Why Do Managers Fight Shareholder Proposals? Evidence from SEC No-Action Letter Decisions

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Why Do Managers Fight Shareholder Proposals? Evidence from SEC No-Action Letter Decisions"

Transcription

1 Why Do Managers Fight Shareholder Proposals? Evidence from SEC No-Action Letter Decisions John G. Matsusaka, Oguzhan Ozbas, and Irene Yi University of Southern California March 2017 New Working Paper Series No. 7 Stigler Center for the Study of the Economy and the State University of Chicago Booth School of Business 5807 S Woodlawn Ave Chicago, IL 60637

2 Why Do Managers Fight Shareholder Proposals? Evidence from SEC No- Action Letter Decisions John G. Matsusaka, Oguzhan Ozbas, and Irene Yi University of Southern California March 2017 This paper studies whether corporate managers are pursuing their own interests, or defending shareholder interests, when they fight shareholder proposals. Managers argue that shareholder proposals are harmful to firm value because they are uninformed or opportunistic, while activists argue that managerial opposition is self-interested and proposals increase firm value by counteracting managerial agency problems. We examine stock price movements following SEC noaction letter decisions to provide evidence on managerial motives. Relative to previous studies that are limited by an inability to identify precisely when investors become aware of a proposal, our new approach is to study a well-defined event date at which the SEC makes an uncertain and expressly value-neutral decision to block or allow a proposal to go forward, allowing causal estimates of the value consequences. We find that over the period , the market reacts positively when the SEC permits a proposal to be omitted from the proxy, suggesting that investors agree with managers that these proposals are value-destroying. Investors appear to be most skeptical about proposals relating to corporate governance and the elements of the E-Index, and proposals targeted at high-profit firms are viewed as particularly damaging. Comments welcome. We thank David Primo and workshop participants at George Mason University, UC- Riverside, University of Chicago, and University of Maryland for helpful comments; Amartya Bose and Elise Matsusaka for able research assistance; and USC for financial support. Contact authors at: matsusak@usc.edu, ozbas@usc.edu, irene.e.yi@gmail.com.

3 Why Do Managers Fight Shareholder Proposals? Evidence from SEC No- Action Letter Decisions 1. Introduction To what extent do managers pursue their own interests at the expense of shareholder interests? This question lies at the heart of ongoing controversies in economics and law concerning the modern corporation, and suspicion of managers is fueling a prominent reform movement that is dedicated to expanding shareholder rights. Economic theory offers two contrasting perspectives: Principal-agent theory emphasizes the self-interest of managers, and the dearth of incentives that would induce them to focus on shareholder value (Jensen and Murphy, 1990). The root problem is dispersed ownership that creates free-riding in monitoring and disciplining managers, a problem highlighted in any number of classic books and articles going back to Berle and Means (1932) if not earlier. In contrast, the competition view calls attention to market forces that pressure managers to pursue the interests of shareholders. Managers are constrained by corporate control markets (Manne, 1965), managerial labor markets, and oversight by boards of directors (Fama, 1980). The view that managers act in the interest of shareholders also has a long tradition in the law, and is the basis for the business judgment rule that creates a presumption that directors and managers are acting in the corporation s best interest. The purpose of this paper is to provide an empirical assessment of whether managers pursue their own or shareholder interests in a situation that seems ripe for conflict: when managers oppose shareholder proposals. A shareholder proposal, as the name suggests, is a proposal to change the company s practices or policies, made by one of the shareholders, that goes to a vote of shareholders at large. Shareholder proposals are an increasingly important weapon in the arsenal of corporate governance reformers. More than 16,000 proposals have been submitted at large corporations since 1997, votes have recently been held to break up the largest commercial banks and drive down executive 1

4 pay, 1 and proposals have pressured many companies to remove staggered boards, replace supermajority with majority voting standards, enhance proxy access, disclose their political contributions, and a variety of other issues. 2 Along with the surge in shareholder proposals has come a series of regulatory changes expanding voting rights and making it easier for shareholders to bring their proposals to a vote. 3 At the same time, managers continue to vigorously resist increased use of shareholder proposals, both through organizations that seek to influence regulations such as the Business Roundtable, and by seeking to exclude individual proposals from appearing in their firms proxy statement through the Securities and Exchange Commission s (SEC) no-action letter process. Managers argue that shareholder proposals are often misguided and likely to harm the firm, or are promoted by activist shareholders in order to advance their private interests. 4 Managerial efforts to shut down shareholder proposals provide an interesting testing ground because the conflict between managers and (a group of) shareholders is so direct. SEC rules allow companies to exclude a proposal from the proxy statement under certain conditions, such as if the proponent fails to demonstrate minimum stock ownership, the proposal relates to redress of a personal grievance, is vague or indefinite, 1 In 2015, shareholders voted on proposals sponsored by labor-affiliated groups to break up Bank of America, Citigroup, JPMorgan Chase, and Wells Fargo. An example on executive pay: Janus cuts CEO pay 40 percent after shareholder vote, Reuters (Kerber, 2012). 2 Examples: In 2005, only nine of the S&P 100 companies used majority voting for director elections; by January 2014, almost 90 percent of the S&P 500 had adopted majority voting (Choi et al., 2016). The number of S&P 500 companies with staggered boards declined from 300 in the year 2000 to 60 in 2013 (Harvard Shareholder Rights Project: 3 Following Dodd-Frank, the SEC modified rule 14a-8(i)(8) to allow proxy access proposals. Another example is the Delaware Supreme Court s CA, Inc. v. AFSCME Employees Pension Plan decision in 2008 that allowed shareholder proposals to alter a company s bylaws concerning decision making processes and procedures. 4 Seen from this perspective, shareholder proposals are at best a distraction to managers, and at worst harmful: proxy advisory firms may be so ill-informed that they advise shareholders to support proposals that are not in their interest (Larcker and Tayan, 2011; Larcker et al., 2015); and certain shareholders might use proposals as bargaining chips to induce managers to allocate corporate resources for the benefit of the proponent at a cost to shareholders at large (Matsusaka et al., 2016). Matsusaka and Ozbas (forthcoming) develop a model that captures these various issues. 2

5 or deals with ordinary business operations. If a company wishes to omit a proposal, it submits a letter to the SEC asking the staff to confirm that the agency will not take action against the company if it omits the proposal, called a no-action letter. Companies seek to exclude 31 percent of proposals that they receive, and the SEC grants a no-action letter permitting omission in 67 percent of its decisions. Our research strategy is to use the stock price reaction in the days surrounding the SEC s decision to infer the market s assessment of a proposal. If managers resist a proposal for responsible (value-maximizing) reasons, then we should observe a positive market reaction when the SEC allows a proposal to be omitted; if managers resist for self-interested (value-reducing) reasons, then we should observe a negative market reaction when the SEC allows a proposal to be omitted. We are not the first to study the effect of shareholder proposals on firm value, but we believe our identification strategy is a significant innovation. Previous research, beginning with Karpoff et al. (1996) almost uniformly fails to uncover evidence of positive or negative effects (Denes et al., forthcoming). 5 There is some reason to wonder, however, if existing research designs have enough power to detect valuation effects. The studies employ event-return methods, which have a good research track record, but the actual date at which a proposal becomes known to the market is difficult to determine; there is seldom a formal announcement or media coverage. In lieu of hard information about when the market learns about a proposal, most studies use either the date that the proxy statement is mailed to shareholders. However, in order to make a proposal, a shareholder must send a notice to the company at least 120 days before the proxy statement is mailed; companies must file their proxy with the SEC 10 days before mailing it; and SEC rule 14a-6(e)(1) requires the preliminary statement to be made immediately available for public inspection. So there is ample reason to expect the information to have reached the market before the proxy is mailed. Our study addresses this issue by employing a new research strategy that focuses on SEC decision dates. We argue that the existence of a proposal is known by the time of the SEC decision (by then it has been reviewed and discussed by the proponents, the company, the law firms representing both parties, and SEC attorneys), but the outcome of the 5 A notable exception, discussed below, is Cuñat et al. (2012) that uses different research methods. 3

6 decision which determines whether the proposal goes to a vote or is shut down is news to investors because it is not fully predictable. The return in excess of market movements in the days surrounding the SEC decision then sheds light on whether management s challenge is for responsible or self-interested reasons. By focusing specifically on proposals opposed by managers, as opposed to all proposals, we are able to speak to the issue of managerial incentives. Last but not least, because we have a specific event date for each proposal (as opposed to the proxy mailing approach, which assigns the same date to all proposals in a given proxy statement), we can estimate proposal-specific returns, and explore how proposal-specific features such as topic and sponsor type affect returns. We study hand-collected data on all 2,828 proposals for which a no-action letter was requested from October 2007 through the end of Our main finding is that the market responded positively to the grant of a no-action letter. The mean cumulative abnormal return ranges from 0.20 percent to 0.55 percent depending on the event window, and is statistically distinguishable from zero, meaning the market approved of shutting down these proposals. As a back-of-the-envelope calculation, if we assume that the probability of being denied a no-action letter is the sample average of 0.28, then the implied expected value from an uncertain shareholder vote on a challenged proposal ranges from percent to percent of firm value. 6 If we further assume that the probability of a proposal being approved, conditional on going to a vote, is 0.27 as reported in Cuñat et al. (2012), then the implied value consequence of a challenged proposal, if it had been approved in the end, ranges from to percent of firm value. These numbers appear to be material, and could explain the resistance of managers. In terms of the question that motivates the paper, the evidence suggests that managers are fighting these proposals for responsible rather than self-interested reasons. After establishing the robustness of the main finding, we explore the extent to which the market s response depended on a proposal s topic or the identity of its proponent. The most common topic is corporate governance, and proposals concerning compensation and social issues are common. We find a positive response to omission of corporate governance 6 In these calculations, for the sake of brevity, we ignore the expected value of withdrawn proposals. We provide a more comprehensive analysis of the implied value of proposals below. 4

7 proposals on average. The mean returns range from 0.33 percent to 0.80 percent and are statistically significant suggesting that managers were acting responsibly when they opposed these proposals. We also find some evidence that investors were skeptical of proposals that would have improved the quality of governance as defined by the G-Index and E-Index. We find no statistically significant response to omission of proposals related to compensation as a group, or social issues as a group. Recent court opinions and some scholarly evidence suggest that certain types of shareholders are more likely to bring proposals that advance their narrow interests rather than overall firm value. Labor unions and public pensions have been singled out (Romano, 1993, 2001; Schwab and Thomas, 1998; Matsusaka et al., 2016). We do not find evidence that the announcement return depended on the type of proponent, whether classified broadly as individuals versus organizations, or classified in a more fine-grained way that differentiates SRI funds, non-sri funds, labor unions, public pensions, and religious groups. When the SEC declined a no-action letter request and allowed a proposal to go to a vote, we find smaller, statistically insignificant mean returns. Given the positive mean return associated with omitted proposals, we might have expected to find a negative mean return associated with proposals that went to a vote, but the lack of statistical significance simply may be due to the 50 percent smaller sample size for proposals that went to a vote. And there is a subtler complication: the return associated with a proposal going to a vote can be positive even if the market considers the value of the proposal to be negative. This is because there is a third possible outcome once a request is made: the proposal can be withdrawn before the SEC makes a decision. This happens in 14 percent of the cases, usually at the request of the proposal s sponsor, following some sort of accommodation by management. If a side deal between an activist and management is harmful to shareholders at large, as suggested by theory and some anecdotes (Matsusaka and Ozbas, forthcoming), then the market might react positively when the SEC allows a proposal to go to a vote because it means that a harmful side deal was not struck, even if the proposal itself is harmful. To gain some insight on this possibility, the second substantive section of the paper develops a theoretical model of the no-action letter process that allows for proposals to be withdrawn. The model illustrates that while the sign of the return associated with an SEC 5

8 decision can be used to infer the market s assessment of whether the manager was pursuing shareholder interests, the sign of the return does not necessarily indicate the market s implied value of the proposal itself. Using the model, we prove a result that allows us to infer the mean implied value of challenged proposals from a regression model using abnormal returns. Using this method, we estimate a mean implied value ranging from to percent for the entire sample. Although not statistically significant, the magnitude of the estimate suggests that part of the positive abnormal return associated with SEC decisions is due to the fact that a withdrawn proposal did not occur. We then investigate for which firms proposals were most likely to be helpful and harmful. Our main finding in this regard is that proposals targeted at high-profit firms were expected to reduce firm value by 0.48 percent to 1.11 percent, depending on the event window, and controlling for topic and proponent type; while proposals at low-profit firms were expected to increase firm value. Investors may dislike proposals targeted at high-profit firms because they threaten to disrupt operations that are performing well. This squares with existing evidence that low-performing firms are most likely to be targeted by shareholder proposals (Denes et al., forthcoming). The main contribution of our paper is to shed light on the motives for managerial resistance to enhanced shareholder rights. The evidence is compatible with the view that managerial resistance is often based on a genuine concern that shareholder proposals harm firm value, particularly when it comes to high-performing firms, and is not merely a convenient rationalization in order to preserve managerial private benefits. This suggests that competitive pressures may be more effective than sometimes believed in controlling managerial agency problems. Our paper is also intended as a contribution to the literature that seeks to determine the value consequences of shareholder rights. The legal environment has been moving steadily in the direction of expanded shareholder rights, giving the impression of a consensus that enhanced rights are beneficial, yet the scholarly evidence is surprisingly inconclusive. At a general level, several studies that estimate the market reaction to expansion of shareholder rights fail to produce compelling evidence that investors value 6

9 having more rights. 7 In terms of shareholder proposals, our finding that the market approves on average when proposals are shut down suggests that many of these proposals are not helpful to shareholders. This does not imply that the process itself lacks value, only that some uses of it are harmful. A more holistic analysis would be necessary to draw conclusions about the overall value of the process, but our analysis suggests that the idea of a positive net value cannot be taken for granted; it requires evidence of concrete benefits that would offset the costs we find. 2. No-Action Letters and the Proposal Process Shareholder voting rights are rooted in state corporation law and corporate charter documents, but the proposal process itself is governed by SEC Rule 14a-8. The SEC began regulating the process in 1935 based on Section 14 of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 that charged the agency to develop proxy regulations in the public interest and for the protection of investors. Over time, the SEC gradually developed a body of regulations that came to be collected in Rule 14a-8. 8 This rule has been amended many times over the years, most recently in Under state law, shareholders have a right to make proposals in person at a company s annual meetings. Because most shareholders do not attend the annual meeting, they cast their votes by proxy. The company is required to distribute a proxy statement prior to the annual meeting to all shareholders that in effect allows them to vote in absentia. The federal proxy access rules govern the conditions under which shareholders can require their proposals to be listed in the company s proxy statement. The proposal process begins with a shareholder proponent drafting a proposal and sending it to the company. The proposal offers a resolution to be voted on, as well as an argument in its favor. The resolution can take the form of a specific change in the 7 Negative evidence is in Akyol et al. (2012); Larcker et al. (2011); Stratmann and Verret (2012). Positive evidence is in Cohn et al. (2016) and Becker et al. (2013). Studies often report findings that appear to be sensitive to certain subsamples and event dates. 8 For histories of the development of the shareholder proposal rules, see Liebeler (1984) and Fisch (1993). For developments over the last two decades, see Bainbridge (2012). 9 In September 2011, 14a-8(i) was amended so that a company could no longer exclude proposals that would facilitate director nominations by shareholders (proxy access). 7

10 company s bylaws or it can be a request for the company to consider taking some action. The proposal must arrive at the company no later than 120 days before the proxy statement is to be mailed. The company then has the option to include the proposal in the proxy statement or the company can attempt to omit the proposal from the proxy statement by appealing to the SEC. If the company wishes to omit the proposal, it must submit a letter to the SEC no later than 80 days before the proxy statement is mailed; the letter notes that the company intends to omit the proposal and indicates the grounds for doing so. Typically, the company s letter also requests that the SEC staff respond by stating that the staff will not recommend the Commission take an enforcement action against the company if it omits the proposal, called an SEC no-action letter. If the company requests a no-action letter, the proponent is given an opportunity to respond, which may be followed by a series of responses from both parties. In most cases, if a no-action letter is issued, then the proposal is omitted from the proxy, while if the SEC declines to issue a no-action letter, the proposal appears in the proxy. Both the company and the proponent have the option of taking their case to a federal court if they disagree with the SEC s decision, which happens occasionally. Sometimes the proponent agrees to withdraw the proposal before or after an SEC decision, based on negotiations with the company. The proxy statement containing the proposal (if included) must be mailed to shareholders within a window before the annual meeting that is stipulated by state law (e.g., not more than 60 or fewer than 10 days in California and Delaware). There are many possible grounds for excluding a proposal under Rule 14a-8. Table 2 provides a summary of the procedural requirements for submitting a proposal (14a-8(b) to 14a-8(e) and 14a-8(h)) and substantive bases for exclusion (14a-8(i)). Procedural requirements include that a proponent must own stock worth at least $2,000 or 1 percent of firm value for at least one year before the meeting; may submit no more than one proposal per meeting; and the proposal and supporting statement may not exceed 500 words. The substantive bases for exclusion are wide ranging. At the most basic level, the proposal must be a proper subject for action under state law. A proposal can be excluded, among other reasons, if it would cause the company to violate a law, is false or misleading, relates to redress of a personal grievance, deals with ordinary business operations, 8

11 conflicts with a management proposal, duplicates another proposal in the proxy statement, or relates to a specific amount of dividends. It is important to note that the SEC does not judge the merits of a proposal when making a no-action letter decision. The Commission s information for companies and shareholders states: Do we [SEC] judge the merits of proposals? No. We have no interest in the merits of a particular proposal. Our concern is that shareholders receive full and accurate information about all proposals that are, or should be, submitted to them under rule 14a This means that there is no reason investors should make inferences about the merits of proposal from the SEC s decision. Table 2 reports the number of times that a given reason was the basis for a noaction letter in our sample. 11 The most common reasons for granting a no-action letter were, in order, that the proposal dealt with ordinary business operations, the proponent failed to demonstrate minimum ownership, and the company had already substantially implemented the proposal. Other common grounds for exclusion were that the proposal contained language that was false or misleading, the proposal conflicted with a company proposal offered at the same meeting, and the proposal was not submitted more than 120 days before the proxy statement is to be mailed. The ability to exclude proposals that are improper under state law is particularly important. Most state laws give the board the authority to run the company, so a proposal that mandates a particular action is often improper under state law (notable exceptions are bylaw amendments concerning decision and governance procedures). Therefore, most proposals are advisory or precatory in nature; they request or urge (or use similar phrasing asking) the company to take an action. In our sample, less than 3 percent of proposals are binding, meaning that proposals are overwhelmingly precatory in nature. 10 See Question 7 in Division of Corporation Finance, Securities and Exchange Commission, Staff Legal Bulletin No. 14 (CF), dated July 13, Companies often claim several grounds for exclusion in their letter to the SEC. If the SEC finds one reason to allow exclusion, it does not offer an opinion on the validity of the other grounds. So this count does not include all grounds for exclusion but rather those grounds that were flagged by the SEC staff. 9

12 3. Research Strategy and Related Literature The essence of our research strategy is to estimate the stock price reaction in the days surrounding the issuance of an SEC no-action letter decision. To put our strategy in perspective, it is useful to review previous work estimating the return associated with shareholder proposals. The key difference is the event date. Table 1, drawn from Denes et al. (forthcoming), lists previous studies. One approach, employed by three studies, is to estimate the abnormal return associated with publication of a media story on a proposal. Its primary limitation is lack of media coverage, leading to small sample sizes: Karpoff et al. (1996) capture 27 events; Smith (1996) studies 39 events sponsored by CalPERS; and Del Guercio and Hawkins (1999) study 102 announcements by public pension funds. The most popular approach, employed by 10 studies, is to estimate the abnormal return on the date that the company mails the proxy statement. A question with this approach is whether new information about proposals is actually revealed to the market on the proxy mailing date. As discussed above, market participants might already be informed because proposals are submitted to the company at least 120 days before the proxy statement is mailed. Also, companies are required by SEC Rule 14a-6 to file their proxy statements with the SEC 10 days before mailing, and the filed statements shall be deemed immediately available for public inspection (14a-6(e)(1)), meaning that proxy statements are publicly available 10 days before they are mailed. The usual finding of a small and statistically insignificant abnormal return on the proxy mailing date may be explained by the information having already reached the market prior to the proxy mailing date, rather than a proposal having no effect on firm value. 12 A third approach, employed by three studies, is to estimate the abnormal return on the date of the annual meeting. Because the existence of a proposal is certainly not news at the time of the annual meeting, unconditional mean returns on the meeting date are 12 Another limitation of using the proxy mailing date is that companies often have multiple proposals on the same ballot. With multiple proposals on one event date, it is not possible to isolate effects for individual proposals, and interpretation of the net effect is cloudy: if there are 4 proposals and an abnormal return of zero percent, it could mean that none of the proposals affects value, that half of them increase and half of them decrease value, and so on. Another concern is that proxy statements deliver a variety of information in addition to shareholder proposals. 10

13 negligible (Karpoff et al., 1996; Thomas and Cotter, 2007). Conditioning on the voting outcome, Karpoff et al. (1996) find a positive mean return for proposals that receive a majority of votes in favor, although the return is not estimated with precision. Cuñat et al. (2012) build on this idea by using regression discontinuity methods to distinguish proposals that narrowly pass from those that narrowly fail ; their conservative estimate is that a successful proposal produces an abnormal return of 1.3 percent on average on the meeting date. 13 The Cuñat et al. (2012) study offers the most convincing causal estimates to date but by construction it mainly considers proposals that management did not choose to oppose. In the conclusion, we discuss how our finding of a negative value for proposals opposed by managers can be reconciled with their finding. Our approach avoids some of the limitations from previous studies, although of course, it comes with its own limitations. Here we describe our identification strategy, and then we outline advantages and limitations. Our main innovation is to study the abnormal return associated with a no-action letter decision. This date is well defined and represents arrival of new information about the prospects of a proposal. In order for our estimates to reveal whether managers are acting in the interest of investors or not when they challenge a proposal, two conditions must hold: first, market participants must be aware of the existence of a proposal before the SEC makes its decision; and second, the decision must be uncertain from the perspective of investors. The first condition is plausible because prior to the decision the proposal has been seen by various officers in the target company, by the sponsors, and by multiple attorneys in the SEC, in many cases by an outside law firm employed by the company, and sometimes legal counsel for the proponents; it has also been publicly posted on the SEC s web site. Prima facie evidence for the second condition unpredictability of the decision is the fact that the SEC grants a no-action letter in only two-thirds of its decisions. An examination of the decision criteria (Table 2) also suggests the difficulty in predicting the SEC s decision. While some criteria seem black and white, such as the proposal not exceeding 500 words, 13 Because most proposals are precatory, the vote functions more as advice to managers than an approval mechanism that triggers at 50 percent. 11

14 whether a proposal violates other restrictions will not be obvious to an outsider. 14 An outsider will not know if the proponent can or cannot demonstrate minimum ownership of the stock, and the most common substantive problems the proposal deals with ordinary business operations or has been substantially implemented or is vague or indefinite are inherently subjective. While a body of precedential decisions helps to interpret these phrases and predict the outcome, there are still gray areas. In any event, if either of these two conditions does not hold, the estimated event return will be zero, which essentially biases against finding a meaningful effect. A strength of our approach is employment of a precise date at which new information arrives about whether a proposal will go to a vote. The SEC decision is communicated to the proponent and company on the decision date, and posted on the SEC web site on the day of the decision or within a few working days. Because the SEC decision is new information, the stock price reaction around the decision date offers a good opportunity to identify management s motives for resisting a shareholder s proposal. A limitation of our approach is that it encompasses only proposals that management attempted to omit from the proxy statement. This is not a problem from the perspective of testing managerial motives for resisting proposals, but it means that our estimates in the second part of the paper regarding the expected value of challenged proposals may not generalize to all proposals. Proposals opposed by managers might have different value implications than proposals that managers accept (as suggested by the evidence in Cuñat et al. (2012)). 4. Data The empirical analysis draws on three data sources. The primary data are handcollected from no-action letter files compiled by the SEC. Since October 2007, the files are published on the SEC s web site in PDF format (the information is also available in LexisNexis). Each file contains a cover letter from the SEC that identifies the company, proponent(s), and decision date; a decision letter that explains the reason for the decision; 14 Even a request to omit a proposal because it exceeds 500 words may not be as obvious as it seems. One decision in our sample concerning the 500-word limit hinged on whether CEO was one or three words. 12

15 and various letters from the company and its legal representatives and from the proponent and its legal representatives including the proposal itself. Using these files, we handcollected the decision and decision date for each case, as well as the company, proponents, and content of the proposal. Proposals were grouped into topics, and proponents were grouped into types, as discussed below. Our data run from mid-2007 through the end of Details of the data collection are reported in the appendix. Table 3 reports the number of proposals received by companies and the number that companies attempted to omit from October 2007 through the end of For the years in which the proposals and SEC data fully overlap ( ), 35 percent of proposals are sent to the SEC with a request for a no-action letter. Of the proposals that reach the SEC during the entire period, 57 percent are granted no-action letters and permitted to be omitted from the ballot; 28 percent are not granted no-action letters; and 15 percent are withdrawn or not decided. Of the proposals for which the SEC issues a decision, 67 percent are granted no-action letters. We use CRSP data to calculate event returns. We calculate the daily abnormal returns using the market-adjusted model and the Fama-French four-factor model of Carhart (1997). The length of the estimation period is 200 trading days, and we require at least 150 days with returns. The estimation period ends 10 days prior to the event date. We winsorize event window cumulative abnormal returns at 1 percent in each tail. We use multiple event windows; all of our event windows start one trading day before the noaction letter decision date and end on dates ranging from one to 10 trading days after the no-action letter decision date. Longer event windows allow for the possibility of some SEC decisions being posted with a delay. We drop an event if the window contains another event (i.e., no-action letter decision date) for the same firm in order to avoid the contamination of abnormal returns with the impact of different decisions. This process leads to a 20 percent decline in sample size because there are many cases in which the SEC makes multiple decisions for a given firm within a short window. There is seasonality in the no-action letter process; 81 percent of no-action letter decision dates are in January, February, or March. Finally, we use Compustat to obtain firm financial information. 13

16 5. Evidence on Managerial Motives A. Overall Returns Table 4 reports the mean abnormal return associated with no-action letter decisions for the full sample. The different panels report mean returns calculated in different ways, in order to assess robustness. In panel A, which contains our main estimates, abnormal returns are calculated using the Fama-French four-factor model, returns are winsorized at the 1 percent level in each tail, and decisions with another decision in the same window are omitted. Column (1) reports the mean abnormal return for decisions that granted a noaction letter, effectively killing the proposal. Returns are reported for various windows beginning one day before the decision and extending to 10 days afterwards. Glancing down column (1), the mean abnormal return ranges from 0.20 percent to 0.55 percent, and is always statistically different from zero. Investors were pleased when the SEC granted a noaction letter, consistent with the idea that managers were acting in shareholder interests when they opposed these proposals. The finding that returns grow as the window becomes longer suggests that information diffuses across the market over a week or two after the decision date. Panels B and C of Table 4 explore the robustness of this finding. In panel B abnormal returns are adjusted simply by subtracting the market return, but are otherwise calculated as in panel A. The estimates are quite similar to those in panel A: the mean return ranges from 0.24 percent to 0.84 percent, is always statistically different from zero, and grows over time. In panel C, the statistics are calculated as in panel A except that returns are winsorized at the 5 percent level in each tail. The magnitude of the mean return declines now ranging from 0.10 percent to 0.38 percent but remains statistically significant except in one case and grows with the length of the window. 15 Table 4 reveals a fairly robust pattern that investors responded positively on average to the grant of a no-action letter, that is, the market approved on average when shareholder proposals were omitted. This supports the argument that managers fight proposals for responsible reasons. 15 The findings are very similar to panel A if returns are winsorized at the 0.5% level. 14

17 Column (2) of Table 4 reports the mean return when the SEC declines to issue a noaction letter, that is, when a proposal is allowed to go to a vote. Given the finding in column (1) that the market approves when proposals are omitted, we might expect to find negative mean returns in column (2), but for the most part that is not what we find. In panel A, which we believe contains the cleanest estimates, the mean return associated with a declined no-action letter request ranges from 0.07 percent to 0.22 percent, depending on the window. None of these estimates can be distinguished from zero statistically at conventional levels of significance, and we do not observe the returns increasing as the window expands. The inability to statistically distinguish the mean from zero is due in part to the much smaller sample size for declined no-action letters compared to granted noaction letters. Examining panels B and C reveals similar findings in that the means are not consistently different from zero, and do not grow in magnitude as the window expands. A mean that is statistically insignificant admits the possibility that the true value is positive, negative, or zero, so we cannot say much here. Figure 1 presents similar evidence graphically. The figure plots the abnormal return using the Fama-French four-factor model from 10 days before to 10 days after the decision date. The red curve shows a gradual increase in the abnormal return for decisions granting a no-action letter after the decision (day 0). The gray curve shows the relatively flat return for decisions that decline to grant a no-action letter; the large confidence interval around the estimates stands out. Once a company requests a no-action letter from the SEC, there are three potential outcomes: the no-action letter is granted, the request for a no-action letter is declined, or the proposal is withdrawn by the proponent. 16 For completeness, column (3) of Table 4 reports the mean abnormal return associated with the SEC announcing that the proposal was withdrawn. Unlike the decision to grant or decline a no-action letter request, the announcement of a withdrawn proposal may not be new information to the market because the SEC is merely conveying information it received from the company, and the company only notifies the SEC after it has received a written notification from the 16 There are two other possibilities that occur very rarely: the company may withdraw its request, and the SEC staff may decline to comment. We omit these cases from our sample. 15

18 proponent. Therefore, our event date (SEC closing the file) is probably several days after the information reaches the market. Table 4 shows that the mean return associated with a withdrawal announcement is usually negative over short windows, sizably so, and statistically different from zero, but statistically insignificant over longer windows. There is some hint that the market views a withdrawn proposal as bad news. B. By Topic of Proposal The topic of proposals varies widely, ranging from corporate governance issues to executive compensation to social issues. Different types of proposals may have different effects on firm value. To get a sense of how investors perceive different types of proposals, this section reports the mean returns associated with different proposal topics. Figure 2 provides some context by showing the number of proposals grouped into three broad categories: compensation, corporate governance, social issues. The appendix describes the category definitions in detail. As can be seen, corporate governance proposals are the most popular subject. Figure 2 also shows the fraction of each group that is withdrawn, granted a 16

19 no-action letter, or had a no-action letter request declined. Withdrawal and SEC decision rates vary somewhat across proposals. Panel A of Table 5 breaks out the mean returns separately for three broad groups of issues: compensation, corporate governance, and social issues. Throughout Table 5, the estimates are based on abnormal returns calculated using the Fama-French four-factor model and winsorized at the 1 percent level in each tail, and windows with more than one event are omitted. Management s decision to oppose proposals concerning their own compensation deserve particular scrutiny due to the inherent conflict of interest. For compensation proposals, Table 5 shows that the mean return associated with the grant of a no-action letter is positive, ranging from 0.05 percent to 0.57 percent, but not statistically significant. Similarly, for social issues, the mean return associated with a no-action letter is usually positive, but never statistically different from zero. The interesting finding is for corporate governance issues, for which the mean return is always positive and statistically different from zero at the 5 percent level. The means range from 0.33 percent to 0.80 percent, and grow with the window size. 17

20 Panel B of Table 5 reports the mean returns for a different grouping of issues. Panel B1 focuses on proposals that would improve governance according to the G-index, and Panel B2 focuses on proposals that would improve governance according to the E-index. Both indexes are intended as summary measures of the quality of a company s governance provisions; they are correlated with a variety of performance metrics and enjoy some popularity among reformers (Bebchuk et al., 2009). The G-index has 24 elements, listed in the appendix., and the E-index has six elements: board declassification, majority voting on bylaw amendments, majority voting for mergers, majority voting for bylaw amendments, limits on golden parachutes, and removal of poison pills. The estimates in Panel B include all proposals that correspond to one of the elements of an index. Somewhat surprisingly, Panel B of Table 5 shows a consistently positive mean return when the SEC shut down proposals that would have improved governance according to the indexes. The mean return associated with omitting G-index proposals ranges from 0.45 percent to 0.60 percent, and is statistically significant for three of four reported windows. The mean return associated with omitting E-index proposals ranges from 0.68 percent to 1.03 percent, and is statistically different from zero in three of four windows. The mean return associated with the SEC declining to issue a no-action letter is smaller, usually negative, and never distinguishable from zero at conventional levels of statistical significance. There is enough noise in the estimates to be cautious about drawing conclusions, but the estimates seem to be suggesting that investors believed that increases in governance quality as measured by the G-Index and E-Index reduced firm value. The estimates in Table 5 suggest that investors were uncomfortable with at least some corporate governance proposals. It is natural to wonder precisely which proposals were the main cause of concern. Table 6 reports the mean returns associated with SEC decisions for the six most common specific types of governance proposals in our sample: special meetings, majority voting, independent chair, proxy access, board declassification, and written consent. Data mining is a risk in this sort of exercise because the number of proposals of any specific type can be small and some means are likely to pass critical values for statistical significance simply by chance, so we are hesitant to draw strong conclusions. The basic patterns are the following: 18

21 Special meetings. The most common type of proposal expands the right of shareholders who meet certain minimum ownership conditions to call a special meeting of shareholders. The mean return is positive from omitting these proposals and negative from allowing them, but not statistically significant. Majority voting. The second most common type of proposal requires a majority vote for corporate elections (for directors, bylaws, or control transactions). The move from plurality to majority voting for corporate directors has been one of the most successful planks in the reform platform over the last decade (Choi et al., 2016). The mean return associated with either type of SEC decision on such proposals is positive (with one exception) but not consistently different from zero statistically. Independent chair. The next most popular type of proposal prohibits the same person from serving as CEO and chair of the board. The mean returns are inconsistently signed and never statistically significant. Proxy access. Perhaps the strongest evidence concerns proposals to enhance proxy access. Such proposals allow shareholders who meet certain ownership conditions to nominate candidates for the board. Reformers won an important victory in 2010 when the SEC adopted new rules allowing shareholder proposals on proxy access. 17 The mean return associated with omitting such proposals is consistently positive, ranging from 0.24 percent to 1.91 percent, and statistically different from zero for the longer windows. The evidence is not conclusive, but suggests that investors view proxy access proposals with some skepticism. This comports with evidence based on legislative histories finding negative or zero market reactions to enhanced proxy access (Akyol et al., 2012; Larcker et al. 2011; Stratmann and Verret, 2012). 17 At the same time, the SEC also adopted a rule mandating the shareholder right to nominate directors, but that rule was vacated by the D.C. Court of Appeals in Business Roundtable v. SEC,

22 Board declassification. Proposals to declassify the board would require all directors to be elected on an annual basis. The alternative staggered elections make it more difficult to change control of the board. Several studies have documented a negative correlation between staggered boards and firm value, but recent causal estimates produced mixed findings, or suggest that staggered boards increase value (Cremers et al, forthcoming). The mean return associated with omission of declassification proposals is large and positive in all windows, ranging from 1.17 percent to 2.04 percent, statistically significant at the 10 percent level in three of four windows. The mean return from allowing declassification proposals is positive, but not statistically significant. Written consent. Finally, the mean return associated with proposals allowing shareholders to act by written consent is positive, and never statistically different from zero. To summarize, the evidence suggests that the market s concern with shareholder proposals is primarily centered on corporate governance proposals. However, we do not have enough data and precision to drill down very deeply into how investors view specific types of proposals. 18 C. By Type of Proponent Just as investors may view some proposal topics more favorably than others, their assessments may also be colored by the identity of the proponent. Because the proponent might be asymmetrically informed about the consequences of a proposal, theory suggests 18 We also calculated but do not report mean returns associated with proposals that ask companies to reveal their political contributions. Such proposals have been popular recently. Min and You (2015) show that such proposals are targeted at companies with a history of donating to Republican candidates, suggesting they may have a political motivation rather than a value-enhancing goal. The mean returns suggest that investors are skeptical of such proposals, but the magnitudes are not large and the means are never statistically different from zero. 20

23 that investors will base their beliefs about its value implications in part on the identity of the sponsor. Here we examine the mean return associated with SEC decisions, by type of proponent. 19 It is not obvious ex ante which proponents are suspect and which are not, so our estimates should be seen as exploratory. Labor unions and public pensions have been singled out by researchers and in court decisions for potentially using the proposal process to advance private goals that do not maximize value, such as benefits for union workers, which might make investors skeptical about their proposals. But on the other hand, unions may have useful information about a company s operations, putting them in a good position to recognize value-enhancing opportunities. Another group that has been the subject of much discussion is hedge funds. Hedge funds have been lauded for their focus on shareholder value, and substantial evidence exists that activist campaigns increase value (Brav et al., 2015). Others have expressed concern that hedge funds might be short-term oriented, pressing the firm to generate short-term cash distributions at the expense of long-run value (Anabtawi, 2006). Figure 3 reports the number of proposals in our sample by type of proponent. Individuals make by far more proposals than any other sponsor category, with 1,477 in our sample. This is not simply because proposals from individuals are more likely to be challenged: for the entire ISS Proposals database over , 38 percent of proposals are sponsored by individuals. Some of these proposals originate with persons who make a one-time proposal on a specific issue, but most come from a small number of so-called corporate gadflies who make dozens of proposals every year. The most active gadflies in our sample are Gerald R. Armstrong, John Chevedden, husband-wife team James McRitchie and Myra Young, and father-son team William Steiner and Kenneth Steiner. Also mirroring the pattern in the ISS Proposals database, we find very few proposals (a total of 45) from hedge funds (included under Fund (non-sri) ). This is because shareholder proposals are not an important element of hedge fund activism in general; hedge funds are more focused 19 Another (indirect) way to assess how other shareholders view a proposal is through their votes: the evidence connecting votes to the identity of the sponsor is mixed and inconclusive (Thomas and Martin, 1998). 21

SHAREHOLDERS & CORPORATE CONTROL

SHAREHOLDERS & CORPORATE CONTROL SHAREHOLDERS & CORPORATE CONTROL DATA SPOTLIGHT David F. Larcker and Brian Tayan Corporate Governance Research Initiative Stanford Graduate School of Business SHAREHOLDER PROPOSALS Shareholders are active

More information

Opportunistic Proposals by Union Shareholders *

Opportunistic Proposals by Union Shareholders * Opportunistic Proposals by Union Shareholders * John G. Matsusaka, Oguzhan Ozbas, and Irene Yi University of Southern California Effective corporate governance requires mechanisms that allow shareholders

More information

Shareholder Proposals: Strategies and Tactics

Shareholder Proposals: Strategies and Tactics Shareholder Proposals: Strategies and Tactics Cam Hoang Gary Tygesson Violet Richardson Dorsey & Whitney LLP 1 Introduction CAM HOANG Cam, a partner in our Corporate Group, advises clients on governance

More information

Shareholder Proposals: Strategies and Tactics

Shareholder Proposals: Strategies and Tactics Shareholder Proposals: Strategies and Tactics Cam Hoang Gary Tygesson Violet Richardson Dorsey & Whitney LLP 1 Introduction CAM HOANG Cam, a partner in our Corporate Group, advises clients on governance

More information

Lessons from the 2017 Proxy Season

Lessons from the 2017 Proxy Season Lessons from the 2017 Proxy Season S&C Client Webinar September 18, 2017 Janet Geldzahler Glen Schleyer Overview of Presentation Summary of proxy access proposals for 2017; further confirmation of market

More information

An analysis of omitted shareholder proposals

An analysis of omitted shareholder proposals An analysis of omitted shareholder proposals Robert Boylan Jacksonville University Richard Cebula Jacksonville University Maggie Foley Jacksonville University Xiaowei Liu St. Ambrose University Abstract

More information

SHAREHOLDER ACTIVISM RESEARCH SPOTLIGHT David F. Larcker and Brian Tayan Corporate Governance Research Initiative Stanford Graduate School of Business

SHAREHOLDER ACTIVISM RESEARCH SPOTLIGHT David F. Larcker and Brian Tayan Corporate Governance Research Initiative Stanford Graduate School of Business SHAREHOLDER ACTIVISM RESEARCH SPOTLIGHT David F. Larcker and Brian Tayan Corporate Governance Research Initiative Stanford Graduate School of Business KEY CONCEPTS Activist shareholders purchase shares

More information

While concerns about shareholder activism and the

While concerns about shareholder activism and the Yoo Jaechang/TongRo Images/Corbis Lessons for the 2015 Proxy Season In her regular column on corporate governance issues, Holly Gregory examines trends emerging from the 2014 proxy season and related developments,

More information

James McRitchie 9295 Yorkship Court Elk Grove, CA December 23, 2014

James McRitchie 9295 Yorkship Court Elk Grove, CA December 23, 2014 Office of Chief Counsel Division of Corporation Finance Securities and Exchange Commission 100 F Street, NE Washington, DC 20549 James McRitchie 9295 Yorkship Court Elk Grove, CA 95758 December 23, 2014

More information

FRE Q U E N T L Y A S K E D Q U E S T I O N S A B O U T S H A R E H O L D E R P R O P O S A L S A N D P R O X Y A C C E S S

FRE Q U E N T L Y A S K E D Q U E S T I O N S A B O U T S H A R E H O L D E R P R O P O S A L S A N D P R O X Y A C C E S S FRE Q U E N T L Y A S K E D Q U E S T I O N S A B O U T S H A R E H O L D E R P R O P O S A L S A N D P R O X Y A C C E S S Shareholder Proposals What are shareholder proposals? Shareholder proposals are

More information

Proxy Access Struck Down by Courts. Additional Dodd-Frank Act Compensation and Governance Provisions Delayed

Proxy Access Struck Down by Courts. Additional Dodd-Frank Act Compensation and Governance Provisions Delayed Proxy Access Struck Down by Courts August 4, 2011 Additional Dodd-Frank Act Compensation and Governance Provisions Delayed As we reached the first anniversary of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer

More information

University of Southern California Law School

University of Southern California Law School University of Southern California Law School Law and Economics Working Paper Series Year 2008 Paper 71 When Are Outside Directors Effective? Ran Duchin John Matsusaka Oguzhan Ozbas University of Southern

More information

SEC Adopts Rules Allowing Shareholder Access to Company Proxy Materials

SEC Adopts Rules Allowing Shareholder Access to Company Proxy Materials Corporate Finance and Securities Client Service Group To: Our Clients and Friends August 26, 2010 SEC Adopts Rules Allowing Shareholder Access to Company Proxy Materials Yesterday, the Securities and Exchange

More information

Lessons from the 2018 Proxy Season

Lessons from the 2018 Proxy Season SC1: 4706990 Lessons from the 2018 Proxy Season S&C Client Webinar September 13, 2018 Janet Geldzahler Melissa Sawyer Marc Trevino Overview of Presentation Environmental/social/political proposals more

More information

Hot Topics in Corporate Governance. November 14, 2017

Hot Topics in Corporate Governance. November 14, 2017 Hot Topics in Corporate Governance November 14, 2017 Changes at the SEC New Chair: Jay Clayton New Director of the Division of Corporation Finance: Bill Hinman Two open Commission seats remain, with two

More information

Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation

Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation University of Massachusetts Boston From the SelectedWorks of Atreya Chakraborty January 1, 2010 Antitakeover amendments and managerial entrenchment: New evidence from investment policy and CEO compensation

More information

Board Declassification and Bargaining Power *

Board Declassification and Bargaining Power * Board Declassification and Bargaining Power * Miroslava Straska School of Business, Virginia Commonwealth University, 301 W. Main Street, Richmond, VA 23220 mstraska@vcu.edu (804) 828-1741 H. Gregory Waller

More information

PRE-DISCLOSURE ACCUMULATIONS BY ACTIVIST INVESTORS: EVIDENCE AND POLICY

PRE-DISCLOSURE ACCUMULATIONS BY ACTIVIST INVESTORS: EVIDENCE AND POLICY Working Draft, May 2013 PRE-DISCLOSURE ACCUMULATIONS BY ACTIVIST INVESTORS: EVIDENCE AND POLICY Forthcoming, Journal of Corporation Law, Volume 39, Fall 2013 Lucian A. Bebchuk, Alon Brav, Robert J. Jackson,

More information

2010 Fall Meeting Washington, DC November 19-20, Practical Guidance on Executive Compensation in the Dodd-Frank Era

2010 Fall Meeting Washington, DC November 19-20, Practical Guidance on Executive Compensation in the Dodd-Frank Era 2010 Fall Meeting Washington, DC November 19-20, 2010 Practical Guidance on Executive Compensation in the Dodd-Frank Era Preparing for the 2011 Proxy Season ABA Subcommittee on Executive Benefits, Executive

More information

Paragon Capital Management, Ltd th Street, Suite 1401 Denver, CO

Paragon Capital Management, Ltd th Street, Suite 1401 Denver, CO Paragon Capital Management, Ltd. 999 18 th Street, Suite 1401 Denver, CO 80202 303-293-3680 www.pcm-net.com August 30, 2017 This Firm brochure is Part 2A of Form ADV a regulatory filing required by the

More information

Corporate Governance of the Largest US Public Companies General Governance Practices

Corporate Governance of the Largest US Public Companies General Governance Practices Corporate Governance of the Largest US Public Companies General Governance Practices 2011 This Survey and our companion survey regarding director and executive compensation are available on the website

More information

DODGE & COX FUNDS PROXY VOTING POLICIES AND PROCEDURES. Revised February 15, 2018

DODGE & COX FUNDS PROXY VOTING POLICIES AND PROCEDURES. Revised February 15, 2018 DODGE & COX FUNDS PROXY VOTING POLICIES AND PROCEDURES Revised February 15, 2018 The Dodge & Cox Funds have authorized Dodge & Cox to vote proxies on behalf of the Dodge & Cox Funds pursuant to the following

More information

Does the Director Election System Matter? Evidence from Majority Voting

Does the Director Election System Matter? Evidence from Majority Voting Does the Director Election System Matter? Evidence from Majority Voting Yonca Ertimur Duke University yertimur@duke.edu Fabrizio Ferri Columbia Business School ff2270@columbia.edu Does the Director Election

More information

Posted by Mary Jo White, U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission, on Thursday, June 25, 2015

Posted by Mary Jo White, U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission, on Thursday, June 25, 2015 Posted by Mary Jo White, U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission, on Thursday, June 25, 2015 Editor s note: Mary Jo White is Chair of the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission. The following post is

More information

Say Pays! Shareholder Voice and Firm Performance

Say Pays! Shareholder Voice and Firm Performance Upjohn Institute Working Papers Upjohn Research home page 2013 Say Pays! Shareholder Voice and Firm Performance Vicente Cuñat London School of Economics Mireia Gine University of Pennsylvania Maria Guadalupe

More information

AN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE OF THE CURRENT BALANCE OF POWER BETWEEN SHAREHOLDERS AND BOARDS OF DIRECTORS

AN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE OF THE CURRENT BALANCE OF POWER BETWEEN SHAREHOLDERS AND BOARDS OF DIRECTORS AN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE OF THE CURRENT BALANCE OF POWER BETWEEN SHAREHOLDERS AND BOARDS OF DIRECTORS Before we turn to a discussion of the appropriate balance of power between boards of directors and

More information

INVESTORS & ACTIVISM. David F. Larcker and Brian Tayan Corporate Governance Research Initiative Stanford Graduate School of Business

INVESTORS & ACTIVISM. David F. Larcker and Brian Tayan Corporate Governance Research Initiative Stanford Graduate School of Business INVESTORS & ACTIVISM David F. Larcker and Brian Tayan Corporate Governance Research Initiative Stanford Graduate School of Business THE ROLE OF SHAREHOLDERS The shareholder-centric view holds that the

More information

UW SYSTEM TRUST FUNDS 2013 PROXY VOTING SEASON RESULTS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

UW SYSTEM TRUST FUNDS 2013 PROXY VOTING SEASON RESULTS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY December 5, 2013 Agenda Item I.2.c.3. UW SYSTEM TRUST FUNDS 2013 PROXY VOTING SEASON RESULTS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY BACKGROUND As provided in Regent Policy 31-10, to the extent that public equity securities

More information

The SEC s Final Pay Ratio Rule: Analysis and Implications

The SEC s Final Pay Ratio Rule: Analysis and Implications The SEC s Final Pay Ratio Rule: Analysis and Implications Membership Discussion Call HR Policy Association August 18, 2015 Today s Discussion Leaders Charles G. Tharp Chief Executive Officer Center On

More information

INSTITUTIONAL SHAREHOLDER SERVICES (ISS) AND GLASS LEWIS PROXY VOTING POLICIES AND OTHER DEVELOPMENTS FOR THE 2013 PROXY SEASON

INSTITUTIONAL SHAREHOLDER SERVICES (ISS) AND GLASS LEWIS PROXY VOTING POLICIES AND OTHER DEVELOPMENTS FOR THE 2013 PROXY SEASON January 29, 2013 INSTITUTIONAL SHAREHOLDER SERVICES (ISS) AND GLASS LEWIS PROXY VOTING POLICIES AND OTHER DEVELOPMENTS FOR THE 2013 PROXY SEASON To Our Clients and Friends: Institutional Shareholder Services

More information

Does the Director Election System Matter? Evidence from Majority Voting

Does the Director Election System Matter? Evidence from Majority Voting Does the Director Election System Matter? Evidence from Majority Voting Yonca Ertimur * Duke University yertimur@duke.edu Fabrizio Ferri Stern School of Business NYU fferri@stern.nyu.edu June 2011 Abstract:

More information

Appendix CA-15. Central Bank of Bahrain Rulebook. Volume 1: Conventional Banks

Appendix CA-15. Central Bank of Bahrain Rulebook. Volume 1: Conventional Banks Appendix CA-15 Supervisory Framework for the Use of Backtesting in Conjunction with the Internal Models Approach to Market Risk Capital Requirements I. Introduction 1. This Appendix presents the framework

More information

T he US Supreme Court s recent decision in Janus Capital Group, Inc. v. First Derivative

T he US Supreme Court s recent decision in Janus Capital Group, Inc. v. First Derivative The Supreme Court s Janus decision: no secondary liability, but many secondary questions Arthur Delibert and Gregory Wright Arthur Delibert and Gregory Wright are both Partners at K&L Gates LLP, Washington,

More information

Corporate Governance Update: Shareholder Activists Risk Destroying Board Effectiveness. David A. Katz and Laura A. McIntosh

Corporate Governance Update: Shareholder Activists Risk Destroying Board Effectiveness. David A. Katz and Laura A. McIntosh May 24, 2007 Corporate Governance Update: Shareholder Activists Risk Destroying Board Effectiveness David A. Katz and Laura A. McIntosh Although stockholder meetings for the most part have been quieter

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

!"#$%"&'(%$)*$&+&,#',-).$%/(,)0$&1)2%3%/4)*$&56)!%#,&/,)7899:;89<<=)

!#$%&'(%$)*$&+&,#',-).$%/(,)0$&1)2%3%/4)*$&56)!%#,&/,)7899:;89<<=) "#$%"&'(%$)*$&+&,#',-).$%/(,)0$&1)2%3%/4)*$&56) %#,&/,)7899:;89

More information

Hot Topics 2013 Proxy season highlights

Hot Topics 2013 Proxy season highlights Hot Topics 2013 Proxy season highlights Recent governance trends, regulatory developments, and the expectation of future governance-related legislation were highlighted in the June 25 Deloitte Dbriefs

More information

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract In this paper we study the market reaction to capital expenditure announcements in the backdrop

More information

Do Auditors Use The Information Reflected In Book-Tax Differences? Discussion

Do Auditors Use The Information Reflected In Book-Tax Differences? Discussion Do Auditors Use The Information Reflected In Book-Tax Differences? Discussion David Weber and Michael Willenborg, University of Connecticut Hanlon and Krishnan (2006), hereinafter HK, address an interesting

More information

FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS ABOUT REGULATION FD

FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS ABOUT REGULATION FD FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS ABOUT REGULATION FD Background What is Regulation FD? Regulation FD (for Fair Disclosure ), promulgated by the SEC under the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, as amended (the

More information

MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM

MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM ) MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM Ersin Güner 559370 Master Finance Supervisor: dr. P.C. (Peter) de Goeij December 2013 Abstract Evidence from the US shows

More information

G OV ERNANC E I NITIATIVE

G OV ERNANC E I NITIATIVE C O R P OR ATE G OV ERNANC E I NITIATIVE Reinvigorating the Public Company Model SPRING 2018 1 INTRODUCTION Over the last few decades the U.S. has experienced a steady decline in public companies. In fact,

More information

APPEAL AND INDEPENDENT DISPUTE RESOLUTION PROCESSES

APPEAL AND INDEPENDENT DISPUTE RESOLUTION PROCESSES APPEAL AND INDEPENDENT DISPUTE RESOLUTION PROCESSES 2016 Fannie Mae. Trademarks of Fannie Mae. 8.17.2016 1 of 20 Contents INTRODUCTION... 4 PART A. APPEAL, IMPASSE, AND MANAGEMENT ESCALATION PROCESSES...

More information

The Role of Industry Affiliation in the Underpricing of U.S. IPOs

The Role of Industry Affiliation in the Underpricing of U.S. IPOs The Role of Industry Affiliation in the Underpricing of U.S. IPOs Bryan Henrick ABSTRACT: Haverford College Department of Economics Spring 2012 This paper examines the significance of a firm s industry

More information

Background and Impact on Retirement Savers

Background and Impact on Retirement Savers Protecting Retirement Savings FAQs as released by the U.S. Department of Labor in April 2016, except for annotations in red added by NELP in June 2017 NELP Note: On February 3, 2017, President Trump directed

More information

The Japanese Institute of Certified Public Accountants

The Japanese Institute of Certified Public Accountants The Japanese Institute of Certified Public Accountants 4-4-1 Kudan-Minami, Chiyoda-ku, Tokyo 102-8264, Japan Phone: 81-3-3515-1130 Fax: 81-3-5226-3355 Email: international@sec.jicpa.or.jp November 21,

More information

The Role of Shareholder Proposals in Corporate Governance

The Role of Shareholder Proposals in Corporate Governance The Role of Shareholder Proposals in Corporate Governance Luc Renneboog a, Peter G. Szilagyi b, a Tilburg University and European Corporate Governance Institute, PO Box 90153, 5000LE Tilburg, The Netherlands,

More information

InsideARM Debt Settlement Survey

InsideARM Debt Settlement Survey InsideARM Debt Settlement Survey How Creditors and Collectors Utilize the Debt Settlement Industry to Increase Collections January 2013 Brought to you by with reporting findings sponsored by Findings and

More information

What Investment Managers Need to Know About Charters and Bylaws

What Investment Managers Need to Know About Charters and Bylaws Published in the June edition of ISSue Alert (Vol. 14, No. 6). Reprinted with the permission of Institutional Shareholder Services, a Thomson Financial company. What Investment Managers Need to Know About

More information

Numerous Proposed 2009 Amendments to the Delaware General Corporation Law Reflect Heightened Focus on Governance Issues

Numerous Proposed 2009 Amendments to the Delaware General Corporation Law Reflect Heightened Focus on Governance Issues ClientAdvisory Numerous Proposed 2009 Amendments to the Delaware General Corporation Law Reflect Heightened Focus on Governance Issues March 10, 2009 Lawmakers in the state of Delaware may soon be addressing

More information

Computer History Museum located at 1401 N. Shoreline Blvd., Mountain View, CA PIRC Global Motor vehicles and passenger car bodies

Computer History Museum located at 1401 N. Shoreline Blvd., Mountain View, CA PIRC Global Motor vehicles and passenger car bodies TESLA MOTORS INC Meeting Date: Tue, 03 Jun 2014 11:00am Type: AGM Issue date: Fri, 06 Jun 2014 Meeting Location: Current Indices: Sector: Computer History Museum located at 1401 N. Shoreline Blvd., Mountain

More information

Corporate Governance Data and Measures Revisited

Corporate Governance Data and Measures Revisited Corporate Governance Data and Measures Revisited David F. Larcker Stanford Graduate School of Business Peter C. Reiss Stanford Graduate School of Business Youfei Xiao Duke University, Fuqua School of Business

More information

Bipartisan Bill Would Require SEC Registration, Annual Reporting, and Disclosure of Conflicts and Policy Formulation

Bipartisan Bill Would Require SEC Registration, Annual Reporting, and Disclosure of Conflicts and Policy Formulation Bipartisan Bill Would Require SEC Registration, Annual Reporting, and Disclosure of Conflicts and Policy Formulation Over the past several years, there has been a significant focus on the influence, conflicts

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

Re: DI/2012/2 Put options written on non-controlling interests (the DI)

Re: DI/2012/2 Put options written on non-controlling interests (the DI) IFRIC 30 Cannon Street London EC4M 6XH UK Paris, September 28, 2012 Re: DI/2012/2 Put options written on non-controlling interests (the DI) Dear Mr Upton As already stated in our previous letter (dated

More information

2010 Proxy Season Review: Say on Pay

2010 Proxy Season Review: Say on Pay Cynthia M. Krus, Sutherland Asbill & Brennan LLP Lisa A. Morgan, Sutherland Asbill & Brennan LLP Reid Pearson, The Altman Group Francis H. Byrd, The Altman Group July 27, 2010 2010 Proxy Season Review:

More information

Dispatches from the Proxy Front: A Preview of the 2013 Annual Meeting Season. Steven M. Pantina Managing Director January 18, 2013

Dispatches from the Proxy Front: A Preview of the 2013 Annual Meeting Season. Steven M. Pantina Managing Director January 18, 2013 Dispatches from the Proxy Front: A Preview of the 2013 Annual Meeting Season Steven M. Pantina Managing Director January 18, 2013 A Look Back at Say-on-Pay Votes in the 2012 Proxy Season Nearly 2,000 ballots

More information

Explanation of the North Dakota Publicly Traded Corporations Act

Explanation of the North Dakota Publicly Traded Corporations Act April 5, 2007 Explanation of the North Dakota Publicly Traded Corporations Act The North Dakota Publicly Traded Corporations Act provides a system of corporate governance that is designed to strengthen

More information

Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance

Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance Firm R&D Strategies Impact of Corporate Governance Manohar Singh The Pennsylvania State University- Abington Reporting a positive relationship between institutional ownership on one hand and capital expenditures

More information

The Case for TD Low Volatility Equities

The Case for TD Low Volatility Equities The Case for TD Low Volatility Equities By: Jean Masson, Ph.D., Managing Director April 05 Most investors like generating returns but dislike taking risks, which leads to a natural assumption that competition

More information

Institutional Shareholders and Activist Investors

Institutional Shareholders and Activist Investors Institutional Shareholders and Activist Investors Professor David F. Larcker Center for Leadership Development & Research Stanford Graduate School of Business The Role of Shareholders The shareholder-centric

More information

1. Respondent Information

1. Respondent Information 1. Respondent Information We appreciate your taking the time to provide your input on these governance issues. This survey covers policy areas on governance topics on a global basis. Please feel free to

More information

Vanguard's proxy voting guidelines

Vanguard's proxy voting guidelines Vanguard's proxy voting guidelines The Board of Trustees (the Board) of each Vanguard fund has adopted proxy voting procedures and guidelines to govern proxy voting by the fund. The Board has delegated

More information

SECURITIES ENFORCEMENT

SECURITIES ENFORCEMENT THE CORPORATE & SECURITIES LAW ADVISOR THE CORPORATE & SECURITIES LAW ADVISOR Volume 20 Number 12, December 2006 SECURITIES ENFORCEMENT How to Succeed at Settling SEC and NASD Enforcement Actions by Katherine

More information

Investment Section INVESTMENT FALLACIES 2014

Investment Section INVESTMENT FALLACIES 2014 Investment Section INVESTMENT FALLACIES 2014 INVESTMENT SECTION INVESTMENT FALLACIES The Fallacy of the Fed Model by David R. Cantor, Adam Butler and Kunal Rajani Managers responsible for asset allocation

More information

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 3 Fall 1994 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: THE CASE OF BANK LOAN COMMITMENTS

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 3 Fall 1994 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: THE CASE OF BANK LOAN COMMITMENTS Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 7 Number 3 Fall 1994 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: THE CASE OF BANK LOAN COMMITMENTS James E. McDonald * Abstract This study analyzes common stock return behavior

More information

WORKING PAPER MASSACHUSETTS

WORKING PAPER MASSACHUSETTS BASEMENT HD28.M414 no. Ibll- Dewey ALFRED P. WORKING PAPER SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT Corporate Investments In Common Stock by Wayne H. Mikkelson University of Oregon Richard S. Ruback Massachusetts

More information

Looking Back: 2010 Proxy Season in Review

Looking Back: 2010 Proxy Season in Review Cynthia M. Krus, Sutherland Asbill & Brennan LLP Lisa A. Morgan, Sutherland Asbill & Brennan LLP Reid Pearson, The Altman Group Francis H. Byrd, The Altman Group June 30, 2010 Looking Back: 2010 Proxy

More information

Howard-Anderson Does Not Increase Potential D&O Liability

Howard-Anderson Does Not Increase Potential D&O Liability Portfolio Media. Inc. 860 Broadway, 6th Floor New York, NY 10003 www.law360.com Phone: +1 646 783 7100 Fax: +1 646 783 7161 customerservice@law360.com Howard-Anderson Does Not Increase Potential D&O Liability

More information

Commentary: Challenges for Monetary Policy: New and Old

Commentary: Challenges for Monetary Policy: New and Old Commentary: Challenges for Monetary Policy: New and Old John B. Taylor Mervyn King s paper is jam-packed with interesting ideas and good common sense about monetary policy. I admire the clearly stated

More information

Corporate Governance and Responsible Investment Policy North America 2018

Corporate Governance and Responsible Investment Policy North America 2018 Corporate Governance and Responsible Investment Policy North America 2018 Contents Company board...3 Structure and operation...3 Board effectiveness...3 Compensation...4 Shareholder rights...6 This policy

More information

Everest REIT Investors

Everest REIT Investors Everest REIT Investors 199 SOUTH LOS ROBLES AVENUE, SUITE 200 PASADENA, CALIFORNIA 91101 TEL (626) 585-5920 FAX (626) 585-5929 To the Shareholders of Hines Global REIT, Inc. May 7, 2018 RE: NOTIFICATION

More information

STUDY & RECOMMENDATIONS REGARDING CONCENTRATION LIMITS ON LARGE FINANCIAL COMPANIES

STUDY & RECOMMENDATIONS REGARDING CONCENTRATION LIMITS ON LARGE FINANCIAL COMPANIES STUDY & RECOMMENDATIONS REGARDING CONCENTRATION LIMITS ON LARGE FINANCIAL COMPANIES FINANCIAL STABILITY OVERSIGHT COUNCIL Completed pursuant to section 622 of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer

More information

3. Measuring the Effect of Monetary Policy

3. Measuring the Effect of Monetary Policy 3. Measuring the Effect of Monetary Policy Here we analyse the effect of monetary policy in Japan using the structural VARs estimated in Section 2. We take the block-recursive model with domestic WPI for

More information

Cumulative Voting and the Tension between Board and Minority Shareholders. Aiwu Zhao and Alex Brehm *

Cumulative Voting and the Tension between Board and Minority Shareholders. Aiwu Zhao and Alex Brehm * Cumulative Voting and the Tension between Board and Minority Shareholders Aiwu Zhao and Alex Brehm * ABSTRACT The separation of management and ownership has created various agency problems and long-lasting

More information

Highlights from RR Donnelley s Groundbreaking investor survey

Highlights from RR Donnelley s Groundbreaking investor survey Highlights from RR Donnelley s Groundbreaking investor survey What you need to know before drafting your next proxy Introduction Over the past few years, there has been an explosion of innovation in proxy

More information

CORPORATE GOVERNANCE ALERT: COMPLYING WITH THE SEC'S FINAL DISCLOSURE RULES REGARDING THE DIRECTOR NOMINATION PROCESS

CORPORATE GOVERNANCE ALERT: COMPLYING WITH THE SEC'S FINAL DISCLOSURE RULES REGARDING THE DIRECTOR NOMINATION PROCESS CORPORATE GOVERNANCE ALERT: COMPLYING WITH THE SEC'S FINAL DISCLOSURE RULES REGARDING THE DIRECTOR NOMINATION PROCESS AND SHAREHOLDER-DIRECTOR COMMUNICATIONS JANUARY 15, 2004 This memorandum is designed

More information

Crestmont Research. Rowing vs. The Roller Coaster By Ed Easterling January 26, 2007 All Rights Reserved

Crestmont Research. Rowing vs. The Roller Coaster By Ed Easterling January 26, 2007 All Rights Reserved Crestmont Research Rowing vs. The Roller Coaster By Ed Easterling January 26, 2007 All Rights Reserved Why are so many of the most knowledgeable institutions and individuals shifting away from investment

More information

Determinants of the Trends in Aggregate Corporate Payout Policy

Determinants of the Trends in Aggregate Corporate Payout Policy Determinants of the Trends in Aggregate Corporate Payout Policy Jim Hsieh And Qinghai Wang * April 28, 2006 ABSTRACT This study investigates the time-series trends of corporate payout policy in the U.S.

More information

Office of the Secretary Public Company Accounting Oversight Board 1666 K Street, N.W. Washington, DC December 11, 2013

Office of the Secretary Public Company Accounting Oversight Board 1666 K Street, N.W. Washington, DC December 11, 2013 Office of the Secretary Public Company Accounting Oversight Board 1666 K Street, N.W. Washington, DC 20006-2803 December 11, 2013 RE: PCAOB Rulemaking Docket Matter No. 034, Proposed Auditing Standards

More information

Private placements and managerial entrenchment

Private placements and managerial entrenchment Journal of Corporate Finance 13 (2007) 461 484 www.elsevier.com/locate/jcorpfin Private placements and managerial entrenchment Michael J. Barclay a,, Clifford G. Holderness b, Dennis P. Sheehan c a University

More information

The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1

The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1 Preservation The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1 Kenneth R. Spong Senior Policy Economist, Banking Studies and Structure, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Richard J. Sullivan Senior

More information

Re: Re-proposal of Rules on Incentive-Based Compensation Arrangements

Re: Re-proposal of Rules on Incentive-Based Compensation Arrangements December 17, 2015 The Honorable Thomas J. Curry Comptroller of the Currency Office of the Comptroller of the Currency ( OCC ) 400 7 th Street, S.W. Washington, DC 20219 The Honorable Janet L. Yellen Chair

More information

Abstract. Standard formulary apportionment, as currently adopted by states which impose a corporate level

Abstract. Standard formulary apportionment, as currently adopted by states which impose a corporate level Abstract Standard formulary apportionment, as currently adopted by states which impose a corporate level income tax on multistate corporations, may have a distortive effect in instances where the corporation

More information

Investor Reaction to the Stock Gifts of Controlling Shareholders

Investor Reaction to the Stock Gifts of Controlling Shareholders Investor Reaction to the Stock Gifts of Controlling Shareholders Su Jeong Lee College of Business Administration, Inha University #100 Inha-ro, Nam-gu, Incheon 212212, Korea Tel: 82-32-860-7738 E-mail:

More information

SUPERVISORY FRAMEWORK FOR THE USE OF BACKTESTING IN CONJUNCTION WITH THE INTERNAL MODELS APPROACH TO MARKET RISK CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS

SUPERVISORY FRAMEWORK FOR THE USE OF BACKTESTING IN CONJUNCTION WITH THE INTERNAL MODELS APPROACH TO MARKET RISK CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS SUPERVISORY FRAMEWORK FOR THE USE OF BACKTESTING IN CONJUNCTION WITH THE INTERNAL MODELS APPROACH TO MARKET RISK CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS (January 1996) I. Introduction This document presents the framework

More information

Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts

Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts We replicate Tables 1-4 of the paper relating quarterly earnings forecasts (QEFs) and long-term growth forecasts (LTGFs)

More information

By Electronic Mail Only. August 24, 2018

By Electronic Mail Only. August 24, 2018 John A. Zecca Senior Vice President General Counsel North America 805 King Farm Blvd, Suite 100 Rockville, MD 20850 / USA (301) 978-8498 john.zecca@nasdaq.com Nasdaq.com By Electronic Mail Only August

More information

Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know?

Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know? Preliminary Private Equity Performance: What Do We Know? by Robert Harris*, Tim Jenkinson** and Steven N. Kaplan*** This Draft: September 9, 2011 Abstract We present time series evidence on the performance

More information

Securities Fraud Class Actions and Corporate Governance: New Evidence on the Role of Merit

Securities Fraud Class Actions and Corporate Governance: New Evidence on the Role of Merit Securities Fraud Class Actions and Corporate Governance: New Evidence on the Role of Merit Christopher F Baum, James G. Bohn, Atreya Chakraborty Boston College/DIW Berlin, UHY Advisors, Univ. of Mass.

More information

SEC ISSUES GUIDANCE ON USE OF CORPORATE WEB SITES. previously posted materials. hyperlinks to third-party information

SEC ISSUES GUIDANCE ON USE OF CORPORATE WEB SITES. previously posted materials. hyperlinks to third-party information August 15, 2008 CORPORATE ALERT SEC ISSUES GUIDANCE ON USE OF CORPORATE WEB SITES four topics: On August 1, 2008, the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) issued an interpretive release providing guidance

More information

smart money, crowded trades?

smart money, crowded trades? by Kristofer Kwait, Managing Director, Head of Research, and John Delano, Director, Hedge Fund Strategies Group, Commonfund smart money, crowded trades? For investors building multi-manager portfolios,

More information

ISS Issues Policy Updates for 2011 Proxy Season Institutional Shareholder Services, the prominent

ISS Issues Policy Updates for 2011 Proxy Season Institutional Shareholder Services, the prominent December 1, 2010 compensia.com ISS Issues Policy Updates for 2011 Proxy Season Institutional Shareholder Services, the prominent corporate governance advisory services firm, has updated its U.S. corporate

More information

SEC Investigations and Securities Class Actions: An Empirical Comparison

SEC Investigations and Securities Class Actions: An Empirical Comparison University of Michigan Law School University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository Law & Economics Working Papers 11-15-2012 SEC Investigations and Securities Class Actions: An Empirical Comparison

More information

Seasonal Analysis of Abnormal Returns after Quarterly Earnings Announcements

Seasonal Analysis of Abnormal Returns after Quarterly Earnings Announcements Seasonal Analysis of Abnormal Returns after Quarterly Earnings Announcements Dr. Iqbal Associate Professor and Dean, College of Business Administration The Kingdom University P.O. Box 40434, Manama, Bahrain

More information

Alternative business entities: liability and insurance issues

Alternative business entities: liability and insurance issues Alternative business entities: liability and insurance issues TABLE OF CONTENTS I. PARTNERSHIPS...2 II. LIMITED LIABILITY COMPANIES...9 III. COVERAGE FOR AFFILIATES...12 i For liability, tax and operating

More information

Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds. Kevin C.H. Chiang*

Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds. Kevin C.H. Chiang* Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds Kevin C.H. Chiang* School of Management University of Alaska Fairbanks Fairbanks, AK 99775 Kirill Kozhevnikov

More information

Volume Title: The Economics of Property-Casualty Insurance. Volume URL:

Volume Title: The Economics of Property-Casualty Insurance. Volume URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Economics of Property-Casualty Insurance Volume Author/Editor: David F. Bradford, editor

More information

SEC Issues New and Revised Guidance to Clarify Its CEO Pay Ratio Rule

SEC Issues New and Revised Guidance to Clarify Its CEO Pay Ratio Rule Heads Up Volume 24, Issue 27 October 17, 2017 In This Issue Background Scope and Exemptions Identifying the Median Employee and Calculating Annual Total Compensation Timing and Transition SEC Issues New

More information