIONAL REGULATION DEALING WITH GLOBAL SYSTEMICALLY IMPORTANT BANKS Forthcoming, Journal of Banking

More information

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure Corporate Financial Management Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure As we discussed in previous lectures, two extreme results, namely the irrelevance of capital structure and 100 percent

More information

Lecture 12: Too Big to Fail and the US Financial Crisis

Lecture 12: Too Big to Fail and the US Financial Crisis Lecture 12: Too Big to Fail and the US Financial Crisis October 25, 2016 Prof. Wyatt Brooks Beginning of the Crisis Why did banks want to issue more loans in the mid-2000s? How did they increase the issuance

More information

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation ECONOMIC BULLETIN 3/218 ANALYTICAL ARTICLES Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation Ángel Estrada and Francesca Viani 6 September 218 Following

More information

The Determinants of Capital Structure: Analysis of Non Financial Firms Listed in Karachi Stock Exchange in Pakistan

The Determinants of Capital Structure: Analysis of Non Financial Firms Listed in Karachi Stock Exchange in Pakistan Analysis of Non Financial Firms Listed in Karachi Stock Exchange in Pakistan Introduction The capital structure of a company is a particular combination of debt, equity and other sources of finance that

More information

DO TARGET PRICES PREDICT RATING CHANGES? Ombretta Pettinato

DO TARGET PRICES PREDICT RATING CHANGES? Ombretta Pettinato DO TARGET PRICES PREDICT RATING CHANGES? Ombretta Pettinato Abstract Both rating agencies and stock analysts valuate publicly traded companies and communicate their opinions to investors. Empirical evidence

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation Tao Wang Queens College and the Graduate Center of the City University of New York Abstract Stock return volatilities are related to firms' financial

More information

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance.

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. RESEARCH STATEMENT Heather Tookes, May 2013 OVERVIEW My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. Much of my work focuses on understanding the ways in which capital market

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

CAN AGENCY COSTS OF DEBT BE REDUCED WITHOUT EXPLICIT PROTECTIVE COVENANTS? THE CASE OF RESTRICTION ON THE SALE AND LEASE-BACK ARRANGEMENT

CAN AGENCY COSTS OF DEBT BE REDUCED WITHOUT EXPLICIT PROTECTIVE COVENANTS? THE CASE OF RESTRICTION ON THE SALE AND LEASE-BACK ARRANGEMENT CAN AGENCY COSTS OF DEBT BE REDUCED WITHOUT EXPLICIT PROTECTIVE COVENANTS? THE CASE OF RESTRICTION ON THE SALE AND LEASE-BACK ARRANGEMENT Jung, Minje University of Central Oklahoma mjung@ucok.edu Ellis,

More information

Differential Pricing Effects of Volatility on Individual Equity Options

Differential Pricing Effects of Volatility on Individual Equity Options Differential Pricing Effects of Volatility on Individual Equity Options Mobina Shafaati Abstract This study analyzes the impact of volatility on the prices of individual equity options. Using the daily

More information

REIT and Commercial Real Estate Returns: A Postmortem of the Financial Crisis

REIT and Commercial Real Estate Returns: A Postmortem of the Financial Crisis 2015 V43 1: pp. 8 36 DOI: 10.1111/1540-6229.12055 REAL ESTATE ECONOMICS REIT and Commercial Real Estate Returns: A Postmortem of the Financial Crisis Libo Sun,* Sheridan D. Titman** and Garry J. Twite***

More information

Factors in Implied Volatility Skew in Corn Futures Options

Factors in Implied Volatility Skew in Corn Futures Options 1 Factors in Implied Volatility Skew in Corn Futures Options Weiyu Guo* University of Nebraska Omaha 6001 Dodge Street, Omaha, NE 68182 Phone 402-554-2655 Email: wguo@unomaha.edu and Tie Su University

More information

Session 28 Systemic Risk of Banks & Insurance. Richard Nesbitt, CEO Global Risk Institute in Financial Services

Session 28 Systemic Risk of Banks & Insurance. Richard Nesbitt, CEO Global Risk Institute in Financial Services Session 28 Systemic Risk of Banks & Insurance Richard Nesbitt, CEO Global Risk Institute in Financial Services Our Mission GRI is the premier risk management institute, that defines thought leadership

More information

Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence

Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence Joshua Livnat Department of Accounting Stern School of Business Administration New York University 311 Tisch Hall

More information

STRESS TEST ON MARKET RISK: SENSITIVITY OF BANKS BALANCE SHEET STRUCTURE TO INTEREST RATE SHOCKS

STRESS TEST ON MARKET RISK: SENSITIVITY OF BANKS BALANCE SHEET STRUCTURE TO INTEREST RATE SHOCKS STRESS TEST ON MARKET RISK: SENSITIVITY OF BANKS BALANCE SHEET STRUCTURE TO INTEREST RATE SHOCKS Juan F. Martínez S.* Daniel A. Oda Z.** I. INTRODUCTION Stress tests, applied to the banking system, have

More information

Determinants of Credit Rating and Optimal Capital Structure among Pakistani Banks

Determinants of Credit Rating and Optimal Capital Structure among Pakistani Banks 169 Determinants of Credit Rating and Optimal Capital Structure among Pakistani Banks Vivake Anand 1 Kamran Ahmed Soomro 2 Suneel Kumar Solanki 3 Firm s credit rating and optimal capital structure are

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

A Statistical Analysis to Predict Financial Distress

A Statistical Analysis to Predict Financial Distress J. Service Science & Management, 010, 3, 309-335 doi:10.436/jssm.010.33038 Published Online September 010 (http://www.scirp.org/journal/jssm) 309 Nicolas Emanuel Monti, Roberto Mariano Garcia Department

More information

Bank Capital, Profitability and Interest Rate Spreads MUJTABA ZIA * This draft version: March 01, 2017

Bank Capital, Profitability and Interest Rate Spreads MUJTABA ZIA * This draft version: March 01, 2017 Bank Capital, Profitability and Interest Rate Spreads MUJTABA ZIA * * Assistant Professor of Finance, Rankin College of Business, Southern Arkansas University, 100 E University St, Slot 27, Magnolia AR

More information

Mandatory supervisory disclosure, voluntary disclosure, and stock market liquidity: Evidence from the EU-wide stress-testing exercises

Mandatory supervisory disclosure, voluntary disclosure, and stock market liquidity: Evidence from the EU-wide stress-testing exercises Mandatory supervisory disclosure, voluntary disclosure, and stock market liquidity: Evidence from the EU-wide stress-testing exercises Jannis Bischof / Holger Daske University of Mannheim Bank Liquidity,

More information

Banks Non-Interest Income and Systemic Risk

Banks Non-Interest Income and Systemic Risk Banks Non-Interest Income and Systemic Risk Markus Brunnermeier, Gang Dong, and Darius Palia CREDIT 2011 Motivation (1) Recent crisis showcase of large risk spillovers from one bank to another increasing

More information

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality DORON NISSIM* Corporate disclosures are an important source of information for investors. Many studies have documented strong price

More information

Taxing Risk* Narayana Kocherlakota. President Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Economic Club of Minnesota. Minneapolis, Minnesota.

Taxing Risk* Narayana Kocherlakota. President Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Economic Club of Minnesota. Minneapolis, Minnesota. Taxing Risk* Narayana Kocherlakota President Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Economic Club of Minnesota Minneapolis, Minnesota May 10, 2010 *This topic is discussed in greater depth in "Taxing Risk

More information

Systemic Risk and Credit Risk in Bank Loan Portfolios

Systemic Risk and Credit Risk in Bank Loan Portfolios Systemic Risk and Credit Risk in Bank Loan Portfolios Yu Shan 1 Department of Economics and Finance, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College, New York, NY 10010, USA Aug 27, 2017 Abstract I investigate

More information

Too-Big-to-Fail: The Role of Metrics 1

Too-Big-to-Fail: The Role of Metrics 1 Too-Big-to-Fail: The Role of Metrics 1 Quantifying the Too Big to Fail Subsidy Workshop Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Minneapolis, Minnesota November 18, 2013 Narayana Kocherlakota President Federal

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

Donald L Kohn: Asset-pricing puzzles, credit risk, and credit derivatives

Donald L Kohn: Asset-pricing puzzles, credit risk, and credit derivatives Donald L Kohn: Asset-pricing puzzles, credit risk, and credit derivatives Remarks by Mr Donald L Kohn, Vice Chairman of the Board of Governors of the US Federal Reserve System, at the Conference on Credit

More information

Issues arising with the implementation of AASB 139 Financial Instruments: Recognition and Measurement by Australian firms in the gold industry

Issues arising with the implementation of AASB 139 Financial Instruments: Recognition and Measurement by Australian firms in the gold industry Issues arising with the implementation of AASB 139 Financial Instruments: Recognition and Measurement by Australian firms in the gold industry Abstract This paper investigates the impact of AASB139: Financial

More information

Perhaps the most striking aspect of the current

Perhaps the most striking aspect of the current COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, CROSS-BORDER MERGERS AND MERGER WAVES:INTER- NATIONAL ECONOMICS MEETS INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION STEVEN BRAKMAN* HARRY GARRETSEN** AND CHARLES VAN MARREWIJK*** Perhaps the most striking

More information

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 17 Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 Luísa Farinha Pedro Prego 2 Abstract The analysis of liquidity management decisions by firms has recently been used as a tool to investigate the

More information

Credit Default Swaps, Options and Systematic Risk

Credit Default Swaps, Options and Systematic Risk Credit Default Swaps, Options and Systematic Risk Christian Dorion, Redouane Elkamhi and Jan Ericsson Very preliminary and incomplete May 15, 2009 Abstract We study the impact of systematic risk on the

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan

Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan Discussion of The initial impact of the crisis on emerging market countries Linda L. Tesar University of Michigan The US recession that began in late 2007 had significant spillover effects to the rest

More information

Banking Concentration and Fragility in the United States

Banking Concentration and Fragility in the United States Banking Concentration and Fragility in the United States Kanitta C. Kulprathipanja University of Alabama Robert R. Reed University of Alabama June 2017 Abstract Since the recent nancial crisis, there has

More information

PhD DISSERTATION THESES

PhD DISSERTATION THESES PhD DISSERTATION THESES KAPOSVÁR UNIVERSITY FACULTY OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES Doctoral (PhD) School for Management and Organizational Science Head of PhD School Prof. Dr. SÁNDOR KEREKES University teacher,

More information

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES Mahir Binici Central Bank of Turkey Istiklal Cad. No:10 Ulus, Ankara/Turkey E-mail: mahir.binici@tcmb.gov.tr

More information

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW 2.1 Background on capital structure Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set of assumptions, capital structure is irrelevant. This

More information

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns?

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? University of Miami School of Business Stan Stilger, Alex Kostakis and Ser-Huang Poon MBS 23rd March 2015, Miami Alex Kostakis (MBS)

More information

Discussion of A Pigovian Approach to Liquidity Regulation

Discussion of A Pigovian Approach to Liquidity Regulation Discussion of A Pigovian Approach to Liquidity Regulation Ernst-Ludwig von Thadden University of Mannheim The regulation of bank liquidity has been one of the most controversial topics in the recent debate

More information

Competition, Risk-Shifting, and Public Bail-out Policies

Competition, Risk-Shifting, and Public Bail-out Policies Competition, Risk-Shifting, and Public Bail-out Policies Reint Gropp European Business School, CFS and ZEW Hendrik Hakenes University of Hannover and MPI Bonn Isabel Schnabel University of Mainz, MPI Bonn,

More information

An Examination of Herd Behavior in The Indonesian Stock Market

An Examination of Herd Behavior in The Indonesian Stock Market An Examination of Herd Behavior in The Indonesian Stock Market Adi Vithara Purba 1 Department of Management, University Of Indonesia Kampus Baru UI Depok +6281317370007 and Ida Ayu Agung Faradynawati 2

More information

An Empirical Investigation of the Lease-Debt Relation in the Restaurant and Retail Industry

An Empirical Investigation of the Lease-Debt Relation in the Restaurant and Retail Industry University of Massachusetts Amherst ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst International CHRIE Conference-Refereed Track 2011 ICHRIE Conference Jul 28th, 4:45 PM - 4:45 PM An Empirical Investigation of the Lease-Debt

More information

Macrostability Ratings: A Preliminary Proposal

Macrostability Ratings: A Preliminary Proposal Macrostability Ratings: A Preliminary Proposal Gary H. Stern* President Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Ron Feldman* Senior Vice President Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Editor s note: The too-big-to-fail

More information

How do insured deposits affect bank stability? Evidence from the 2008 Emergency Economic Stabilization Act

How do insured deposits affect bank stability? Evidence from the 2008 Emergency Economic Stabilization Act How do insured deposits affect bank stability? Evidence from the 2008 Emergency Economic Stabilization Act Claudia Lambert, Felix Noth and Ulrich Schüwer preliminary version June 4, 2013 Abstract This

More information

Asymmetric Market Reactions to the Financial Crisis: From Wall Street to Main Street

Asymmetric Market Reactions to the Financial Crisis: From Wall Street to Main Street Asymmetric Market Reactions to the 2007-08 Financial Crisis: From Wall Street to Main Street William J. Hippler, III, Ph.D. Assistant Professor of Finance College of Business and Public Management University

More information

Online Appendix to The Costs of Quantitative Easing: Liquidity and Market Functioning Effects of Federal Reserve MBS Purchases

Online Appendix to The Costs of Quantitative Easing: Liquidity and Market Functioning Effects of Federal Reserve MBS Purchases Online Appendix to The Costs of Quantitative Easing: Liquidity and Market Functioning Effects of Federal Reserve MBS Purchases John Kandrac Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Appendix. Additional

More information

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They?

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They? The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They? Massimiliano Marzo and Paolo Zagaglia This version: January 6, 29 Preliminary: comments

More information

Are Banks Still Special When There Is a Secondary Market for Loans?

Are Banks Still Special When There Is a Secondary Market for Loans? Are Banks Still Special When There Is a Secondary Market for Loans? The Journal of Finance, 2012 Amar Gande 1 and Anthony Saunders 2 1 The Edwin L Cox School of Business, Southern Methodist University

More information

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision Modern Applied Science; Vol. 9, No. 4; 2015 ISSN 1913-1844 E-ISSN 1913-1852 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision Seok Weon Lee 1 1 Division

More information

Trinity College and Darwin College. University of Cambridge. Taking the Art out of Smart Beta. Ed Fishwick, Cherry Muijsson and Steve Satchell

Trinity College and Darwin College. University of Cambridge. Taking the Art out of Smart Beta. Ed Fishwick, Cherry Muijsson and Steve Satchell Trinity College and Darwin College University of Cambridge 1 / 32 Problem Definition We revisit last year s smart beta work of Ed Fishwick. The CAPM predicts that higher risk portfolios earn a higher return

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University Volume 30, Issue Random risk aversion and the cost of eliminating the foreign exchange risk of the Euro Samih A Azar Haigazian University Abstract This paper answers the following questions. If the Euro

More information

14. What Use Can Be Made of the Specific FSIs?

14. What Use Can Be Made of the Specific FSIs? 14. What Use Can Be Made of the Specific FSIs? Introduction 14.1 The previous chapter explained the need for FSIs and how they fit into the wider concept of macroprudential analysis. This chapter considers

More information

April The Value Reversion

April The Value Reversion April 2016 The Value Reversion In the past two years, value stocks, along with cyclicals and higher-volatility equities, have underperformed broader markets while higher-momentum stocks have outperformed.

More information

Structural credit risk models and systemic capital

Structural credit risk models and systemic capital Structural credit risk models and systemic capital Somnath Chatterjee CCBS, Bank of England November 7, 2013 Structural credit risk model Structural credit risk models are based on the notion that both

More information

THE EUROSYSTEM S EXPERIENCE WITH FORECASTING AUTONOMOUS FACTORS AND EXCESS RESERVES

THE EUROSYSTEM S EXPERIENCE WITH FORECASTING AUTONOMOUS FACTORS AND EXCESS RESERVES THE EUROSYSTEM S EXPERIENCE WITH FORECASTING AUTONOMOUS FACTORS AND EXCESS RESERVES reserve requirements, together with its forecasts of autonomous excess reserves, form the basis for the calibration of

More information

This short article examines the

This short article examines the WEIDONG TIAN is a professor of finance and distinguished professor in risk management and insurance the University of North Carolina at Charlotte in Charlotte, NC. wtian1@uncc.edu Contingent Capital as

More information

LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. October 10, 2018

LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing. October 10, 2018 Economics 210c/236a Fall 2018 Christina Romer David Romer LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Quantitative Easing October 10, 2018 Announcements Paper proposals due on Friday (October 12).

More information

Discussion of Liquidity, Moral Hazard, and Interbank Market Collapse

Discussion of Liquidity, Moral Hazard, and Interbank Market Collapse Discussion of Liquidity, Moral Hazard, and Interbank Market Collapse Tano Santos Columbia University Financial intermediaries, such as banks, perform many roles: they screen risks, evaluate and fund worthy

More information

A Barrier Option Utility Framework for Bank Interest Margin under Government Bailout

A Barrier Option Utility Framework for Bank Interest Margin under Government Bailout www.sciedu.ca/ijfr International Journal of Financial Research Vol. 5, No. 4; 014 A Barrier Option Utility Framework for Bank Interest Margin under Government Bailout Ku-Jun in 1, Rosemary Jou & Tzu-Hao

More information

Chinese Firms Political Connection, Ownership, and Financing Constraints

Chinese Firms Political Connection, Ownership, and Financing Constraints MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Chinese Firms Political Connection, Ownership, and Financing Constraints Isabel K. Yan and Kenneth S. Chan and Vinh Q.T. Dang City University of Hong Kong, University

More information

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016)

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016) Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016) 68-131 An Investigation of the Structural Characteristics of the Indian IT Sector and the Capital Goods Sector An Application of the

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Shadow Banking & the Financial Crisis

Shadow Banking & the Financial Crisis & the Financial Crisis April 24, 2013 & the Financial Crisis Table of contents 1 Backdrop A bit of history 2 3 & the Financial Crisis Origins Backdrop A bit of history Banks perform several vital roles

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 3 Fall 1994 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: THE CASE OF BANK LOAN COMMITMENTS

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 3 Fall 1994 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: THE CASE OF BANK LOAN COMMITMENTS Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 3 Fall 1994 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: THE CASE OF BANK LOAN COMMITMENTS James E. McDonald * Abstract This study analyzes common stock return behavior

More information

Dynamic Macroeconomic Effects on the German Stock Market before and after the Financial Crisis*

Dynamic Macroeconomic Effects on the German Stock Market before and after the Financial Crisis* Dynamic Macroeconomic Effects on the German Stock Market before and after the Financial Crisis* March 2018 Kaan Celebi & Michaela Hönig Abstract Today we live in a post-truth and highly digitalized era

More information

The Altman Z is 50 and Still Young: Bankruptcy Prediction and Stock Market Reaction due to Sudden Exogenous Shock (Revised Title)

The Altman Z is 50 and Still Young: Bankruptcy Prediction and Stock Market Reaction due to Sudden Exogenous Shock (Revised Title) The Altman Z is 50 and Still Young: Bankruptcy Prediction and Stock Market Reaction due to Sudden Exogenous Shock (Revised Title) Abstract This study is motivated by the continuing popularity of the Altman

More information

A Fistful of Dollars: Lobbying and the Financial Crisis

A Fistful of Dollars: Lobbying and the Financial Crisis A Fistful of Dollars: Lobbying and the Financial Crisis by Deniz Igan, Prachi Mishra, and Thierry Tressel Research Department, IMF The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not

More information

1 Commodity Quay East Smithfield London, E1W 1AZ

1 Commodity Quay East Smithfield London, E1W 1AZ 1 Commodity Quay East Smithfield London, E1W 1AZ 14 July 2008 The Committee of European Securities Regulators 11-13 avenue de Friedland 75008 PARIS FRANCE RiskMetrics Group s Reply to CESR s technical

More information

Mispriced Index Option Portfolios George Constantinides University of Chicago

Mispriced Index Option Portfolios George Constantinides University of Chicago George Constantinides University of Chicago (with Michal Czerwonko and Stylianos Perrakis) We consider 2 generic traders: Introduction the Index Trader (IT) holds the S&P 500 index and T-bills and maximizes

More information

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle: Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia May 31, 214 Midwest Macro Conference Raju Huidrom Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle Background

More information

Is regulatory capital pro-cyclical? A macroeconomic assessment of Basel II

Is regulatory capital pro-cyclical? A macroeconomic assessment of Basel II Is regulatory capital pro-cyclical? A macroeconomic assessment of Basel II (preliminary version) Frank Heid Deutsche Bundesbank 2003 1 Introduction Capital requirements play a prominent role in international

More information

Insolvency risk in the Jamaican banking system. Locksley Todd Financial Stability Department Bank of Jamaica

Insolvency risk in the Jamaican banking system. Locksley Todd Financial Stability Department Bank of Jamaica Insolvency risk in the Jamaican banking system Locksley Todd Financial Stability Department Bank of Jamaica Outline Introduction Overview Literature Review Methodology Model refinement Data Results and

More information

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4 Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4.1 Introduction Modelling and predicting financial market volatility has played an important role for market participants as it enables

More information

Dividend Policy and Investment Decisions of Korean Banks

Dividend Policy and Investment Decisions of Korean Banks Review of European Studies; Vol. 7, No. 3; 2015 ISSN 1918-7173 E-ISSN 1918-7181 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Dividend Policy and Investment Decisions of Korean Banks Seok Weon

More information

Pricing & Risk Management of Synthetic CDOs

Pricing & Risk Management of Synthetic CDOs Pricing & Risk Management of Synthetic CDOs Jaffar Hussain* j.hussain@alahli.com September 2006 Abstract The purpose of this paper is to analyze the risks of synthetic CDO structures and their sensitivity

More information

The Credit Research Initiative (CRI) National University of Singapore

The Credit Research Initiative (CRI) National University of Singapore 2018 The Credit Research Initiative (CRI) National University of Singapore First version: March 2, 2017, this version: January 18, 2018 Probability of Default (PD) is the core credit product of the Credit

More information

MULTI FACTOR PRICING MODEL: AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH TO CAPM

MULTI FACTOR PRICING MODEL: AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH TO CAPM MULTI FACTOR PRICING MODEL: AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH TO CAPM Samit Majumdar Virginia Commonwealth University majumdars@vcu.edu Frank W. Bacon Longwood University baconfw@longwood.edu ABSTRACT: This study

More information