A Generalized Empirical Model of Corruption, Foreign Direct Investment, and Growth

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A Generalized Empirical Model of Corruption, Foreign Direct Investment, and Growth"

Transcription

1 A Generalized Empirical Model of Corruption, Foreign Direct Investment, and Growth Michael S. Delgado Department of Economics Binghamton University Subal C. Kumbhakar Department of Economics Binghamton University Nadine McCloud Department of Economics University of the West Indies at Mona March 27, 2011 Abstract We propose a generalized empirical model for estimating the effect of foreign direct investment on GDP growth rates, as well as for determining the effect of corruption on the growth rate, and on the relationship between foreign direct investment and growth. Our model allows for parameter heterogeneity between all conditioning variables (including foreign direct investment) and growth, as well as in the effects of corruption on growth. We estimate the regression using a recently developed nonparametric method of moments estimator that allows us to concurrently use instrumental variables to mitigate any endogeneity bias that may be present in the relationship between foreign direct investment and growth, and model parameter heterogeneity. We find that there is substantial heterogeneity in the relationship between foreign direct investment and growth, and that foreign direct investment has a positive and significant effect on growth for many of the countries in our sample. Corruption is shown to significantly diminish the effectiveness of foreign direct investment at improving growth rates, but overall has an insignificant net effect on growth. Keywords: Foreign direct investment; corruption; parameter heterogeneity; economic growth; nonparametric method of moments; instrumental variables. Michael S. Delgado, Department of Economics, State University of New York at Binghamton, PO Box 6000, Binghamton, NY mdelgad1@binghamton.edu Corresponding author: Subal C. Kumbhakar, Department of Economics, State University of New York at Binghamton, PO Box 6000, Binghamton, NY Phone: Fax: kkar@binghamton.edu Nadine McCloud, Department of Economics, University of the West Indies at Mona, Kingston 7, Jamaica. nadine.mccloud02@uwimona.edu.jm 1

2 1 Introduction Foreign direct investment (FDI) is generally thought to be an important factor of growth and development in developing countries. It is through the investments of large multinational corporations that developing countries have access to advanced technologies, management practices, and research and development that are crucial for growth, but are otherwise unavailable in the developing world (e.g., Borensztein et al and Carkovic and Levine 2005). Unfortunately, while there has been a broad consensus as to the theoretical importance of FDI for growth and development in developing countries, there has yet to be a consensus among empirical researchers as to the significance of FDI at increasing growth rates. Blomstrom (1986), Borensztein et al. (1998) and Alfaro et al. (2004) all find evidence that FDI positively contributes to economic growth, whereas Haddad and Harrison (1993), Aitken and Harrison (1999), and Carkovic and Levine (2005) find no evidence in support of growth-enhancing effects of FDI. These conflicting empirical results among studies on the FDI-growth relationship may be due to the failure to appropriately incorporate parameter heterogeneities, which can lead to a misspecified model and inaccurate estimation of the relationships of interest. Durlauf (2001), for example, advocates modeling all the parameters in growth regressions as functions of developmental variables, rather than as constants. Constant parameter growth models may suffer from misspecification since they ignore crucial heterogeneities induced by the developmental variables that are fundamental to the growth process. Moreover, constant-parameter models will most likely be sensitive to different specifications of functional forms, or samples of observations. Growth models that allow for constant parameters provide a description of the average relation, at best. In the presence of substantial heterogeneity in the growth process, constant-parameter models are unlikely to accurately estimate the relationship between FDI and growth. One important developmental element that is likely correlated with the absorptive capabilities of host countries and ultimately influences the effectiveness of FDI at improving growth rates is institutional quality. While there are different measures of institutional quality that may result in heterogeneity in the effect of FDI on growth across developing countries, corruption may be of extra importance because of its effect on many avenues that all ultimately influence absorptive capabilities and growth rates. Mauro (1998), Gupta et al. (2002) and Tanzi et al. (2002) all document a negative relationship between corruption and human capital. Countries that are more corrupt tend to invest less in human capital, which ultimately decreases the ability of the country to absorb new technologies from developed nations (Borensztein et al. 1998). Bribery, for example, which is associated with higher levels of corruption, may lead to an imbalance in the relative payoffs between productive and unproductive sectors in the economy (Baumol 1990 and Murphy et al. 1991). Workers are less likely to move to domestic from foreign firms (i.e., the multinational corporations) where their payoffs are relatively higher; the result is less diffusion of technology from the domestic firms to foreign firms, and a weakening of the effect of FDI on growth. Building on previous studies that have identified heterogeneity within the relationship between FDI and GDP growth (e.g., Borensztein et al and Alfaro et al. 2004), as well as studies that have shown an important interaction between institutional factors (e.g., corruption) and the effectiveness of FDI at improving growth rates (e.g., McCloud and Kumbhakar 2

3 2011), we present a generalized empirical growth model with which to re-analyze the relationship between corruption, FDI, and GDP growth (as well as the relationship between growth rates and other conditioning variables). Our generalization is based on a standard growth regression that assumes homogeneous parameters. We generalize the standard model to allow for a heterogeneous relationship between GDP growth and all conditioning variables, by making the coefficients unknown smooth-functions of an index of corruption, and country- and time-specific indicators. Thus, our model allows us to obtain estimates that are specific to each country in each year, and estimates that depend on the level of corruption in each country and in each year. While we present an alternative approach that complements previous studies that have allowed for heterogeneity within the corruption-fdi-growth relationship, our approach also allows us to analyze the effect of corruption on GDP growth rates through its effect on all conditioning variables (e.g., trade openness, or inflation), and not solely through its influence on the FDI-growth relationship. To estimate our generalized regression model, we use a recently developed nonparametric version of a standard method of moments estimator (Cai and Li 2008) that assumes the primary conditioning variables (e.g., FDI) enter linearly into the regression model, but allows the intercept and slope coefficients to vary nonparametrically (i.e., either linearly or nonlinearly) with respect to certain environmental factors (e.g., corruption). Hence, this model is a version of the varying coefficient models of Hastie and Tibshirani (1993), or more recently Li et al. (2002). One advantage of this nonparametric generalized methods of moments (NPGMM) estimator over other smooth coefficient models, e.g., Durlauf et al. (2001) and Li et al. (2002), is that it allows all of the conditioning variables to be endogenous. This, in part, addresses one concern raised by Durlauf (2001), who argues that in a growth specification, all conditioning variables can be taken to be endogenous; that is, all variables typically included in a growth specification are determined, in part, by omitted factors that also determine growth rates. In particular, Borensztein et al. (1998) provide a discussion of the potential endogeneity of FDI in a growth regression. Hence, it is important to consider an instrumental-variables approach to estimating the relationship between FDI (or any other conditioning variables of interest) and growth in order to obtain consistent estimates. 1 Although the generalized model differs from standard homogeneous models by incorporating parameter heterogeneity in the coefficients, the generalized model maintains the traditional functional form assumptions embedded in the standard models. The advantage of maintaining such assumptions (e.g., additive separability and linearity of the regressors), is that the standard model exists as a special case of the generalized model. We can econometrically test whether the data support the assumption of parameter homogeneity inherent in the standard model. Another advantage of maintaining such functional form assumptions is that we can avoid dimensionality issues that often arise in fully-specified nonparametric models. In the present context, dimensionality issues can only arise when estimating the coefficient functions in the smooth coefficient model; because the number of continuous environmental factors is likely to 1 In the empirical growth literature, Liu and Stengos (1999) and Durlauf et al. (2001) also use semiparametric models to examine parameter heterogeneity. Their works differ from that of the present paper in many ways including the use of cross-sectional and not panel data, exclusion of FDI from the set of independent variables, sample selection (inclusion of OECD and non-oecd countries), assumed sources(s) of parameter heterogeneity, and analysis of endogeneity. 3

4 be relatively small, or at least smaller than the entire conditioning set in a fully nonparametric regression, the curse of dimensionality can often be avoided. Our results confirm that there exists substantial heterogeneity in the relationship between FDI and growth, and we find strong evidence that FDI has a positive and significant influence on growth rates for about 80 percent of the developing countries in our sample. In addition to providing observation-specific estimates of the coefficients (e.g., the FDI coefficient), our model also provides estimates of the marginal effect of corruption on each of the coefficients. Our estimates show that corruption significantly reduces the effectiveness of FDI on growth, which supports previous studies that suggest that corruption influences the absorptive capabilities of developing countries. However, when considering the total effect of corruption on growth rates (i.e., the sum of the indirect effects of corruption on all of the coefficients in the model), we find that corruption does not significantly influence growth rates. Through our heterogeneous parameter estimates, we analyze separate groups of countries that have substantially different coefficients and isolate characteristics common within such groups. This type of analysis is useful for international investment policies: knowledge of whether there is a positive and significant relationship between FDI and growth rates for any particular country, or how this relationship varies with respect to corruption is crucial for designing policies aimed at improving growth rates. While we do not find evidence of regional or geographical groups, we find that with respect to heterogeneity within the FDI-growth relation, many countries with the highest returns to FDI also have the lowest returns to corruption. Conversely, countries with an insignificant or relatively low correlation between FDI and growth have the highest estimated returns to corruption. Hence, our results suggest that developing countries with relatively low correlations between FDI and growth may benefit substantially from a reduction in corruption. Our empirical results are robust to using different instruments for FDI, allowing for all conditioning variables to be endogenous, using different measures of corruption, controlling for other measures of institutional quality that may be correlated with the dependent and independent variables. Moreover, a specification test suggests our semiparametric model that allows for endogeneity is more consistent with the data than the standard-homogeneous model. The structure of the rest of the paper is as follows. Section 2 presents and discusses our generalized empirical growth model and its nonparametric method of moments estimator. Section 3 discusses the data. Section 4 provides the main empirical results and discusses their implied policy prescriptions. Section 5 investigates the robustness of our main results. Section 6 concludes. The excluded empirical results can be furnished on request. 2 Empirical Methodology 2.1 Growth Models We consider a standard growth model with the growth rate of real GDP per capita as the dependent variable and a set of control variables. Letting g it denote the real GDP per capita growth rate in country i at time t, we write the standard model as: 4

5 g it = β 0 + Y it β 1 + X itβ 2 + ǫ it, i = 1,...,n t = 1,...,T, (1) in which Y it is our measure of FDI, X it is a vector of control variables, β (β 0, β 1, β 2 ) is a vector of parameters to be estimated, and ǫ it is a zero-mean random error. The advantage of (1) is that, under certain regularity assumptions, it is easy to consistently estimate the effect of FDI on growth using a least squares criterion. One primary drawback of this model, however, is that it fails to incorporate parameter heterogeneity that more likely exists in a cross-country panel of observations. In particular, model (1) does not allow the effect of FDI on growth, β 1, to vary with respect to the index of corruption. Allowing the parameter estimates to vary with respect to corruption is a pragmatic way to identify the indirect effect of corruption on growth. An alternative way to incorporate the level of corruption into the growth regression would be to add the corruption index as another conditioning (i.e., X) variable, but this approach does not identify indirect channels through which corruption influences growth. Corrupt governments (or officials) are more likely to embezzle funds and redirect public expenditures towards personal and private ventures, rather than direct them towards more publicly beneficial avenues. The effect is that FDI and other correlates of economic growth may be directly influenced by the level of corruption. Through these channels, corruption may indirectly influence GDP growth rates. However, it is important to incorporate the direct effects of corruption in the regression model to obtain an accurate picture of the effect of corruption on growth rates and on the relationship between the conditioning variables (e.g., FDI) and growth, and results that are comparable to those of existing growth studies. Since our interest is on the estimation of the effect of FDI on growth, and how this effect varies with respect to the level of corruption, we generalize the model to incorporate the effect of corruption on the β-parameters. Specifically, we generalize (1) by allowing the β-parameters in the model to vary with respect to a particular set of environmental variables, Z it, which contains the index of corruption. Hence, we write our generalized model as: g it = β 0 (Z it ) + Y it β 1 (Z it ) + X itβ 2 (Z it ) + ǫ it, i = 1,...,n t = 1,...,T. (2) An advantage of using the generalized model in (2) is that it provides observation-specific estimates of the coefficients of the model thereby allowing us to analyze the heterogeneity in the effect of FDI (and other control variables) on growth rates. As previously argued, an accurate modeling of parameter heterogeneity is crucial for designing cross-country policies to increase growth rates in developing countries; if the effect of FDI on growth rates varies substantially across different countries (or different groups or types of countries), investment policies governing FDI should be tailored to each specific country (or group of countries). The policy prescriptions for boosting growth through FDI, which are implied by homogeneous parameter estimated, may be too passive or active for some developing countries. If we assume that corruption is orthogonal to the error term, then it is straightforward to extract the direct and indirect effects of corruption on growth. The direct effect of corruption on growth comes through the effect of corruption on the intercept function, β 0 ( ); we can obtain 5

6 an estimate of this direct effect through the partial derivative of the intercept function with respect to corruption at a particular point, z: β 0 / z. The indirect effects come through the effect of corruption on the other coefficient functions in the model, β j 0 ( ); we obtain these effects through the partial derivatives of each of the slope coefficient functions with respect to corruption, β j 0 / z. The total effect of corruption on GDP growth rates is the sum of the direct and indirect effects of corruption on growth. Hence, taking a partial derivative of the growth rate in (2) with respect to corruption at a particular point yields the total effect of corruption on growth: 2.2 Estimation g it z = β 0 z + Y β 1 it z + β 2 X it z. (3) To exploit the generality of our model in (2), we assume that the coefficient functions are unknown smooth functions of Z. For ease of exposition, we rewrite (2) more compactly as: g it = X itβ(z it ) + ǫ it, i = 1,...,n t = 1,...,T, (4) in which X it is a vector of dimension k with the first column containing a one and the remaining columns containing the (k 1) regressors (including FDI); β( ) is a vector of smooth coefficient functions of unknown form; Z it is a vector of dimension p containing environmental factors that are assumed to be the sources of parameter heterogeneity. If we assume also that all regressors in X are exogenous then (4) is a standard semiparametric smooth coefficient model that can be consistently estimated using the nonparametric kernel estimator proposed by Li et al. (2002). This exogeneity assumption seems strong in the present growth application, hence we allow the variables in X to be endogenous. This key endogeneity assumption distinguishes our model in (4) from other semiparametric smooth coefficient models. In the special case where all regressors in X are exogenous, our model is equivalent to a standard semiparametric smooth coefficient model. If any element in X is endogenous, then E[g it X it, Z it ] X it β(z it) and estimation using typical semiparametric estimators (e.g., Li et al. 2002) will provide inconsistent estimates of the unknown coefficient functions. Several nonparametric estimators have been proposed to deal with the problem of endogeneity in smooth coefficient models, for example, Das (2005), Cai et al. (2006), and Cai and Li (2008). Both the estimators in Das (2005) and Cai et al. (2006) are two-step estimators that require nonparametric estimation of the endogenous variables on the instruments and exogenous variables in the first step followed by semiparametric regression of the dependent variable on the first stage estimates of the endogenous variables. Cai and Li (2008), however, propose a one-step estimator of (4) when X is allowed to be endogenous. We apply this one-step Cai and Li (2008) estimator to reap the gains in efficiency that the one-step estimator likely has over the two-step estimators. We note that the Cai and Li (2008) framework allows for all X variables to be endogenous, and explicitly assumes that the environmental variables in Z are exogenous. To circumvent the endogeneity problem and obtain consistent estimates of the coefficient 6

7 functions, Cai and Li (2008) propose the following conditional moment restriction: E[Q(Ω it )ǫ it Ω it ] = E[Q(Ω it ){g it X itβ(z it )} Ω it ] = 0, (5) in which Ω it = (W it, Z it ), W it is a vector of instrumental variables such that E[ǫ it W it ] = 0, and Q(Ω it ) is some vector function such that the conditional moment restriction in equation (5) is satisfied. While in principle any vector for Q(Ω it ) that satisfies the conditional moment restriction in (5) can be used, Cai and Li (2008) suggest using Q(Ω it ) = ( W it W it (Z it z)/h), where h is a smoothing parameter, and is the Kronecker product operator, to make use of the instrumental variables in W it. Cai and Li (2008) suggest estimating the coefficients, β(z it ), with nonparametric kernel methods which, combined with the conditional moment restriction in (5), yields a nonparametric equivalent of a GMM estimator (or NPGMM). We assume the coefficients, β(z it ), are twice continuously differentiable, so that we can apply local-linear least-squares to estimate the unknown functions. A first order Taylor expansion around a given point z yields an approximation to the function β j (Z it ) given by β j (z)+δ j (Z it z), in which δ j is a gradient vector of the partial effects β j (z)/ z. Thus the local-linear procedure provides a vector of estimated coefficient functions, ˆβ j (Z it ), along with their first order gradient vectors, ˆβ j (z)/ z. Letting U it = ( Xit X it (Z it z)) and α = (βj (z), δ j ) be the vector of coefficients and their first order partial derivatives, the conditional moment restriction in equation (5) gives rise to the following locally weighted orthogonality condition: n i=1 t=1 T Q(Ω it )(g it U itα)k h (Z it z) = 0 (6) in which K h (Z it z) is a generalized product kernel of dimension p that admits a mix of continuous and discrete environmental factors contained in Z (see Racine and Li 2004), and h denotes a vector of smoothing parameters. Cai and Li (2008) show that a consistent estimate of α can be obtained from: in which and S n = 1 n T n = 1 n ˆα = (S ns n ) 1 (S nt n ), (7) n i=1 t=1 n i=1 t=1 T Q(Ω it )U itk h (Z it z) (8) T Q(Ω it )K h (Z it z)g it. (9) To avoid any pitfalls associated with an ad hoc choice of smoothing parameters, we use least-squares cross-validation to select the parameters in h. The least-squares cross-validation criterion function is given by min h nt i=1 (g i ĝ i ) 2 (10) in which ĝ i is the leave-one-out estimate of the conditional mean, X ˆβ(Z). All standard errors 7

8 are estimated using a wild-bootstrap. 3 Data 3.1 Overview The data set comes from McCloud and Kumbhakar (2011). It consists of a balanced panel of 60 non-oecd countries spanning the period giving a total of 1080 observations. Our primary interest is in estimation of the effect of FDI on GDP growth and how this effect varies with respect to the level of corruption in each country in each year. Our secondary interest is in identifying the overall effect of corruption on GDP growth, both directly through its influence on the intercept term and indirectly through its role in the effects of other control variables on growth. Our measure of GDP growth is the per capita GDP growth rate that comes from the Penn World Table (version 6.2). 3.2 FDI Our measure of FDI is the percentage of FDI inflow relative to GDP in constant 2002 dollars, which comes from the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development online statistical database. It is generally believed that FDI may be correlated with any factors that influence growth rates but are omitted from the regression model; that is, FDI may be endogenous in a growth specification such as (1). The empirical FDI literature has been unable to identify an ideal instrumental variable to completely control for any endogeneity bias. Several studies have proposed several different instrumental variables that have been shown to mitigate, at least part of, the endogeneity of FDI. Borensztein et al. (1998), for example, suggest using lagged values of FDI or measures of institutional quality. Carkovic and Levine (2005) suggest using lagged FDI as well as lagged differences of FDI as instrumental variables. We find that in our data set, lagged values of FDI work reasonably well and appear to mitigate, at least part of, the endogeneity of FDI; see section 4.1. Measures of institutional quality (i.e., ethnolinguistic fractionalization and latitude from La Porta et al. (2009), and the log of the life expectancy and log of the fertility rate from the 2005 World Development Indicators) and lagged differences of FDI appear irrelevant based on their low explanatory power in the first-stage parametric regressions. Moreover, semiparametric regressions using these latter instrumental variables did not yield meaningful estimates or appear to mitigate any endogeneity bias. In addition to the above instrumental variables proposed in previous studies, we propose using total world FDI flows and total FDI flows to developing countries as alternative instrumental variables. Currently, we are unaware of other studies that use these total FDI flows as instrumental variables for individual country FDI flows. Our rationale for using these variables is that measures of total FDI flows will cause fluctuations in individual country FDI flows, but are uncorrelated with growth rates of individual countries. Parametric first-stage regressions suggest that total world FDI flows and total FDI flows to developing nations may be reasonable alternative instrumental variables for FDI. The sample correlations between FDI (the endogenous variable of interest) and each of the instrumental variables are 0.74, 0.32, and 0.13, for lagged FDI, world FDI flows, and developing world FDI flows, respectively. We use lagged FDI 8

9 as our preferred instrumental variable since it provides the strongest first-stage correlations with FDI (as well as strongest sample correlation), but we consider both measures of total FDI flows as alternative instrumental variables in our sensitivity analysis. 3.3 Corruption We combine two indices of corruption that are widely used in the existing empirical literature. One index of corruption is from Knack and Philip (1998), which is for the period 1984 to This index ranges from 0 to 6 and lower scores indicate lower levels of corruption in that high government officials are likely to demand special payments and illegal payments are generally expected throughout lower levels of government in the form of bribes connected with import and export licenses, exchange controls, tax assessment, police protection, or loans. The other corruption index is from Transparency International (TI) for the period 1997 to The TI s corruption index measures the overall extent of corruption and therefore does not distinguish between administrative and political corruption, nor between petty and grand corruption. It ranges from 0 to 10 with higher values indicating lower levels of corruption. For ease of exposition, we rescale the TI index so that lower values represent lower levels of corruption. An important assumption in this analysis is that our proxies for corruption are time invariant. Our rationale is based on the fact that the extent to which corruption is entrenched in many non-oecd countries makes it difficult for these countries to lower their corruption levels in the absence of proper legal recourse through institutional reform. Consequently, we transform the Knack and Philip index to be within the range of 0 to 10 and then construct an aggregated corruption index by using the time average of the Knack and Philip and TI indices as the measure of corruption for the entire time span. We note that the Spearman s rank correlation coefficient for the average PRS and TI indices is with a p-value of 0 for the null hypothesis of independence. Hence, combining the different measures of corruption from these two sources should not bias the qualitative implications about the effect of corruption on FDI-growth relation. 3.4 Additional Control Variables We use the following list of covariates to control primarily for any omitted variables bias between GDP growth and FDI, but also to serve as possible channels through which corruption may effect growth. The variables include initial GDP per capita defined as GDP per capita in the previous year; openness, defined as the ratio of exports plus imports as a percentage of GDP; government consumption, defined as the ratio of general government consumption as a percentage of GDP; domestic investment as a percentage of GDP; the US treasury bill rate; and the inflation rate. All variables come from the Penn World Table (version 6.2) except for the US treasury bill rate which comes from the IMF International Financial Statistics Database. We include the US treasury bill rate to control for changes in the growth rate that are caused by macroeconomic conditions that are exogenous to each individual country. 2 The TI index was first launched in 1995 with only a small number of countries. Using earlier years of this index would have reduced our effective sample size. 9

10 In addition to corruption, the vector of environmental variables, Z, also contains an unordered categorical country indicator and an ordered categorical indicator for year to control for country and year fixed effects, respectively. Alternative specifications include the fertility rate (total births per woman) and an index of democracy as additional environmental variables. Our index of democracy comes from the Polity IV database and ranges from -10 to +10 with +10 representing complete democracy and -10 complete autocracy. With the exception of the variables already measured in percentage terms or growth rates, all continuous variables are measured in logs. 4 Results 4.1 Ordinary Least Squares We first estimate the standard homogeneous model in (1) using ordinary least squares. Since the coefficients do not vary in this model, we include corruption and country and time dummy variables as standard conditioning (i.e., X) variables. The purpose of estimating the homogeneous model is to provide estimates that are directly comparable to other studies that do not use semiparametric estimators, and to anchor our semiparametric results to the standard case. Table 1 contains the results from the different model specifications. The first three columns in Table 1 show estimates from three standard models: the first column reports the results from a parsimonious model in which the only regressors are FDI and fixed effect dummy variables; the second column adds corruption; and the third column adds the rest of the conditioning set. We find that FDI has a positive and significant effect on growth rates in columns 1 and 2; that is, including corruption in the regression does not erode the effect of FDI on growth. In particular, an increase of 10 percent in the FDI inflows to GDP is associated with an increase of 3 percent in economic growth rate. Interestingly, the coefficient on corruption is positive and significant. A positive coefficient on corruption implies that holding everything else constant, increasing the level of corruption in a country will increase its rate of real GDP per capita growth. We find this result to be counter-intuitive; our prior expectation is that corruption has a negative (or perhaps insignificant) effect on GDP growth rates. Moreover, the R 2 does not improve substantially after including corruption into the regression, which suggests that corruption may not contain much predictive power. Including the rest of the conditioning set (column 3) does not change the effect of corruption on growth, but it does erode the effect of FDI on growth by approximately 67 percent. This large reduction in the estimated FDI coefficient suggests that the FDI-growth effects in the columns 1 and 2 may be driven by omitted variables bias. Indeed, there may be other factors that are subsumed in the errors and are correlated with both FDI and economic growth. To explore this possibility, we use instrumental variables methods. Columns 4 through 6 report estimates from two-stage least squares regressions that use the one-period lagged value of FDI to control for any possible endogeneity of FDI in the standard models. Specifically, we include all exogenous variables including corruption in the first stage regression, as well as country and time dummy variables to control for country and time fixed effects. We find that for each first-stage specification, the FDI instrument is positive and sta- 10

11 tistically significant, and the F-statistic for the null hypothesis of no regression exceeds 10, suggesting strength of the instrumental variable (Staiger and Stock, 1997). We find that in the second-stage regressions, including the fully specified model in column 6, the instrumented FDI variable has a positive and significant effect on growth rates. In addition, the magnitude of the FDI coefficient is substantially larger than in the simple ordinary least squares models. This suggests that there is a downward bias in the ordinary least squares estimates of FDI, most likely caused by endogeneity; the lagged FDI instrument is able to correct for (at least part of) the downward bias on the FDI coefficient. Corruption remains positive and significant, and many other conditioning variables maintain their sign and significance observed in their ordinary least squares counterparts. The explanatory power in the two-stage least squares models is comparable to that from the ordinary least squares models. The aforementioned ordinary least squares and two-stage least squares homogeneous estimates yield three important observations: One, on average, FDI has a positive and significant effect on GDP growth rates in non-oecd countries, but the effect is subject to a downward endogeneity bias that will potentially mask the significance of FDI. Two, the use of lagged FDI as an instrument for FDI is able to mitigate this downward bias and provides more precise estimates of the effect of FDI on growth. This positive mean effect of FDI on growth, as implied by the homogeneous models, should not be taken to imply that in all countries, FDI has a positive and significant effect on growth rates. Three, corruption appear to have strongly positive and significant, albeit counter-intuitive, effect on growth rates. This latter counterintutive result may be a manifestation of model misspecification, at least with regards to the way in which corruption is included in the model. A maintained hypothesis is this paper is that corruption itself is an environmental variable and thus it should be included as such in the regression, and not included as a typical conditioning (i.e., X) regressor. In light of these observations, we move on to the results from our generalized semiparametric specifications that concurrently allow for (a) corruption to enter into the model indirectly through its influence on the relationship between the conditioning variables and GDP growth rates, (b) parameter heterogeneity and (c) endogenous regressors. 4.2 Semiparametric Smooth Coefficient Models Columns 7 through 10 in Table 1 report the mean coefficients and standard errors for four semiparametric smooth coefficient specifications. The first two specifications (columns 7 and 8) do not control for endogeneity of FDI; hence, these models are standard semiparametric smooth coefficient models (SPSCM). Columns 9 and 10 control for endogeneity of FDI using lagged FDI and the Cai and Li (2008) NPGMM estimator. Columns 7 and 9 include only FDI as a conditioning variable, whereas columns 8 and 10 include all other conditioning variables. Each of the four models include corruption and indicators for country and year as environmental variables Mean Parameter Estimates We find that the mean coefficient on FDI is positive and statistically significant in all semiparametric specifications. In the semiparametric models that do not allow for instrumental variables 11

12 (columns 7 and 8), we observe FDI coefficients that are similar in magnitude to their ordinary least squares estimates in columns 1 and 2. After controlling for endogeneity, we observe that the mean FDI coefficients in the semiparametric models (columns 9 and 10) are close in magnitude to their counterparts from the two-stage least squares models. In essence, the FDI coefficients are substantially larger in magnitude in the semiparametric models that control for endogeneity, suggesting that the endogeneity of FDI biased its coefficients downward bias. Thus, we again find evidence that supports the validity of using lagged FDI values to correct for any endogeneity bias associated with FDI. Turning to the additional conditioning variables in the fully-specified models (columns 8 and 10), we find that regardless of whether we instrument for FDI, the mean estimates of initial income, openness and the inflation rate are negative and highly statistically significant, whereas those associated with domestic investment are positive and highly statistically significant. The mean estimates of all other conditioning variables are insignificant. Turning to the total effect of corruption on growth, g/ Z, we find in each of the four semiparametric models that corruption has an insignificant effect on GDP growth rates. This result is more in line with our prior expectations, and is in contrast to the results from the ordinary least squares and two-stage least squares estimates that found corruption to have a positive and significant effect on growth rates. Table 2 shows the means and standard errors of the direct effect of corruption on the coefficients in the semiparametric models. At the mean, we find that corruption has a negative and significant effect on the coefficient on FDI (columns 2 to 4). Thus, coupling this result with the positive and significant FDI coefficients in Table 1 (columns 8 to 10) implies that an increase in corruption will decrease the effectiveness of FDI on growth, and through this channel, holding everything else constant, decrease GDP growth. From Table 2, we also find that corruption has a positive and significant effect on the coefficient on openness (column 2) and on inflation (column 4). Since both the openness and inflation coefficients are negative and significant (see columns 8 and 10 of Table 1), these positive partial derivatives imply that the effect of openness and inflation on growth is dampened by an increase in corruption. In addition, we find that in each of the four semiparametric models, the R 2 is substantially higher than in the corresponding homogeneous regressions. These higher R 2 values suggest that there are sizeable parameter heterogeneities across countries and modeling these parameter heterogeneities substantially improves the fit of the model to the data. We now turn to the distribution of the coefficients and their partial effects with respect to corruption to further assess the degree of parameter heterogeneity that exists in the estimates, and to understand the policy implications of heterogeneity in the relationship between FDI and growth Heterogeneous Parameter Estimates To present the distribution of coefficients in a concise manner, we use 45-degree gradient plots to simultaneously show the magnitude, sign, standard errors, statistical significance and density of the coefficients. To construct these plots, we first plot the observation-specific coefficients on the 45 degree line. The location of any particular coefficient to the horizontal axis determines the sign and magnitude of the coefficient, whereas the density can be seen by the proximity 12

13 of surrounding observations to any particular observation. Areas with a high concentration of coefficients are areas of higher density. We then calculate observation-specific confidence bounds by adding (and subtracting) twice the observation-specific standard error from each coefficient. We then overlay the confidence bounds above (and below) the scatterplot of coefficients. This allows us to assess whether each observation is statistically significant; if the horizontal line at zero runs between the coefficient and its upper or lower confidence bound, the observation has a statistically insignificant coefficient. If the horizontal line at zero does not intersect the confidence bound for a particular observation, that observation is statistically significant. Figure 1 displays the 45-degree gradient plots for the distribution of observation-specific FDI coefficients and standard errors for each of the four semiparametric models that are described in Table 1. In each model, many of the observations are positive. Specifically, for the standard semiparametric models that do not use instrumental variables (SPSCM models), 56 percent and 65 percent of the FDI coefficients are positive and significant, respectively SPSCM1 and SP- SCM2. In the semiparametric models that use lagged FDI as an instrumental variable (NPGMM models), the FDI coefficients are positive and significant for 59 percent and 76 percent of the observations, respectively NPGMM1 and NPGMM2. While the plots show a substantial amount of heterogeneity in the parameter estimates, it is clear that, on average, FDI has a positive and significant effect on GDP growth rates. Moreover, after instrumenting for any endogeneity bias on the coefficients, we find that the fraction of coefficients that are positive and significant increases. These results provide evidence that the lagged value of FDI is also able to mitigate (at least part of) the downward bias on the FDI coefficients in the semiparametric models. In reference to the additional conditioning variables in the fully-specified models that have statistically significant mean estimates, we find that 59 percent of the initial income coefficients are negative and significant in the model that does not instrument for FDI, whereas 72 percent of the coefficients are negative and significant in the instrumental variables model. We find that 46 percent of the coefficients on openness are negative and significant in the non-instrumental variables model, and 75 percent of the coefficients are negative and significant in the instrumental variables model. In the non-instrumental variables model we find that 94 percent of the coefficients on domestic investment are positive and significant, and 94 percent of the coefficients on inflation are negative and significant. In the instrumental variables model, we find that 95 percent of the coefficients on domestic investment are positive and significant, and 91 percent of the coefficients on inflation are negative and significant. These results suggest that endogeneity of FDI induces biases in the estimates associated with the other regression coefficients, and the size and direction of these biases appear to differ across countries and regressors. Figure 2 contains 45 degree plots for the partial effects of the FDI coefficients with respect to corruption. For the standard semiparametric models, 42 percent and 74 percent of the FDI coefficients show a significantly negative partial effect with respect to corruption, respectively SPSCM1 and SPSCM2. In the semiparametric instrumental variables models, 45 percent and 84 percent of the FDI coefficients show a negative and significant partial effect with respect to corruption, respectively NPGMM1 and NPGMM2. These results, especially in the fully specified models, lend additional support to the view that corruption decreases the effectiveness of FDI on GDP growth. 13

14 The effect of corruption on the additional coefficients in the fully-specified models is insignificant, except for the coefficients associated with openness and inflation. In the non-instrumental variables model, we find that corruption significantly reduces the effectiveness of openness on growth rates for 58 percent of the observations. In the instrumental variables model, the effect of corruption on openness ceases to be statistically significant; however, we find that 56 percent of the observations have a positive and significant partial effect of the inflation coefficient with respect to corruption. In general, these results suggest that corruption strongly affects the FDI coefficient, and has a neutral effect on the coefficients of (many of) the other conditioning variables in the model. For the fully-specified models, 45-degree gradient plots for the additional conditioning variables are available upon request from the authors. Figure 3 shows the 45 degree plots for the total effect of corruption on growth rates. In the first two semiparametric models (that do not instrument for endogeneity), we find 64 percent and 70 percent of the partial effects to be insignificant, respectively SPSCM1 and SPSCM2. In the semiparametric instrumental variables models, we find 66 percent and 72 percent of the partial effects to be insignificant, respectively NPGMM1 and NPGMM2. Hence, we find strong evidence that although corruption decreases the effectiveness of FDI on growth rates, corruption has an overall insignificant effect on growth. With regards to the estimated bandwidths, we find in each of our four semiparametric models that the bandwidth on corruption exceeds several standard deviations of the data. In the local-linear least-squares context, a relatively large bandwidth on corruption implies that corruption enters linearly into the parameters, β j ( ). Local-linear least-squares is nothing more than weighted least-squares through the kernel function providing a local weight for each observation; a large bandwidth means that the local neighborhood includes all observations, and hence a globally linear estimate with respect to corruption. 3 We leave further analysis of any potential linearity between corruption, FDI, and GDP growth for future research. Our empirical results so far are in favor of parameter heterogeneity. To formally test whether the semiparametric models yielding heterogeneous parameter estimates are indeed preferred to the homogeneous parameter models, we use the model specification test of Cai et al. (2000). The Cai et al. (2000) test allows us to determine whether the data support the null hypothesis of the simple two-stage least-squares model. We test the null hypothesis against two alternative hypotheses: the two primary semiparametric smooth coefficient models that include the entire conditioning set of regressors (one using instrumental variables and the other without). We are able to reject the null hypothesis of correct specification for the constant parameter model in both tests with a p-value of Hence, the data support our generalized semiparametric specification that admits parameter heterogeneity as a function of corruption over the homogeneous parameter specification. 3 This does not imply any particular parametric functional form for the coefficients, β j( ), since a large bandwidth on corruption does not necessarily point towards any specifications regarding interactions between corruption and other environmental variables, or towards correct parametric specification for other environmental variables. 14

15 4.2.3 Policy Implications One of the advantages of incorporating parameter heterogeneity into the regression model is that it allows us to identify the country specific returns to both FDI and a marginal change in corruption. We can analyze the placement of countries in the distribution of FDI coefficients to ascertain which countries have the highest returns to FDI. In addition, we can identify which group of countries may benefit the most from a reduction in corruption; countries that have the highest partial effect of the FDI coefficient with respect to corruption may benefit substantially from FDI if their level of corruption were to decrease. Moreover, the present analysis may help directly with international FDI policies. One stipulation in an international FDI agreement may be a mandatory reduction in the level of corruption in the developing host country. At the very least, this analysis can assist policymakers in determining in which countries FDI will most effectively improve growth rates, and in which countries FDI may have a neutral effect. Focusing now on the fully-specified semiparametric instrumental variables model (NPGMM), we analyze which countries appear to have the highest and lowest returns to FDI. Table 3 shows the lists of countries divided based on their relative returns to FDI. For those observations with positive and significant FDI coefficients, we divide the countries into separate lists for each of the four quantiles based on the magnitude of the coefficient. That is, the countries with FDI coefficients that are in the highest 75 percentile are grouped together in the 4 th quantile group; we do the same for each quantile. 4 Since all of the countries in these quantile lists realize positive returns to FDI, we also include a list of countries that have insignificant FDI coefficients. 5 Because we have a panel data set, some countries have FDI coefficients that appear in each category for at least one year. To provide a bit more clarity as to which countries receive high or low returns, we group the countries based on their modal classification: if a country appears most frequently in the column for insignificant returns to FDI, we classify it as insignificant. It is important to highlight which countries have consistently insignificant returns to FDI; policymakers may want to reconsider investment policies or investment stipulations aimed at these particular countries. 6 We can see in Table 3 that there does not appear to be any geographical similarities between the groupings of countries. Each group of countries contains countries from each continent or geographical region. This result implies that there exists heterogeneity in FDI returns even within geographical regions. Hence, geographical-oriented investment policies may be inappropriate for enhancing growth-effects of FDI, the best FDI policies may most likely be country-specific. With this in mind, the country lists in Table 3 provide preliminary estimates of the potential returns each country may realize from further FDI. Table 4 shows a similar breakdown of countries based on the partial derivative of the FDI coefficient with respect to corruption. 7 Here, we classify the modal observation into quantiles of 4 The smallest positive and significant coefficient is 0.004, and the largest positive and significant coefficient is The quartile values are 0.37, 0.61, and 0.78, respectively, for the 25 th, 50 th, and 75 th percentiles. All estimated values are in percentage terms. 5 Only 2 percent of the coefficients were negative and significant; none of the negative and significant coefficients represented the modal classification, so we do not include a category for negative returns. 6 It is important to acknowledge that although these classifications are based on the modal observations, many of the countries appear in the same category for many of the years in the panel. Hence the modal classification provides an accurate depiction of the distribution of the countries across the classification groups. 7 Specifically, the largest negative and significant partial effect is -4.16, and the smallest negative and significant 15

Foreign Direct Investment and the Domestic Capital Stock: The Good-Bad Role of Higher Institutional Quality

Foreign Direct Investment and the Domestic Capital Stock: The Good-Bad Role of Higher Institutional Quality Foreign Direct Investment and the Domestic Capital Stock: The Good-Bad Role of Higher Institutional Quality Michael S. Delgado Department of Agricultural Economics Purdue University Nadine McCloud Department

More information

Foreign Direct Investment and the Domestic Capital Stock: Heterogeneous Spillover Effects and the Good-Bad Role of Higher Institutional Quality

Foreign Direct Investment and the Domestic Capital Stock: Heterogeneous Spillover Effects and the Good-Bad Role of Higher Institutional Quality Foreign Direct Investment and the Domestic Capital Stock: Heterogeneous Spillover Effects and the Good-Bad Role of Higher Institutional Quality Michael S. Delgado Department of Agricultural Economics Purdue

More information

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade

The Time Cost of Documents to Trade The Time Cost of Documents to Trade Mohammad Amin* May, 2011 The paper shows that the number of documents required to export and import tend to increase the time cost of shipments. However, this relationship

More information

Nonparametric Estimation of a Hedonic Price Function

Nonparametric Estimation of a Hedonic Price Function Nonparametric Estimation of a Hedonic Price Function Daniel J. Henderson,SubalC.Kumbhakar,andChristopherF.Parmeter Department of Economics State University of New York at Binghamton February 23, 2005 Abstract

More information

Nonlinearities and Robustness in Growth Regressions Jenny Minier

Nonlinearities and Robustness in Growth Regressions Jenny Minier Nonlinearities and Robustness in Growth Regressions Jenny Minier Much economic growth research has been devoted to determining the explanatory variables that explain cross-country variation in growth rates.

More information

Financial Development and Economic Growth at Different Income Levels

Financial Development and Economic Growth at Different Income Levels 1 Financial Development and Economic Growth at Different Income Levels Cody Kallen Washington University in St. Louis Honors Thesis in Economics Abstract This paper examines the effects of financial development

More information

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment? Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment? Chang-Tai Hsieh, University of California Working Paper Series Vol. 2006-30 December 2006 The views expressed in this publication are those

More information

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017 Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality June 19, 2017 1 Table of contents 1 Robustness checks on baseline regression... 1 2 Robustness checks on composition

More information

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination Arvind Magesan and Jordi Mondria January 31, 2011 Abstract In this paper we study the economic and strategic incentives for a country to financially liberalize

More information

Does Manufacturing Matter for Economic Growth in the Era of Globalization? Online Supplement

Does Manufacturing Matter for Economic Growth in the Era of Globalization? Online Supplement Does Manufacturing Matter for Economic Growth in the Era of Globalization? Results from Growth Curve Models of Manufacturing Share of Employment (MSE) To formally test trends in manufacturing share of

More information

Macroeconomic Policy: Evidence from Growth Laffer Curve for Sri Lanka. Sujith P. Jayasooriya, Ch.E. (USA) Innovation4Development Consultants

Macroeconomic Policy: Evidence from Growth Laffer Curve for Sri Lanka. Sujith P. Jayasooriya, Ch.E. (USA) Innovation4Development Consultants Macroeconomic Policy: Evidence from Growth Laffer Curve for Sri Lanka Sujith P. Jayasooriya, Ch.E. (USA) Innovation4Development Consultants INTRODUCTION The concept of optimal taxation policies has recently

More information

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They?

The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They? The Comovements Along the Term Structure of Oil Forwards in Periods of High and Low Volatility: How Tight Are They? Massimiliano Marzo and Paolo Zagaglia This version: January 6, 29 Preliminary: comments

More information

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility Current Account Balances and Output Volatility Ceyhun Elgin Bogazici University Tolga Umut Kuzubas Bogazici University Abstract: Using annual data from 185 countries over the period from 1950 to 2009,

More information

Does the Equity Market affect Economic Growth?

Does the Equity Market affect Economic Growth? The Macalester Review Volume 2 Issue 2 Article 1 8-5-2012 Does the Equity Market affect Economic Growth? Kwame D. Fynn Macalester College, kwamefynn@gmail.com Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.macalester.edu/macreview

More information

Topic 2. Productivity, technological change, and policy: macro-level analysis

Topic 2. Productivity, technological change, and policy: macro-level analysis Topic 2. Productivity, technological change, and policy: macro-level analysis Lecture 3 Growth econometrics Read Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992, QJE); Durlauf et al. (2004, section 3-7) ; or Temple, J. (1999,

More information

DOES MONEY BUY CREDIT? FIRM-LEVEL EVIDENCE ON BRIBERY AND BANK DEBT

DOES MONEY BUY CREDIT? FIRM-LEVEL EVIDENCE ON BRIBERY AND BANK DEBT DOES MONEY BUY CREDIT? FIRM-LEVEL EVIDENCE ON BRIBERY AND BANK DEBT Zuzana Fungáčová (Bank of Finland) Anna Kochanova (Max Planck Institute, Bonn) Laurent Weill (University of Strasbourg & Bank of Finland)

More information

Deregulation and Firm Investment

Deregulation and Firm Investment Policy Research Working Paper 7884 WPS7884 Deregulation and Firm Investment Evidence from the Dismantling of the License System in India Ivan T. andilov Aslı Leblebicioğlu Ruchita Manghnani Public Disclosure

More information

Investment and Financing Constraints

Investment and Financing Constraints Investment and Financing Constraints Nathalie Moyen University of Colorado at Boulder Stefan Platikanov Suffolk University We investigate whether the sensitivity of corporate investment to internal cash

More information

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada Evan Gatev Simon Fraser University Mingxin Li Simon Fraser University AUGUST 2012 Abstract We examine

More information

US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies

US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies Nathan Foley-Fisher Bernardo Guimaraes August 2009 Abstract We empirically analyse the appropriateness of indexing emerging market sovereign

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence ISSN 2029-4581. ORGANIZATIONS AND MARKETS IN EMERGING ECONOMIES, 2012, VOL. 3, No. 1(5) Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence from and the Euro Area Jolanta

More information

AUTHOR ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

AUTHOR ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT AUTHOR ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT FINAL PUBLICATION INFORMATION Heterogeneity in the Allocation of External Public Financing : Evidence from Sub-Saharan African Post-MDRI Countries The definitive version of the

More information

Analyzing the Determinants of Project Success: A Probit Regression Approach

Analyzing the Determinants of Project Success: A Probit Regression Approach 2016 Annual Evaluation Review, Linked Document D 1 Analyzing the Determinants of Project Success: A Probit Regression Approach 1. This regression analysis aims to ascertain the factors that determine development

More information

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes Syed M. Hussain Samreen Malik May 9,. Online Appendix.. Anticipated versus Unanticipated Tax changes Comparing our estimates with the estimates

More information

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004

Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck. May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck May 2004 Personal Dividend and Capital Gains Taxes: Further Examination of the Signaling Bang for the Buck

More information

The Effect of Exchange Rate Risk on Stock Returns in Kenya s Listed Financial Institutions

The Effect of Exchange Rate Risk on Stock Returns in Kenya s Listed Financial Institutions The Effect of Exchange Rate Risk on Stock Returns in Kenya s Listed Financial Institutions Loice Koskei School of Business & Economics, Africa International University,.O. Box 1670-30100 Eldoret, Kenya

More information

Gains from Trade 1-3

Gains from Trade 1-3 Trade and Income We discusses the study by Frankel and Romer (1999). Does trade cause growth? American Economic Review 89(3), 379-399. Frankel and Romer examine the impact of trade on real income using

More information

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns Yongheng Deng and Joseph Gyourko 1 Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton University of Pennsylvania Prepared for the Corporate

More information

Online Appendix. income and saving-consumption preferences in the context of dividend and interest income).

Online Appendix. income and saving-consumption preferences in the context of dividend and interest income). Online Appendix 1 Bunching A classical model predicts bunching at tax kinks when the budget set is convex, because individuals above the tax kink wish to decrease their income as the tax rate above the

More information

Online Appendix (Not For Publication)

Online Appendix (Not For Publication) A Online Appendix (Not For Publication) Contents of the Appendix 1. The Village Democracy Survey (VDS) sample Figure A1: A map of counties where sample villages are located 2. Robustness checks for the

More information

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland The International Journal of Business and Finance Research Volume 6 Number 2 2012 AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

FDI and economic growth: new evidence on the role of financial markets

FDI and economic growth: new evidence on the role of financial markets MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive FDI and economic growth: new evidence on the role of financial markets W.N.W. Azman-Saini and Siong Hook Law and Abdul Halim Ahmad Universiti Putra Malaysia, Universiti

More information

A PVAR Approach to the Modeling of FDI and Spill Overs Effects in Africa

A PVAR Approach to the Modeling of FDI and Spill Overs Effects in Africa International Journal of Business and Economics, 2014, Vol. 13, No. 2, 181-185 A PVAR Approach to the Modeling of FDI and Spill Overs Effects in Africa Sheereen Fauzel Boopen Seetanah R. V. Sannassee 1.

More information

the display, exploration and transformation of the data are demonstrated and biases typically encountered are highlighted.

the display, exploration and transformation of the data are demonstrated and biases typically encountered are highlighted. 1 Insurance data Generalized linear modeling is a methodology for modeling relationships between variables. It generalizes the classical normal linear model, by relaxing some of its restrictive assumptions,

More information

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS JOHANNES KEPLER UNIVERSITY LINZ Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison by Burkhard Raunig and Johann Scharler* Working Paper

More information

Citation for published version (APA): Shehzad, C. T. (2009). Panel studies on bank risks and crises Groningen: University of Groningen

Citation for published version (APA): Shehzad, C. T. (2009). Panel studies on bank risks and crises Groningen: University of Groningen University of Groningen Panel studies on bank risks and crises Shehzad, Choudhry Tanveer IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish to cite from it.

More information

Acemoglu, et al (2008) cast doubt on the robustness of the cross-country empirical relationship between income and democracy. They demonstrate that

Acemoglu, et al (2008) cast doubt on the robustness of the cross-country empirical relationship between income and democracy. They demonstrate that Acemoglu, et al (2008) cast doubt on the robustness of the cross-country empirical relationship between income and democracy. They demonstrate that the strong positive correlation between income and democracy

More information

Redistribution Effects of Electricity Pricing in Korea

Redistribution Effects of Electricity Pricing in Korea Redistribution Effects of Electricity Pricing in Korea Jung S. You and Soyoung Lim Rice University, Houston, TX, U.S.A. E-mail: jsyou10@gmail.com Revised: January 31, 2013 Abstract Domestic electricity

More information

Inequality and GDP per capita: The Role of Initial Income

Inequality and GDP per capita: The Role of Initial Income Inequality and GDP per capita: The Role of Initial Income by Markus Brueckner and Daniel Lederman* September 2017 Abstract: We estimate a panel model where the relationship between inequality and GDP per

More information

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings J Econ Finan (2010) 34:23 29 DOI 10.1007/s12197-008-9070-2 Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings Faruk Balli Rosmy J. Louis Mohammad Osman Published online: 24 December 2008 Springer Science + Business

More information

INTERNATIONAL REAL ESTATE REVIEW 2002 Vol. 5 No. 1: pp Housing Demand with Random Group Effects

INTERNATIONAL REAL ESTATE REVIEW 2002 Vol. 5 No. 1: pp Housing Demand with Random Group Effects Housing Demand with Random Group Effects 133 INTERNATIONAL REAL ESTATE REVIEW 2002 Vol. 5 No. 1: pp. 133-145 Housing Demand with Random Group Effects Wen-chieh Wu Assistant Professor, Department of Public

More information

FINANCIAL INTEGRATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CASE OF PORTFOLIO EQUITY FLOWS TO SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

FINANCIAL INTEGRATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CASE OF PORTFOLIO EQUITY FLOWS TO SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA FINANCIAL INTEGRATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CASE OF PORTFOLIO EQUITY FLOWS TO SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA A Paper Presented by Eric Osei-Assibey (PhD) University of Ghana @ The African Economic Conference, Johannesburg

More information

DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN BRICS COUNTRIES

DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN BRICS COUNTRIES IJER Serials Publications 13(1), 2016: 227-233 ISSN: 0972-9380 DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN BRICS COUNTRIES Abstract: This paper explores the determinants of FDI inflows for BRICS countries

More information

Input Tariffs, Speed of Contract Enforcement, and the Productivity of Firms in India

Input Tariffs, Speed of Contract Enforcement, and the Productivity of Firms in India Input Tariffs, Speed of Contract Enforcement, and the Productivity of Firms in India Reshad N Ahsan University of Melbourne December, 2011 Reshad N Ahsan (University of Melbourne) December 2011 1 / 25

More information

Appendix A. Mathematical Appendix

Appendix A. Mathematical Appendix Appendix A. Mathematical Appendix Denote by Λ t the Lagrange multiplier attached to the capital accumulation equation. The optimal policy is characterized by the first order conditions: (1 α)a t K t α

More information

The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment on the Export Performance: Empirical Evidence for Western Balkan Countries

The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment on the Export Performance: Empirical Evidence for Western Balkan Countries Abstract The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment on the Export Performance: Empirical Evidence for Western Balkan Countries Nasir Selimi, Kushtrim Reçi, Luljeta Sadiku Recently there are many authors that

More information

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang Pre-print version: Tang, Tuck Cheong. (00). "Does exchange rate volatility matter for the balancing item of balance of payments accounts in Japan? an empirical note". Rivista internazionale di scienze

More information

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru i Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE 2012 ii Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru (B.Sc National University

More information

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN The International Journal of Business and Finance Research Volume 5 Number 1 2011 DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN Ming-Hui Wang, Taiwan University of Science and Technology

More information

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage Jin-Chuan Duan * and Yun Li (First draft: April 12, 2006) (This version: May 16, 2006) Abstract This paper identifies a key cause for the documented diversification

More information

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* Sónia Costa** Luísa Farinha** 133 Abstract The analysis of the Portuguese households

More information

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University

Volume 30, Issue 1. Samih A Azar Haigazian University Volume 30, Issue Random risk aversion and the cost of eliminating the foreign exchange risk of the Euro Samih A Azar Haigazian University Abstract This paper answers the following questions. If the Euro

More information

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS. Bounds on the Return to Education in Australia using Ability Bias

WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS. Bounds on the Return to Education in Australia using Ability Bias WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS & ECONOMETRICS Bounds on the Return to Education in Australia using Ability Bias Martine Mariotti Research School of Economics College of Business and Economics Australian National

More information

THE EFFECTS OF THE EU BUDGET ON ECONOMIC CONVERGENCE

THE EFFECTS OF THE EU BUDGET ON ECONOMIC CONVERGENCE THE EFFECTS OF THE EU BUDGET ON ECONOMIC CONVERGENCE Eva Výrostová Abstract The paper estimates the impact of the EU budget on the economic convergence process of EU member states. Although the primary

More information

Wage Inequality and Establishment Heterogeneity

Wage Inequality and Establishment Heterogeneity VIVES DISCUSSION PAPER N 64 JANUARY 2018 Wage Inequality and Establishment Heterogeneity In Kyung Kim Nazarbayev University Jozef Konings VIVES (KU Leuven); Nazarbayev University; and University of Ljubljana

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011 Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011 Kurt G. Lunsford University of Wisconsin Madison January 2013 Abstract I propose an augmented version of Okun s law that regresses

More information

Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance.

Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance. Ownership Concentration of Family and Non-Family Firms and the Relationship to Performance. Guillermo Acuña, Jean P. Sepulveda, and Marcos Vergara December 2014 Working Paper 03 Ownership Concentration

More information

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1 Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1 Abstract: The main purpose of this study 2 is to analyze whether the Organization of Islamic Cooperation (OIC) countries show a regional economic

More information

Social Security and Saving: A Comment

Social Security and Saving: A Comment Social Security and Saving: A Comment Dennis Coates Brad Humphreys Department of Economics UMBC 1000 Hilltop Circle Baltimore, MD 21250 September 17, 1997 We thank our colleague Bill Lord, two anonymous

More information

Outward FDI and Total Factor Productivity: Evidence from Germany

Outward FDI and Total Factor Productivity: Evidence from Germany Outward FDI and Total Factor Productivity: Evidence from Germany Outward investment substitutes foreign for domestic production, thereby reducing total output and thus employment in the home (outward investing)

More information

Omitted Variables Bias in Regime-Switching Models with Slope-Constrained Estimators: Evidence from Monte Carlo Simulations

Omitted Variables Bias in Regime-Switching Models with Slope-Constrained Estimators: Evidence from Monte Carlo Simulations Journal of Statistical and Econometric Methods, vol. 2, no.3, 2013, 49-55 ISSN: 2051-5057 (print version), 2051-5065(online) Scienpress Ltd, 2013 Omitted Variables Bias in Regime-Switching Models with

More information

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings Abstract This paper empirically investigates the value shareholders place on excess cash

More information

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data

Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data Edith Cowan University Research Online ECU Publications 2013 2013 Forecasting Singapore economic growth with mixed-frequency data A. Tsui C.Y. Xu Zhaoyong Zhang Edith Cowan University, zhaoyong.zhang@ecu.edu.au

More information

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Yongsik Kim * Abstract This paper provides empirical evidence that analysts generate firm-specific

More information

Deep Determinants. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () Deep Determinants 1 / 65

Deep Determinants. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () Deep Determinants 1 / 65 Deep Determinants Sherif Khalifa Sherif Khalifa () Deep Determinants 1 / 65 Sherif Khalifa () Deep Determinants 2 / 65 There are large differences in income per capita across countries. The differences

More information

Financial Openness and Financial Development: An Analysis Using Indices

Financial Openness and Financial Development: An Analysis Using Indices Financial Openness and Financial Development: An Analysis Using Indices Abstract This paper examines the link between financial openness and financial through panel data analysis on advanced and emerging

More information

THE EFFECTIVENESS OF COMPETITION LAW IN PROMOTING ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT

THE EFFECTIVENESS OF COMPETITION LAW IN PROMOTING ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT THE EFFECTIVENESS OF COMPETITION LAW IN PROMOTING ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT Bineswaree Bolaky United Nations Conference on Trade and Development Economic Affairs Officer E-mail: bineswaree.bolaky@unctad.org

More information

Country Fixed Effects and Unit Roots: A Comment on Poverty and Civil War: Revisiting the Evidence

Country Fixed Effects and Unit Roots: A Comment on Poverty and Civil War: Revisiting the Evidence The University of Adelaide School of Economics Research Paper No. 2011-17 March 2011 Country Fixed Effects and Unit Roots: A Comment on Poverty and Civil War: Revisiting the Evidence Markus Bruckner Country

More information

Determinants of foreign direct investment in Malaysia

Determinants of foreign direct investment in Malaysia Nanyang Technological University From the SelectedWorks of James B Ang 2008 Determinants of foreign direct investment in Malaysia James B Ang, Nanyang Technological University Available at: https://works.bepress.com/james_ang/8/

More information

The Effects of Public Debt on Economic Growth and Gross Investment in India: An Empirical Evidence

The Effects of Public Debt on Economic Growth and Gross Investment in India: An Empirical Evidence Volume 8, Issue 1, July 2015 The Effects of Public Debt on Economic Growth and Gross Investment in India: An Empirical Evidence Amanpreet Kaur Research Scholar, Punjab School of Economics, GNDU, Amritsar,

More information

Determinants of Unemployment: Empirical Evidence from Palestine

Determinants of Unemployment: Empirical Evidence from Palestine MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Determinants of Unemployment: Empirical Evidence from Palestine Gaber Abugamea Ministry of Education&Higher Education 14 October 2018 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/89424/

More information

Volume 37, Issue 2. Handling Endogeneity in Stochastic Frontier Analysis

Volume 37, Issue 2. Handling Endogeneity in Stochastic Frontier Analysis Volume 37, Issue 2 Handling Endogeneity in Stochastic Frontier Analysis Mustafa U. Karakaplan Georgetown University Levent Kutlu Georgia Institute of Technology Abstract We present a general maximum likelihood

More information

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation Internet Appendix A. Participation constraint In evaluating when the participation constraint binds, we consider three

More information

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence Loyola University Chicago Loyola ecommons Topics in Middle Eastern and orth African Economies Quinlan School of Business 1999 Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MEA Countries: Theory

More information

9. Logit and Probit Models For Dichotomous Data

9. Logit and Probit Models For Dichotomous Data Sociology 740 John Fox Lecture Notes 9. Logit and Probit Models For Dichotomous Data Copyright 2014 by John Fox Logit and Probit Models for Dichotomous Responses 1 1. Goals: I To show how models similar

More information

Interest groups and investment: A further test of the Olson hypothesis

Interest groups and investment: A further test of the Olson hypothesis Public Choice 117: 333 340, 2003. 2003 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. 333 Interest groups and investment: A further test of the Olson hypothesis DENNIS COATES 1 & JAC C. HECKELMAN

More information

Cross- Country Effects of Inflation on National Savings

Cross- Country Effects of Inflation on National Savings Cross- Country Effects of Inflation on National Savings Qun Cheng Xiaoyang Li Instructor: Professor Shatakshee Dhongde December 5, 2014 Abstract Inflation is considered to be one of the most crucial factors

More information

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension

Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4 Implied Volatility v/s Realized Volatility: A Forecasting Dimension 4.1 Introduction Modelling and predicting financial market volatility has played an important role for market participants as it enables

More information

Modeling of Price. Ximing Wu Texas A&M University

Modeling of Price. Ximing Wu Texas A&M University Modeling of Price Ximing Wu Texas A&M University As revenue is given by price times yield, farmers income risk comes from risk in yield and output price. Their net profit also depends on input price, but

More information

Online Appendices for

Online Appendices for Online Appendices for From Made in China to Innovated in China : Necessity, Prospect, and Challenges Shang-Jin Wei, Zhuan Xie, and Xiaobo Zhang Journal of Economic Perspectives, (31)1, Winter 2017 Online

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

CFA Level II - LOS Changes

CFA Level II - LOS Changes CFA Level II - LOS Changes 2018-2019 Topic LOS Level II - 2018 (465 LOS) LOS Level II - 2019 (471 LOS) Compared Ethics 1.1.a describe the six components of the Code of Ethics and the seven Standards of

More information

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE I. Introduction Income disparities between males and females have been identified as one major issue in the process

More information

CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS

CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS This chapter presents the results of the study and its analysis in order to meet the objectives. These results confirm the presence and impact of the biases taken into consideration,

More information

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV

Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV Advanced Topic 7: Exchange Rate Determination IV John E. Floyd University of Toronto May 10, 2013 Our major task here is to look at the evidence regarding the effects of unanticipated money shocks on real

More information

Does Growth make us Happier? A New Look at the Easterlin Paradox

Does Growth make us Happier? A New Look at the Easterlin Paradox Does Growth make us Happier? A New Look at the Easterlin Paradox Felix FitzRoy School of Economics and Finance University of St Andrews St Andrews, KY16 8QX, UK Michael Nolan* Centre for Economic Policy

More information

The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis

The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis The Determinants of Bank Mergers: A Revealed Preference Analysis Oktay Akkus Department of Economics University of Chicago Ali Hortacsu Department of Economics University of Chicago VERY Preliminary Draft:

More information

Market Microstructure Invariants

Market Microstructure Invariants Market Microstructure Invariants Albert S. Kyle and Anna A. Obizhaeva University of Maryland TI-SoFiE Conference 212 Amsterdam, Netherlands March 27, 212 Kyle and Obizhaeva Market Microstructure Invariants

More information

Bias in Reduced-Form Estimates of Pass-through

Bias in Reduced-Form Estimates of Pass-through Bias in Reduced-Form Estimates of Pass-through Alexander MacKay University of Chicago Marc Remer Department of Justice Nathan H. Miller Georgetown University Gloria Sheu Department of Justice February

More information

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability Christopher J. Erceg and Andrew T. Levin Division of International Finance Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington, DC 2551 USA

More information

Quantile Regression due to Skewness. and Outliers

Quantile Regression due to Skewness. and Outliers Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 5, 2011, no. 39, 1947-1951 Quantile Regression due to Skewness and Outliers Neda Jalali and Manoochehr Babanezhad Department of Statistics Faculty of Sciences Golestan

More information

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin June 15, 2008 Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin Abstract The trade effect of the euro is typically

More information

Local Government Spending and Economic Growth in Guangdong: The Key Role of Financial Development. Chi-Chuan LEE

Local Government Spending and Economic Growth in Guangdong: The Key Role of Financial Development. Chi-Chuan LEE 2017 International Conference on Economics and Management Engineering (ICEME 2017) ISBN: 978-1-60595-451-6 Local Government Spending and Economic Growth in Guangdong: The Key Role of Financial Development

More information

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4. Cross-Sectional Models and Trading Strategies Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 09/26/2013 Outline 1 Cross-Sectional Methods for Evaluation of Factor

More information

Top income share and economic growth: Linear and non-linear effects

Top income share and economic growth: Linear and non-linear effects RESEARCH DEPARTMENT WORKING PAPER NO. 17 Top income share and economic growth: Linear and non-linear effects MATTHIEU CHARPE MAY 2017 Research Department Working Paper No. 17 Top income share and economic

More information