A theory on the role of wholesalers in international trade based on economies of scope

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A theory on the role of wholesalers in international trade based on economies of scope"

Transcription

1 156 A theory on the role of wholesalers in international trade based on economies of scope Anders Akerman Department of Economics, Stockholm University Abstract. This paper offers a theoretical foundation for the existence of wholesalers and other intermediaries in international trade and analyzes their role in an economy with heterogeneous manufacturing firms and fixed costs of exporting. Wholesalers are assumed to possess a technology such that they can buy manufacturing goods domestically and sell in foreign markets and they can, unlike manufacturers, export more than one good. A wholesaler therefore faces an additional fixed cost, which increases in the number of goods it handles. The presence of wholesale firms leads to productivity sorting. The most productive firms export on their own by paying a fixed cost, but a range of firms with intermediate productivity levels export through international wholesalers. A higher fixed cost of exporting to a destination means that wholesalers handle: (i) a higher share of total export volumes to this destination and (ii) a higher share of the exported product scope (i.e., the number of exported products) to this destination. A higher fixed cost of exporting gives wholesalers a larger role, since these can spread the fixed cost across more than one good. The wholesale technology therefore exhibits economies of scope. An empirical analysis using Swedish firm-level data supports the main assumption and predictions of the model. Résumé. Une théorie du rôle des grossistes dans le commerce international fondée sur les économies de portée. Ce texte offre un fondement théorique pour l existence des grossistes et d autres intermédiaires dans le commerce international, et analyse leur rôle dans une économie riche de firmes manufacturières hétérogènes face à des coûts d exportation fixes. Les grossistes sont censés posséder une technologie Corresponding author: Anders Akerman, anders.akerman@ne.su.se I am grateful for helpful comments and suggestions from two anonymous referees, Andrew Bernard, Gregory Corcos, Matthieu Crozet, Jonathan Eaton, Gabriel Felbermayr, Harry Flam, Rikard Forslid, Benjamin Jung, Sebastian Krautheim, James Markusen, Lindsay Oldenski, Horst Raff, Peter Schott, Anson Soderbery, Heiwai Tang and Stephen Yeaple as well as seminar participants at the Midwest International Trade Meetings in Chicago, NOITS in Helsinki, RIEF in Kiel, Uppsala International Trade Workshop, the EEA Meetings in Glasgow, the ETSG in Lausanne and the EITI in Tokyo. Financial support from the Jan Wallander and Tom Hedelius Research Foundation and the Torsten Söderberg Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. Canadian Journal of Economics / Revue canadienne d économique (1) February Printed in Canada / Février Imprimé au Canada ISSN: / 18 / pp / Canadian Economics Association

2 Wholesalers in international trade 157 telle qu ils peuvent acheter des biens manufacturiers dans une économie nationale et les vendre à l étranger, et peuvent, ce qui n est pas nécessairement le cas pour les manufacturiers, exporter plus qu un bien. Un grossiste fait donc face à un coût fixe additionnel à proportion que le nombre de biens dont on s occupe s accroît. La présence des firmes grossistes mène à un départage des producteurs selon leur productivité. Les producteurs les plus productifs s occupent eux-mêmes de leurs exportations en déboursant un coût fixe, mais un éventail de producteurs à productivité intermédiaire va exporter par le truchement de grossistes internationaux. Un coût fixe plus élevé de l exportation vers une destination donnée veut dire que les grossistes s occupent (i) d une portion plus grande du volume total des exportations vers cette destination, et (ii) d une portion plus grande de la portée de produits exportés (i.e., du nombre de produits exportés) vers cette destination. Un coût fixe plus élevé de l exportation donne aux grossistes un rôle plus important puisqu ils peuvent étaler ce coût fixe sur plus qu un produit. La technologie du commerce en gros bénéficie donc d économies de portée. Une analyse empirique utilisant des données suédoises au niveau de la firme confirme le postulat de base de ce modèle et ses prédictions. JEL classification: D21, F12, F15 1. Introduction I I tisbynowa well-known empirical regularity that wholesalers other intermediaries account for a substantial share of exports from most countries and that they assist less productive firms in overcoming barriers to foreign markets. Recent research has shown that intermediary firms handle about 22% of aggregate Chinese export sales (Ahn et al., 2011), 10% of US and Italian exports (Bernard et al. 2010a, 2015), 20% of French exports (Crozet et al., 2013) and about 35% of imports into Chile (Blum et al., 2010). Feenstra and Hanson (2004) examine the role of Hong Kong in re-exporting goods from China during and find that 53% of Chinese exports were shipped through Hong Kong as re-exports. The authors argue that intermediation was one of the more important reasons. These ratios are even larger for some goods typically associated with China s rapid export growth in the 1990s, such as 77% for footwear and 83% for toys. Basker and Van (2011) document the role of Wal-Mart as a catalyst for US imports from China and note that this large US retailer accounts for 15% of US imports from China. It has also become clear that firms in most countries and sectors are highly heterogeneous in several dimensions and that this is strongly correlated with export performance (see, for example, Mayer and Ottaviano 2008). It is thus highly likely that the effect of intermediaries on producing firms is asymmetric. Bernard et al. (2010a) find that exporting firms in the US exhibit substantial heterogeneity as regards export mode, i.e., whether firms manage their own exporting activities or export through intermediaries. McCann (2013) and Abel-Koch (2013) use East European and Turkish datasets, respectively, to find that indirect exporting (exporting through intermediaries) is correlated with important firm characteristics. Most importantly, the largest and most

3 158 A. Akerman productive firms export directly while firms in the middle of the productivity distribution instead choose to export indirectly through an intermediary. 1 Based on an assumption of why wholesalers exist and how they operate, this paper develops a model of international trade with wholesalers in a setting of heterogenous manufacturing firms. 2 Unlike much of the related literature, the model is characterized by free entry in all sectors and it therefore allows for a welfare analysis of the presence and structure of a wholesale industry in a general equilibrium framework. As in Melitz (2003), exporting is subject to a fixed cost. The role of wholesalers in international trade is that they are able to pool the fixed cost of exporting across more than one good. They do not produce goods themselves but instead buy goods in their local market and export these to foreign markets. The fixed cost of exporting for wholesalers is assumed to be convex and increasing in product scope (the number of goods that a wholesaler exports) since a more complex product portfolio is more costly to handle, but they have to incur the fixed cost only once (regardless of how many goods they export). For a producer, exporting through a wholesaler is therefore an alternative to setting up its own distribution channel. Wholesalers are assumed to be homogeneous since the main focus of this study is on how aggregate trade flows and heterogeneous producers of goods respond to the possibility of exporting through wholesalers as an alternative to managing their own distribution networks. The core mechanism that operates in the model is thus the following. Wholesalers spread the fixed cost of exporting across more than one good. But to cover the fixed cost, they need to charge a markup between the procurement price of the good and what it charges the final consumer in the foreign country. This markup causes productivity sorting in the choice of export mode: the most productive firms choose to incur their own fixed cost of exporting since their operating profit of exporting is large enough. However, some goods, which cannot be profitably exported by the producer itself, can be exported at a lower fixed cost (per good) by wholesalers, who export several goods but have to make only one investment in the fixed cost. 3 This means that the wholesale technology exhibits economies of scope. When fixed costs increase, wholesalers become more important, since fewer firms find it profitable to export on their own. Moreover, wholesalers have to expand and handle more goods to be able to cover the higher fixed cost. Wholesalers therefore help producers in overcoming 1 See also Bai et al. (2015) and Davies and Jeppesen (2012) for additional evidence. 2 The term wholesalers will be used in the paper since the empirical analysis uses data for wholesale firms, but the theoretical model could be applied to intermediaries in general. 3 The mechanisms that cause sorting are analogous to those in Helpman et al. (2004). They model horizontal FDI as a mode of foreign market entry, which, compared to exporting, is associated with a higher fixed cost but a lower variable cost. Here, exporting through a wholesaler is instead associated with a lower fixed cost but a higher variable cost.

4 Wholesalers in international trade 159 destination-specific barriers to entry. In an appendix section, I develop a multicountry gravity model where the multilateral resistance variable of a country is found to include the number of wholesalers of trading partners. The presence of wholesalers lowers a country s price index as well as mitigates the positive effect of fixed trade costs on the price level. Since the price level is indirectly a measure of welfare, I therefore also show that wholesalers increase welfare. This generates a number of predictions about how exporting is conducted in the presence of intermediation. First, producers sort according to productivity in determining their mode of exporting. The most productive firms continue to manage their own exporting activities and incur the fixed cost associated with this as in the standard model. However, some firms that were almost productive enough to export on their own in the standard model now choose to do so, but instead through wholesalers. The least productive firms do not export through any of the two modes. Second, a higher fixed cost of exporting is associated with a larger importance of wholesalers both in terms of export volumes and export scope. Finally, a higher fixed cost of exporting is also associated with each wholesaler handling more goods (having a larger scope). Swedish data from 2005 are used to test the main predictions of the model. I match data from Swedish Customs with production data for the universe of Swedish firms. The dataset contains a sector classification of firms according to main business activity as well as each firm s export transactions for each eightdigit Combined Nomenclature (CN8) product code and destination. Therefore, it can be observed what goods that are exported by wholesalers versus manufacturers where the latter are treated as the producers of goods. The empirical analysis supports the main predictions of the model. Crucially for the basic assumption about economies of scope, Swedish wholesalers export a larger scope of products than producers. A wholesaler exports about 54% more products per firm when destination-specific effects and firm size are accounted for, an empirical fact that supports the notion that there is a technological difference between wholesalers and producers related to the product scope in exporting. Moreover, as predicted by the model, wholesalers do, on average, export substantially lower volumes (between 33 and 54% less) per firm within a product category than producers. Finally, wholesalers play a more important role in aggregate exports (both in terms of total volumes and product scope) from Sweden to countries characterized by higher fixed costs. The result for aggregate export volumes is in line with previous studies by Ahn et al. (2011) for China, Bernard et al. (2015) for Italy and Crozet et al. (2013) for France. This paper is most directly related to a growing literature that studies the effects of intermediary firms on international trade in a setting with heterogeneous producing firms. Ahn et al. (2011) introduce the choice of indirect exporting through an intermediary into a partial equilibrium model of firm heterogeneity along the lines of Melitz (2003). This new export mode is assumed to be associated with lower fixed costs but higher variable costs and therefore, it causes productivity sorting among producers regarding export mode. These assumptions also mean that intermediaries become more important for destina-

5 160 A. Akerman tions characterized by higher fixed costs of entry. Felbermayr and Jung (2011) develop a similar model but where the difference in the ratio between fixed costs versus de facto variable costs instead comes from contracting frictions between producers and intermediaries. The predictions of these papers are in line with the predictions that I generate but this paper goes further. First, my model allows free entry and exit in all sectors and therefore provides a general equilibrium framework unlike the previous literature. This also enables a welfare analysis, and I show formally how intermediation in international trade increases welfare and through what mechanisms. Moreover, I specifically derive the additional marginal cost of indirect exporting as a result of the double marginalization based on the elasticity of substitution. This generates several predictions of, for example, product scope and intermediation, as well as the role of elasticity of substitution and competitive pressure in explaining crosssector variation in the importance of intermediated trade. Blum et al. (2011) also analyze the role of intermediaries in a setting with heterogeneous firms but do instead focus on how intermediaries reduce the costs of matching between producers and foreign consumers and find that intermediaries are especially important in matching small producers with small foreign consumers. Finally, Tang and Zhang (2011) and Crozet et al. (2013) analyze how quality differentiation among producers interacts with the possibility of choosing intermediation as an alternative export mode. Other theoretical work has also explored the issue of intermediation in international trade but has instead focused either on the role of intermediaries in reducing contracting or matching frictions between buyers and sellers, as in Antràs and Costinot (2010, 2011), Biglaiser (1993), Olsen (2013) or Rubinstein and Wolinsky (1987) or on their positions in networks in international trade, as in Petropoulou (2008), Rauch (1999, 2001) or Rauch and Watson (2004). An emerging literature also analyzes the fact that many producing firms appear to also export products that they do not produce themselves. Such carry-along trade, in the words of Bernard et al. (2012), is something that I do not analyze since I want to make the distinction between firms with versus without an intermediation technology as clear as possible. The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 develops the model by introducing a wholesale industry into the model in Melitz (2003) and derives the main results. Section 3 describes the Swedish data and provides the empirical analysis. Section 4 concludes the paper. 2. The model 2.1. Basic setup without wholesalers The model builds on the structure in Melitz (2003) but with an additional agricultural sector characterized by constant returns to scale. It depicts two economies (Home and Foreign, the latter denoted by superscript F) with a primary production factor labour, L, which is used in all sectors. As in Krugman

6 Wholesalers in international trade 161 (1980), consumers in each country have two-tier utility functions with the upper tier (Cobb Douglas) determining the consumer s division of expenditure among sectors and the second tier (CES) dictating the consumer s preferences over the various differentiated varieties within the manufacturing sector. All individuals in Home have the utility function U = C ¹ M C1 ¹ A where ¹ (0, 1), and C A is the consumption of the homogeneous good. Manufactures enter the utility function through the index C M, defined by C M = ( N 0 c ¾ 1 ¾ i di) ¾ 1 ¾ where N is the mass of varieties consumed, c i the amount of variety i consumed and ¾ > 1 the elasticity of substitution between varieties. Each consumer spends a share ¹ of his income on manufactures and demand for a variety i is therefore x i = Ap ¾ i, where A ¹L is the demand per firm, p P 1 ¾ i is the consumer price of variety i, L is the population size and P ( i Ä p1 ¾ i di) 1 ¾ 1 the price index of manufacturing goods available in the Home country. The set of available varieties is denoted by Ä. Ignoring the wholesale sector for now, the economy consists of an agricultural and a manufacturing sector. The agricultural sector is a Walrasian, homogeneous-good sector with costless trade. The manufacturing sector is characterized by increasing returns, Dixit Stiglitz monopolistic competition and iceberg trade costs. Manufacturers face constant marginal production costs and three types of fixed costs. The fixed cost, F E, is the standard Dixit Stiglitz cost of developing a new variety. Manufacturing firms are assumed to be singleproduct firms. 4 The other two fixed costs involved reflect the one-time expense of introducing a new variety into a market: F D (μ, wl) for the domestic market and F X (μ F, w F L F ) for the foreign market, where μ denotes a vector of country-specific characteristics that determine the difficulty of entry (such as, for example, the quality of institutions) and w denotes the wage level in a country. Consequently, wl denotes the gross domestic product of a country. When analyzing comparative statics of the model, I will use these relationships to see how country characteristics affect outcomes through the fixed cost of entry but, for ease of exposition, I denote F j F j (μ j, w j L j ) until then. 5 4 Modelling manufacturing firms as single-product firms is convenient for tractability and facilitates the focus of the paper on the unique feature of the wholesaler firms technology, namely the economies of scope in exporting. I should also add that assuming that multi-product manufacturing firms pay separate fixed costs of exporting and make independent choices on exporting for each product makes it theoretically possible to treat such firms as several independent single-product firms as long as their decisions do not change the underlying productivity distribution of products. For an extensive analysis of multi-product manufacturing firms in international trade, see, for example, Bernard et al. (2011) or Mayer et al. (2014). 5 I will not make any assumption on exactly how the fixed cost is affected by country size since this is difficult to know. For example, Arkolakis (2010) points out that due to returns to scale in the technology of entry (i.e., advertising technology), firms tend to pay a smaller fixed cost per customer in large economies but a higher total fixed cost. Moreover, larger destinations tend to attract more exporters; see, for example, Mayer and Ottaviano (2008). This may make it easier for a potential new exporter to enter since it can observe the methods of entry of other exporters.

7 162 A. Akerman There is heterogeneity in firms productivity levels, '. Each Dixit Stiglitz firm/variety is therefore associated with a particular labour output coefficient denoted by ' i for firm i. After spending F E units of labour in the product innovation process, the firm is randomly assigned ' i from the cumulative distribution function G('). The analysis focuses on steady-state equilibria and intertemporal considerations are ignored; the present value of firms is kept finite by assuming that firms face a constant Poisson hazard rate ± of forced exit. The unit factor requirement of the homogeneous good is one unit of labour. This good is freely traded and, since it is chosen as the numeraire, its price p A = w = 1, where w is the nominal wage of workers. Shipping the manufactured good involves a frictional trade cost of the iceberg form: for one unit of a good from Home to arrive in the Foreign country, > 1 units must be shipped. It is assumed that trade costs are equal in both directions. Profit maximization by a manufacturing firm i located in Home exporting to the Foreign country leads to the following ¾ ¾ 1 '. consumer price in Foreign of firm i s good: p F i = Entrepreneurs entering the manufacturing sector draw their marginal productivity, ' i, from the probability distribution G(') after having sunk F E units of labour to develop a new variety. Having learned their productivity, firms decide on entry in the domestic and foreign market, respectively. Doing so is associated with fixed market entry costs; firms pay F D to enter the domestic market and F X to enter the foreign market. Firms will therefore enter a market as long as the operating profit in this market is sufficiently large to cover the market entry cost associated with the market. The critical cut-off levels of productivity needed in order to enter the domestic and foreign markets (for the operating profit to be as large as the discounted fixed cost of entry) are given by ' ¾ 1 D A = F D and (1) ' X ¾ 1 1 ¾ A F = F X, (2) where F D ±(¾ 1) 1 ¾ ¾ ¾ F D and F X ±(¾ 1) 1 ¾ ¾ ¾ F X. Accounting also for free entry, which means that the expected operating profit, ¼, equals the fixed cost of entry, E(¼) = F E, yields that A = A F (see, for example, Helpman et al., 2004). Equations (1) and (2) yield the well-known result from Melitz (2003), 1 F which can be summarized as follows (provided that X 1 ¾ FD > 1). In a world without wholesalers, only firms with a marginal productivity above ' X choose to export, firms with a productivity between ' D and ' X serve the domestic market only and firms with a marginal productivity below ' D exit immediately Wholesalers The third sector, and the novel feature of this model, is the wholesale sector (variables relating to this sector are denoted by superscript W). Wholesale firms are indexed by j and are homogeneous. The wholesale technology gives a wholesaler firm j the ability to source a range of goods and ship these to the Foreign country. The mass of goods that wholesaler j ships (equal to the mass

8 Wholesalers in international trade 163 of manufacturing firms from which the wholesaler is buying goods) is denoted by mj W. The sector is characterized by free entry. A wholesaler faces the same cost as manufacturing firms to establish a retail channel in the foreign country, F X, but has the technology to export several goods. Operations are assumed to become more costly the more goods a firm handles, so it also faces a per-period fixed cost that is monotonically and convexly increasing in the range of goods it handles. Its total fixed cost of foreign market entry is therefore F W Xj = F X + (mw j ), (3) where > 1 and mj W is the mass of domestic manufacturing goods that the wholesale firm j is handling. Since manufacturing firms are atomistic and have a mass equal to zero, if a wholesale firm were to export only one single good, its scope measure mj W would be zero and lim m W j 0 FW Xj = F X. A wholesale firm that exports only one good therefore has the same fixed cost of exporting as a manufacturer. Moreover, the functional form in (3) is chosen both for technical and intuitive reasons. The technical reason is that some convexity needs to be included in this function to put an upper bound on the scope of wholesalers. If not (i.e., if =0), the economies of scope would be infinite and only one wholesaler would exist and this firm would export all goods. The intuitive reason is that it is more costly to maintain an international distribution system the more different goods are in nature. If mj W is low, the wholesaler is more specialized in a more narrow range of products, for example sport cars of different kinds. However, as mj W increases, the products necessarily become more different; in the specific example, the wholesaler firm also starts to export other types of cars or motor vehicles etc., which means that the level of specialization decreases and the cost per product increases. The wider the scope, the more costly each product is to export. I assume that a wholesaler gets the exclusive right to sell the manufacturing good in the foreign market. Since the wholesaler faces CES demand abroad, its demand function towards manufacturing firms when procuring their products is also characterized by a CES structure. This causes manufacturing firms to charge the same price to wholesalers as they do to consumers. And since the manufacturer imposes a CES markup over its marginal cost and the wholesaler does the same, the final consumer price in the foreign economy for a good sold by a wholesaler is characterized by a double marginalization ; the CES markup of ¾=(¾ 1) is imposed twice: ( ) ¾ 2 p W ij =, (4) ¾ 1 ' i where p W ij is the price charged by wholesaler j selling manufacturing firm i s good in the foreign market. 6 One can also immediately see that the term ( ¾ 1 ¾ )2 6 See proof 1 in online appendix A.3.

9 164 A. Akerman FIGURE 1 Relative profits for different export modes NOTE: ¼ X indicates the operating profit of a producer that exports on its own and ¼ W indicates the operating profit of a producer exporting through a wholesaler. decreases in the elasticity of substitution, which means that the degree of double marginalization is smaller in sectors where varieties are more substitutable. One might argue that double marginalization is a strong assumption. However, it is an endogenous outcome of a CES demand structure: wholesalers choose a CES markup since this is profit maximizing. The demand of their consumers is characterized by CES preferences, which cause their input demand (as derived by Shephard s lemma from the cost function of wholesalers) to be characterized by CES preferences as well, which motivates the markup choice by manufacturing firms. Moreover, even if wholesalers and manufacturers are able to negotiate, there are many reasons to believe that such contracts would not be completely non-distortionary in reality and that there would indeed be some additional margin component that is paid to the wholesaler. In any case, for wholesalers to generate non-negative profits, they must charge the manufacturer (whose product it is buying) some strictly positive price for their services in order to cover their fixed costs. Such an additional price will make it more profitable for the manufacturer to export on its own if it can. 7 Finally, the empirical facts that wholesalers and manufacturers co-exist in most export markets and that the most productive manufacturers choose to export on their own, as in McCann (2013) and Abel-Koch (2013), suggest that there is some reason for manufacturers to avoid using intermediation services if they can. Since manufacturers can choose their export mode (i.e., by establishing their own distribution system or exporting through a wholesaler), their choices are 7 In the Swedish data, wholesalers charge higher unit prices than manufacturing firms when exporting. And this difference decreases in the elasticity of substitution, which is in line with corollary 2. The estimates of this relationship are, however, very imprecise and therefore not reported here. They are instead available from the author upon request.

10 Wholesalers in international trade 165 determined by what mode yields the highest profits from exporting. The expected profits (discounted by the forced exit rate ±) of a manufacturing firm i that exports through wholesaler j are 1 ± ( p ij,px ij (p W ij ) ' i x ij (p W ij )) where x ij(p W ij ) indicates foreign sales of good i at price p W ij, i.e., the price set by the wholesaler. The expected discounted profits of a manufacturing firm exporting on its own are instead 1 ± ( p ix i ( p i ) ' i x i ( p i )) F X. Comparing the profits between the two export modes yields the following condition for a manufacturer to choose to export on its own: ' ¾ 1 i > F X 1 1 ¾ A F ( ( 1 ¾ 1 ¾ ) ¾ ). (5) This means that more productive firms will want to export on their own rather than through a wholesaler. This is due to the fact that they are productive enough to take the fixed cost of exporting themselves and avoid the markup incurred by the wholesaler. Note also that (5) defines the new export cut-off ' X ¾ 1 = F X 1 1 ¾ A F ( 1 ( ¾ 1 ¾ ) ¾ ) > F X 1 ¾ A F = ' ¾ 1 X. The inequality sign demonstrates that, with wholesalers present, some producers that previously exported on their own now decide to use wholesalers instead. Therefore, the export cut-off is higher with wholesalers in the model than without. This phenomenon is illustrated in figure 1. The lines ¼ X and ¼ W show the operating profits of a manufacturing firm exporting on its own and exporting through a wholesaler, respectively, as functions of the manufacturing firm s productivity. The line ¼ W starts from zero since a manufacturing firm does not have to pay any fixed costs when exporting through a wholesaler. However, exporting directly requires paying a fixed cost F X. The slope of ¼ W is lower than that of ¼ X due to the additional markup charged by the wholesaler. A manufacturer with a productivity higher than ' X will always have higher profits from exporting on its own (¼ X > ¼ W if and only if ' > ' X ). Supposing that wholesalers find it profitable to buy only goods with a productivity higher than ' W means that firms with productivity levels between ' W and ' X will prefer to export through a wholesaler rather than on their own. Moreover, the export cut-off in an economy without wholesalers, ' X, will always lie to the left of ' X, which can be seen in the graph. The model generates productivity sorting as regards choice of export mode. The most productive firms, ' > ' X, export their products on their own, firms with intermediate productivity levels, ' [' W, ' X ), export through wholesalers and the least productive firms, ' [' D, ' W ), do not export (it must, however, be assumed that ' D < ' W ). Note also that since wholesaler prices are higher, they also export smaller volumes per good. Their prices are higher due to: (i) their additional

11 166 A. Akerman FIGURE 2 Productivity sorting and export mode markup and (ii) the fact that they export goods produced by less productive firms. Finally, equation (5) shows that the degree of competition (the elasticity of substitution across varieties) in a sector affects the productivity cutoff for direct exporting since it determines the impact of the double marginalization imposed by wholesalers. Less competition (i.e., a smaller ¾) means that the cutoff for direct exporting is lower since the wholesaler s additional margin is higher, making it relatively more expensive to use. 8 Wholesale firms are homogeneous and I make the simplifying assumption that the atomistic manufacturing firms that use wholesalers for the distribution of their goods are randomly matched with wholesaler firms (see figure 2). This ensures that wholesaler firms will, in equilibrium, on average have identical baskets of goods that they export. 9 8 See proof 2 in online appendix A.3. 9 The assumption of random matching between manufacturing firms and wholesalers may appear to be strong, especially given the convexity in the fixed cost function of wholesalers, which indicates that wholesalers prefer to export products that are closer to each other in nature. However, the results would hold also if manufacturing firms were matched within only, for example, broader sector categories as long as wholesalers are homogenous in terms of costs. Moreover, the key mechanism in the model, that wholesalers face a lower fixed cost per product, would hold even if manufacturers were matched less randomly. One example would be that some wholesalers are matched with more productive manufacturers than others. These wholesalers with a portfolio of more productively produced products would, however, still demand a markup from the producers, ¾=(¾ 1) under CES preferences, and therefore deter the most productive exporters but attract manufacturers from the intermediate productivity range. Finally, even if

12 Wholesalers in international trade 167 Therefore, they will have the same number of products and also the same productivity distribution among the goods in their baskets. 10 The scope of goods that wholesaler firms handle will be equal to the mass of manufacturing firms that use wholesalers for exporting (i.e., those with a level of productivity between ' W and ' X ). The mass of manufacturers in this range is M M G(' X ) G(' W ) 1 G(' D ), where M M is the mass of manufacturing firms in total. The scope per wholesaler, mj W, is then equal to this expression divided by the number of wholesale firms, n W : mj W = MM G(' X ) G(' W ) n W 1 G(' D ). A wholesaler takes as given the number of other wholesale firms and the mass of domestic manufacturing firms and its pricing mechanism is, as described in equation (4), a constant markup over the marginal cost. Therefore, the number of wholesale firms and the range of goods they consume can be determined by two conditions. First, the free entry condition for wholesalers states that the profits of wholesale firms should be zero. Second, an optimal scope condition by wholesalers, i.e., that the marginal increase in operating profits for a wholesaler firm to expand its set of goods distributed (its scope) must equal the resulting marginal increase in fixed costs, specifies the scope of each wholesale firm: F X + (mw j ) = mj W ¼ W j (Zero W j ( F X + (mw j ) W ( m W j ¼ W j ) (Optimal scope) wholesalers were assumed to be heterogeneous in terms of their cost function, and even if this were to be correlated with the markup they choose, the key difference between the two export modes would prevail since all wholesalers, regardless of costs, must charge some markup for each good for them to finance the extra cost of adding an additional product to their existing scope. 10 Wholesalers control more than one good and are therefore no longer atomistic like the manufacturing firms. This could potentially have implications for how they affect prices, but it is assumed here that the parameters are such that these baskets of atomistic products are still small enough not to have an effect on the aggregate price level. In a sense, a wholesaler could be labelled moleculistic, i.e., larger than an atomistic firm but still small enough not to have an effect on the aggregate price level. In this context, it can also be noted that in the seminal contributions by, for example, Dixit and Stiglitz (1977) and Krugman (1979, 1980), the distribution of differentiated varieties is discrete and not continuous such as in the more recent trade literature. With a discrete and finite set of varieties, all manufacturing firms are theoretically able to affect the aggregate price index so it has to be assumed that they do not.

13 168 A. Akerman These two conditions jointly determine the mass of manufacturing firms exporting through each wholesaler, m W j, and the weighted average of profits per good handled, ¼ W j : m W j ( ) 1 1 = FX (6) 1 ¼ W 1 ( ) 1 j = FX (7) 1 The fixed cost of exporting, F X, is the key variable in understanding how the size of wholesaler firms is determined. A higher fixed cost of exporting forces wholesale firms to expand their scope so that the fixed cost is spread across more goods. It also makes the operating profit per good handled larger in equilibrium. The parameter determining how difficult it is for wholesalers to handle more goods,, also plays an important role. The elasticity of the optimal scope with respect to the fixed cost in equation (6) is 1 which decreases in ; the more difficult it is to handle many goods, the less responsive is the scope of wholesalers to fixed costs. One can also note that the elasticity of the optimal scope of wholesalers with respect to the fixed cost of exporting is lower when it is more difficult for wholesalers to expand their scope (when is high). To close the equilibrium, I note that the operating profit of wholesaler j selling good i is ¼ij W = p W ij x ij p ij,p x ij = A F 1 ¾ ' i ¾ 1 ( ¾ 1 ¾ )1 2¾ ¾ 1 1. Therefore, the total operating profit of wholesale firm j is m W j ¼ W j (' W, ' X ) = mw j 1 ¾ A F G(' X ) G(' W ) ( ¾ ¾ 1 ) 1 2¾ 1 ¾ 1 'X ' W ' ¾ 1 dg('), where ¼ W j (' W, ' X ) is the average operating profit per good handled given the range of productivity in the basket. Combining this with (7) gives 1 ¾ A F ( ¾ ) 1 2¾ 1 G(' X ) G(' W ) ¾ 1 ¾ 1 'X ' W ' ¾ 1 1 ( ) 1 dg(') = FX, (8) 1 where ' W is the equilibrium level of the lowest productivity needed for a manufacturing firm to use a wholesaler firm to export. 11 The export cut-off, ' X,is determined according to equation (2) by, F X and A F. The variable and fixed trade costs are exogenous but A F is endogenous. Since the left-hand side of equation (8) is monotonically increasing in ' W, equation (8) yields an implicit solution for ' W as a function of A F. 11 There is nothing in the model that ensures that ' W > ' D (that manufacturers exporting through wholesalers need to be more productive than manufacturers producing for the domestic market). This has to be assumed but this restriction is similar to the assumption in the literature that ' X > ' D (that exporters are more productive than non-exporters). However, this does not matter for the final results.

14 Wholesalers in international trade 169 Using the equilibrium value for ' W, it is also possible to find a solution for the number of wholesale firms by combining mj W = MM G(' X ) G(' W ) n W 1 G(' D ) and (6): M M ( ) ( ) 1 G('X 1 ) G(' W ) n W = FX (9) 1 G(' D ) 1 Finally, the free entry condition for manufacturing firms says that, in expectation, the expected total profit of the entrepreneur must equal the fixed entry cost: 'X ( ) ¾ 1 ¾ (' ¾ 1 A F D )dg(')+ ' ¾ 1 1 ¾ A F dg(') ' D ' W ¾ (10) + (' ¾ 1 1 ¾ A F F X )dg(') = F E, ' X where F E ±(¾ 1) 1 ¾ ¾ ¾ F E. The set of equations (1), (5), (8), (9) and (10) yields implicit solutions for the productivity cutoffs ' D, ' W, ' X and the mass of wholesale and manufacturing firms, n W, M M. The per-firm demand A in Home and A F in Foreign is determined by the mass of firms, the number of wholesalers together with the productivity cutoff levels through the expression for the price levels. This set of equations therefore defines a general equilibrium in the sense that there is free entry in all sectors and that price levels and market demand are endogenous Imposing the Pareto distribution To find exact expressions for the importance of wholesalers in the economy, the exact distribution of productivity, G(') has to be specified. Therefore, I impose the scale-free Pareto distribution which has been found to correspond reasonably well with observed distributions of firm productivity. 12 Therefore, G(') = 1 ' k where ' [1, ). As is well known in the literature, it is also required that ¾ 1 k > 1 for a solution to exist in equilibrium. To calculate the relative export volumes that occur by firms exporting on their own versus through wholesalers, it can be noted that the export volume of a good through the two export modes is ( ¾ V i,x (' i ) = p i x i = V j,w (' i ) = p W ij xw ij = ¾ 1 ( ¾ ¾ 1 ) 1 ¾ 1 ¾ ' i ¾ 1 A F (direct exporting) ) 2(1 ¾) 1 ¾ ' i ¾ 1 A F (wholesale). 12 See Axtell (2001) or Luttmer (2007).

15 170 A. Akerman The ratio of total export volumes will therefore be V W V X = 'X V W (')dg(') ' W = V X (')dg(') ' X ( ) ( ¾ 1 ¾ 1 ( ) k (¾ 1) 'X 1), (11) ¾ which is an explicit function of the relative productivity cut-off levels ' X and ' W. The relative mass of firms exporting on their own versus through wholesalers can be written 'X dg ( ' ) ( ) k ' W 'X dg ( ' ) = 1, (12) ' W ' X which is also an explicit function of the relative productivity cutoffs. To see what affects the relative importance of wholesalers in total export volumes, equation (11), and scope, equation (12), it is thus necessary to understand what affects the relative productivity cut-off, ' X ' W. An explicit solution for ' W cannot be found but using equation (5) in equation (8) yields the following nonlinear relationship: ( ) k 'X 1 ' W ( 'X ' W ) k (¾ 1) 1 = 1F X (μ, w F L F ) 1, (13) ' W where 1 is a constant of parameters. 13 The expression shows that the relative productivity cut-off increases in the fixed cost of exporting where I now, again, include country-specific characteristics as mentioned at the beginning of this section. First, a higher fixed cost causes the relative productivity cut-off to increase. This causes: (i) more firms to export through wholesalers (which is equivalent to more varieties or products being exported through wholesalers) and (ii) the relative export volume that is managed by wholesalers to increase. 14 This result originates in the central mechanism provided by the model: the wholesale industry pools the fixed costs of exporting across goods and therefore reduces the fixed cost per good, a feature that is more important when fixed costs are large. We saw previously that a higher fixed cost causes wholesale firms to expand the set of goods that they handle. By doing so, the fixed cost per good decreases. Second, neither the variable trade cost,, nor per firm demand, A F, play any direct role for the choice of export mode. This is due to the fact that 13 1 k k (¾ 1) ( 1 ) ( ¾ 1 ¾ )¾ 1 ¾ ( ¾ 1 ¾ )2(¾ 1). 14 See proof 3 in online appendix A.3.

16 Wholesalers in international trade 171 for the operating profit, these variables affect wholesalers and direct exporters in identical ways (the only way in which they can affect the relative productivity cut-off is through their effect on the fixed cost). 15 The wholesale technology therefore exhibits an increasing returns to scale property with regard to product scope. An increase in the number of products that a wholesaler exports lowers the fixed cost per good, thus making wholesalers more important as fixed costs increase. The net effect of the elasticity of substitution, however, is unclear. More competition (higher ¾) makes firms at the margin between choosing direct or wholesale exporting opt for exporting through wholesalers. This should make ¾ increase the role played by wholesalers. However, a higher ¾ also makes price differences more important for revenues and profitability. When the elasticity of substitution is high, the additional markup imposed by wholesalers becomes more important for how much is actually sold and this has a negative effect on the aggregate role played by wholesalers in exporting. Finally, a welfare analysis of a multi-country setting of the model is conducted in online appendix A.1. This adds two main insights to what has been described so far. First, the ratio of the productivity cutoffs, 'J X, to each export ' J W destination J depends on country J s fixed cost of entry. Since such costs differ across countries, many manufacturing firms would export directly to some countries but through a wholesaler to other countries. A firm s export mode also depends on each country s multilateral resistance (as proposed by Anderson and van Wincoop, 2003), which takes into account the industry structure in the destination but also the level of exports from other countries to that specific market. In this case, the equilibrium would contain firms that use both export modes at the same time but not both export modes to the same country. 15 Distance and size appear to significantly affect the importance of intermediaries in activities relating to foreign trade in many empirical studies. Indeed, the empirical analysis in this paper shows that wholesalers are more important in distant and small markets, while contrary to the results of this paper, a range of possible mechanisms could create this pattern. An obvious candidate is that the fixed cost of entering a foreign market increases with distance, since cultural barriers, supervision costs etc. are larger in markets far away than in those close to the home country of a firm. This would be in line with the theoretical predictions presented here. As argued at the beginning of this section, there are also several potential mechanisms through which the fixed cost varies with size. Arkolakis (2010) shows how returns to scale in marketing technologies potentially make it easier for firms to enter large countries. Alternatively, the fact that more firms export to larger destinations could also create potential spillover effects across firms, thus making it easier to access larger markets. The main technical reason why my model does not give an explicit role to distance and size is the combination of using CES preferences and the Pareto distribution of firm productivity. The purpose of this paper, however, is to show what the specific assumption of wholesalers possessing economies of scope in international trade can explain; therefore, I do not extend the model further to incorporate these empirical facts.

17 172 A. Akerman Second, I find that the presence of wholesalers contributes positively to welfare by assisting firms at intermediate levels of productivity to overcome fixed costs of exporting. Therefore, wholesalers increase the range of products available for consumption in each country and reduce price indices and increase real wages. In other words, wholesalers mitigate the effects of fixed costs in international trade on welfare. This analysis also shows that the expression for a country s welfare can be reduced to a simple expression that makes it directly comparable to Chaney (2008) (one of the standard references for analyzing the welfare consequences of firm heterogeneity in a Melitz-style economy) and how the existence of wholesalers strictly raises welfare as compared to a world without wholesalers as in Chaney (2008). 3. Empirical evidence 3.1. Data I use a dataset from Statistics Sweden that contains information on the economic activities of the universe of Swedish firms in 2005 (a firm is defined as the legal unit). The data are collected by the Swedish Tax Agency (Skatteverket) and contain information on, for example, total annual revenues, number of employees (reported once every year at a certain point in time) and total fixed assets. A firm in this dataset is classified according to its main business activity, and the following analysis will use firms that are listed as wholesalers and firms active in any of the manufacturing sectors. The only restriction I make is to exclude firms with no employees. Since misreporting is prosecuted and these data are subjected to quality controls by statisticians at Statistics Sweden, measurement errors are most likely rare. Through a common firm identifier, I match these data with a trade dataset collected by Swedish Customs (Tullverket) that records all trade flows per firm, product code (according to the Combined Nomenclature, CN, up to 8 digits) and destination country. 16 I use only exporting firms (about 35% of both manufacturers and wholesalers export) and in 2005, there were 7,248 wholesaler firms exporting and 8,768 manufacturing firms. In total, 468,710 transactions are reported over 8,272 CN8 categories and 194 destination countries. I conduct only a cross-sectional analysis in this study since a panel study with several years would use only variation in the definition of a firm s main business activity, which would not be very informative, or in the destination country characteristics and this variation is very small. Due to the extreme detail of the CN8 classification, I use the number of CN8 categories exported by a firm as a proxy for the number of products exported by a firm. 17 The average number of CN8 product categories that a 16 The CN is a classification system used by the European Commission in its external statistics and it is based on the Harmonized System of product classification. 17 As stated, I observe more than 8,000 product categories in the data. An example of its level of detail is the subcategory CN code 6601, containing umbrellas. It is

18 Wholesalers in international trade 173 firm exported was 11 for wholesalers and nine for manufacturers. In terms of volumes, however, manufacturers were much larger and accounted for 86% of aggregate export volumes. As for market size (GDP) and the institutional variables used, all data come from the World Bank s World Development Indicators (WDI) and Doing Business databases. Distance measures are from Centre d études prospectives et d informations internationales (CEPII). A full list and description of each variable can be found in online appendix table A1. Table 1 reports descriptive statistics for exporting wholesalers and manufacturers. The main conclusion from this table is that manufacturing firms are, on average, much larger than wholesale firms in terms of turnover, number of workers as well as capital employed. Moreover, despite the smaller size of wholesalers, they export a larger number of products than manufacturers. This difference between manufacturing firms and wholesale firms in the sense that manufacturing firms tend to be larger in terms of export volumes while wholesalers, instead, export a larger scope, can also be seen in figure 3 which shows how wholesalers share of export volumes and export scope, respectively, are distributed across destinations. It can be seen that the distribution of the share of the scope controlled by wholesalers clearly lies to the right of the distribution of the share of export volumes controlled by wholesalers Main assumption and predictions This section will empirically assess the main predictions of the model: 1. Wholesalers export more products than manufacturers. 2. Export sales per good are lower for wholesalers than for producers exporting on their own. 3. A larger share of aggregate export volumes is handled by wholesalers to countries with high fixed costs of entry. 4. A larger share of the number of exported products is handled by wholesalers to countries with high fixed costs of entry. The underlying assumption of the model is that the wholesale technology is characterized by economies of scope, while that of manufacturers is not. This is a simplification of the case in which wholesalers have more economies of scope as compared to manufacturers (i.e., that wholesalers have a comparative advantage in generating economies of scope in exporting). We already know from a vast literature that manufactures often sell more than one product and that firms doing so are often important in terms of size and export volumes. 18 However, one way of seeing whether this assumption is reasonable is to look at divided into Garden or similar umbrellas and Other umbrellas. The latter category is divided into umbrellas with a telescopic shaft and those without. These are then divided into umbrellas with a cover of woven textiles and those without. Therefore, it seems reasonable to view a CN8 category as a manufacturing variety (or a product the two are equivalent in the model) in the analysis. 18 See, for example, Bernard et al. (2010b) and Mayer and Ottaviano (2008).

A Theory on the Role of Wholesalers in International Trade Based on Economies of Scope

A Theory on the Role of Wholesalers in International Trade Based on Economies of Scope A Theory on the Role of Wholesalers in International Trade Based on Economies of Scope Anders Akerman January 5, 2014 (first version January, 2010) Abstract This paper offers an explanation for the existence

More information

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Class Notes on Chaney (2008) Class Notes on Chaney (2008) (With Krugman and Melitz along the Way) Econ 840-T.Holmes Model of Chaney AER (2008) As a first step, let s write down the elements of the Chaney model. asymmetric countries

More information

Firms in International Trade. Lecture 2: The Melitz Model

Firms in International Trade. Lecture 2: The Melitz Model Firms in International Trade Lecture 2: The Melitz Model Stephen Redding London School of Economics 1 / 33 Essential Reading Melitz, M. J. (2003) The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and

More information

International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity

International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity .. International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity Akihiko Yanase (Graduate School of Economics) January 13, 2017 1 / 28 Introduction Krugman (1979, 1980)

More information

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Trading Company and Indirect Exports Trading Company and Indirect Exports Kiyoshi Matsubara June 015 Abstract This article develops an oligopoly model of trade intermediation. In the model, manufacturing firm(s) wanting to export their products

More information

Economics 689 Texas A&M University

Economics 689 Texas A&M University Horizontal FDI Economics 689 Texas A&M University Horizontal FDI Foreign direct investments are investments in which a firm acquires a controlling interest in a foreign firm. called portfolio investments

More information

Foreign Direct Investment I

Foreign Direct Investment I FD Foreign Direct nvestment [My notes are in beta. f you see something that doesn t look right, would greatly appreciate a heads-up.] 1 FD background Foreign direct investment FD) occurs when an enterprise

More information

The heterogeneous effects of trade facilitation: theory and evidence

The heterogeneous effects of trade facilitation: theory and evidence The heterogeneous effects of trade facilitation: theory and evidence Shon Ferguson and Rikard Forslid September 2011, Work in progress Abstract The purpose of this study is to test what type of firms start

More information

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Journal of Economic Integration 20(4), December 2005; 631-643 Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare Noritsugu Nakanishi Kobe University Toru Kikuchi Kobe University

More information

Econ 8401-T.Holmes. Lecture on Foreign Direct Investment. FDI is massive. As noted in Ramondo and Rodriquez-Clare, worldwide sales of multinationals

Econ 8401-T.Holmes. Lecture on Foreign Direct Investment. FDI is massive. As noted in Ramondo and Rodriquez-Clare, worldwide sales of multinationals Econ 8401-T.Holmes Lecture on Foreign Direct Investment FDI is massive. As noted in Ramondo and Rodriquez-Clare, worldwide sales of multinationals is on the order of twice that of total world exports.

More information

ECO2704 Lecture Notes: Melitz Model

ECO2704 Lecture Notes: Melitz Model ECO2704 Lecture Notes: Melitz Model Xiaodong Zhu University of Toronto October 15, 2010 1 / 22 Dynamic Industry Model with heterogeneous firms where opening to trade leads to reallocations of resources

More information

FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out

FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out Kiyoshi Matsubara August 2005 Abstract This article addresses the decision of plant location by a home firm and its impact on the home economy, especially through

More information

Export intermediaries and adjustments to exchange rate movements

Export intermediaries and adjustments to exchange rate movements ISSN 2282-6483 Export intermediaries and adjustments to exchange rate movements Stefano Bolatto Marco Grazzi Chiara Tomasi Quaderni - Working Paper DSE N 2004 Export intermediaries and adjustments to exchange

More information

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business

Discussion Papers In Economics And Business Discussion Papers In Economics And Business The Effect of Technology Choice on Specialization and Welfare in a Two-Country Model Yukiko Sawada Discussion Paper 15-10 Graduate School of Economics and Osaka

More information

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium Online Appendix to Partnerships versus Corporations: Moral Hazard, Sorting and Ownership Structure Ayca Kaya and Galina Vereshchagina Appendix A formally defines an equilibrium in our model, Appendix B

More information

Volume 30, Issue 4. A decomposition of the home-market effect

Volume 30, Issue 4. A decomposition of the home-market effect Volume 30, Issue 4 A decomposition of the home-market effect Toru Kikuchi Kobe University Ngo van Long McGill University Abstract Although the home-market effect has become one of the most important concepts

More information

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

Trading Company and Indirect Exports Trading Company and Indirect Exports Kiyoshi atsubara August 0 Abstract This article develops an oligopoly model of trade intermediation. In the model, two manufacturing firms that want to export their

More information

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics PhD Topics in Macroeconomics Lecture 5: heterogeneous firms and trade, part three Chris Edmond 2nd Semester 204 This lecture Chaney (2008) on intensive and extensive margins of trade - Open economy model,

More information

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS Bielefeld University phemelo.tamasiga@uni-bielefeld.de 01-July-2013 Agenda 1 Motivation 2 3 4 5 6 Motivation Samuelson (1939);there are gains from trade, consequently

More information

Intermediaries, Firm Heterogeneity, and Exporting Behavior

Intermediaries, Firm Heterogeneity, and Exporting Behavior Intermediaries, Firm Heterogeneity, and Exporting Behavior Jiangyong Lu a, Yi Lu b, and Zhigang Tao c a Peking University b National University of Singapore c University of Hong Kong First Draft: November

More information

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University April 12, 2008 Abstract A model of mixed oligopoly is constructed in which a Home public firm

More information

Endogenous FDI Spillovers: Do You Want to Keep Your Recipe to Yourself?

Endogenous FDI Spillovers: Do You Want to Keep Your Recipe to Yourself? Endogenous FDI Spillovers: Do You Want to Keep Your Recipe to Yourself? Kiyoshi Matsubara July 007 Abstract This paper aims to explore the role of spillovers in the strategic choice for a MNE in a duopoly

More information

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade. Product Di erentiation Introduction We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade. Now we see how product di erentiation can provide a basis for trade due to consumers valuing

More information

Melitz Model: Heterogenous Firm Model of Trade

Melitz Model: Heterogenous Firm Model of Trade Melitz Model: Heterogenous Firm Model of Trade Seyed Ali Madanizadeh Sharif U. of Tech. May 7, 2014 Seyed Ali Madanizadeh (Sharif U. of Tech.) Melitz Model: Heterogenous Firm Model of Trade May 7, 2014

More information

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003)

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003) 14.581 Week 8 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 8) Melitz (2003) Spring 2013 1 / 42 Firm-Level Heterogeneity and Trade What s wrong

More information

Introduction to New New Trade Theory

Introduction to New New Trade Theory Introduction to New New Trade Theory Beverly Lapham October 2017 Traditional Theory: Country Level Analysis Assumes that average production cost is independent of output level. Gains from trade result

More information

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description

Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description Assessing the Spillover Effects of Changes in Bank Capital Regulation Using BoC-GEM-Fin: A Non-Technical Description Carlos de Resende, Ali Dib, and Nikita Perevalov International Economic Analysis Department

More information

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices : Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices (2008, AER) December 5 th, 2008 Empirical motivation US PPI-based RER is highly volatile Under PPP, this should induce a high volatility

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours Ekonomia nr 47/2016 123 Ekonomia. Rynek, gospodarka, społeczeństwo 47(2016), s. 123 133 DOI: 10.17451/eko/47/2016/233 ISSN: 0137-3056 www.ekonomia.wne.uw.edu.pl Aggregation with a double non-convex labor

More information

Trade Intermediation and the Organization of Exporters

Trade Intermediation and the Organization of Exporters Trade Intermediation and the Organization of Exporters by Gabriel Felbermayr and Benjamin Jung Nr.309/2009 ISSN 0930-8334 Trade Intermediation and the Organization of Exporters Gabriel J. Felbermayr and

More information

1 The Solow Growth Model

1 The Solow Growth Model 1 The Solow Growth Model The Solow growth model is constructed around 3 building blocks: 1. The aggregate production function: = ( ()) which it is assumed to satisfy a series of technical conditions: (a)

More information

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot Online Theory Appendix Not for Publication) Equilibrium in the Complements-Pareto Case

More information

Facts and Figures on Intermediated Trade

Facts and Figures on Intermediated Trade Bernardo S. Blum Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto Sebastian Claro Ponti cia Universidad Catolica de Chile and Central Bank of Chile Ignatius J. Horstmann Rotman School of Management,

More information

A Model of Trade with Ricardian Comparative Advantage and Intra-sectoral Firm Heterogeneity

A Model of Trade with Ricardian Comparative Advantage and Intra-sectoral Firm Heterogeneity A Model of Trade with Ricardian Comparative Advantage and Intra-sectoral Firm Heterogeneity Haichao FAN Edwin L.-C. LAI Han QI December 24, 20 Abstract In this paper, we merge the heterogenous firm trade

More information

Theory Appendix for: Buyer-Seller Relationships in International Trade: Evidence from U.S. State Exports and Business-Class Travel

Theory Appendix for: Buyer-Seller Relationships in International Trade: Evidence from U.S. State Exports and Business-Class Travel Theory Appendix for: Buyer-Seller Relationships in International Trade: Evidence from U.S. State Exports and Business-Class Travel Anca Cristea University of Oregon December 2010 Abstract This appendix

More information

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress Stephen D. Williamson Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis May 14, 015 1 Introduction When a central bank operates under a floor

More information

Do multinational retailers affect the export competitiveness of their host countries?

Do multinational retailers affect the export competitiveness of their host countries? Do multinational retailers affect the export competitiveness of their host countries? Angela Cheptea* (IAW, Tuebingen, Germany & UMR SMART, INRA Rennes, France) The accelerated overseas expansion of multinational

More information

Lecture 3: New Trade Theory

Lecture 3: New Trade Theory Lecture 3: New Trade Theory Isabelle Méjean isabelle.mejean@polytechnique.edu http://mejean.isabelle.googlepages.com/ Master Economics and Public Policy, International Macroeconomics October 30 th, 2008

More information

ESSAYS ON TRADE LIBERALIZATION WITH FIRM HETEROGENEITY. Aleksandr Vashchilko. Dissertation. Submitted to the faculty of the

ESSAYS ON TRADE LIBERALIZATION WITH FIRM HETEROGENEITY. Aleksandr Vashchilko. Dissertation. Submitted to the faculty of the ESSAYS ON TRADE LIBERALIZATION WITH FIRM HETEROGENEITY By Aleksandr Vashchilko Dissertation Submitted to the faculty of the Graduate School of Vanderbilt University in partial ful llment of the requirements

More information

Offshoring and skill-upgrading in French manufacturing: a Heckscher-Ohlin-Melitz view

Offshoring and skill-upgrading in French manufacturing: a Heckscher-Ohlin-Melitz view Offshoring and skill-upgrading in French manufacturing: a Heckscher-Ohlin-Melitz view Juan Carluccio (Banque de France and U. of Surrey) Alejandro Cuñat (University of Vienna) Harald Fadinger (University

More information

Impact of Tariff under Hecksher-Ohlin Comparative Advantage Setting and Firm Heterogeneity

Impact of Tariff under Hecksher-Ohlin Comparative Advantage Setting and Firm Heterogeneity Impact of Tariff under Hecksher-Ohlin Comparative Advantage Setting and Firm Heterogeneity ERASMUS UNIVERSITY ROTTERDAM Erasmus School of Economics Department of Economics Supervisor: Dr. J. Emami Namini

More information

Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade

Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade Klaus Desmet November 2010. Economic () Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade November 2010 1 / 35 Outline 1 The seminal model of economic

More information

Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices

Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices Haichao Fan Amber Li Sichuang Xu Stephen Yeaple Fudan, HKUST, HKUST, Penn State and NBER May 2018 Mark-Ups

More information

Location, Productivity, and Trade

Location, Productivity, and Trade May 10, 2010 Motivation Outline Motivation - Trade and Location Major issue in trade: How does trade liberalization affect competition? Competition has more than one dimension price competition similarity

More information

International Trade Gravity Model

International Trade Gravity Model International Trade Gravity Model Yiqing Xie School of Economics Fudan University Dec. 20, 2013 Yiqing Xie (Fudan University) Int l Trade - Gravity (Chaney and HMR) Dec. 20, 2013 1 / 23 Outline Chaney

More information

Facts and Figures on Intermediated Trade

Facts and Figures on Intermediated Trade Facts and Figures on Intermediated Trade By BERNARDO S. BLUM, SEBASTIAN CLARO AND IGNATIUS HORSTMANN Over the past several years, trade economists have begun exploring the role that intermediaries play

More information

Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location. This Version: 9 May 2006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE

Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location. This Version: 9 May 2006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location This Version: 9 May 006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location Nathaniel P.S. Cook Abstract This paper examines

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Heterogeneous Firms. Notes for Graduate Trade Course. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. January 30, 2013

Heterogeneous Firms. Notes for Graduate Trade Course. J. Peter Neary. University of Oxford. January 30, 2013 Heterogeneous Firms Notes for Graduate Trade Course J. Peter Neary University of Oxford January 30, 2013 J.P. Neary (University of Oxford) Heterogeneous Firms January 30, 2013 1 / 29 Plan of Lectures 1

More information

Should small countries fear deindustrialization?

Should small countries fear deindustrialization? Should small countries fear deindustrialization? Ai-Ting Goh and Tomasz Michalski Finance and Economics Department, HEC Paris May 9, 29 Abstract Will small countries deindustrialize when opening up to

More information

Université Paris I Panthéon-Sorbonne Cours de Commerce International L3 Exercise booklet

Université Paris I Panthéon-Sorbonne Cours de Commerce International L3 Exercise booklet Université Paris I Panthéon-Sorbonne Cours de Commerce International L3 Exercise booklet Course by Lionel Fontagné and Maria Bas Academic year 2017-2018 1 Differences Exercise 1.1 1. According to the traditional

More information

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities Wojciech Kopczuk Address: Department of Economics, University of British Columbia, #997-1873 East Mall, Vancouver BC V6T1Z1, Canada and NBER

More information

Multiproduct-Firm Oligopoly: An Aggregative Games Approach

Multiproduct-Firm Oligopoly: An Aggregative Games Approach Multiproduct-Firm Oligopoly: An Aggregative Games Approach Volker Nocke 1 Nicolas Schutz 2 1 UCLA 2 University of Mannheim ASSA ES Meetings, Philadephia, 2018 Nocke and Schutz (UCLA &Mannheim) Multiproduct-Firm

More information

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Transport Costs and North-South Trade Transport Costs and North-South Trade Didier Laussel a and Raymond Riezman b a GREQAM, University of Aix-Marseille II b Department of Economics, University of Iowa Abstract We develop a simple two country

More information

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes James E. Anderson February 6, 2009 These notes derive the useful concepts of trade expenditure functions, the closely related trade indirect utility

More information

International Trade

International Trade 4.58 International Trade Class notes on 5/6/03 Trade Policy Literature Key questions:. Why are countries protectionist? Can protectionism ever be optimal? Can e explain ho trade policies vary across countries,

More information

Federico Esposito. 41 Trumbull Street, Third floor Dept. of Economics, Yale University

Federico Esposito. 41 Trumbull Street, Third floor Dept. of Economics, Yale University Federico Esposito Home Address: Office Address: 41 Trumbull Street, Third floor Dept. of Economics, New Haven, CT 06510 37 Hillhouse Avenue Telephone: 203-772-9529 E-mail: mailto:federico.esposito@yale.edu

More information

Gravity, Trade Integration and Heterogeneity across Industries

Gravity, Trade Integration and Heterogeneity across Industries Gravity, Trade Integration and Heterogeneity across Industries Natalie Chen University of Warwick and CEPR Dennis Novy University of Warwick and CESifo Motivations Trade costs are a key feature in today

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory Chapter Microeconomics of Consumer Theory The two broad categories of decision-makers in an economy are consumers and firms. Each individual in each of these groups makes its decisions in order to achieve

More information

The Effects of Regional Free Trade Agreements on Industrial Structure: An Extension of Krugman s Economic Geography Model (1991)

The Effects of Regional Free Trade Agreements on Industrial Structure: An Extension of Krugman s Economic Geography Model (1991) Journal of Economic Integration 18(1), March 003; 4-59 The Effects of Regional Free Trade Agreements on Industrial Structure: An Extension of Krugman s Economic Geography Model (1991) Jung Hur National

More information

Firm Productivity and Exports in the Wholesale Sector: Evidence from Japan

Firm Productivity and Exports in the Wholesale Sector: Evidence from Japan RIETI Discussion Paper Series 13-E-007 Firm Productivity and Exports in the Wholesale Sector: Evidence from Japan TANAKA Ayumu RIETI The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/

More information

Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle

Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle Sophie Gruber Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle James E. Anderson and Eric van Wincoop American Economic Review, March 2003, Vol. 93(1), pp. 170-192 Outline 1. McCallum s Gravity Equation

More information

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics PhD Topics in Macroeconomics Lecture 16: heterogeneous firms and trade, part four Chris Edmond 2nd Semester 214 1 This lecture Trade frictions in Ricardian models with heterogeneous firms 1- Dornbusch,

More information

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION Matthias Doepke University of California, Los Angeles Martin Schneider New York University and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

More information

NOT FOR PUBLICATION. Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome. Small Open Economy Model

NOT FOR PUBLICATION. Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome. Small Open Economy Model NOT FOR PUBLICATION Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome Small Open Economy Model In this appendix, we develop a general equilibrium model of how increased import competition from China affects employment

More information

Comparison of Welfare Gains in the Armington, Krugman and Melitz Models

Comparison of Welfare Gains in the Armington, Krugman and Melitz Models Policy Research Working Paper 8570 WPS8570 Comparison of Welfare Gains in the Armington, Krugman and Melitz Models Insights from a Structural Gravity Approach Edward J. Balistreri David G. Tarr Public

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL SUPPLY CHAINS AND WAGE INEQUALITY. Arnaud Costinot Jonathan Vogel Su Wang

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL SUPPLY CHAINS AND WAGE INEQUALITY. Arnaud Costinot Jonathan Vogel Su Wang NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL SUPPLY CHAINS AND WAGE INEQUALITY Arnaud Costinot Jonathan Vogel Su Wang Working Paper 17976 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17976 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050

More information

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Paper No. 07/05 Firm heterogeneity, foreign direct investment and the hostcountry welfare: Trade costs vs. cheap labor By Arijit Mukherjee

More information

(b) per capita consumption grows at the rate of 2%.

(b) per capita consumption grows at the rate of 2%. 1. Suppose that the level of savings varies positively with the level of income and that savings is identically equal to investment. Then the IS curve: (a) slopes positively. (b) slopes negatively. (c)

More information

Langenmayr, Dominika: Limiting Profit Shifting in a Model with Heterogeneous Firm Productivity

Langenmayr, Dominika: Limiting Profit Shifting in a Model with Heterogeneous Firm Productivity Langenmayr, Dominika: Limiting Profit Shifting in a Model with Heterogeneous Firm Productivity Munich Discussion Paper No. 2011-19 Department of Economics University of Munich Volkswirtschaftliche Fakultät

More information

Trade effects based on general equilibrium

Trade effects based on general equilibrium e Theoretical and Applied Economics Volume XXVI (2019), No. 1(618), Spring, pp. 159-168 Trade effects based on general equilibrium Baoping GUO College of West Virginia, USA bxguo@yahoo.com Abstract. The

More information

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry Lin, Journal of International and Global Economic Studies, 7(2), December 2014, 17-31 17 Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically

More information

The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model

The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model Wisarut Suwanprasert Vanderbilt University December 206 Abstract I study the impact of the Most Favored Nation (MFN)

More information

Lecture 12: New Economic Geography

Lecture 12: New Economic Geography Econ 46 Urban & Regional Economics Lecture : New Economic Geography Instructor: Hiroki Watanabe Summer / 5 Model Assumptions Agricultural Sector Monopolistic Competition Manufacturing Sector Monopolistic

More information

"Gains from Intra-Firm Trade and Multinational Production"

Gains from Intra-Firm Trade and Multinational Production Thema Working Paper n 2014-14 Université de Cergy Pontoise, France "Gains from Intra-Firm Trade and Multinational Production" Pamela Bombarda Stefania Marcassa July, 2014 Gains from Intra-Firm Trade and

More information

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries BACKGROUND PAPER FOR THE WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2008 Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries Larry Karp The findings, interpretations, and conclusions

More information

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand Economics 101 Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand 1 Intro First, a note on wealth and endowment. Varian generally uses wealth (m) instead of endowment. Ultimately, these two are equivalent. Given prices p, if

More information

Productivity, Fair Wage and Offshoring Domestic Jobs

Productivity, Fair Wage and Offshoring Domestic Jobs Productivity, Fair Wage and Offshoring Domestic Jobs Xi Chen July 7, 2017 Preliminary draft Abstract This paper develops a general equilibrium model with monopolistic competition that incorporates: (i)

More information

The E ciency Comparison of Taxes under Monopolistic Competition with Heterogenous Firms and Variable Markups

The E ciency Comparison of Taxes under Monopolistic Competition with Heterogenous Firms and Variable Markups The E ciency Comparison of Taxes under Monopolistic Competition with Heterogenous Firms and Variable Markups November 9, 23 Abstract This paper compares the e ciency implications of aggregate output equivalent

More information

International Trade in Resource Goods and Returns to Labor in the Non-Resource Sectors

International Trade in Resource Goods and Returns to Labor in the Non-Resource Sectors IIFET 2000 roceedings International Trade in Resource Goods and Returns to Labor in the Non-Resource Sectors Ali Emami Departments of Finance and Economics University of Oregon USA Richard S. ohnston Department

More information

Distribution Costs & The Size of Indian Manufacturing Establishments

Distribution Costs & The Size of Indian Manufacturing Establishments Distribution Costs & The Size of Indian Manufacturing Establishments Alessandra Peter, Cian Ruane Stanford University November 3, 2017 Question Selling manufactured goods involves costs of distribution:

More information

Christian Mugele und Monika Schnitzer: Organization of Multinational Activities and Ownership Structure

Christian Mugele und Monika Schnitzer: Organization of Multinational Activities and Ownership Structure Christian Mugele und Monika Schnitzer: Organization of Multinational Activities and Ownership Structure Munich Discussion Paper No. 006-3 Department of Economics University of Munich Volkswirtschaftliche

More information

Intermediaries in International Trade: direct versus indirect modes of export

Intermediaries in International Trade: direct versus indirect modes of export : direct versus indirect modes of export Andrew B. Bernard Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth, CEPR & NBER Marco Grazzi LEM Scuola Superiore S.Anna Chiara Tomasi LEM Scuola Superiore S.Anna & Universita

More information

International Development and Firm Distribution

International Development and Firm Distribution International Development and Firm Distribution Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis February 2016 1 A. Introduction Conventional macroeconomic models employ aggregate production

More information

Lecture 14. Multinational Firms. 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies

Lecture 14. Multinational Firms. 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies Lecture 14 Multinational Firms 1. Review of empirical evidence 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies 3. A model with endogenous multinationals 4. Pattern of trade in goods

More information

The Effect of Globalization in a Semi Endogenous Growth Model with Firm Heterogeneity, Endogenous International Spillover, and Trade

The Effect of Globalization in a Semi Endogenous Growth Model with Firm Heterogeneity, Endogenous International Spillover, and Trade The Effect of Globalization in a Semi Endogenous Growth Model with Firm Heterogeneity, Endogenous International Spillover, and Trade Katsufumi Fukuda 1 August 3, 214 Abstract This paper shows that globalization

More information

Intermediaries, Firm Heterogeneity, and Exporting Behavior

Intermediaries, Firm Heterogeneity, and Exporting Behavior Intermediaries, Firm Heterogeneity, and Exporting Behavior Jiangyong Lu a, Yi Lu b, and Zhigang Tao c a Peking University b National University of Singapore c University of Hong Kong January 2015 Abstract

More information

International Trade: Lecture 4

International Trade: Lecture 4 International Trade: Lecture 4 Alexander Tarasov Higher School of Economics Fall 2016 Alexander Tarasov (Higher School of Economics) International Trade (Lecture 4) Fall 2016 1 / 34 Motivation Chapter

More information

Trade Costs and Job Flows: Evidence from Establishment-Level Data

Trade Costs and Job Flows: Evidence from Establishment-Level Data Trade Costs and Job Flows: Evidence from Establishment-Level Data Appendix For Online Publication Jose L. Groizard, Priya Ranjan, and Antonio Rodriguez-Lopez March 2014 A A Model of Input Trade and Firm-Level

More information

Unemployment, Income Growth and Social Security

Unemployment, Income Growth and Social Security MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Unemployment, Income Growth and Social Security Minoru Watanabe and Yusuke Miyake and Masaya Yasuoka Hokusei Gakuen University, Shigakukan University, Kwansei Gakuin

More information

Optimal Redistribution in an Open Economy

Optimal Redistribution in an Open Economy Optimal Redistribution in an Open Economy Oleg Itskhoki Harvard University Princeton University January 8, 2008 1 / 29 How should society respond to increasing inequality? 2 / 29 How should society respond

More information

Monetary union enlargement and international trade

Monetary union enlargement and international trade Monetary union enlargement and international trade Alessandro Marchesiani and Pietro Senesi June 30, 2006 Abstract This paper studies the effects of monetary union enlargement on international trade in

More information

Competition for goods in buyer-seller networks

Competition for goods in buyer-seller networks Rev. Econ. Design 5, 301 331 (2000) c Springer-Verlag 2000 Competition for goods in buyer-seller networks Rachel E. Kranton 1, Deborah F. Minehart 2 1 Department of Economics, University of Maryland, College

More information

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy George Alogoskoufis* Athens University of Economics and Business September 2012 Abstract This paper examines

More information

TEACHING OPEN-ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS WITH IMPLICIT AGGREGATE SUPPLY ON A SINGLE DIAGRAM *

TEACHING OPEN-ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS WITH IMPLICIT AGGREGATE SUPPLY ON A SINGLE DIAGRAM * Australasian Journal of Economics Education Volume 7, Number 1, 2010, pp.9-19 TEACHING OPEN-ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS WITH IMPLICIT AGGREGATE SUPPLY ON A SINGLE DIAGRAM * Gordon Menzies School of Finance

More information

Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions

Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions Open economies review 14: 5 9, 2003 c 2003 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in The Netherlands. Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions TORU KIKUCHI kikuchi@econ.kobe-u.ac.jp Graduate School of Economics,

More information

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 1: Ricardian Models (I)

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 1: Ricardian Models (I) CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 1: Ricardian Models (I) Dave Donaldson (MIT) CEMMAP MC July 2018 1 All material based on earlier courses

More information

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth Robert J. Barro 1990 Represented by m.sefidgaran & m.m.banasaz Graduate School of Management and Economics Sharif university of Technology 11/17/2013

More information