An asymmetric Melitz model of trade and growth

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "An asymmetric Melitz model of trade and growth"

Transcription

1 An asymmetric Melitz model of trade and growth Takumi Naito Waseda University October 15, 2015 Abstract To examine the effects of unilateral trade liberalization on growth and welfare of the liberalizing and partner countries through intraindustry reallocations, we formulate an asymmetric two-country Melitz model of trade and endogenous growth based on capital accumulation. We obtain two main results. First, each country s mass of exported varieties, revenue share of exported varieties, and growth rate increase if and only if its export productivity cutoff decreases. Second, compared with the old balanced growth path, a permanent fall in any import trade cost raises the growth rates of all countries for all periods, and welfare of all countries. JEL classification: F13; F43 Keywords: Melitz model; Unilateral trade liberalization; Endogenous growth; Heterogeneous firms; Asymmetric countries Takumi Naito. Faculty of Political Science and Economics, Waseda University, Nishiwaseda, Shinjuku-ku, Tokyo , Japan. tnaito@waseda.jp. 1

2 1 Introduction Trade liberalization in one country creates a greater export opportunity for more efficient firms in another country. This drives down the profits from domestic sales in the latter country, forcing the least efficient firms to exit. Such reallocation of resources improves the average productivity of surviving firms, which brings about additional gains from trade. This idea, known as the Melitz (2003) model of heterogeneous firms, has become one of the standard theories of international trade since the beginning of this century. However, since users of the Melitz model largely keep the assumption of symmetric countries, nothing is known about how the reallocation process caused by unilateral trade liberalization such as illustrated above affects the growth paths of the liberalizing and partner countries in asymmetric ways. 1 It is important to consider unilateral trade liberalization because trade costs indeed vary across countries: developing countries, on average, have more room for liberalizing imports than developed countries. 2 To examine the effects of unilateral trade liberalization on growth and welfare of the liberalizing and partner countries through intraindustry reallocations, we formulate an asymmetric two-country Melitz model of trade and endogenous growth. Some researchers combine the Melitz model with the R&D-based endogenous growth models synthesized by Grossman and Helpman (1991) to investigate the effects of symmetric trade liberalization on long-run growth (e.g., Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud, 2008; Haruyama and Zhao, 2008; Dinopoulos and Unel, 2011; Perla et al., 2014; Sampson, forthcoming). The literature starts from Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud (2008), who introduce heterogeneity in unit labor requirements for production in the standard variety expansion model. Trade liberalization affects each country s expected R&D cost through two channels. On one hand, it lowers the price of knowledge good if and only if it increases the degree of international spillovers of knowledge stocks. On the other hand, it makes it harder for potential entrants to survive in their domestic market (i.e., decreases the cutoff unit labor requirement for domestic sales), which increases the expected units of knowledge good required for successful entry. Overall, trade liberalization raises or lowers the long-run growth rate, depending on whether the former channel is stronger or weaker than the latter. Dinopoulos and Unel (2011) and Perla et al. (2014) also report an ambiguous relationship between symmetric trade costs and long-run growth, whereas Haruyama and Zhao (2008) and Sampson (forthcoming) find that the relationship is always negative. 3 However, all of these works depend on the assumption of symmetric countries. This suggests that, at least at this point, the R&D-based endogenous growth models with heterogeneous firms are not useful for our purpose of studying the effects of unilateral trade liberalization on asymmetric countries. To allow for asymmetric countries, we build on the multi-country AK model of Acemoglu and Ventura (2002). Motivated by their own empirical findings that a one percentage point rise in a country s growth rate 1 Helpman et al. (2004) and Melitz and Ottaviano (2008) deal with asymmetric countries by adding a homogeneous good sector, whose constant marginal product of labor fixes each country s wage. In contrast, Felbermayr et al. (2013) and Demidova and Rodríguez-Clare (2013) allow wages to be endogenously determined in their asymmetric two-country models without a homogeneous good sector. Segerstrom and Sugita (forthcoming) introduce multiple industries to study the effects of unilateral and industry-specific trade liberalization. However, all of these models are either static or stationary. In their review of heterogeneous firm trade models, Melitz and Redding (2014) point out that: (d)espite some work on dynamics, much of the literature on firm heterogeneity and trade remains static, and we have relatively little understanding of the processes through which large and successful firms emerge and the implications of these processes for the transitional dynamics of the economy s response to trade liberalization. (Melitz and Redding, 2014, p. 49) 2 In their comprehensive survey of trade costs, Anderson and van Wincoop (2004) conclude that: (t)rade costs also vary widely across countries. On average, developing countries have significantly larger trade costs, by a factor of two or more in some important categories. (Anderson and van Wincoop, 2004, p. 747) 3 Haruyama and Zhao (2008) employ the standard quality ladder model with international knowledge spillovers of the secondhighest quality goods. Dinopoulos and Unel (2011) deal with heterogeneity in product quality (i.e., marginal utility) instead of productivity in the variety expansion model. Perla et al. (2014) consider heterogeneous firms choices between remaining in production and paying a cost to adopt a better technology from more productive domestic firms. Sampson (forthcoming) assumes that productivity of each entrant is proportional to the average productivity of domestic incumbents, which in turn shifts the productivity distribution of entrants to the right over time. 2

3 deteriorates its terms of trade by 0.6 percentage points, they construct a model where such terms of trade adjustments in the differentiated intermediate good sector lead the growth rates of capital in all countries to converge, so that the world income distribution is stable, in the long run. We incorporate the asymmetric Melitz framework with endogenous factor prices developed by Felbermayr et al. (2013) and Demidova and Rodríguez-Clare (2013) into the intermediate good sector of the two-country Acemoglu-Ventura model. For each country s capital to grow at a constant rate, the masses of domestic and imported varieties must be constant along a balanced growth path (BGP). This requires us to assume that the fixed entry and overhead costs are increasing in the GDP of the source countries as negative externalities. This assumption is consistent with Bollard et al. (2014), who find empirically that the number of firms per worker increases only modestly with output per worker over time and across countries, with elasticities of at most around 0.2, implying that the fixed costs rise with economic growth. Our simple model enables us to examine, in a completely analytical manner, how unilateral trade liberalization affects each country s productivity cutoffs, extensive margin of exports (i.e., mass of exported varieties), openness (i.e., revenue share of exported varieties), and growth rate not only in the long run but also during the transition, and welfare. We obtain two main results. First, each country s mass of exported varieties, revenue share of exported varieties, and growth rate increase if and only if its export productivity cutoff decreases. Although it sounds natural that a decrease in a country s export productivity cutoff increases its mass and revenue share of exported varieties, it is far from trivial that such cutoff change always raises the country s own growth rate because its growth equation does not include the cutoff directly. The nontrivial relationship can be understood by considering that a decrease in a country s export productivity cutoff is followed by an increase in its domestic productivity cutoff from the free entry condition, and the resulting increase in its average productivity of surviving firms contributes to its faster growth. Just like a country s domestic productivity cutoff is a sufficient statistic for its welfare in static or stationary heterogeneous firm trade models (e.g., Melitz and Redding, 2014), a country s export productivity cutoff is a sufficient statistic for its growth rate as well as its mass and revenue share of exported varieties in our model. Second, compared with the old BGP, a permanent fall in any import trade cost raises the growth rates of all countries for all periods, and welfare of all countries. 4 In the initial period, a permanent fall in a country s import trade cost directly decreases the export productivity cutoff of the partner country, but it also indirectly decreases that of the liberalizing country itself through a fall in its relative rental rate of capital restoring its zero balance of trade. This raises the growth rates of both countries, with the relative supply of capital in one country to the other predetermined in that period. After the initial period, the relative supply of capital of either faster-growing country increases. Since this makes it more difficult for the intermediate good firms in that country to start exporting, its growth rate falls, whereas that of the other country rises for the opposite reason. Along the new BGP, both countries grow at the same rate, which is higher than the old BGP. One contribution of this result to the literature on heterogeneous firm models of trade and endogenous growth is that positive externalities from knowledge spillovers are unnecessary for trade liberalization to raise longrun growth. International spillovers are necessary for the case of growth-enhancing trade liberalization in Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud (2008), Haruyama and Zhao (2008), and Dinopoulos and Unel (2011), whereas domestic spillovers are the engine of endogenous growth in Perla et al. (2014) and Sampson (forthcoming). 4 This result itself is the same as Naito (2012), who introduces a continuum-good Ricardian structure in the intermediate good sector of the two-country Acemoglu-Ventura model. This does not mean that the present result is not original: as Arkolakis et al. (2012) point out that the heterogeneous firm monopolistic competition model of Melitz (2003) and the Ricardian perfect competition model of Eaton and Kortum (2002) share the same welfare formula under specific productivity distributions, we find that our dynamic Melitz model delivers the same growth effects of unilateral trade liberalization as a dynamic Ricardian model of Naito (2012) through completely different mechanisms to be discussed later. 3

4 Our model shows the positive growth effect of trade liberalization even under negative externalities. Another contribution is that even unilateral trade liberalization is sufficient for faster growth of all countries for all periods. In contrast to the literature, where cross-country symmetry needs to be imposed, our model is so flexible as to yield such a strong result. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 sets up the model. Section 3 derives some basic properties. Section 4 examines the effects of unilateral trade liberalization. Section 5 concludes. 2 The model Consider a two-country world economy. In country i(= 1, 2), there is a nontradable final good, which is used for consumption and investment. The final good is produced from a continuum of tradable differentiated intermediate goods under constant returns to scale and perfect competition. Each variety of intermediate good is produced from nontradable capital under increasing returns to scale and monopolistic competition. Capital is the only primary factor, whose growth rate is endogenously determined. 2.1 Households The representative household in country i maximizes its overall utility U i = 0 lnc it exp( ρ i t)dt, subject to its budget constraint: p Y it(c it + K it + δ i K it ) = r it K it ; K it dk it /dt, (1) with {p Y it, r it} t=0 and K i0 given, where t( [0, )) is time, C i is consumption, ρ i is the subjective discount rate, p Y i is the price of the final good, K i is the supply of capital, δ i is the depreciation rate of capital, and r i is the rental rate of capital. The time subscript is omitted whenever no confusion arises. Dynamic optimization under the logarithmic instantaneous utility implies that capital always grows at the same rate as consumption given by the Euler equation: 5 K it /K it = Ċit/C it = r it /p Y it δ i ρ i γ it t. (2) 2.2 Final good firms The representative final good firm in country i maximizes its profit Π Y i = p Y i Y i Ω i p i (ω)x i (ω)dω, subject to its production function Y i = ( Ω i x i (ω) α dω) 1/α ; α (σ 1)/σ (0, 1), with p Y i and {p i (ω)} ω Ωi given, where Y i is the supply of the final good, Ω i is the set of available varieties, p i (ω) is the demand price of variety ω, x i (ω) is the demand for variety ω, and σ(> 1) is the elasticity of substitution between any two varieties. Cost minimization yields the conditional input demand function for variety ω: x i (ω) = p i (ω) σ Pi σ Y i; P i ( p i (ω) 1 σ dω) 1/(1 σ), (3) Ω i where P i is the price index of the intermediate goods. Then the minimized expenditure for the intermediate goods is expressed as Ω i p i (ω)x i (ω)dω = P i Y i E i. Finally, perfect competition drives the price of the final good to its unit cost: 5 Integrating the budget constraint (1) from s = t to infinity, and using the Euler equation and the transversality condition, we obtain C it = ρ i K it t. 4

5 p Y i = P i. (4) 2.3 Intermediate good firms Our description of the intermediate good sector is based on Felbermayr et al. (2013), which is an asymmetric, two-country, and static version of Melitz (2003). After paying a sunk fixed entry cost, an intermediate good firm in country i draws its productivity ϕ from a country-specific cumulative distribution G i (ϕ) (to be specified later) with its density g i (ϕ). If a firm s ϕ is sufficiently high that the resulting gross profit covers its fixed overhead cost which is specific to each source-destination pair (i, j), i, j = 1, 2, then it survives selling its variety to the destination country j; otherwise, it exits from market j without having to pay the overhead cost. The fixed entry and overhead costs are specified as r i K i f e i and r i K i f ij, respectively, where f e i and f ij are exogenous constants. This means that all fixed costs are proportional to the GDP of the source country i as negative externalities. This is not unrealistic: Bollard et al. (2014) estimate that the elasticity of the number of firms per worker with respect to the value added per worker is at most around 0.2 over time and across countries, suggesting that the fixed costs rise with development. Finally, we assume that all decisions of individual firms are static. More specifically, each variety has a product life of only one period, and so each intermediate good firm has to pay not only the overhead costs but also the entry cost in each period with no hysteresis in productivity draws. 6 We will see that, even though the entry status of individual firms changes randomly, macroeconomic variables including the productivity cutoffs and the masses of varieties change smoothly over time. An intermediate good firm in country i with productivity ϕ maximizes its profit in country j π ij (ϕ) = p f ij (ϕ)y ij(ϕ) r i k ij (ϕ), subject to its cost function (measured in terms of capital) k ij (ϕ) = K i f ij +y ij (ϕ)/ϕ, the market-clearing condition for its variety y ij (ϕ) = τ ij x ij (ϕ), and the conditional input demand function for its variety x ij (ϕ) = p ij (ϕ) σ Pj σ 1 E j = (τ ij p f ij (ϕ)) σ Pj σ 1 E j from Eq. (3), with r i, K i, P j, and E j given, where p f ij (ϕ) is the FOB supply price of a variety, y ij(ϕ) is the supply of a variety, k ij (ϕ) is the demand for capital as overhead and variable costs, and τ ij ( 1) is the iceberg trade cost factor of delivering one unit of a variety from country i to country j, with τ ii = 1. Since σ is common across countries, each firm sets the same supply price for all destinations: (p f ij (ϕ) r i/ϕ)/p f ij (ϕ) = 1/σ pf ij (ϕ) = r i/(αϕ) j. (5) Using Eq. (5), the resulting revenue and profit are calculated as: e ij (ϕ) p f ij (ϕ)y ij(ϕ) = (τ ij r i ) 1 σ (αϕp j ) σ 1 E j, π ij (ϕ) = e ij (ϕ)/σ r i K i f ij = (τ ij r i ) 1 σ (αϕp j ) σ 1 E j /σ r i K i f ij. Since π ij (ϕ) is increasing in ϕ, a firm in country i survives in country j if and only if ϕ, where the productivity cutoff is determined by: 6 According to the Osiris database, in a total of 9,891 industrial companies, whose R&D expenses per operating revenue in 2010 is available, 8,497 firms pay no less than 0.1 percent of their revenue for R&D, of which 5,193 firms pay no less than 1 percent, for all available years during This implies that the R&D cost, which can be regarded as the fixed entry cost in our model, is more likely to be paid recurrently than only one time. 5

6 π ij ( ) = 0 e ij ( ) = (τ ij r i ) 1 σ (α P j ) σ 1 E j = σr i K i f ij. (6) Dividing Eq. (6) by itself with j = i, we obtain /ϕ ii = (P i /P j )(E i /E j ) 1/(σ 1) τ ij (f ij /f ii ) 1/(σ 1), i, j = 1, 2. In line with Melitz (2003), we assume that the variable and fixed export costs are sufficiently large that country i s export productivity cutoff is larger than its domestic productivity cutoff: /ϕ ii > 1, i, j = 1, 2, j i. Let m ij (1 G i ( ))/(1 G i (ϕ ii )), i, j = 1, 2. For j i, m ij (< 1) represents the ex-ante probability of export survival conditional on domestic survival. We also define the density of ϕ conditional on survival: { g i (ϕ)/(1 G i ( )) if ϕ ; µ ij (ϕ ) = 0 otherwise. From now on, G i (ϕ) is specified as Pareto, the most common functional form in the literature: G i (ϕ) = 1 (b i /ϕ) θ = 1 b θ i ϕ θ ; θ > 0, ϕ [b i, ). The shape parameter θ is common, whereas the scale parameter b i can be different, across countries. Then it follows that g i (ϕ) = θb θ i ϕ θ 1, µ ij (ϕ ) = θϕ θ ij ϕ θ 1 for ϕ, and m ij = ( /ϕ ii ) θ. The expected values of revenue and profit are calculated as: e ij (ϕ)g i (ϕ)dϕ = (1 G i ( )) π ij (ϕ)g i (ϕ)dϕ = (1 G i ( )) e ij (ϕ)µ ij (ϕ )dϕ = b θ i ϕ θ ij (θ/λ)σr ik i f ij, (7) λ θ (σ 1) > 0, π ij (ϕ)µ ij (ϕ )dϕ = b θ i ϕ θ ij (θ/λ 1)r ik i f ij ; where we use e ij (ϕ) = (ϕ/ ) σ 1 e ij ( ) = (ϕ/ ) σ 1 σr i K i f ij from Eq. (6), and ϕ σ 1 µ ij (ϕ )dϕ = (θ/λ)ϕ σ 1 ij. The assumption that λ > 0 ensures that the average productivity of surviving firms ( ) ( ϕ σ 1 µ ij (ϕ )dϕ) 1/(σ 1) is finite, and θ/λ(> 1) is equal to the ratio of the average productivity to the cutoff productivity (both raised to the power of σ 1). Free entry implies that the total expected profit of an entrant in country i is equal to its fixed entry cost, that is, j ϕ π ij ij(ϕ)g i (ϕ)dϕ = r i K i fi e.7 Noting that r i K i appears in both sides of the free entry condition, it is simplified to: fi e /[(θ/λ 1)b θ i] = j ϕ θ ij f ij = ϕ θ ii j m ijf ij. (8) The simplified free entry condition (8) means that country i s domestic productivity cutoff ϕ ii is always negatively related to its export productivity cutoff : a decrease in, for example, makes it easier for firms in country i to survive in their export market. For the free entry condition to be satisfied, ϕ ii increases so that surviving in their domestic market should become more difficult. Finally, let Mi e denote the mass of entrants in country i. Then the mass of entrants in country i surviving in country j, or the mass of varieties sold from country i to country j, is given by M ij = Mi e(1 G i( )). 7 What happens to the free entry condition if each firm has an infinite patent life, so that it pays the fixed entry cost only once? Then the one-time fixed entry cost should be equal to the present value of the total expected profits for all future periods. However, since the latter includes the future paths of endogenous variables, whose growth rates are not always constant under asymmetric countries, the productivity cutoffs in period t depend not only on period t endogenous variables just like Eq. (14), but also on their future paths. To avoid such intractability, we are assuming a one-period patent life. 6

7 This immediately implies that M ij /M ii = m ij. 2.4 Markets The market-clearing conditions for the final good, capital, and the intermediate goods are given by: Y i = C i + K i + δ i K i, i = 1, 2, (9) K i = j M ij k ij (ϕ)µ ij (ϕ )dϕ + M e i K i f e i, i = 1, 2, (10) y ij (ϕ) = τ ij x ij (ϕ), i, j = 1, 2. (11) On the other hand, summing up the household budget constraint (1), the zero profit condition in the final good sector (4), and the free entry condition in the intermediate good sector (8), we obtain Walras law in country i: 0 = p Y i (C i + K i + δ i K i Y i ) + r i ( j M ij + j M ji τ ji p f ji (ϕ)x ji(ϕ)µ ji (ϕ ϕ ji )dϕ j M ij ϕ ji k ij (ϕ)µ ij (ϕ )dϕ + M e i K if e i K i) p f ij (ϕ)y ij(ϕ)µ ij (ϕ )dϕ. Summing this up for all countries, we can confirm Walras law in the world, implying that any one of the eight (i.e., (9) 2, (10) 2, (11) 4) types of the market-clearing conditions is redundant, and that the price of any one of the eight types of goods and factors can be normalized to unity. 2.5 Dynamic system From now on, we derive the dynamic system, regarding the iceberg trade costs τ 21 and τ 12 as the only policy variables. Let capital in country 2 be the numeraire: r 2 1, and let κ K 1 /K 2 be the relative supply of capital in country 1 to country 2. From the zero cutoff profit condition (6) for all source-destination pairs, the ratio of the foreign export productivity cutoff to the domestic productivity cutoff in each destination is obtained as: ϕ 21 /ϕ 11 = (r1 σ κ) 1/(σ 1) τ 21 (f 21 /f 11 ) 1/(σ 1), (12) ϕ 12 /ϕ 22 = (r1 σ κ) 1/(σ 1) τ 12 (f 12 /f 22 ) 1/(σ 1). (13) A fall in a country s import trade cost, and/or an increase in its relative rental rate and/or its relative supply of capital, makes more foreign firms survive relative to domestic firms. From Eqs. (8), (12), and (13), all productivity cutoffs can be solved as functions of r1 σκ, τ 21, and τ 12 : = (r σ 1 κ, τ 21, τ 12 ), i, j = 1, 2. (14) Using Eqs. (7), (8), and M ij = m ij M ii, the capital market-clearing condition (10) is solved for M ii. Substituting the solution into M ij = ( /ϕ ii ) θ M ii, we obtain: 7

8 M ij = (α/θ)b θ i ϕ θ ij /fe i, i, j = 1, 2. (15) This means that the mass of varieties sold from country i to country j is decreasing in the corresponding productivity cutoff. Our specification of the fixed entry and overhead costs implies that M ij does not grow proportionately with the source country s GDP, which is consistent with the empirical findings of Bollard et al. (2014). Walras law in country i, together with Eqs. (9), (10), and (11), implies that its balance of trade is zero: M ij e ij (ϕ)µ ij (ϕ )dϕ = M ji ϕ ji e ji (ϕ)µ ji (ϕ ϕ ji )dϕ, i, j = 1, 2, j i. Using Eqs. (7) and (15), this is rewritten as: r 1 κb θ 1ϕ θ 12 f 12/f e 1 = b θ 2ϕ θ 21 f 21/f e 2. (16) The left- and right-hand sides of Eq. (16) correspond to country 1 s exports and imports, respectively. The intermediate good price index in Eq. (3) is rewritten as: 8 P i = (α σ /λ) 1/(1 σ) [ j (bθ j/f e j )ϕ λ ji (τ jir j ) 1 σ ] 1/(1 σ) Q i (ϕ ii, ϕ ji, r i, τ ji r j ), i, j = 1, 2, j i. (17) Country i s simplified intermediate good price index Q i (ϕ ii, ϕ ji, r i, τ ji r j ) is increasing in the suppliers productivity cutoffs (ϕ ii, ϕ ji ), whereas increasing and homogeneous of degree one in the suppliers factor and trade costs (r i, τ ji r j ). 9 From Eqs. (2), (4), and (17), country i s growth rate is expressed as: γ i = 1/q i (ϕ ii, ϕ ji, τ ji r j /r i ) δ i ρ i ; q i (ϕ ii, ϕ ji, τ ji r j /r i ) Q i (ϕ ii, ϕ ji, 1, τ ji r j /r i ), i, j = 1, 2, j i, (18) where q i (ϕ ii, ϕ ji, τ ji r j /r i ) is country i s simplified intermediate good price index divided by its rental rate, meaning that 1/q i (ϕ ii, ϕ ji, τ ji r j /r i ) is country i s gross rate of return to capital. Country i s growth rate is decreasing in (ϕ ii, ϕ ji ) whereas decreasing in τ ji r j /r i, country i s import trade cost divided by its relative rental rate. From Eq. (18), the growth rate of κ is simply given by: κ/κ = γ 1 γ 2 = 1/q 1 (ϕ 11, ϕ 21, τ 21 /r 1 ) δ 1 ρ 1 (1/q 2 (ϕ 22, ϕ 12, τ 12 r 1 ) δ 2 ρ 2 ). (19) With the initial condition κ 0 = K 10 /K 20 and the trade costs τ 21 and τ 12 given, Eqs. (14), (16), and (19) characterize an equilibrium path {ϕ 11t, ϕ 12t, ϕ 21t, ϕ 22t, r 1t, κ t } t=0. Finally, using Eqs. (7) and (15), country i s revenue share of exported varieties β i M ij e ij (ϕ)µ ij (ϕ )dϕ/ k M ik ϕ e ik ik(ϕ)µ ik (ϕ ϕ ik )dϕ is rewritten as: β i = ϕ θ ij f ij/ k ϕ θ ik f ik = ϕ θ ij f ij/(ϕ θ ii f ii + ϕ θ ij f ij) (0, 1), i, j, k = 1, 2, j i. (20) Considering the zero balance of trade, this is equal to country i s expenditure share of imported varieties ζ i M ji ϕ ji e ji (ϕ)µ ji (ϕ ϕ ji )dϕ/ k M ki ϕ ki e ki(ϕ)µ ki (ϕ ϕ ki )dϕ. Eq. (20) serves as a measure of country 8 The intermediate good price index in Eq. (3) is given by P i = ( P j M ji R ϕ ji p ji(ϕ) 1 σ µ ji (ϕ ϕ ji )dϕ) 1/(1 σ). Using Eq. (5) and R ϕ ϕ σ 1 µ ji (ϕ ϕ ji )dϕ = (θ/λ)ϕ σ 1 ji ji, this is rewritten as P i = {(θ/λ) P j M ji[τ ji r j /(αϕ ji )] 1 σ } 1/(1 σ). Substituting Eq. (15) into this, we obtain Eq. (17). 9 An increase in ϕ ji tends to lower P i through an increase in the average productivity of surviving firms, whereas it tends to raise P i through a decrease in the mass of varieties. The latter is stronger than the former if and only if λ > 0. 8

9 i s openness. 3 Basic properties 3.1 Productivity cutoffs, extensive margins, growth rates, and openness First of all, logarithmically differentiating Eqs. (8), (12), and (13), and solving them for d ln = d /, the rate of change in, we obtain: ϕ 21 = [(1 β 2 )/(1 β 1 β 2 )][ (σ r 1 + κ)/(σ 1) + (1 β 1 ) τ 21 β 1 τ 12 ], (21) ϕ 12 = [(1 β 1 )/(1 β 1 β 2 )][(σ r 1 + κ)/(σ 1) β 2 τ 21 + (1 β 2 ) τ 12 ], (22) ϕ 11 = [β 1 /(1 β 1 )] ϕ 12 = [β 1 /(1 β 1 β 2 )][(σ r 1 + κ)/(σ 1) β 2 τ 21 + (1 β 2 ) τ 12 ], (23) ϕ 22 = [β 2 /(1 β 2 )] ϕ 21 = [β 2 /(1 β 1 β 2 )][ (σ r 1 + κ)/(σ 1) + (1 β 1 ) τ 21 β 1 τ 12 ]. (24) To obtain intuitions, consider the normal case where 1 β 1 β 2 is positive (it turns out, however, that all propositions hold regardless of its sign). 10 In Eq. (21), for example, lnϕ 21 / lnτ 21 > 0 and lnϕ 21 / ln(r1 σ κ) < 0 are consistent with the discussion right after Eqs. (12) and (13). On the other hand, lnϕ 21 / lnτ 12 < 0 can be interpreted as follows. A fall in country 2 s import trade cost τ 12 allows more firms in country 1 to start exporting to country 2 (i.e., ϕ 12 decreases). For country 1 s free entry condition to be restored, some low-productivity firms in country 1 exit from their domestic market (i.e., ϕ 11 increases). Due to tougher competition in market 1, some firms in country 2 cease exporting (i.e., ϕ 21 increases). The following proposition states important relationships among each country s export productivity cutoff, extensive margin of exports, openness, and growth rate: Proposition 1 Each country s mass of exported varieties, revenue share of exported varieties, and growth rate increase if and only if its export productivity cutoff decreases. Proof. See Appendix A. A decrease in country i s export productivity cutoff increases the probability of survival in its export market, which increases its mass and revenue share of exported varieties. On the other hand, since country i s domestic cutoff firm becomes more productive, it can survive at a higher factor cost relative to the intermediate good price index, meaning that its gross rate of return to capital and hence its growth rate rise. An implication of this proposition is that looking at either one of the four endogenous variables is sufficient for predicting the other three. For example, if a country s growth rate rises for whatever reason, then its export productivity cutoff decreases whereas its mass and revenue share of exported varieties increase. 3.2 Balanced growth path By endogenizing all productivity cutoffs and country 1 s rental rate from Eqs. (14) and (16), country i s growth rate (18) is rewritten as γ i (κ; τ 21, τ 12 ). This means that our dynamic system is reduced to a onedimensional autonomous differential equation for κ as κ/κ = γ 1 (κ; τ 21, τ 12 ) γ 2 (κ; τ 21, τ 12 ) from Eq. (19). 10 According to the World Development Indicators, the annual averages of the total trade/gdp ratios of the aggregate highincome countries and low- and middle-income countries during were 52.0% and 58.0%, respectively. Under the assumption of zero balance of trade, dividing them by two gives estimates of β i, which were below 30%, or

10 As usual, a balanced growth path (BGP) is defined as a path along which all variables grow at constant rates. In the present model, a BGP is simply characterized by: where an asterisk represents a BGP. 0 = γ 1 (κ ; τ 21, τ 12 ) γ 2 (κ ; τ 21, τ 12 ), Proposition 2 Suppose that γ 1 γ 2 > 0 at lnκ = lnκ and γ 1 γ 2 < 0 at lnκ = lnκ, where lnκ and lnκ correspond to ln(ϕ 12 /ϕ 11 ) = 0 and ln(ϕ 21 /ϕ 22 ) = 0, respectively. Then there exists a unique lnκ (ln κ, ln κ) which is globally stable. Proof. See Appendix B. Dynamics of our model is illustrated in Fig. 1, where κ and γ i are measured on the horizontal and vertical axes, respectively. Country 1 s growth rate is drawn by the downward-sloping dashed curve γ 1 (κ; τ 21, τ 12 ) because an increase in κ increases r1 σ κ (cf. Eq. (B.2)), which discourages exporting from country 1 (cf. Eq. (22)). Similarly, since an increase in r1 σ κ arising from an increase in κ encourages exporting from country 2 (cf. Eq. (21)), its growth rate is represented by the upward-sloping dashed curve γ 2 (κ; τ 21, τ 12 ). The two curves intersect at point A: (κ, γi ), a unique BGP. If κ starts from a low value, then country 1 starts to grow faster than country 2. Since this pushes κ toward κ, country 1 s growth rate falls whereas country 2 s growth rate rises. This process continues until the two growth rates are equalized at point A. 4 Effects of unilateral trade liberalization General expressions for the growth rates are derived as (see Appendix B): dγ 1 = [(β 1 /q 1 )/A]{(σ 1) κ + [θσ(1 β 2 ) + (σ 1)β 2 ] τ 21 + [θσ (σ 1)](1 β 2 ) τ 12 }, (25) dγ 2 = [(β 2 /q 2 )/A]{ (σ 1) κ + [θσ (σ 1)](1 β 1 ) τ 21 + [θσ(1 β 1 ) + (σ 1)β 1 ] τ 12 }; (26) A σθ(2 β 1 β 2 ) (σ 1)(1 β 1 β 2 ) > 0. Eqs. (25) and (26) mean that, with κ given, a fall in any import trade cost raises the growth rates of both countries. At first sight Eq. (25) seems to contradict partly with Eq. (22): the latter suggests that a fall in τ 21 directly increases ϕ 12. In fact, an increase in ϕ 12 and a decrease in ϕ 21 caused by a fall in τ 21 tend to create a trade deficit for country 1 (cf. Eq. (16)). For the deficit to be cleared, its capital should become relatively cheaper (cf. Eq. (B.1)). This indirectly decreases ϕ 12. Since the indirect effect outweighs the direct effect, γ 1 rises as a result. To examine the long-run growth effects, we substitute Eqs. (25) and (26) into dγ 1 = dγ 2 to solve for κ : κ = [1/(σ 1)][1/(β 1/q 1 + β 2/q 2)] { {(β 1 /q 1 )[θσ(1 β 2 ) + (σ 1)β 2 ] (β 2 /q 2 )[θσ (σ 1)](1 β 1 )} τ 21 + {(β 2 /q 2 )[θσ(1 β 1 ) + (σ 1)β 1 ] (β 1 /q 1 )[θσ (σ 1)](1 β 2 )} τ 12}. Substituting this back into either Eq. (25) or (26), we obtain: 10

11 dγ1 = dγ2 = [(β1/q 1)(β 2/q 2)/(β 1/q 1 + β2/q 2)]( τ 21 + τ 12 ). This implies that a fall in any import trade cost raises the balanced growth rate. To consider the short-run growth effects of unilateral trade liberalization, e.g., a fall in τ 21, we first see its growth effects in the initial period, where κ 0 = 0. Eqs. (25) and (26) immediately give: γ 10 / lnτ 21 = [(β 1 /q 1 )/A ][θσ(1 β 2 ) + (σ 1)β 2 ] < 0, γ 20 / lnτ 21 = [(β 2/q 2)/A ][θσ (σ 1)](1 β 1) < 0, where all endogenous variables are evaluated at the old BGP. Fig. 1 illustrates the case where (β 1/q 1)[θσ(1 β 2) + (σ 1)β 2] > (β 2/q 2)[θσ (σ 1)](1 β 1). This is more likely, the more open country 1 is relative to country 2 at the old BGP. 11 Suppose that we are originally at point A, the old BGP, and that τ 21 falls permanently to τ 21(< τ 21 ). Then both dashed curve γ 1 (κ; τ 21, τ 12 ) and curve γ 2 (κ; τ 21, τ 12 ) shift up to solid curve γ 1 (κ; τ 21, τ 12) and curve γ 2 (κ; τ 21, τ 12), respectively, but the former shift is larger than the latter. The growth rates of country 1 and country 2 in the initial period are given by point B: (κ, γ 10 ) and point C: (κ, γ 20 ), respectively. Since country 1 starts to grow faster than country 2, κ starts to increase. This continues to pull down country 1 s growth rate whereas pushes up country 2 s growth rate along curve γ 1 (κ; τ 21, τ 12) and curve γ 2 (κ; τ 21, τ 12), respectively. The growth rates are equalized at point D: (κ, γi ), the new BGP, which is to the northeast of point A. We observe that, compared with the old BGP, a permanent fall in τ 21 raises the growth rates of all countries for all periods. Moreover, from Proposition 1, this is also true for masses and revenue shares of exported varieties. It can also be pointed out that the relatively more open country 1 experiences an overshooting in its growth rate. In the other case where (β1 /q 1 )[θσ(1 β 2 )+(σ 1)β 2 ] < (β 2 /q 2 )[θσ (σ 1)](1 β 1 ), which is possible if country 2 is relatively more open at the old BGP, the upward shift of curve γ 2 (κ; τ 21, τ 12) is now larger than curve γ 1 (κ; τ 21, τ 12), so point C is now higher than point B. Since κ starts to decrease, country 1 s growth rate goes up whereas country 2 s growth rate goes down until they are equalized at point D, which is now to the northwest of point A. Even in this case, compared with the old BGP, a permanent fall in τ 21 raises the growth rates as well as masses and revenue shares of exported varieties of all countries for all periods. We again observe an overshooting in the growth rate of the relatively more open country 2. Finally, considering that country i s consumption in period t is given by C it = C i0 exp( t 0 γ isds) = ρ i K i0 exp( t 0 γ isds) under the logarithmic instantaneous utility, the fact that γ is > γ is s 0 implies that C it > C it t > 0, and hence U i > U i. The following proposition summarizes our results: Proposition 3 Compared with the old BGP, a permanent fall in any import trade cost raises the growth rates of all countries for all periods, and welfare of all countries. This result, together with Proposition 1, shows a striking coincidence with Naito (2012, Propositions 2 to 4), who embeds a continuum-good Ricardian framework with perfect competition in the intermediate good sector of the two-country Acemoglu-Ventura model. However, the mechanisms behind the result are quite different. In Naito (2012), a fall in a country s import trade cost directly raises its own growth rate, but the former indirectly lowers the latter through a fall in its relative rental rate due to the decreased demand for 11 This case applies when the old BGP is symetric because (β 1 /q 1 )[θσ(1 β 2 ) + (σ 1)β 2 ] (β 2 /q 2 )[θσ (σ 1)](1 β 1 ) = (β 1 /q 1 )(σ 1) > 0 if β 2 = β 1 and q 2 = q 1. 11

12 its capital. Since the direct effect outweighs the indirect effect, the growth rate of the liberalizing country goes up in total. On the other hand, the growth rate of the partner country also goes up because of a rise in its relative rental rate. In contrast, in the present model, a fall in a country s import trade cost directly lowers its own growth rate whereas raises that of the partner country through changes in export productivity cutoffs. In addition, such trade liberalization lowers the relative rental rate of the liberalizing country satisfying its zero balance of trade, which has counteracting effects on countries growth rates. The indirect effect is stronger than the direct effect for the liberalizing country, whereas the opposite is true for the partner country. The robust positive growth effect of (even unilateral) trade liberalization is theoretically remarkable because it is obtained even with imperfect competition and without positive externalities from knowledge spillovers. In the literature, trade liberalization can raise long-run growth only under international spillovers (e.g., Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud, 2008; Haruyama and Zhao, 2008; Dinopoulos and Unel, 2011) or domestic spillovers (e.g., Perla et al., 2014; Sampson, forthcoming). This tempts us to suppose that freer trade cannot foster economic growth in the Melitz-type models of trade and growth without positive externalities. Our result shows that the conjecture is not true. 5 Concluding remarks This paper makes both theoretical and policy contributions. On the theoretical side, we first provide an asymmetric Melitz model of trade and growth. In the literature on heterogeneous firm models of trade and growth (e.g., Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud, 2008; Haruyama and Zhao, 2008; Dinopoulos and Unel, 2011; Perla et al., 2014; Sampson, forthcoming), all papers consider R&D as the engine of endogenous growth, but they cannot drop the assumption of symmetric countries. By replacing R&D with capital accumulation, we successfully formulate an asymmetric Melitz model, where a possible difference in countries growth rates itself creates asymmetric adjustments of their export productivity cutoffs and hence their growth rates toward convergence. On the policy side, our model supports unilateral trade liberalization as a way of promoting growth globally. Naito (2012) obtains a similar result in his two-country Acemoglu-Ventura model with a perfectly competitive intermediate good sector. This paper complements his work by showing that the growth-enhancing effect of unilateral trade liberalization is valid even under imperfect competition. Because of its flexibility, our theoretical framework can be applied to problems involving asymmetric countries. For example, by replacing the iceberg import trade costs with the revenue-generating import tariffs, we can study the optimal tariff of each country. Compared with the static optimal tariff model of Felbermayr et al. (2013), the growth effect will pull down a country s optimal tariff in our model. Another example is to increase the number of countries to more than two. By doing this, we can see the effects of preferential trade liberalization on both member and nonmember countries. Even the nonmember countries will partly gain from preferential trade liberalization due to the growth effect. Although these extensions might cause some technical difficulties, it is worth trying them. Appendix A. Proof of Proposition 1 First of all, logarithmic differentiation of Eq. (15) immediately gives: M ij = θ, i, j = 1, 2. (A.1) 12

13 Next, logarithmically differentiating Eq. (20) gives β i = θ(1 β i )( ϕ ii ). Since 0 = (1 β i ) ϕ ii +β i, or = (1 β i )( ϕ ii ) from Eq. (8), we obtain: β i = θ = M ij, i, j = 1, 2, j i, (A.2) where the last equality follows from Eq. (A.1). Finally, considering that E i = P i Y i = p Y i (C i + K i + δ i K i ) = r i K i from Eqs. (1), (4), and (9), and remembering that 1/q i = r i /P i from Eq. (18), the zero cutoff profit condition (6) for j = i is rewritten as [r i /(αϕ ii P i )] 1 σ = σf ii, or 1/q i = (σf ii ) 1/(1 σ) αϕ ii. Together with 0 = (1 β i ) ϕ ii + β i from Eq. (8), this implies that: q i = ϕ ii = [β i /(1 β i )], i, j = 1, 2, j i. (A.3) Differentiating Eq. (18), and using Eq. (A.3), the amount of change in γ i is simply given by: dγ i = (1/q i )( q i ) = (1/q i )[β i /(1 β i )], i, j = 1, 2, j i. (A.4) Eqs. (A.1), (A.2), and (A.4) imply Proposition 1. Appendix B. Proof of Proposition 2 We first derive Eqs. (25) and (26). Logarithmically differentiating Eq. (16), and using Eqs. (21) and (22), r 1 is solved as: r 1 = (1/A){ B κ + θ(σ 1)[(1 β 1 ) τ 21 (1 β 2 ) τ 12 ]}; (B.1) A σθ(2 β 1 β 2 ) (σ 1)(1 β 1 β 2 ) > 0, B θ(2 β 1 β 2 ) (σ 1)(1 β 1 β 2 ) (0, A). Substituting Eq. (B.1) into σ r 1 + κ, and noting that A σb = (σ 1) 2 (1 β 1 β 2 ), we obtain: (σ r 1 + κ)/(σ 1) = (1/A){(σ 1)(1 β 1 β 2 ) κ + θσ[(1 β 1 ) τ 21 (1 β 2 ) τ 12 ]}. (B.2) Substituting Eq. (B.2) into Eqs. (21) and (22), and substituting them into Eq. (A.4), we obtain Eqs. (25) and (26). We next study dynamics. With τ 21 = τ 12 = 0, Eqs. (25) and (26) give: dγ 1 = (β 1 /q 1 )[(σ 1)/A] κ, dγ 2 = (β 2 /q 2 )[(σ 1)/A] κ. Substituting them into the differentiated form of Eq. (19), and noting that κ/κ = d lnκ/dt and κ = d lnκ, we obtain: d(d ln κ/dt)/d lnκ = (β 1 /q 1 + β 2 /q 2 )[(σ 1)/A] < 0. 13

14 This implies that lnκ determined by d lnκ/dt = 0 is unique if exists. Also, since d lnκ/dt > 0 if and only if lnκ < lnκ, a BGP is globally stable. To ensure existence, we first find the lower and upper bounds of lnκ. From Eqs. (21) to (24) and (B.2), ln(ϕ 12 /ϕ 11 ) is increasing, whereas ln(ϕ 21 /ϕ 22 ) is decreasing, in lnκ. Considering the assumption that ϕ 12 /ϕ 11 > 1 and ϕ 21 /ϕ 22 > 1, lnκ, the lower bound of lnκ, is determined by ϕ 12 /ϕ 11 = 1, or ln(ϕ 12 /ϕ 11 ) = 0. Similarly, lnκ, the upper bound of lnκ, is determined by ϕ 21 /ϕ 22 = 1, or ln(ϕ 21 /ϕ 22 ) = 0. Then there exists lnκ (ln κ, lnκ) if d ln κ/dt = γ 1 γ 2 > 0 at lnκ = lnκ and d lnκ/dt = γ 1 γ 2 < 0 at lnκ = lnκ. 14

15 References [1] Acemoglu, D., Ventura, J., The world income distribution. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, [2] Anderson, J. E., Wincoop, E. v., Trade costs. Journal of Economic Literature 42, [3] Arkolakis, C., Costinot, A., Rodríguez-Clare, A., New trade models, same old gains? American Economic Review 102, [4] Baldwin, R. E., Robert-Nicoud, F., Trade and growth with heterogeneous firms. Journal of International Economics 74, [5] Bollard, A., Klenow, P. J., Li, H., Entry costs rise with development. unpublished. [6] Demidova, S., Rodríguez-Clare, A., The simple analytics of the Melitz model in a small economy. Journal of International Economics 90, [7] Dinopoulos, E., Unel, B., Quality heterogeneity and global economic growth. European Economic Review 55, [8] Eaton, J., Kortum, S., Technology, geography, and trade. Econometrica 70, [9] Felbermayr, G., Jung, B., Larch, M., Optimal tariffs, retaliation, and the welfare loss from tariff wars in the Melitz model. Journal of International Economics 89, [10] Grossman, G. M., Helpman, E., Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. [11] Haruyama, T., Zhao, L., Trade and firm heterogeneity in a quality-ladder model of growth. Discussion Paper Series No. 223, RIEB, Kobe University. [12] Helpman, E., Melitz, M. J., Yeaple, S. R., Export versus FDI with heterogeneous firms. American Economic Review 94, [13] Melitz, M. J., The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71, [14] Melitz, M. J., Ottaviano, G. I. P., Market size, trade, and productivity. Review of Economic Studies 75, [15] Melitz, M. J., Redding, S. J Heterogeneous firms and trade, in: Helpman, E., Rogoff, K., Gopinath, G. (Eds.), Handbook of International Economics, Volume 4. Elsevier B. V., Amsterdam, pp [16] Naito, T., A Ricardian model of trade and growth with endogenous trade status. Journal of International Economics 87, [17] Perla, J., Tonetti, C., Waugh, M. E., Equilibrium technology diffusion, trade, and growth. unpublished. 15

16 [18] Sampson, T., forthcoming. Dynamic selection: an idea flows theory of entry, trade and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics. DOI: /qje/qjv032 [19] Segerstrom, P. S., Sugita, Y., forthcoming. The impact of trade liberalization on industrial productivity. Journal of the European Economic Association. DOI: /jeea

17 γ i γ 2 (κ; τ 21, τ 12) K i K i γ 2 (κ; τ 21, τ 12 ) γ 10 γi γ 20 γ i B C A D γ 1 (κ; τ 21, τ 12) (τ 21 < τ 21) γ 1 (κ; τ 21, τ 12 ) O κ κ κ K1 K 2 Note: i s growth rate γ i moves in the same direction as its: mass of exported varieties M ij revenue share of exported varieties β i Fig. 1. Growth effects of a permanent fall in country 1 s import trade cost τ

Firms in International Trade. Lecture 2: The Melitz Model

Firms in International Trade. Lecture 2: The Melitz Model Firms in International Trade Lecture 2: The Melitz Model Stephen Redding London School of Economics 1 / 33 Essential Reading Melitz, M. J. (2003) The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and

More information

International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity

International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity .. International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity Akihiko Yanase (Graduate School of Economics) January 13, 2017 1 / 28 Introduction Krugman (1979, 1980)

More information

The Effect of Globalization in a Semi Endogenous Growth Model with Firm Heterogeneity, Endogenous International Spillover, and Trade

The Effect of Globalization in a Semi Endogenous Growth Model with Firm Heterogeneity, Endogenous International Spillover, and Trade The Effect of Globalization in a Semi Endogenous Growth Model with Firm Heterogeneity, Endogenous International Spillover, and Trade Katsufumi Fukuda 1 August 3, 214 Abstract This paper shows that globalization

More information

ECO2704 Lecture Notes: Melitz Model

ECO2704 Lecture Notes: Melitz Model ECO2704 Lecture Notes: Melitz Model Xiaodong Zhu University of Toronto October 15, 2010 1 / 22 Dynamic Industry Model with heterogeneous firms where opening to trade leads to reallocations of resources

More information

A Larger Country Sets a Lower Optimal Tariff

A Larger Country Sets a Lower Optimal Tariff RIETI Discussion Paper Series 17-E-037 A Larger Country Sets a Lower Optimal Tariff NAITO Takumi Vanderbilt University / Waseda University The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/

More information

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003)

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003) 14.581 Week 8 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 1 / 42 Firm-Level Heterogeneity and Trade What s wrong

More information

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business Discussion Papers In Economics And Business The Effect of Technology Choice on Specialization and Welfare in a Two-Country Model Yukiko Sawada Discussion Paper 15-10 Graduate School of Economics and Osaka

More information

Dynamic Selection and the New Gains from Trade with. Heterogeneous Firms

Dynamic Selection and the New Gains from Trade with. Heterogeneous Firms Dynamic Selection and the New Gains from Trade with Heterogeneous Firms Thomas Sampson London School of Economics & CEP November 202 Abstract This paper develops an open economy growth model in which firm

More information

Dynamic Selection and the New Gains from Trade with. Heterogeneous Firms

Dynamic Selection and the New Gains from Trade with. Heterogeneous Firms Dynamic Selection and the New Gains from Trade with Heterogeneous Firms Thomas Sampson London School of Economics & CEP March 2013 Abstract This paper develops an open economy growth model in which firm

More information

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Journal of Economic Integration 20(4), December 2005; 631-643 Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Noritsugu Nakanishi Kobe University Toru Kikuchi Kobe University

More information

International Trade Gravity Model

International Trade Gravity Model International Trade Gravity Model Yiqing Xie School of Economics Fudan University Dec. 20, 2013 Yiqing Xie (Fudan University) Int l Trade - Gravity (Chaney and HMR) Dec. 20, 2013 1 / 23 Outline Chaney

More information

Impact of Tariff under Hecksher-Ohlin Comparative Advantage Setting and Firm Heterogeneity

Impact of Tariff under Hecksher-Ohlin Comparative Advantage Setting and Firm Heterogeneity Impact of Tariff under Hecksher-Ohlin Comparative Advantage Setting and Firm Heterogeneity ERASMUS UNIVERSITY ROTTERDAM Erasmus School of Economics Department of Economics Supervisor: Dr. J. Emami Namini

More information

Economics 689 Texas A&M University

Economics 689 Texas A&M University Horizontal FDI Economics 689 Texas A&M University Horizontal FDI Foreign direct investments are investments in which a firm acquires a controlling interest in a foreign firm. called portfolio investments

More information

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy George Alogoskoufis* Athens University of Economics and Business September 2012 Abstract This paper examines

More information

Heterogeneous Firms. Notes for Graduate Trade Course. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. January 30, 2013

Heterogeneous Firms. Notes for Graduate Trade Course. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. January 30, 2013 Heterogeneous Firms Notes for Graduate Trade Course J. Peter Neary University of Oxford January 30, 2013 J.P. Neary (University of Oxford) Heterogeneous Firms January 30, 2013 1 / 29 Plan of Lectures 1

More information

Trade Liberalization and Productivity Growth

Trade Liberalization and Productivity Growth Trade Liberalization and Productivity Growth Peter Gustafsson National Institute of Economic Research Paul Segerstrom Stockholm School of Economics Current version: August 9, 28 Abstract: This paper presents

More information

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Problem Set 2: Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g)) Exercise 2.1: An infinite horizon problem with perfect foresight In this exercise we will study at a discrete-time version of Ramsey

More information

Thomas Sampson Dynamic selection: an idea flows theory of entry, trade and growth

Thomas Sampson Dynamic selection: an idea flows theory of entry, trade and growth Thomas Sampson Dynamic selection: an idea flows theory of entry, trade and growth Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Sampson, Thomas (2016) Dynamic selection: an idea flows theory

More information

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Paper No. 07/05 Firm heterogeneity, foreign direct investment and the hostcountry welfare: Trade costs vs. cheap labor By Arijit Mukherjee

More information

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Class Notes on Chaney (2008) Class Notes on Chaney (2008) (With Krugman and Melitz along the Way) Econ 840-T.Holmes Model of Chaney AER (2008) As a first step, let s write down the elements of the Chaney model. asymmetric countries

More information

Trade Costs and Job Flows: Evidence from Establishment-Level Data

Trade Costs and Job Flows: Evidence from Establishment-Level Data Trade Costs and Job Flows: Evidence from Establishment-Level Data Appendix For Online Publication Jose L. Groizard, Priya Ranjan, and Antonio Rodriguez-Lopez March 2014 A A Model of Input Trade and Firm-Level

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Human Capital, Technology Diffusion and Interdependencies

Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Human Capital, Technology Diffusion and Interdependencies 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Human Capital, Technology Diffusion and Interdependencies Daron Acemoglu MIT December 1, 2009. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 11 December 1, 2009. 1 /

More information

International Development and Firm Distribution

International Development and Firm Distribution International Development and Firm Distribution Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis February 2016 1 A. Introduction Conventional macroeconomic models employ aggregate production

More information

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth 14.05 Lecture Notes Endogenous Growth George-Marios Angeletos MIT Department of Economics April 3, 2013 1 George-Marios Angeletos 1 The Simple AK Model In this section we consider the simplest version

More information

Volume 30, Issue 4. A decomposition of the home-market effect

Volume 30, Issue 4. A decomposition of the home-market effect Volume 30, Issue 4 A decomposition of the home-market effect Toru Kikuchi Kobe University Ngo van Long McGill University Abstract Although the home-market effect has become one of the most important concepts

More information

Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade

Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade Klaus Desmet November 2010. Economic () Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade November 2010 1 / 35 Outline 1 The seminal model of economic

More information

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography Increasing Returns and Economic Geography Department of Economics HKUST April 25, 2018 Increasing Returns and Economic Geography 1 / 31 Introduction: From Krugman (1979) to Krugman (1991) The award of

More information

Location, Productivity, and Trade

Location, Productivity, and Trade May 10, 2010 Motivation Outline Motivation - Trade and Location Major issue in trade: How does trade liberalization affect competition? Competition has more than one dimension price competition similarity

More information

Dynamic Selection: An Idea Flows Theory of Entry, Trade and Growth

Dynamic Selection: An Idea Flows Theory of Entry, Trade and Growth Dynamic Selection: An Idea Flows Theory of Entry, Trade and Growth Thomas Sampson London School of Economics June 2014 Abstract This paper develops an idea flows theory of trade and growth with heterogeneous

More information

The Composition of Knowledge and Long-Run Growth

The Composition of Knowledge and Long-Run Growth The Composition of Knowledge and Long-Run Growth Jie Cai Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Nan Li International Monetary Fund 4th Joint WTO-IMF-WB trade workshop, 2015 Jie Cai & Nan Li 1/25

More information

Effects on the cross-country difference in the minimum. wage on international trade, growth and unemployment

Effects on the cross-country difference in the minimum. wage on international trade, growth and unemployment Effects on the cross-country difference in the minimum wage on international trade, growth and unemployment Chihiro Inaba Department of Economics, Kobe University Katsufumi Fukuda Hiroshima University

More information

The Cleansing Effect of R&D Subsidies

The Cleansing Effect of R&D Subsidies The Cleansing Effect of R&D Subsidies Tetsugen Haruyama October 2014 Discussion Paper No.1425 GRDUTE SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS KOBE UNIVERSITY ROKKO, KOBE, JPN The Cleansing Effect of R&D Subsidies Tetsugen

More information

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot Online Theory Appendix Not for Publication) Equilibrium in the Complements-Pareto Case

More information

Competition and Growth in an Endogenous Growth Model with Expanding Product Variety without Scale Effects

Competition and Growth in an Endogenous Growth Model with Expanding Product Variety without Scale Effects MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Competition and Growth in an Endogenous Growth Model with Expanding Product Variety without Scale Effects Dominique Bianco CRP Henri Tudor, University of Nice-Sophia-Antipolis,

More information

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Trading Company and Indirect Exports Trading Company and Indirect Exports Kiyoshi Matsubara June 015 Abstract This article develops an oligopoly model of trade intermediation. In the model, manufacturing firm(s) wanting to export their products

More information

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Transport Costs and North-South Trade Transport Costs and North-South Trade Didier Laussel a and Raymond Riezman b a GREQAM, University of Aix-Marseille II b Department of Economics, University of Iowa Abstract We develop a simple two country

More information

Econ 8401-T.Holmes. Lecture on Foreign Direct Investment. FDI is massive. As noted in Ramondo and Rodriquez-Clare, worldwide sales of multinationals

Econ 8401-T.Holmes. Lecture on Foreign Direct Investment. FDI is massive. As noted in Ramondo and Rodriquez-Clare, worldwide sales of multinationals Econ 8401-T.Holmes Lecture on Foreign Direct Investment FDI is massive. As noted in Ramondo and Rodriquez-Clare, worldwide sales of multinationals is on the order of twice that of total world exports.

More information

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry Lin, Journal of International and Global Economic Studies, 7(2), December 2014, 17-31 17 Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically

More information

The Effects of Regional Free Trade Agreements on Industrial Structure: An Extension of Krugman s Economic Geography Model (1991)

The Effects of Regional Free Trade Agreements on Industrial Structure: An Extension of Krugman s Economic Geography Model (1991) Journal of Economic Integration 18(1), March 003; 4-59 The Effects of Regional Free Trade Agreements on Industrial Structure: An Extension of Krugman s Economic Geography Model (1991) Jung Hur National

More information

Technology, Geography and Trade J. Eaton and S. Kortum. Topics in international Trade

Technology, Geography and Trade J. Eaton and S. Kortum. Topics in international Trade Technology, Geography and Trade J. Eaton and S. Kortum Topics in international Trade 1 Overview 1. Motivation 2. Framework of the model 3. Technology, Prices and Trade Flows 4. Trade Flows and Price Differences

More information

Growth with Time Zone Differences

Growth with Time Zone Differences MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Growth with Time Zone Differences Toru Kikuchi and Sugata Marjit February 010 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/0748/ MPRA Paper No. 0748, posted 17. February

More information

Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies

Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies George Alogoskoufis, International Macroeconomics, 2016 Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies Our analysis up to now was related to small open economies, which took developments

More information

Productivity, Fair Wage and Offshoring Domestic Jobs

Productivity, Fair Wage and Offshoring Domestic Jobs Productivity, Fair Wage and Offshoring Domestic Jobs Xi Chen July 7, 2017 Preliminary draft Abstract This paper develops a general equilibrium model with monopolistic competition that incorporates: (i)

More information

Monopolistic competition: the Dixit-Stiglitz-Spence model

Monopolistic competition: the Dixit-Stiglitz-Spence model Monopolistic competition: the Dixit-Stiglitz-Spence model Frédéric Robert-Nicoud October 23 22 Abstract The workhorse of modern Urban Economics International Trade Economic Growth Macroeconomics you name

More information

Distribution Costs & The Size of Indian Manufacturing Establishments

Distribution Costs & The Size of Indian Manufacturing Establishments Distribution Costs & The Size of Indian Manufacturing Establishments Alessandra Peter, Cian Ruane Stanford University November 3, 2017 Question Selling manufactured goods involves costs of distribution:

More information

International Trade: Lecture 4

International Trade: Lecture 4 International Trade: Lecture 4 Alexander Tarasov Higher School of Economics Fall 2016 Alexander Tarasov (Higher School of Economics) International Trade (Lecture 4) Fall 2016 1 / 34 Motivation Chapter

More information

The heterogeneous effects of trade facilitation: theory and evidence

The heterogeneous effects of trade facilitation: theory and evidence The heterogeneous effects of trade facilitation: theory and evidence Shon Ferguson and Rikard Forslid September 2011, Work in progress Abstract The purpose of this study is to test what type of firms start

More information

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE Macroeconomic Dynamics, (9), 55 55. Printed in the United States of America. doi:.7/s6559895 ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE KEVIN X.D. HUANG Vanderbilt

More information

Trade Volume and Economic Growth

Trade Volume and Economic Growth Trade Volume and Economic Growth Shun-Fa Lee * Department of Industrial Economics, Tamkang University February 014 Abstract Do open economies earn better economic performance than closed economies? The

More information

Tariff Reductions, Entry, and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for the Last Two Decades

Tariff Reductions, Entry, and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for the Last Two Decades Tariff Reductions, Entry, and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for the Last Two Decades Lorenzo Caliendo Yale University and NBER Robert C. Feenstra UC Davis and NBER John Romalis University of Sydney and

More information

Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices

Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices Haichao Fan Amber Li Sichuang Xu Stephen Yeaple Fudan, HKUST, HKUST, Penn State and NBER May 2018 Mark-Ups

More information

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS Bielefeld University phemelo.tamasiga@uni-bielefeld.de 01-July-2013 Agenda 1 Motivation 2 3 4 5 6 Motivation Samuelson (1939);there are gains from trade, consequently

More information

Labor Market Rigidities, Trade and Unemployment

Labor Market Rigidities, Trade and Unemployment Labor Market Rigidities, Trade and Unemployment Elhanan Helpman Harvard and CIFAR Oleg Itskhoki Princeton Chicago Booth May 2011 1 / 30 Motivation Institutional differences as a source of comparative advantage

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model

The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model Wisarut Suwanprasert Vanderbilt University December 206 Abstract I study the impact of the Most Favored Nation (MFN)

More information

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Robert J. Barro 1990 Represented by m.sefidgaran & m.m.banasaz Graduate School of Management and Economics Sharif university of Technology 11/17/2013

More information

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University April 12, 2008 Abstract A model of mixed oligopoly is constructed in which a Home public firm

More information

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 The Ramsey Model Lectures 11 to 14 Topics in Macroeconomics November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008 Lecture 11, 12, 13 & 14 1/50 Topics in Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model: Introduction 2 Main Ingredients Neoclassical

More information

Foreign Direct Investment I

Foreign Direct Investment I FD Foreign Direct nvestment [My notes are in beta. f you see something that doesn t look right, would greatly appreciate a heads-up.] 1 FD background Foreign direct investment FD) occurs when an enterprise

More information

Reallocation Effects in the Specific Factors and Heckscher-Ohlin. Models under Firm Heterogeneity

Reallocation Effects in the Specific Factors and Heckscher-Ohlin. Models under Firm Heterogeneity Reallocation Effects in the Specific Factors and Heckscher-Ohlin Models under Firm Heterogeneity Eddy Bekkers University of Bern Robert Stehrer The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies -

More information

The Dixit-Stiglitz-Krugman Trade Model: A Geometric Note

The Dixit-Stiglitz-Krugman Trade Model: A Geometric Note The Dixit-Stiglitz-Krugman Trade Model: A Geometric Note Toru Kikuchi Abstract In this note, we briefly review the now standard Dixit-Stiglitz- Krugman trade model of monopolistic competition. Furthermore,

More information

Optimal Redistribution in an Open Economy

Optimal Redistribution in an Open Economy Optimal Redistribution in an Open Economy Oleg Itskhoki Harvard University Princeton University January 8, 2008 1 / 29 How should society respond to increasing inequality? 2 / 29 How should society respond

More information

Micro to Macro: Optimal Trade Policy with Firm Heterogeneity

Micro to Macro: Optimal Trade Policy with Firm Heterogeneity Micro to Macro: Optimal Trade Policy with Firm Heterogeneity Arnaud Costinot, Andrés Rodríguez-Clare, Ivan Werning MIT, UC Berkeley, MIT March 29th, 2017 Optimal Policy in New Trade Models March 29th,

More information

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters

The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem when the Labor Market Structure Matters A. Kerem Coşar Davide Suverato kerem.cosar@chicagobooth.edu davide.suverato@econ.lmu.de University of Chicago Booth School of Business

More information

Melitz Model: Heterogenous Firm Model of Trade

Melitz Model: Heterogenous Firm Model of Trade Melitz Model: Heterogenous Firm Model of Trade Seyed Ali Madanizadeh Sharif U. of Tech. May 7, 2014 Seyed Ali Madanizadeh (Sharif U. of Tech.) Melitz Model: Heterogenous Firm Model of Trade May 7, 2014

More information

Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Welfare Consequences of Globalization

Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Welfare Consequences of Globalization Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Welfare Consequences of Globalization Andrés Rodríguez-Clare (UC Berkeley and NBER) September 29, 2012 The Armington Model The Armington Model CES preferences:

More information

Trade and Labor Market: Felbermayr, Prat, Schmerer (2011)

Trade and Labor Market: Felbermayr, Prat, Schmerer (2011) Trade and Labor Market: Felbermayr, Prat, Schmerer (2011) Davide Suverato 1 1 LMU University of Munich Topics in International Trade, 16 June 2015 Davide Suverato, LMU Trade and Labor Market: Felbermayr,

More information

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

Oil Monopoly and the Climate Oil Monopoly the Climate By John Hassler, Per rusell, Conny Olovsson I Introduction This paper takes as given that (i) the burning of fossil fuel increases the carbon dioxide content in the atmosphere,

More information

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing Ming-Jen Chang, Shikuan Chen and Yen-Chen Wu National DongHwa University Thursday 22 nd November 2018 Department of Economics,

More information

From Solow to Romer: Teaching Endogenous Technological Change in Undergraduate Economics

From Solow to Romer: Teaching Endogenous Technological Change in Undergraduate Economics MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive From Solow to Romer: Teaching Endogenous Technological Change in Undergraduate Economics Angus C. Chu Fudan University March 2015 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/81972/

More information

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics Chapter 11 AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics The simplest model featuring fully-endogenous exponential per capita growth is what is known as the AK model. Jones

More information

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment Goal: Endogenize firm characteristics and risk. Value/growth Size Leverage New issues,... This lecture: q theory of investment Irreversible investment and real

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ). ECON 8040 Final exam Lastrapes Fall 2007 Answer all eight questions on this exam. 1. Write out a static model of the macroeconomy that is capable of predicting that money is non-neutral. Your model should

More information

Reallocation Effects in the Specific Factors and Heckscher-Ohlin. Models under Firm Heterogeneity

Reallocation Effects in the Specific Factors and Heckscher-Ohlin. Models under Firm Heterogeneity Reallocation Effects in the Specific Factors and Heckscher-Ohlin Models under Firm Heterogeneity Eddy Bekkers Johannes Kepler University Linz Robert Stehrer The Vienna Institute for International Economic

More information

A Two-sector Ramsey Model

A Two-sector Ramsey Model A Two-sector Ramsey Model WooheonRhee Department of Economics Kyung Hee University E. Young Song Department of Economics Sogang University C.P.O. Box 1142 Seoul, Korea Tel: +82-2-705-8696 Fax: +82-2-705-8180

More information

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation Fujisaki Seiya and Mino Kazuo Institute of Economic Research, Kyoto University 20. October 2010

More information

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics 202: Dynamic Macroeconomics Solow Model Mausumi Das Delhi School of Economics January 14-15, 2015 Das (Delhi School of Economics) Dynamic Macro January 14-15, 2015 1 / 28 Economic Growth In this course

More information

Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development. H. Uzawa. Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan. (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting)

Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development. H. Uzawa. Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan. (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting) Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development H. Uzawa Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting) In this paper, we prove in terms of the prototype model of

More information

NOT FOR PUBLICATION. Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome. Small Open Economy Model

NOT FOR PUBLICATION. Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome. Small Open Economy Model NOT FOR PUBLICATION Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome Small Open Economy Model In this appendix, we develop a general equilibrium model of how increased import competition from China affects employment

More information

Growth Effects of the Allocation of Government Expenditure in an Endogenous Growth Model with Physical and Human Capital

Growth Effects of the Allocation of Government Expenditure in an Endogenous Growth Model with Physical and Human Capital Growth Effects of the Allocation of Government Expenditure in an Endogenous Growth Model with Physical and Human Capital Christine Achieng Awiti The growth effects of government expenditure is a topic

More information

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics PhD Topics in Macroeconomics Lecture 16: heterogeneous firms and trade, part four Chris Edmond 2nd Semester 214 1 This lecture Trade frictions in Ricardian models with heterogeneous firms 1- Dornbusch,

More information

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS) ECO 521 Fall 216 TAKE-HOME EXAM The exam is due at 9AM Thursday, January 19, preferably by electronic submission to both sims@princeton.edu and moll@princeton.edu. Paper submissions are allowed, and should

More information

International Trade: Lecture 3

International Trade: Lecture 3 International Trade: Lecture 3 Alexander Tarasov Higher School of Economics Fall 2016 Alexander Tarasov (Higher School of Economics) International Trade (Lecture 3) Fall 2016 1 / 36 The Krugman model (Krugman

More information

International Economics: Lecture 10 & 11

International Economics: Lecture 10 & 11 International Economics: Lecture 10 & 11 International Economics: Lecture 10 & 11 Trade, Technology and Geography Xiang Gao School of International Business Administration Shanghai University of Finance

More information

Export Subsidies and Oligopoly with Switching Costs

Export Subsidies and Oligopoly with Switching Costs Export Subsidies and Oligopoly with Switching Costs Theodore To September 1993 Abstract I examine export policy using a two-period model of oligopolistic competition with switching costs. A switching costs

More information

A Model of Trade with Ricardian Comparative Advantage and Intra-sectoral Firm Heterogeneity

A Model of Trade with Ricardian Comparative Advantage and Intra-sectoral Firm Heterogeneity A Model of Trade with Ricardian Comparative Advantage and Intra-sectoral Firm Heterogeneity Haichao FAN Edwin L.-C. LAI Han QI December 24, 20 Abstract In this paper, we merge the heterogenous firm trade

More information

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade. Product Di erentiation Introduction We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade. Now we see how product di erentiation can provide a basis for trade due to consumers valuing

More information

Proximity vs Comparative Advantage: A Quantitative Theory of Trade and Multinational Production

Proximity vs Comparative Advantage: A Quantitative Theory of Trade and Multinational Production Proximity vs Comparative Advantage: A Quantitative Theory of Trade and Multinational Production Costas Arkolakis, Natalia Ramondo, Andres Rodriguez-Clare, Stephen Yeaple June 2011 Motivation WSJ (April

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Chapter 11 AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. In his Chapter 11 Acemoglu discusses simple fully-endogenous growth models in the form of Ramsey-style AK and reduced-form AK models, respectively.

More information

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017] Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017] 1. A tax is to be levied on a commodity bought and sold in a competitive market. Two possible forms of tax may be used: In one case, a per unit tax

More information

Entry on Export Markets and Firm-Level Performance Growth: Intra-Industrial Convergence or Divergence?

Entry on Export Markets and Firm-Level Performance Growth: Intra-Industrial Convergence or Divergence? Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Working Papers -7-20 Entry on Export Markets and Firm-Level Performance Growth: Intra-Industrial Convergence or Divergence? Florian Mayneris CORE, florian.mayneris@uclouvain.be

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TARIFF REDUCTIONS, ENTRY, AND WELFARE: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FOR THE LAST TWO DECADES

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TARIFF REDUCTIONS, ENTRY, AND WELFARE: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FOR THE LAST TWO DECADES NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TARIFF REDUCTIONS, ENTRY, AND WELFARE: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FOR THE LAST TWO DECADES Lorenzo Caliendo Robert C. Feenstra John Romalis Alan M. Taylor Working Paper 21768 http://www.nber.org/papers/w21768

More information

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Part A (Prof. Laibson): 60 minutes Part B (Prof. Barro): 60

More information

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership Attila Tasnádi Department of Mathematics, Budapest University of Economic Sciences and Public Administration, H-1093 Budapest, Fővám tér 8, Hungary

More information

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Trading Company and Indirect Exports Trading Company and Indirect Exports Kiyoshi atsubara August 0 Abstract This article develops an oligopoly model of trade intermediation. In the model, two manufacturing firms that want to export their

More information

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomics, 2016 Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model The representative household model is a dynamic general equilibrium model, based on the assumption that the

More information

Economic Determinants of Free Trade Agreements Revisited: Distinguishing Sources of Interdependence

Economic Determinants of Free Trade Agreements Revisited: Distinguishing Sources of Interdependence Economic Determinants of Free Trade Agreements Revisited: Distinguishing Sources of Interdependence Scott L. Baier, Jeffrey H. Bergstrand, Ronald Mariutto December 20, 2011 Abstract One of the most notable

More information

Patterns of Technology, Industry Concentration, and. Productivity Growth Without Scale Effects

Patterns of Technology, Industry Concentration, and. Productivity Growth Without Scale Effects Patterns of Technology, Industry Concentration, and Productivity Growth Without Scale Effects Colin Davis Doshisha University Ken-ichi Hashimoto Kobe University June, 2011 Abstract This paper investigates

More information