A ROBUST MODEL OF BUBBLES WITH MULTIDIMENSIONAL UNCERTAINTY. ANTONIO DOBLAS-MADRID Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI 48824, U.S.A.

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A ROBUST MODEL OF BUBBLES WITH MULTIDIMENSIONAL UNCERTAINTY. ANTONIO DOBLAS-MADRID Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI 48824, U.S.A."

Transcription

1 Econometrica, Vol. 80, No. 5 (September, 2012), A ROBUST MODEL OF BUBBLES WITH MULTIDIMENSIONAL UNCERTAINTY ANTONIO DOBLAS-MADRID Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI 48824, U.S.A. The copyright to this Article is held by the Econometric Society. It may be downloaded, printed and reproduced only for educational or research purposes, including use in course packs. No downloading or copying may be done for any commercial purpose without the explicit permission of the Econometric Society. For such commercial purposes contact the Office of the Econometric Society (contact information may be found at the website or in the back cover of Econometrica). This statement must be included on all copies of this Article that are made available electronically or in any other format.

2 Econometrica, Vol. 80, No. 5 (September, 2012), A ROBUST MODEL OF BUBBLES WITH MULTIDIMENSIONAL UNCERTAINTY BY ANTONIO DOBLAS-MADRID 1 Observers often interpret boom bust episodes in asset markets as speculative frenzies where asymmetrically informed investors buy overvalued assets hoping to sell to a greater fool before the crash. Despite its intuitive appeal, however, this notion of speculative bubbles has proven difficult to reconcile with economic theory. Existing models have been criticized on the basis that they assume irrationality, that prices are somewhat unresponsive to sales, or that they depend on fragile, knife-edge restrictions. To address these issues, I construct a rational version of Abreu and Brunnermeier (2003), where agents invest growing endowments into an asset, fueling appreciation and eventual overvaluation. Riding bubbles is optimal as long as the growth rate of the bubble and the probability of selling before the crash are high enough. This probability increases with the amount of noise in the economy, as random short-term fluctuations make it difficult for agents to infer information from prices. KEYWORDS: Bubbles, coordination, noisy prices. 1. INTRODUCTION OVER THE LAST TWO DECADES, a series of dramatic boom bust episodes in global asset markets have led many economists to question the long dominant efficient market hypothesis and to devote increasing attention to theories of asset price bubbles. Asset price bubbles are often referred to as speculative bubbles, a term that conjures the idea of a market timing game, in which investors buy overvalued assets hoping to sell to a greater fool before the crash. This idea comes up repeatedly, for example, in Kindleberger and Aliber s (2005)famous chronicles of historical boom bust episodes. There is also experimental work (Moinas and Pouget (2009)) documenting the emergence of bubbles in a design with asymmetrically informed participants who ride the bubble knowing that they may earn speculative profits by riding the bubble, but also that they may suffer losses if they get stuck with the asset at the end of the game. Despite its intuitive appeal, however, this notion of a speculative bubble has traditionally been difficult to reconcile with standard economic theory. As Tirole (1982) and Milgrom and Stokey (1982) showed, bubbles are inconsistent with rational expectations equilibrium in a wide range of environments with finite numbers of rational agents, even under asymmetric information. Some approaches that have been taken to circumvent these impossibility results include introducing some form of irrationality, assuming heterogeneous 1 This paper has greatly benefited from comments by Luis Araujo, Braz Camargo, John Conlon, Thomas Jeitschko, Timothy Kehoe, Andreas Park, Francisco Peñaranda, Juan Rubio-Ramírez, and Jean Tirole, as well as by a co-editor and three anonymous referees. I am also indebted to participants in various seminars and conferences for helpful comments and suggestions. All errors are my own The Econometric Society DOI: /ECTA7887

3 1846 ANTONIO DOBLAS-MADRID priors or marginal utilities, and assuming an infinite number of overlapping generations. For example, Harrison and Kreps (1978) and Scheinkman and Xiong (2003) considered agents who are overconfident in the sense that they consider their own information to be superior to that of others, and fail to fully adjust their beliefs as they observe what others believe. In Abreu and Brunnermeier (2003), there are rational agents who ride the bubble and make profits with a certain probability along with behavioral agents who fuel bubble growth and who are doomed to suffer losses in the crash. In Allen, Morris, and Postlewaite (1993)and Conlon (2004), agents are rational, but have either heterogenous priors or heterogenous state-contingent marginal utilities that may give rise to gains from trade. This approach generates speculative bubbles, but has the drawback of relying on fragile, knife-edge parameter restrictions. Another strand of literature (Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2006),Fahri and Tirole (2012), and others) builds on Tirole s (1985) workonrationalbubbles with overlapping generations, where bubbles like money in Samuelson (1958) improve allocations by alleviating a shortage of stores of value. However, the bubbles in these models are less reminiscent of speculation. Trades are typically driven by the life cycle rather than beliefs, and the focus is often on steady states where bubbles grow slowly and never burst. 2 The aim of this paper is to contribute to the theory of speculation by developing a model of a greater fool s bubble that circumvents some of the main critiques of previous studies. To this end, I construct a discrete-time version of Abreu and Brunnermeier (2003; henceforth referred to as AB), where all agents are rational and prices reflect supply and demand at all times. The model inherits from AB the property of being robust to small changes in parameters, and is therefore not subject to the fragility critique of Allen, Morris, and Postlewaite (1993)andConlon (2004). Following AB, I model a bubble as a market overreaction to events that are initially fundamental in nature. An asset price boom is at first justified by fundamentals, but a bubble emerges as growth continues past the point where real gains have been priced in. I also borrow from AB the assumption that the time when the bubble starts is not perfectly observed. Instead, for a number of periods, different agents observe private overvaluation signals, which reveal that a bubble has begun. Since agents do not know when others observe the signal, they make probabilistic assessments about when the bubble and hence the signals may have started. They understand that those who received signals relatively early will make profits, while others will suffer losses in the crash. However, if the chances of being an early-signal agent and the speed at which the bubble grows are high enough, it is optimal to take a risk and ride the bubble. 2 Further approaches to bubbles focus on agency problems (Allen and Gorton (1993), Allen andgale (2000), Barlevy (2008), AcharyaandNaqvi (2012)), solvency constraints (Kocherlakota (2008)), and others. For a survey, see Brunnermeier (2001).

4 A ROBUST MODEL OF BUBBLES 1847 While these core ideas are the same as in AB, I modify the environment so as to address the two critiques of irrationality and of partial disconnect between sales and prices. In AB, bubble growth is fueled by behavioral agents who invest growing amounts into a risky asset and are willing to do so indefinitely. These agents are doomed to get caught in the crash, which occurs when a critical mass of rational agents exit the market. By contrast, in this paper, there are no behavioral agents. The bubble is fueled by rational agents who invest in it as long as it is optimal to do so. Agents receive growing endowments, which they can use to buy the risky asset. Importantly, these endowments cannot be pledged as collateral, that is, agents cannot borrow against their time-t endowment at some earlier date s<t. Borrowing constraints limit the amounts that agents can use to bid up the risky asset. Thus, the price does not reflect agents private valuations given by their best guesses about fundamentals plus the value of the chance to sell at the peak of the bubble. Instead, the price simply reflects the maximum resources that agents are able to invest at each date. This also has the important implication that the boom, instead of consisting of a one-time jump in the price, takes place gradually over time as investors access larger endowments. I also assume that, every period, preference shocks force a fraction θ t of agents to sell for reasons such as life events or liquidity needs unrelated to price expectations. This ensures that a positive mass of shares is sold every period, even when nobody expects an imminent crash. 3 Preference shocks also serve another function, adding noise to the economy. Because θ t is subject to random variability, prices are noisy. If the variability of θ t is high enough, prices can hide sales, as late-signal agents cannot distinguish price slowdowns due to sales by early-signal agents from those due to high realization of θ t.thus, the likelihood that an agent can sell before the crash tends to increase with the variability of θ t. The second critique is that prices in AB are somewhat independent of sales. During the time interval when a growing mass of early-signal agents is leaving the market, the price is assumed to continue to grow at the same rate as if nobody was selling. 4 To address this, I explicitly model market clearing and price formation. I model the asset market as a Shapley Shubik trading post. In a first stage, agents submit orders to buy the risky asset (bidding a risk-free asset) or submit shares of the risky asset for sale. In a second stage, all orders are combined, and the price emerges as the ratio of the risk-free asset bid to the amount of the risky asset sold. 3 Note that the preference shock is not a substitute for irrational agents, since it does not force agents to stay in the market during the crash. On the contrary, it forces some agents to sell before they otherwise would. 4 AB conjectured, in a remark, that adding noise to the price process would allow prices to respond to supply and demand at all times without revealing all private information.

5 1848 ANTONIO DOBLAS-MADRID To solve the model, I first consider the case with so little noise that as soon as one type sells (a type includes all those who observe the overvaluation signal in the same period), all uncertainty is revealed, triggering a crash in the next period. In this case without noise, the effect of the first type s sales on the price is always greater than the effect of any possible random fluctuation in θ t. I show that in this effectively noiseless environment, a no-bubble equilibrium in which agents sell as soon as they observe the signal always exists. The no-bubble equilibrium is unique if G/R, the growth rate of the bubble net of the riskfree rate, is below a threshold Γ. This threshold depends on λ, the parameter governing the relative likelihoods of early versus late overvaluation signals. As G/R rises above Γ, the set of equilibria expands to include, in addition to the no-bubble equilibrium, equilibria with bubbles. The duration of the bubbles ranges from zero to a maximum that is a function of G/R and λ. I continue the analysis by increasing the amount of noise so that it can conceal sales of one type, but not more. This allows multiple types to sell before the crash, since sales of the first type can be confused with noise and thus may fail to burst the bubble. In this case, prices reflect selling pressure monotonically, but reveal information only imperfectly. When noise can hide sales by one type, but not two, prices fall into one of three categories. High prices reveal with certainty that nobody has sold, medium prices reveal that sales may or may not have begun, and low prices reveal with certainty that sales have begun, thereby triggering the crash. If the number of types is large, the analysis of equilibria with Markov strategies is simple enough to be analytically tractable. The strategies I consider are Markovian, in the sense that agents sell-or-wait choices depend only on how much time has passed since observing the signal and on whether the last price observed was high, medium, or low. Restricting attention to this class of strategies, I show that there are two key ways in which noise helps generate bubbles. First, in the noisy case, it is possible to rule out equilibria without bubbles for high enough G/R. Second, there exist parameters such that, with noise, (arbitrarily) long bubbles may arise, even if G/R is below Γ. In other words, there exist parameters such that in the noiseless case, the only equilibrium is the one without bubbles, while in the noisy case, arbitrarily long bubbles may arise. Finally, I relax the assumption made in the basic analysis for simplicity that agents cannot reenter the market after selling and show that although some equilibria vanish, the overall picture remains unchanged, and bubbles with Markovian strategies still arise. The paper is organized as follows. In Sections 2 and 3, respectively, I describe the model and define equilibrium. In Section 4, I illustrate how bubbles arise in equilibrium. In Section 5, I consider the extension where agents may reenter the market after selling. Section 6 concludes.

6 A ROBUST MODEL OF BUBBLES THE MODEL 2.1. The Environment Time is discrete and infinite with periods labeled t = There are two assets: a risk-free asset with exogenous gross return R>1andarisky asset. At all times, the risk-free asset can be turned into consumption at a one to one rate. The supply of the risky asset is fixed at 1, and its price at time t is p t units of the risk-free asset. As in AB, the risky asset s fundamental value f t is based on dividends to be paid in the distant future, with current dividends set equal to zero for convenience. While t 0, the expected value of future dividends, discounted at the risk-free rate, is αr t. The fundamental value f t and price p t also equal αr t in expectation. At t = 1, fundamental shocks increase the risky asset s expected future dividends. The fundamental value f t and price p t begin to grow, on average, at the rate G>R. Booming prices are justified by fundamentals until period t = t 0 1, but starting at time t 0 1, the average f t /f t 1 falls back to R, andifp t continues to grow on average at the rate G, p t starts to diverge from f t, that is, a bubble arises. The bubble inflates until period T t 0 and bursts at T + 1, at which point equality between price and fundamental value is restored. Thus, as in AB, bubbles arise as markets overreact to events that are at first fundamental. 5 The first period of overvaluation t 0 is geometrically distributed with probability function ϕ given by (1) ϕ(t 0 ) = ( e λ 1 ) e λt 0 for all t 0 = 1 2 where λ>0. The expected value of t 0 is given by 1/(1 e λ ). There is a unit mass of rational agents indexed by i [0 1]. Theydonot observe t 0 perfectly. Instead, every period from t 0 to t 0 + N 1 a mass 1/N of them observe a signal revealing that the risky asset is overvalued. In other words, the signal reveals that f t is no longer growing at the rate G. Signals define N types, n = t 0 t 0 + N 1. Formally, ν : [0 1] {t 0 t 0 + N 1} assigns a type to each agent, where ν(i) = n denotes that agent i is of type n or, in other words, that agent i observes the signal at time n. As in AB, agents observe n, butnott 0. Once an agent observes her signal at time n, sheknows that t 0 may have been as early as n (N 1) or as late as n. (Except for the special case with t 0 <N, where types with n<n know that t 0 must be above 5 According to Kindleberger and Aliber (2005), bubbles often occur in the aftermath of major displacements, which cause large shifts in prices. Price movements that are justified by fundamentals for some time turn into bubbles if markets overshoot. In keeping with this idea, AB mentioned episodes in stock markets after the arrival of new technologies (e.g., the Internet in the 1990s, the radio in the 1920s) as examples of bubbles.

7 1850 ANTONIO DOBLAS-MADRID n (N 1), sincen (N 1) 0.) Conditional on n, the distribution of t 0 becomes e λt 0 ϕ(t 0 n) = e λ(max{1 n (N 1)}) + +e λn (2) if max { 1 n (N 1) } t 0 n 0 otherwise Sequential arrival of signals places agents along a line, but they are uncertain about their relative order in the line. This plays a key role in generating bubbles, as all agents even those late in the line assign positive probability to the event that they could be early in the line. 6 As we will see later, signals are the key reference points on which agents condition their equilibrium selling strategies. In the absence of noise, type-n agents will plan to ride the bubble for τ 0 periods and sell at time n + τ 0.When prices are noisy, strategies will be augmented to allow agents to wait longer if they observe higher prices. Figure 1 summarizes the assumptions made thus far. The boom starting at t = 1 is at first fundamental, but turns into a bubble at the imperfectly observed time t 0, with signals arriving at t = t 0 t 0 + N 1. Bubble duration T t 0 will be endogenously determined in equilibrium. Preferences are characterized by risk neutrality and preference shocks à la Diamond and Dybvig (1983), which force agents to liquidate assets and consume. At time t, a randomly chosen mass θ t (0 1) of agents are hit by a shock FIGURE 1. Timeline of events. 6 One could also assume that some agents receive no signal. These agents would find themselves in a situation similar, but not identical, to that of agents who know that they will observe a signal but have not yet observed it. As we will see when solving the model, agents who have yet to observe the signal are less inclined to sell preemptively than agents who have observed it. In fact, the agents whose choices set limits on bubble duration are those whose signal arrives just one period after the agents who sell at the peak. Given this, introducing agents who do not observe signals would add complications to the analysis without affecting results.

8 A ROBUST MODEL OF BUBBLES 1851 that sets their discount factor δ i t equal to zero. The remaining mass 1 θ t have δ i t = 1/R.Agenti s expected utility is defined as (3) E i t [ U ( {ci τ } τ=t )] = Ei t [ c i t + ( τ 1 τ=t+1 s=t ) δ i s c i τ ] where c i t denotes agent i s time-t consumption, U denotes utility, and E i t denotes expectation given information available to agent i in period t. This information includes whether δ i t is zero, in which case (3) reduces to E i t c i t. Preference shocks induce an urgent need to consume, but do not represent the agent s death. After being hit, agents continue to receive endowments and can be hit again. To simplify, shocks are assumed to be independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.), so that the probability that δ i t = 0 is independent of past values δ i t 2 δ i t 1 ; that is, agents who have not been hit for a long time are no more likely to be hit than those who were recently hit. Shocks are also type-independent, in the sense that for all t, and within any type, the fraction of agents hit by the shock is θ t. Since θ t is unobservable, agent i knows whether she has been hit by the shock, but not how many agents have been hit. Moreover, θ t varies over time as (4) θ t = θ + ε t where θ (0 1) is a constant and ε t is an i.i.d. random variable uniformly distributed over [ ε ε], with0< ε <min{ θ 1 θ}. The term ε t serves an important function in the model by generating random price fluctuations. If θ t is constant, as soon as the first agents sell in anticipation of the crash, the price reveals these sales, precipitating a crash. In a noisy environment, by contrast, agents cannot distinguish whether a price deceleration is due to a high ε t or the start of the crash. It is important to note that the role of preference shocks is precisely to generate a positive and noisy amount of sales. The role of the shock is not to make speculation a positive sum game by forcing some agents to stay in the market and get caught in the crash. On the contrary, the shock saves some agents from the crash by forcing them to sell. The boom is fueled by agents investing endowments into the risky asset. Every period, agents receive e t > 0 units of the risk-free asset. As long as they do not anticipate an impending crash and are not hit by the shock, they invest the endowment into the risky asset. Endowments cannot be capitalized, that is, an

9 1852 ANTONIO DOBLAS-MADRID agent receiving e t at t cannot borrow against it at earlier dates s<t. After time 0, endowment growth accelerates as 7 (5) { Rt if t 0, e t = G t if t>0. Three remarks are in order. First, the assumption that e t grows at the rate G forever should not be interpreted literally. In the long run, endowment growth must eventually slow down. Limits to endowment growth are not modeled, however, because the focus of the paper is on endogenous crashes, where agents sales burst the bubble before growth decelerates for exogenous reasons. 8 Second, AB also assumed that rational agents are constrained and fully invested in the bubble. 9 However, in AB the inflow of funds that fuels bubble growth is dumb money from behavioral agents who are doomed to suffer losses. Here, rational agents invest in the bubble only as long as it is optimal to do so. The third remark is that an alternative specification with constant θ t and noisy aggregate endowment would also generate fluctuations in price, but notintradingvolume. The within-period timing of shocks and actions is as follows. Agent i starts period t with nonnegative holdings b i t and h i t of the risk-free and risky assets, respectively. The period proceeds in two steps. In Step 1, agent i receives e t, learns whether δ i t is zero or 1/R, and,ifν(i) = t, observes her signal. Also in Step 1, agent i knowing δ i t, p t 1 ={ p t 2 p t 1 } and, if ν(i) t, the 7 Endowment growth captures the idea that as a bubble grows, the availability of funds that can be invested into it also grows. Two interpretations of this increasing availability of resources were suggested by Kindleberger and Aliber (2005), who saw expanding credit and the arrival of new investors as usual sources of bubble fuel. Regarding the first interpretation, risky assets such as stocks and especially real estate are typically more pledgeable as collateral than labor income/endowments, because unlike human capital, risky assets can be seized and sold by lenders. If the risky asset serves as collateral, price growth loosens credit constraints, allowing investors to borrow more and bid prices even higher. The other interpretation gradual arrival of investors may reflect liberalization of capital flows into a country or industry, or it may reflect technological factors that prevent agents from investing all their wealth into the risky asset at time 1. For example, in the short run, some wealth may be tied up in projects that can only be liquidated at a heavy loss. In such a setting, funds would become progressively available as projects matured. 8 A similar issue arises in AB, where behavioral agents are assumed able to purchase a given number of shares of the risky asset no matter how high the price becomes. The price in AB may become arbitrarily large because, although there is an exogenous cap on bubble duration, the distribution of t 0 is not bounded. 9 Note that borrowing constraints depress fundamental values for t {1 t 0 2}. During these periods, expected fundamental value f t is αg t, since agents cannot afford to pay α(g/r) t0 1 R t, the present value of future dividends discounted at the rate R.Fromperiodt 0 1 onward, agents can afford to pay this, and the fundamental value becomes α(g/r) t0 1 R t ;that is, borrowing constraints depress fundamental values in the early phase of the boom. However, when agents start to observe signals and knowingly ride the bubble, borrowing constraints continue to bind, since agents view the risky asset as valuable, not only because of its dividends, but also because of the chance to sell at the top of the bubble.

10 A ROBUST MODEL OF BUBBLES 1853 signal chooses actions a i t = (m i t s i t χ i t ).Thepair(m i t s i t ) captures asset market choices, and χ i t [0 1] captures the consumption choice. (Although agents consume in Step 2, the decision to consume is driven by the preference shock, which is known in Step 1.) The asset market is modeled as a Shapley Shubik trading post, where each agent i bids m i t units of the risk-free asset and offers s i t shares of the risky asset for sale. Due to borrowing/short sales constraints, agent i s choices must satisfy (6) 0 m i t b i t + e t and (7) 0 s i t h i t Agent i chooses (m i t s i t ) before knowing the price p t, which will be determined in Step 2 when all bids and offers are combined. 10 Preference shocks and risk neutrality greatly simplify decision problems. Agents with δ i t = 0 sell everything so as to consume in Step 2, that is, they set (m i t s i t ) = (0 h i t ). Agents with δ i t = 1/R sell, setting (m i t s i t ) = (0 h i t ), if they expect the risky asset s return p t+1 /p t to be less than R; they buy, setting (m i t s i t ) = (b i t + e t 0), if the expected return is greater than R, and they are indifferent between buying, selling, and doing nothing in the knife-edge case. 11 Agent i comes out of the asset market holding (8) and h i t+1 = h i t + m i t p t s i t (9) b i t = b i t + e t m i t + p t s i t where b i t denotes agent i s within-period or interim risk-free asset holdings. In Step 2, bids and offers are combined and the price is determined by market clearing: (10) h i t di = 1 i [0 1] 10 The assumption that agents submit orders before observing others orders or the price is similar to Kyle (1985) and also to models à la Cournot. In microstructure terms, agents are placing market orders, which they know will be executed, but they do not know at what price. 11 Although individual agents within a type hold different amounts of the risky asset, they all buy/sell it in lockstep (except for agents who are forced by the shock to sell). This is a consequence of risk neutrality and of the fact that all agents within a type observe the same signal.

11 1854 ANTONIO DOBLAS-MADRID Substituting (8) into (10), noting that (10) alsoholdsattimet + 1, and solving for the price yields p t = M t (11) S t where for all t, (12) M t i [0 1] m i t di and S t s i t di; i [0 1] that is, the price is the ratio of the amount of the riskless asset bid to the number of shares of the risky asset offered for sale. Since there is always a positive mass of shock-induced sellers, S t is always positive and p t is well defined. Finally, agent i consumes a fraction χ i t [0 1] of b i t, (13) c i t = χ i t bi t and saves the rest, so that next period s risk-free asset holdings b i t+1 are given by (14) b i t+1 = R(1 χ i t ) b i t Figure 2 summarizes within-period timing. Having described market clearing, we can now fill in details about the preboom, boom and post-crash phases. Before proceeding, however, it will be useful to assume that even if the boom is not anticipated the risky asset is valuable enough to absorb agents entire wealth in the pre-boom phase. This makes it (weakly) optimal for agents to hold b i t = 0whilet 0. In turn, this implies FIGURE 2. Within-period timing.

12 A ROBUST MODEL OF BUBBLES 1855 that price growth accelerates at t = 1, but there is no additional one-time jump in price. 12 With this assumption in place, consider now a pre-boom period t 0, and let agents start with b i t = 0 units of the risk-free asset. Preference shocks force a mass θ t of agents to sell S t = θ t shares of the risky asset, while all other agents use their endowments to bid for these shares. Since b i t is zero, M t = (1 θ t )e t and thus (15) p t = ( θ 1 t 1 ) e t Since the expected p t+1 /p t is R, agents who are not hit by the shock find it (weakly) optimal to invest only in the risky asset, letting b i t+1 = 0. Agents who are hit by the shock consume c i t = b i t = e t + p t h i t and save nothing, setting (b i t+1 h i t+1 ) = (0 0). Given(15) and the assumption that p t αe t in the preboom and boom phases, it must be that (16) α = E [ θ 1 t 1 ] = 1 2 ε ε ε [ ( θ + ε t ) 1 1 ] dε t = ln(( θ + ε)/( θ ε)) 1 2 ε At t = 1, endowment and price growth accelerate. For a while, the only sales are the ones that are forced by shocks. Agents who are not hit remain fully invested in the risky asset, and p t is given by (15) withe t = G t.sinceshocks are type-independent, in the aggregate, each type holds h n t = 1/N shares of the risky asset, where for all n {t 0 t 0 + N 1} and for all t, (17) h n t h i t di {i ν(i)=n} All N types hold h n t = 1/N shares until the last few periods of the boom, when some start to sell in anticipation of the crash. When the first z t > 0 types sell at t, the mass of shares for sale becomes S t = z t /N + θ t (1 z t /N),whereamass z t /N of agents sell, anticipating a crash, and a mass θ t (1 z t /N) of agents sell because of preference shocks. Total bids M t amount to (1 θ t )(1 z t /N)G t, 12 If the risky asset during the pre-boom phase is not valuable enough to absorb all of the agents wealth, agents accumulate shares of the risk-free asset before the boom starts. They pour these holdings into the risky asset once the boom begins, causing a price jump at time 1, followed by some time where the price grows at the rate R. Once holdings of risk-free asset reach zero, borrowing constraints bind again and the price grows at the rate G. As long as the time it takes for the risk-free holdings to reach zero is not too long, relative to the expected duration of the boom, it is possible to incorporate these additional dynamics into the analysis without affecting results.

13 1856 ANTONIO DOBLAS-MADRID as only agents who are not hit by the shock and are not of the exiting types buy. Consequently, the price becomes ([ ( zt p t = N + θ t 1 z )] 1 t (18) 1) G t N After trade, h n t+1 is 0 for the z t types who have sold and 1/(1 z t /N) for the other types. Agents hit by the shock consume the proceeds from selling the risky asset. Those who sold without being hit store their wealth in the risk-free asset, setting b i t+1 = R b i t. The likelihood that p t reveals the exit of these z t types depends on the relative magnitudes of ε and z t /N.If ε<(1 θ)z t /(2N z t ), sales will surely be revealed, because (( θ+ ε) 1 1)G t the lowest possible price if z t = 0 exceeds ([z t /N + ( θ ε)(1 z t /N)] 1 1)G t the highest possible price if z t types sell. However, if ε (1 θ)z t /(2N z t ), p t may be greater than or equal to (( θ + ε) 1 1)G t, in which case the bubble will continue until period t + 1. If the bubble survives period t and another z t+1 0typessellatt + 1, the aggregate bid becomes M t+1 = (1 θ t+1 )(1 (z t + z t+1 )/N)G t On the selling side, z t+1 /N sellers anticipate a crash and θ t+1 (1 (z t + z t+1 )/N) sellers are strictly shock-induced. Since risky-asset holdings across sellers average 1/(1 z t /N), the total mass of shares for sale equals [ S t+1 = 1 z ] 1 ( ( t zt+1 N N + θ t+1 1 z )) t + z t+1 N Rearranging terms, the equilibrium price can be written as ( p t+1 = 1 z ) t 1 z t N (19) N ( z t+1 N + θ t+1 1 z ) 1 t + z t+1 Gt+1 N The likelihood that p t+1 /G t+1 falls below (( θ + ε) 1 1) now depends on ε, z t, and z t+1.ifp t+1 /G t+1 falls below this threshold, sales will be revealed, causing a crash; otherwise, the bubble will last until time t + 2 or later. Equation (19) can be generalized to allow sales over more than two periods. 14 However, since in the equilibria analyzed later, sales burst the bubble in one or two periods, (19) lays all the groundwork necessary for our purposes. 13 M t+1 and S t+1 would be different for negative z t+1 (i.e., if some types reentered the market after selling). I restrict attention to z t+1 0, because although reentry is allowed in Section 5, it does not actually happen in equilibrium. 14 If sales start at t 0andz t z t+h 0 types sell at times t t+ h,thepricep t+h is given by (19), replacing (θ t+1 G t+1 z t+1 ) with (θ t+h G t+h z t+h ) and z t with z t + +z t+h 1.

14 A ROBUST MODEL OF BUBBLES 1857 The post-crash phase starts at time T + 1, where T is the first period in which p t /G t falls below (( θ + ε) 1 1). Assuming that t 0 is revealed at T, the expected fundamental value α(g/r) t 0 1 R t also becomes known. 15 From time T + 1 onward, agents who are not hit by the shock invest a decreasing fraction (R/G) t (t 0 1) of their endowments in the risky asset, and the rest in the risk-free asset. This is weakly optimal since, throughout the post-crash phase, the expected ratio p t+1 /p t equals R. Moreover, equality between p t and f t is preserved. 3. EQUILIBRIUM I next define equilibrium under the restriction to be relaxed in Section 5 that once a type has sold in anticipation of the crash, agents of that type stay out of the market until the bubble bursts. (Note that this does not preclude agents who are forced to sell by shocks from investing their endowments in the risky asset in later periods.) RESTRICTION I No Reentry: For any i and any t T, if b i t > 0, then h i τ = 0 τ {t + 1 T}. The equilibrium concept is perfect Bayesian equilibrium (PBE), consisting of strategies and beliefs {a i μ i } i [0 1].Agenti s strategy a i is a sequence {a i t } t Z, where a i t is a triplet (m i t s i t χ i t ).Agenti s belief μ i t (t 0 ) is a probability distribution over values of t 0.Botha i t and μ i t (t 0 ) are contingent on information available to agent i in Step 1 of date t. This includes the discount factor δ i t, past prices p t 1 ={ p t 2 p t 1 },and,ifν(i) t, the signal ν(i). Sinceδ i t does not inform about t 0, and all agents within a type observe the same prices and signal, they have the same common belief, defined as μ n t (t 0 ) μ i t (t 0 ) for all i with ν(i) = n. In equilibrium, for all i, a i t is optimal given agent i s shock realization δ i t and the belief μ i t (t 0 ),andμ i t (t 0 ) is consistent with the equilibrium strategy profile. To be consistent with a strategy profile, a belief μ i t (t 0 ) must assign positive probability only to values of t 0 that are not ruled out by strategies, given past prices and, if t ν(i), the signal. The set of values of t 0 that are not ruled out is the support of t 0, denoted by supp i t (t 0 ). Since beliefs are the same for all agents within a type, one can define supp n t (t 0 ) supp i t (t 0 ) for all i with ν(i) = n. Toseehowsupp n t (t 0 ) evolves in equilibrium, recall that the signal n implies that supp n t (t 0 ) {max{1 n (N 1)} n}.moreover, 15 In the equilibria presented later, prices p 1 p T often reveal t 0 exactly. However, in some instances, this will hold only approximately, and for some agents a couple of values of t 0 will be consistent with prices. In these cases, it would take some time after the crash for agents to learn the exact value of t 0. Modeling these details explicitly, however, would add complications without significantly affecting results or providing much insight.

15 1858 ANTONIO DOBLAS-MADRID prices p t 1 and strategies rule out values of t 0 as follows. If t 0 takes on the value τ 0, given the price history p t 1, there are discount-factor contingent implied values of a i τ for all i and all τ<t. These implied actions and the price p τ can be substituted into (19) to compute the implied ε τ = θ τ θ. The value τ 0 is excluded from supp n t (t 0 ) if it implies ε τ > ε for some τ. After discarding all the values of t 0 that are ruled out by this process, the probabilities that μ n t (t 0 ) assigns to each remaining value in supp n t (t 0 ) are obtained using Bayes rule as follows 16 : (20) μ n t (t 0 ) = ϕ(t 0 ) ϕ(τ 0 ) τ 0 supp n t (t 0 ) For all agents and at all times, given b i t and h i t, the equilibrium strategy a i t solves the problem [ ( τ 1 ) ] (21) max E i t c i t + δ i τ c i τ m i t s i t χ i t τ=t+1 s=t subject to (6) (9), (13), (14), 0 χ i t 1 and Restriction I. Note that equilibrium beliefs are embedded in the expectations operator E i t. As previously stated, preference shocks and risk neutrality greatly simplify this decision problem. Agents hit by the shock set a i t = (0 h i t 1), that is, they sell and consume everything. Agents with δ i t = 1/R set χ i t = 0 and, depending on whether E i t [p t+1 /p t ] is above, below, or equal to R, they choose to be, respectively, fully invested in the risky asset, fully invested in the risk-free asset, or indifferent between any mix of the two. 4. EQUILIBRIA WITH BUBBLES: BASIC ANALYSIS For ease of exposition, I will carry out the analysis in Sections 4 and 5 under the assumption that N is large, which implies that throughout the boom including the last few periods the price p t approximates αg t ; that is, I assume that price fluctuations matter because of their informational content, but are otherwise too small to have any sizable revenue effects. This assumption keeps formulas simple enough to convey intuition and tractable enough to allow for analytical equilibrium characterization. In Appendix D, I derive the formulas for general values of N. 16 In a more general expression, ϕ would be multiplied by the likelihood of observed prices for each value of t 0.Butin(20), this likelihood is simplified away, because in the coming analysis, it is equal for all values in supp n t (t 0 ). This does hold exactly in most instances, although in a few cases it is only true under an approximating assumption. In Appendix D, I show how the analysis is modified when that assumption is removed.

16 A ROBUST MODEL OF BUBBLES 1859 I will begin the analysis in Section 4.1 with the case in which ε <(1 θ)/(2n 1). In this case, which for brevity I will refer to as the noiseless case, the price is certain to reveal sales as soon as one type (z t = 1) exits the market. I examine the possibility of bubbly equilibria with simple trigger strategies akin to those studied by AB. These strategies dictate that after observing the signal at t = ν(i), agenti shall unless forced to sell by the preference shock ride the bubble for τ periods and sell at t = ν(i) + 0 τ 0. Although noise cannot hide sales of the first type, the discreteness of the model, together with the withinperiod timing, allows a mass 1/N of agents to sell at the peak of the bubble. Since there is positive probability of being among these sellers, there are equilibria with bubbles if G/R is high enough. 17 More precisely, in Proposition 1, I will show that to support equilibria with τ 0 = 1 G/R must surpass a threshold Γ = Γ(λ). More generally, I derive an (increasing) relationship between the highest τ 0 that can be supported and G/R. The proposition also establishes that τ 0 = 0 is always an equilibrium, no matter how high we set G/R. This is because if an agent knows that others of her same type are selling, she knows that sales will be revealed for sure and, therefore, she sells. In Section 4.2, I increase the amount of noise so that it can hide sales by one type. In this case, which I will refer to as the noisy case, the inference from prices is often ambiguous, with investors unable to distinguish the beginning of the crash from a temporary price dip due to noise. For tractability, I restrict attention to the case where noise can hide sales of one type, but not two, so that prices can be categorized as high, medium, or low. High prices reveal that no types have left the market, medium prices are consistent with either no sales or with sales by one type, and low prices reveal with certainty that sales have begun. While restrictive, this assumption simplifies the analysis and makes it possible to focus on Markovian strategies, which condition behavior in addition to the signal and preference shock only on the most recent price. In Proposition 2, I establish conditions under which the equilibrium without bubbles can be ruled out. Proposition 2 also establishes conditions under which there exist equilibria with long bubbles. By long bubbles, I mean bubbles that are so large relative to fundamental value that the fraction of the price lost in the crash is close to 100 percent. Finally, in Proposition 3, I contrast Propositions 1 and 2 to compare bubble formation with and without noise. 17 In AB, since time and types are continuous, in the benchmark case, sales begin gradually and the mass of agents selling at any given instant is zero. If the price reflected sales, any positive mass of sales would be detected, and thus the probability of selling before the crash would be zero. To avoid this, AB assumed that as long as sales do not surpass a threshold κ, the price simply does not reveal these sales. The price continues to grow as if sales had not started, and it reacts only when total sales reach a threshold κ. As far as the ability of agents to exit the market is concerned, assuming discrete periods and types is in a sense similar to having κ = 1/N in AB s continuous model.

17 1860 ANTONIO DOBLAS-MADRID Strategies and Equilibria 4.1. The Noiseless Case In the noiseless case, the amount of noise ε is so low that, as soon as the first type sells, the price is certain to reveal these sales, because ([ θ + ε] 1 1)G t the lowest possible price while all types are still in the market exceeds ([1/N + ( θ ε)(1 1/N)] 1 1)G t the highest possible price when one type sells; that is, in the noiseless case, ε is below a threshold ε 0 1 given by (22) ε 0 1 (1 θ)/(2n 1) where the subscript 0 1 denotes zero types selling before time t and one type selling at t. The strategy of agent i is the following: if hit by the shock, she sells and consumes; otherwise, she does not consume. Pre-crash, she invests into the bubble before period ν(i) + τ 0 and exits the market at time ν(i) + τ 0.Postcrash, she invests a fraction (R/G) t (t 0 1) of her endowment into the risky asset and the rest into the risk-free asset. Put more formally, we have the following profile. STRATEGY PROFILE 1: For any i [0 1], the strategy of agent i is defined as follows: If δ i t = 0, then a i t = (0 h i t 1) for any t. If δ i t = 1/R, then χ i t = 0forallt and the choice of (m i t s i t ) is as follows: (a) If t T, then (23) { (bi t + e t 0) if t<ν(i)+ τ 0 (m i t s i t ) =, (0 h i t ) if t ν(i) + τ, 0 with τ 0 0. (b) If t T + 1, then (m i t s i t ) = ((R/G) t (t 0 1) e t 0). When agents follow these strategies, only type-t 0 agents succeed in riding the bubble. They sell at t 0 + τ, p 0 t 0 +τ 0 reveals their sales, and the crash happens at T +1 = t 0 + τ In Proposition 1, I characterize the set of possible equilibria in different regions of the parameter space. I show that if e λ <G/R<Γ,where Γ e λ ( e λ )/2, then agents follow (23) ifandonlyifτ 0 = 0; that is, if e λ <G/R<Γ, there is a unique no-bubble equilibrium where agents sell as soon as they observe the signal. We will later use this case as a benchmark for comparison with the noisy case. If Γ G/R < 1 + e λ, equilibrium can be supported for any τ 0 between zero and a positive upper bound, and if G/R

18 A ROBUST MODEL OF BUBBLES e λ, any integer τ 0 can be supported in 0 equilibrium.18 Note that even when bubbly equilibria exist, τ 0 = 0 is always an equilibrium. Before proceeding to the proposition and proof, it may be useful to sketch the main ideas behind the results. In an equilibrium with τ 0 0, type-n agents must be willing to (i) sell at time n + τ and (ii) not sell before n + 0 τ.for 0 any τ 0, a type-n agent will always sell at n + 0 τ 0, since other type-n agents are selling and p n+τ 0 will reveal the sales, causing a crash. The key to (ii) is to focus on the time when a type-n agent is most tempted to deviate from the strategy by selling early. This crucial time is t = n + τ 0 1, one period before she is supposed to sell. Since the bubble has not burst, she knows that type n must have been either first or second to observe the signal. Thus, supp n t (t 0 ) = {n 1 n} with μ n t (n 1) = 1/(1 + e λ ) and μ n t (n) = e λ /(1 + e λ ).Ifshe waits, she will receive the discounted post-crash price αg n 2 R τ 0 +1 if t 0 = n 1; if t 0 = n, she will ride the bubble for one more period and earn the discounted price αg n+τ 0/R. If she sells, she will earn the expected time-t price αg n+τ 0 1. In sum, waiting is preferable if (24) ( ) (τ 1 G 0 +1) 1 + e λ G 1 + e λ R 1 + e λ R Since the right-hand side of (24) is decreasing in τ,if(24) 0 failsforτ 0 = 1, it fails for all τ > 1. In Appendix A, I show that e λ >(G/R) 2 + e λ G/R holds if 1 <G/R<Γ; that is, if G/R < Γ, there are no equilibria with τ 0 1. If G/R Γ, equilibrium can be sustained for any integer below an upper bound 1 ln(1 + (1 G/R)e λ )/ ln(g/r), which is obtained solving (24) forτ. 0 Finally, note that if G/R 1 + e λ, then (24)holdsforanyτ 0. 0 To see why type-n agents are most tempted to sell at t = n + τ 0 1, consider, for instance, period n + τ 0 2. Two periods before agents are supposed to sell, supp n t (t 0 ) ={n 2 n 1 n} and the crash probability is μ n t (n 2) = 1/(1 + e λ + e 2λ ),lessthanin(24). The crash probability only falls further as we consider type-n agents choices at times n + τ 0 s for s>2. PROPOSITION 1: Assuming that 1/N 0 and letting Γ e λ ( e λ )/2, the values of τ 0 that can be supported in equilibrium depend on parameters as follows: (a) If e λ <G/R<Γ, only τ 0 = 0 can be supported in equilibrium. (b) If Γ G/R < 1 + e λ, equilibrium can be supported for any integer τ between zero and an upper bound 1 ln(1 + (1 G/R)e λ )/ ln(g/r). 0 (c) If 1 + e λ G/R, any integer τ 0 0 can be supported in equilibrium. 18 While infinite bubbles are technically possible for some parameter values, this possibility is not of interest, since as remarked in Section 2, the focus of the paper is on bubbles that burst endogenously in finite time.

19 1862 ANTONIO DOBLAS-MADRID PROOF: Choices by agents who are hit by the shock, as well as the choices of agents who are not hit in pre-boom and post-crash periods, are rather trivial. Agents hit by the shock do not value the future, and thus willingly sell and consume everything. Pre-boom and post-crash, agents have no reason to deviate from strategies, since the expected price growth rate is R. Thus, for the rest of the proof, we will focus on the choices of agents who have not been hit by the shock in boom periods t {1 T}. Moreover, the assumption that 1/N is small will allow us to neglect revenue effects of the sales by the first type and make the convenient approximation p T αg T. To support a given τ 0 0inequilibrium,itmustbethatforanyn and any boom period t {1 T}, type-n agents are willing to (i) sell at time n + τ 0 and (ii) not sell before time n + τ. Condition (i) holds for any n and 0 τ 0. 0 To see why, note that at t = n + τ,atype-n agent knows that t 0 0 = n, that other type-n agents are selling, and that p n+τ 0 will reveal these sales, causing acrashatn + τ + 1. Selling is optimal as the expected time-t price 0 αgn+τ 0 exceeds the payoff from waiting, given by the expected discounted post-crash price αg n 1 /R. 19 Regarding (ii), consider the sell-or-wait choice of a type-n agentattimet = n + τ s, withs>0. First, focus on cases with s 0 τ 0, so that the agent has observed the signal as of time t. The agent may be motivated to deviate from the strategy and sell preemptively if it is possible that t 0 = n s, in which case type-t 0 agents will sell at t and precipitate a crash at t + 1. Clearly, the greater the probability that t 0 = n s, denoted by μ n t (n s), the greater the agent s incentive to deviate. Since t 0 must be positive and greater than n N, the probability μ n t (n s) is zero if s n or s N. Ifs<min{n N}, however, supp n t (t 0 ) is given by {n s n} and the likelihood of a crash at t + 1is μ n t (n s) = 1/(1 + +e λs ). Clearly, this likelihood is highest for s = 1, as in (24), and, therefore, if agents choose not to sell preemptively when s = 1, they will not choose to do so when s>1 either. Next, consider cases with s>τ 0, which implies that t<n. Before observing the signal, the type-n agent only knows that t 0 must be positive, greater than t (N 1), since otherwise she would have observed the signal, and greater than t τ 1, since otherwise sales would have started. Thus, supp (t 0 n t 0) = {τ 0 Z τ 0 max{1 t N + 2 t τ 0 }} and the likelihood of a crash at t + 1 is μ n t (t τ ).Ift 0 τ 0 max{1 t N + 2}, as is the case in the equilibrium with τ = 0, μ 0 n t(t τ ) = 1 0 e λ.(ift τ < max{1 t N + 2}, then μ 0 n t(t τ ) = 0.) An agent in this situation can sell preemptively at a price 0 αgt or wait, in which case with probability e λ she will sell at t + 1 at a higher (discounted) price αg t+1 /R and with probability 1 e λ obtain the post-crash price. Even if 19 Note that the expected payoff to the agent is she waits is αg n 1, regardless of whether she is hit by the shock at t + 1 or not. If she is hit, she will have a strict preference for selling at t + 1; if not, she will be indifferent between selling and not selling. In either case, the utility she expects fromoneunitoftheriskyassetisαg n 1.

20 A ROBUST MODEL OF BUBBLES 1863 the post-crash price is zero, if 1 <e λ G/R, waiting is optimal. Thus, the mild condition e λ <G/Rsuffices to rule out preemptive sales if t<n. Note that since 1 e λ < 1/(1 + e λ ), agents are less tempted to sell preemptively before observing the signal than in the situation captured by (24). We have now established that of all situations a type-n agent may face before n + τ, the situation considered in (24), with t = n + 0 τ 1, n 0 2andτ 0 1, is the one where she is most inclined to sell preemptively. Thus, if (24) precludes preemptive sales when they are most tempting, it also precludes such sales in allpossiblecaseswitht<n+ τ 0. Parts (a) (c) follow directly from (24). As I show in Appendix A,ifG/R < Γ, agents are not even willing to wait for τ = 0 1 period after observing the signal. Part (a) follows from here. If G/R > Γ, equilibrium can be sustained for any integer τ 0 between zero and an upper bound. If G/R Γ, equilibrium can be sustained for any integer below an upper bound 1 ln(1 + (1 G/R)e λ )/ ln(g/r), which is obtained solving (24) forτ 0. Part (b) follows from here. To establish (c), simply note that if G/R 1 + e λ, then (24)holdsforanyτ, including 0 τ =. Q.E.D Discussion Equilibria with positive and finite τ 0 are examples of speculative bubbles that do not last forever and are not supported by irrational buyers. To better understand what makes such bubbles possible, it is useful to recall previous well known results. Tirole (1982) famously provided three arguments to explain why bubbles cannot occur in a finite horizon model. The first is that if there is a final date T, then nobody would pay more than the discounted present value of the asset at T 1 and similarly for all dates before. The second argument is that if the probability of selling the asset goes to zero as the horizon approaches, then the price must go to infinity. But this is not possible because there is a finite amount of wealth. The third argument is that since a bubble is a zero-sum game, risk-averse investors cannot all be better off by participating in the bubble and thus refuse to participate. Risk-neutral investors would be indifferent between participating and not, since they expect zero profits. Regarding the first argument, it is important to note that while the model is infinite, bubbles are always finite in the equilibria of interest. 20 In a typical equilibrium, the bubble lasts for a finite number of periods τ 0 until period 20 Given the distribution in (1), the model as presented is infinite. However, one could construct a finite version by truncating the distribution at a maximum value, and assuming that there is a date when dividends are paid and the model ends. In choosing equilibrium strategies, one would have to be mindful of the fact that some agents may observe signals that reveal that they are late in the line. Clearly, these agents would be unwilling to ride the bubble. However, agents observing signals earlier would face a situation more similar to agents in the infinite model, not knowing where they are in the line. To generate bubbles in such a finite model, strategies would have to specify longer waiting times for agents receiving earlier signals, with waiting times gradually falling and being equal to zero for agents who observe the latest possible signals. While the

Econometrica Supplementary Material

Econometrica Supplementary Material Econometrica Supplementary Material PUBLIC VS. PRIVATE OFFERS: THE TWO-TYPE CASE TO SUPPLEMENT PUBLIC VS. PRIVATE OFFERS IN THE MARKET FOR LEMONS (Econometrica, Vol. 77, No. 1, January 2009, 29 69) BY

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Bubbles and Crashes. Jonathan Levin. October 2003

Bubbles and Crashes. Jonathan Levin. October 2003 Bubbles and Crashes Jonathan Levin October 2003 These notes consider Abreu and Brunnermeier s (2003) paper on the failure of rational arbitrage in asset markets. Recall that the no-trade theorem states

More information

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Harold L. Cole and Narayana Kocherlakota Working Paper 604 September 2000 Cole: U.C.L.A. and Federal Reserve

More information

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence A The infinite horizon model This section defines the equilibrium of the infinity horizon model described in Section III of the paper and characterizes

More information

1 Dynamic programming

1 Dynamic programming 1 Dynamic programming A country has just discovered a natural resource which yields an income per period R measured in terms of traded goods. The cost of exploitation is negligible. The government wants

More information

Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring.

Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring. Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring. Olivier Compte First Version: June 2001 This Version: November 2003 Abstract In principal-agent relationships, a termination threat is often thought

More information

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring Holmstrom and Tirole (JPE, 1993) The main idea A firm would like to issue shares in the capital market because once these shares are publicly traded, speculators

More information

Efficiency in Decentralized Markets with Aggregate Uncertainty

Efficiency in Decentralized Markets with Aggregate Uncertainty Efficiency in Decentralized Markets with Aggregate Uncertainty Braz Camargo Dino Gerardi Lucas Maestri December 2015 Abstract We study efficiency in decentralized markets with aggregate uncertainty and

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Government Safety Net, Stock Market Participation and Asset Prices

Government Safety Net, Stock Market Participation and Asset Prices Government Safety Net, Stock Market Participation and Asset Prices Danilo Lopomo Beteto November 18, 2011 Introduction Goal: study of the effects on prices of government intervention during crises Question:

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles Gadi Barlevy REVISED July 8, 2013 WP 2011-07 A Leverage-based Model of Speculative Bubbles Gadi Barlevy Economic Research Department

More information

Speculative Bubble Burst

Speculative Bubble Burst *University of Paris1 - Panthéon Sorbonne Hyejin.Cho@malix.univ-paris1.fr Thu, 16/07/2015 Undefined Financial Object (UFO) in in financial crisis A fundamental dichotomy a partition of a whole into two

More information

Markets Do Not Select For a Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk

Markets Do Not Select For a Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk Markets Do Not Select For a Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk Thorsten Hens a Klaus Reiner Schenk-Hoppé b October 4, 003 Abstract Tobin 958 has argued that in the face of potential capital

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions 1. (45 points) Consider the following normal form game played by Bruce and Sheila: L Sheila R T 1, 0 3, 3 Bruce M 1, x 0, 0 B 0, 0 4, 1 (a) Suppose

More information

Crises and Prices: Information Aggregation, Multiplicity and Volatility

Crises and Prices: Information Aggregation, Multiplicity and Volatility : Information Aggregation, Multiplicity and Volatility Reading Group UC3M G.M. Angeletos and I. Werning November 09 Motivation Modelling Crises I There is a wide literature analyzing crises (currency attacks,

More information

PRINCETON UNIVERSITY Economics Department Bendheim Center for Finance. FINANCIAL CRISES ECO 575 (Part II) Spring Semester 2003

PRINCETON UNIVERSITY Economics Department Bendheim Center for Finance. FINANCIAL CRISES ECO 575 (Part II) Spring Semester 2003 PRINCETON UNIVERSITY Economics Department Bendheim Center for Finance FINANCIAL CRISES ECO 575 (Part II) Spring Semester 2003 Section 5: Bubbles and Crises April 18, 2003 and April 21, 2003 Franklin Allen

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics I ECON 525a - Fall 2009 Yale University

Advanced Macroeconomics I ECON 525a - Fall 2009 Yale University Advanced Macroeconomics I ECON 525a - Fall 2009 Yale University Week 5 - Bubbles Introduction Why a rational representative investor model of asset prices does not generate bubbles? Martingale property:

More information

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems Microeconomics II CIDE, MsC Economics List of Problems 1. There are three people, Amy (A), Bart (B) and Chris (C): A and B have hats. These three people are arranged in a room so that B can see everything

More information

Information Processing and Limited Liability

Information Processing and Limited Liability Information Processing and Limited Liability Bartosz Maćkowiak European Central Bank and CEPR Mirko Wiederholt Northwestern University January 2012 Abstract Decision-makers often face limited liability

More information

Market Size Matters: A Model of Excess Volatility in Large Markets

Market Size Matters: A Model of Excess Volatility in Large Markets Market Size Matters: A Model of Excess Volatility in Large Markets Kei Kawakami March 9th, 2015 Abstract We present a model of excess volatility based on speculation and equilibrium multiplicity. Each

More information

Bubbles. Macroeconomics IV. Ricardo J. Caballero. Spring 2011 MIT. R.J. Caballero (MIT) Bubbles Spring / 29

Bubbles. Macroeconomics IV. Ricardo J. Caballero. Spring 2011 MIT. R.J. Caballero (MIT) Bubbles Spring / 29 Bubbles Macroeconomics IV Ricardo J. Caballero MIT Spring 2011 R.J. Caballero (MIT) Bubbles Spring 2011 1 / 29 References 1 2 3 Allen, F. and D. Gale, Bubbles and Crises, Economic Journal, 110:236-255,

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions.

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions. Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions. Ilan Kremer and Andrzej Skrzypacz March 21, 2002 1 Introduction In many papers considering the sale of many objects in a sequence of auctions the seller

More information

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation May 1, 1997 On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation Yoshitsugu Kanemoto 1 Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo 7-3-1 Hongo, Bunkyo-ku, Tokyo 113 Japan Abstract The most important drawback

More information

Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers

Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers WP-2013-015 Bargaining Order and Delays in Multilateral Bargaining with Asymmetric Sellers Amit Kumar Maurya and Shubhro Sarkar Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research, Mumbai August 2013 http://www.igidr.ac.in/pdf/publication/wp-2013-015.pdf

More information

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 287 March 2001 Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Harold L. Cole University of California, Los Angeles and Federal Reserve Bank

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008 Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008 There are two questions on the exam, representing Asset Pricing (236D = 234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Princeton University TexPoint fonts used in EMF. Read the TexPoint manual before you delete this box.: AAAAAA

Princeton University TexPoint fonts used in EMF. Read the TexPoint manual before you delete this box.: AAAAAA Princeton University crisis management preventive Systemic risk a broad definition Systemic risk build-up during (credit) bubble and materializes in a crisis Volatility Paradox contemp. measures inappropriate

More information

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints

1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints 1 Precautionary Savings: Prudence and Borrowing Constraints In this section we study conditions under which savings react to changes in income uncertainty. Recall that in the PIH, when you abstract from

More information

The International Transmission of Credit Bubbles: Theory and Policy

The International Transmission of Credit Bubbles: Theory and Policy The International Transmission of Credit Bubbles: Theory and Policy Alberto Martin and Jaume Ventura CREI, UPF and Barcelona GSE March 14, 2015 Martin and Ventura (CREI, UPF and Barcelona GSE) BIS Research

More information

Credit-Fuelled Bubbles

Credit-Fuelled Bubbles FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Credit-Fuelled Bubbles Antonio Doblas-Madrid Michigan State University Kevin J. Lansing Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco March 2016 Working

More information

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria and Rational Expectations Equilibria 1 Basic Setup Two periods: 0 and 1 One riskless asset with interest rate r One risky asset which pays a normally distributed

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2016 Section 1. Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements,

More information

Multiperiod Market Equilibrium

Multiperiod Market Equilibrium Multiperiod Market Equilibrium Multiperiod Market Equilibrium 1/ 27 Introduction The rst order conditions from an individual s multiperiod consumption and portfolio choice problem can be interpreted as

More information

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1 Satyajit Chatterjee Burcu Eyigungor Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia February 15, 2008 1 Corresponding Author: Satyajit Chatterjee, Research Dept., 10 Independence

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2016 Section 1. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of the following 6 statements, state

More information

Asset Price Bubbles and Bubbly Debt

Asset Price Bubbles and Bubbly Debt Asset Price Bubbles and Bubbly Debt Jan Werner ****** Andrzej Malawski Memorial Session Kraków, October 2017 p. 1/2 Understanding Asset Price Bubbles price = fundamental value + bubble. Economic Theory:

More information

A Three-State Rational Greater-Fool Bubble With. Intertemporal Consumption Smoothing

A Three-State Rational Greater-Fool Bubble With. Intertemporal Consumption Smoothing A Three-State Rational Greater-Fool Bubble With Intertemporal Consumption Smoothing Feng Liu a and Joseph S.S. White b a Department of Economics and Decision Sciences, Western Illinois University, United

More information

Assets with possibly negative dividends

Assets with possibly negative dividends Assets with possibly negative dividends (Preliminary and incomplete. Comments welcome.) Ngoc-Sang PHAM Montpellier Business School March 12, 2017 Abstract The paper introduces assets whose dividends can

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Dynamic signaling and market breakdown

Dynamic signaling and market breakdown Journal of Economic Theory ( ) www.elsevier.com/locate/jet Dynamic signaling and market breakdown Ilan Kremer, Andrzej Skrzypacz Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, Stanford, CA 94305, USA

More information

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions? March 3, 215 Steven A. Matthews, A Technical Primer on Auction Theory I: Independent Private Values, Northwestern University CMSEMS Discussion Paper No. 196, May, 1995. This paper is posted on the course

More information

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017 Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein 1 Introduction In this document we derive the main results Atkeson Burstein (Aggregate Implications

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Speculative Bubbles, Heterogeneous Beliefs, and Learning

Speculative Bubbles, Heterogeneous Beliefs, and Learning Speculative Bubbles, Heterogeneous Beliefs, and Learning Jan Werner University of Minnesota October 2017. Abstract: Speculative bubble arises when the price of an asset exceeds every trader s valuation

More information

Self-Fulfilling Credit Market Freezes

Self-Fulfilling Credit Market Freezes Working Draft, June 2009 Self-Fulfilling Credit Market Freezes Lucian Bebchuk and Itay Goldstein This paper develops a model of a self-fulfilling credit market freeze and uses it to study alternative governmental

More information

Liquidity and Risk Management

Liquidity and Risk Management Liquidity and Risk Management By Nicolae Gârleanu and Lasse Heje Pedersen Risk management plays a central role in institutional investors allocation of capital to trading. For instance, a risk manager

More information

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility and Coordination Failures What makes financial systems fragile? What causes crises

More information

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy 1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy For a long time, when economists thought about the effect of government debt on aggregate output, they focused on the so called crowding-out effect. To simplify

More information

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES 1. REVIEW: SMALL TAXES SMALL DEADWEIGHT LOSS Static analysis suggests that deadweight loss from taxation at rate τ is 0(τ 2 ) that is, that for small tax rates the

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A BRAZILIAN DEBT-CRISIS MODEL. Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A BRAZILIAN DEBT-CRISIS MODEL. Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A BRAZILIAN DEBT-CRISIS MODEL Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka Working Paper 9211 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9211 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge,

More information

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS 247 16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS Let us associate each state S with a numeric utility U(S), which expresses the desirability of the state A nondeterministic action A will have possible outcome states Result

More information

A key characteristic of financial markets is that they are subject to sudden, convulsive changes.

A key characteristic of financial markets is that they are subject to sudden, convulsive changes. 10.6 The Diamond-Dybvig Model A key characteristic of financial markets is that they are subject to sudden, convulsive changes. Such changes happen at both the microeconomic and macroeconomic levels. At

More information

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction By: Stephen P. Holland Holland, Stephen P. (2003) Extraction Capacity and the Optimal Order of Extraction, Journal of Environmental Economics and

More information

Group-lending with sequential financing, contingent renewal and social capital. Prabal Roy Chowdhury

Group-lending with sequential financing, contingent renewal and social capital. Prabal Roy Chowdhury Group-lending with sequential financing, contingent renewal and social capital Prabal Roy Chowdhury Introduction: The focus of this paper is dynamic aspects of micro-lending, namely sequential lending

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours Ekonomia nr 47/2016 123 Ekonomia. Rynek, gospodarka, społeczeństwo 47(2016), s. 123 133 DOI: 10.17451/eko/47/2016/233 ISSN: 0137-3056 www.ekonomia.wne.uw.edu.pl Aggregation with a double non-convex labor

More information

Cooperation and Rent Extraction in Repeated Interaction

Cooperation and Rent Extraction in Repeated Interaction Supplementary Online Appendix to Cooperation and Rent Extraction in Repeated Interaction Tobias Cagala, Ulrich Glogowsky, Veronika Grimm, Johannes Rincke July 29, 2016 Cagala: University of Erlangen-Nuremberg

More information

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2013 D. Romer UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Economics 202A DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 203 D. Romer FORCES LIMITING THE EXTENT TO WHICH SOPHISTICATED INVESTORS ARE WILLING TO MAKE TRADES THAT MOVE ASSET PRICES BACK TOWARD

More information

A Model with Costly Enforcement

A Model with Costly Enforcement A Model with Costly Enforcement Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania December 25, 2012 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Costly-Enforcement December 25, 2012 1 / 43 A Model with Costly

More information

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Ahmer Tarar Department of Political Science Texas A&M University 4348 TAMU College Station, TX 77843-4348 email: ahmertarar@pols.tamu.edu

More information

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts 6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts Asu Ozdaglar MIT February 9, 2010 1 Introduction Outline Review Examples of Pure Strategy Nash Equilibria

More information

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms On Existence of Equilibria in Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms Northwestern University April 23, 2014 Bayesian Allocation Mechanisms In allocation mechanisms, agents choose messages. The messages determine

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

Making Money out of Publicly Available Information

Making Money out of Publicly Available Information Making Money out of Publicly Available Information Forthcoming, Economics Letters Alan D. Morrison Saïd Business School, University of Oxford and CEPR Nir Vulkan Saïd Business School, University of Oxford

More information

The Effect of Speculative Monitoring on Shareholder Activism

The Effect of Speculative Monitoring on Shareholder Activism The Effect of Speculative Monitoring on Shareholder Activism Günter Strobl April 13, 016 Preliminary Draft. Please do not circulate. Abstract This paper investigates how informed trading in financial markets

More information

Public Goods Provision with Rent-Extracting Administrators

Public Goods Provision with Rent-Extracting Administrators Supplementary Online Appendix to Public Goods Provision with Rent-Extracting Administrators Tobias Cagala, Ulrich Glogowsky, Veronika Grimm, Johannes Rincke November 27, 2017 Cagala: Deutsche Bundesbank

More information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information - preliminary and incomplete, please do not cite - Working Paper R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information Andreas Frick Heidrun C. Hoppe-Wewetzer Georgios Katsenos June 28, 2016 Abstract

More information

Speculative Trade under Ambiguity

Speculative Trade under Ambiguity Speculative Trade under Ambiguity Jan Werner March 2014. Abstract: Ambiguous beliefs may lead to speculative trade and speculative bubbles. We demonstrate this by showing that the classical Harrison and

More information

The Demand and Supply of Safe Assets (Premilinary)

The Demand and Supply of Safe Assets (Premilinary) The Demand and Supply of Safe Assets (Premilinary) Yunfan Gu August 28, 2017 Abstract It is documented that over the past 60 years, the safe assets as a percentage share of total assets in the U.S. has

More information

Dynamic Contracts. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. December 5, Econ720

Dynamic Contracts. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. December 5, Econ720 Dynamic Contracts Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ720 December 5, 2016 1 / 43 Issues Many markets work through intertemporal contracts Labor markets, credit markets, intermediate input supplies,... Contracts

More information

Macroeconomics and finance

Macroeconomics and finance Macroeconomics and finance 1 1. Temporary equilibrium and the price level [Lectures 11 and 12] 2. Overlapping generations and learning [Lectures 13 and 14] 2.1 The overlapping generations model 2.2 Expectations

More information

Learning in a Model of Exit

Learning in a Model of Exit ömmföäflsäafaäsflassflassflas ffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffffff Discussion Papers Learning in a Model of Exit Pauli Murto Helsinki School of Economics and HECER and Juuso Välimäki Helsinki School of

More information

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam Summer 2018 Microeconomics Qualifying Exam There are 100 points possible on this exam, 50 points each for Prof. Lozada s questions and Prof. Dugar s questions. Each professor asks you to do two long questions

More information

A Diamond-Dybvig Model in which the Level of Deposits is Endogenous

A Diamond-Dybvig Model in which the Level of Deposits is Endogenous A Diamond-Dybvig Model in which the Level of Deposits is Endogenous James Peck The Ohio State University A. Setayesh The Ohio State University January 28, 2019 Abstract We extend the Diamond-Dybvig model

More information

Understanding Krugman s Third-Generation Model of Currency and Financial Crises

Understanding Krugman s Third-Generation Model of Currency and Financial Crises Hisayuki Mitsuo ed., Financial Fragilities in Developing Countries, Chosakenkyu-Hokokusho, IDE-JETRO, 2007. Chapter 2 Understanding Krugman s Third-Generation Model of Currency and Financial Crises Hidehiko

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017 Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 017 1. Sheila moves first and chooses either H or L. Bruce receives a signal, h or l, about Sheila s behavior. The distribution

More information

Bailouts, Bail-ins and Banking Crises

Bailouts, Bail-ins and Banking Crises Bailouts, Bail-ins and Banking Crises Todd Keister Rutgers University Yuliyan Mitkov Rutgers University & University of Bonn 2017 HKUST Workshop on Macroeconomics June 15, 2017 The bank runs problem Intermediaries

More information

STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION

STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION BINGCHAO HUANGFU Abstract This paper studies a dynamic duopoly model of reputation-building in which reputations are treated as capital stocks that

More information

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012 Game Theory Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012 The Revenue Equivalence Theorem Note: This is a only a draft

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS

16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS 253 16 MAKING SIMPLE DECISIONS Let us associate each state S with a numeric utility U(S), which expresses the desirability of the state A nondeterministic action a will have possible outcome states Result(a)

More information

Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms

Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms 19 Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms Vol I Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms Annika Westphäling * Four eyes see more than two that information gets more precise being aggregated

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure

Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure Yosuke Kimura Graduate School of Economics, The University of Tokyo March 20, 2017 Abstract This paper considers the relationship between stock

More information

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Minh Vo Metropolitan State University Abstract This paper develops a model of financing with informational feedback effect that jointly determines a firm s capital

More information

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015. FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.) Hints for Problem Set 2 1. Consider a zero-sum game, where

More information

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Evaluating Strategic Forecasters Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Motivation Forecasters are sought after in a variety of

More information

Macroeconomics of Financial Markets

Macroeconomics of Financial Markets ECON 712, Fall 2017 Bubbles Guillermo Ordoñez University of Pennsylvania and NBER September 30, 2017 Beauty Contests Professional investment may be likened to those newspaper competitions in which the

More information

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam Optimal Financial Education Avanidhar Subrahmanyam Motivation The notion that irrational investors may be prevalent in financial markets has taken on increased impetus in recent years. For example, Daniel

More information

Directed Search and the Futility of Cheap Talk

Directed Search and the Futility of Cheap Talk Directed Search and the Futility of Cheap Talk Kenneth Mirkin and Marek Pycia June 2015. Preliminary Draft. Abstract We study directed search in a frictional two-sided matching market in which each seller

More information

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty 1.1 Modelling uncertainty As in the deterministic case, we keep assuming that agents live for two periods. The novelty here is that their earnings in the second

More information

B. Online Appendix. where ɛ may be arbitrarily chosen to satisfy 0 < ɛ < s 1 and s 1 is defined in (B1). This can be rewritten as

B. Online Appendix. where ɛ may be arbitrarily chosen to satisfy 0 < ɛ < s 1 and s 1 is defined in (B1). This can be rewritten as B Online Appendix B1 Constructing examples with nonmonotonic adoption policies Assume c > 0 and the utility function u(w) is increasing and approaches as w approaches 0 Suppose we have a prior distribution

More information

ABattleofInformedTradersandtheMarket Game Foundations for Rational Expectations Equilibrium

ABattleofInformedTradersandtheMarket Game Foundations for Rational Expectations Equilibrium ABattleofInformedTradersandtheMarket Game Foundations for Rational Expectations Equilibrium James Peck The Ohio State University During the 19th century, Jacob Little, who was nicknamed the "Great Bear

More information

Double Auction Markets vs. Matching & Bargaining Markets: Comparing the Rates at which They Converge to Efficiency

Double Auction Markets vs. Matching & Bargaining Markets: Comparing the Rates at which They Converge to Efficiency Double Auction Markets vs. Matching & Bargaining Markets: Comparing the Rates at which They Converge to Efficiency Mark Satterthwaite Northwestern University October 25, 2007 1 Overview Bargaining, private

More information

BARGAINING AND REPUTATION IN SEARCH MARKETS

BARGAINING AND REPUTATION IN SEARCH MARKETS BARGAINING AND REPUTATION IN SEARCH MARKETS ALP E. ATAKAN AND MEHMET EKMEKCI Abstract. In a two-sided search market agents are paired to bargain over a unit surplus. The matching market serves as an endogenous

More information