The Cross Section of Long-Term Expected Returns *

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Cross Section of Long-Term Expected Returns *"

Transcription

1 The Cross Section of Long-Term Expected Returns * Zhongjin Lu June 5, 2016 Abstract Eective capital budgeting decisions require reliable estimates of long-term expected returns. I extract a predictor for long-term returns from the book-to-market ratio (B/M) by using a cross-sectional regression to control for B/M's variation associated with long-term expected protability. The resulting predictor reliably describes the cross section of returns out-of-sample for at least ve years, even when focusing exclusively on large-cap stocks and controlling for expected-return estimates generated by implied cost of capital models, factor models, and characteristic-based models. My results have important implications for improving our cost of equity estimates. Keywords: out-of-sample, cross section, long-term returns, expected protability, book-to-market ratio, cost of equity * First Version: Mar 21, I thank Kent Daniel, Robert Hodrick, Sara Holland, Harold Mulherin, David Ng, Bradley Paye, Robert Resutek, Tano Santos and seminar participants at University of Georgia for detailed comments on the rst draft. I thank Zhi Da, Peter Easton, Andrey Ermolov, Pengjie Gao, Paul Irvine, Dana Kiku, Lars Lochstoer, Harold Mulherin, Annette Poulsen, Gil Sadka, Sophie Shive, Paul Tetlock, one referee from Texas Finance Festival conference program committee and participants at numerous seminars and conferences for their helpful comments. I thank Ken French, Yan Li, and Chen Xue for providing data. Assistant Professor of Finance, Terry College of Business, University of Georgia, Athens, GA zlu15@uga.edu. 1

2 1 Introduction Corporate managers make investment decisions by discounting future cash ows at the opportunity cost of capital. Since the typical useful life for corporate investments is between 5 and 10 years for xed assets and 15 years for intangible assets, 1 discounting the associated cash ows requires an estimate of long-term expected returns. However, asset pricing models are commonly tested on the grounds of explaining short-term expected returns. Due to the term structure of risk premia (e.g., Van Binsbergen, Brandt, and Koijen, 2012), models that describe short-term expected returns may not accurately describe long-term expected returns. In fact, although the ability to predict long-term returns is a necessary property of the discount rate desired for eective corporate capital budgeting decisions, there are only a handful of studies that focus on long-term return predictability at the rm level. In this paper, I develop prediction of long-term expected returns based on a present value model. The resulting predictor can reliably describe the cross section of returns for at least ve yearsthe lower bound of the typical useful life for corporate investments. My approach exploits the fact that the book-to-market ratio (hereafter B/M) reects both longterm expected returns and long-term expected protability. I rst estimate the variation in B/M associated with long-term expected protability by running a cross-sectional regression of B/M on variables commonly used in earnings forecast models. Subtracting the estimated variation from B/M, the resulting residual is a cleaner measure of the B/M's information about long-term expected returns. I name the residual the implied discount rate (IDR) and use the IDR to forecast future returns in the second stage regression. My approach to forecast long-term returns has several distinct features. First and foremost, my regression model is used to control for expected protability and the discount rate is then implied from the present value relation. The choice of predictors in my regression model is less susceptible to data mining because the economic mechanisms of earnings predictors are better understood than the economic mechanisms of popular return predictors. 1 See IRS Publication 946 (2014) and IRS Regulation Ÿ1.167(a)-3, respectively. 2

3 As a result, my approach may result in more robust predictions. 2 Second, my approach diers from the implied cost of capital (ICC) approaches, which also infer the discount rate from the stock price using the present value relation, in how I control for long-term expected protability. 3 Unlike the commonly used ICC approaches, my approach does not rely on analysts' earnings forecasts, which are known to have a general upward bias (e.g., Easton and Sommers, 2007) and are potentially cross-sectionally dierentially biased (Bradshaw, Richardson, and Sloan, 2001). Moreover, not requiring analyst coverage also allows me to study the full cross section of rms. The benet of this is highlighted in Hou, Dijk, and Zhang (2012), who propose a novel ICC approach that uses predicted earnings from a regression model instead of analysts' forecasts and show the resulting ICC has improved accuracy in forecasting subsequent returns. 4 However, since analysts rarely forecast earnings beyond 5 years and since the earnings regressions in Hou, Dijk, and Zhang (2012) quickly run into survivorship bias when one tries to forecast earnings multiple periods ahead, all ICC methods have to extrapolate the predicted short-term earnings to an innite horizon by imposing ad hoc assumptions on the terminal growth rate. In contrast, my approach does not need any extrapolation since the variation in B/M captured by my cross-sectional model is inherently linked to the long-term protability. Third, my computation of the IDR purges the variation in B/M predicted by earnings forecasting variables to arrive at a cleaner predictor of long-term returns. The IDR thus does not utilize the expected-return information contained in those earnings forecasting variables. In Section 2, I formally discuss the trade-o between noise reduction and the use of limited information associated with my approach. In Section 6.3, I explore a vector autoregression (VAR) approach in which I jointly estimate the B/M information about expected return and the B/M information about expected protability. The disadvantage of the VAR approach 2 Mclean and Ponti (2006) nd many return predictors lose a substantial amount of their predictive power out-of-sample. 3 Both the ICC approaches and my approach build on the present value relation and thus are silent about whether dierences in expected returns are driven by risk or irrational cash ow expectations. 4 Hou, Dijk, and Zhang's (2012) approach builds on Fama and French (2000, 2006), who rst advocate using cross-sectional models to predict future protability. 3

4 compared to my approach is that the VAR imposes a potentially restrictive structure on the long run dynamics, which can hurt the out-of-sample predictive power. To explore whether my IDR approach helps improve the existing description of the cross section of long-term returns, I rst contrast the IDR to the closely related ICC measures, which are also inferred from stock prices by controlling for long-term protability. To put results into a broader perspective, I also examine expected-return estimates from two other prominent types of models: factor-based models and a characteristic-based model. There are three challenges in testing long-term predictive power. First, explanatory variables have estimation errors because they are estimates of the expected returns. Second, a substantial number of rms are delisted over the 5-year investment period. Third, because the 40-year time span of my sample is short relative to the 5-year holding period, autocorrelations of overlapping holding period returns may not be accurately estimated. I use two approaches, portfolio sorts and Fama-MacBeth (1973) regressions, to confront these challenges. 5 Both the portfolio sorts and Fama-MacBeth regressions demonstrate that the IDR is a far more reliable predictor for long-term returns than the existing ICC measures considered. I also nd poor long-term predictive power associated with expected-return estimates generated by the factor models considered. The seven-characteristic model in Lewellen (2014) is the only model considered that has similarly strong predictive power when compared to the IDR. Furthermore, when the IDR and an expected-return estimate from each of the other models are used to predict returns in bivariate regressions, I nd that the IDR remains highly signicant in all regressions. Finally, since the bulk of the literature focuses on one-month holding period returns, I run spanning tests of the monthly returns of portfolios sorted on the IDR. Results reveal that the IDR has signicant predictive power over a one-month horizon and this predictive 5 To ensure that corporate managers can ultimately use these estimates as real-time guidance for their investments, I use only prevailing information to calculate all expected-return estimates in order to avoid look-ahead bias. 4

5 power cannot be fully explained by exposures to the two latest factor models (Fama and French (2015) and Hou, Xue, Zhang (2014)). 1.1 Related literature A relatively limited amount of literature studies the long-term predictability in the cross section of stock returns (see Fama and French (1997), Hou, Dijk, and Zhang (2012), Levi and Welch (2014) and Lyle and Wang (2015)). I contribute to this literature by proposing a new approach that reliably forecasts the cross section of long-term returns. Additionally, I present a comprehensive study of existing models in terms of their ability to forecast longterm returns, and I nd most of them exhibit weak long-term predictive power. My work builds on the B/M decomposition in Vuolteenaho (2002). Cohen, Polk, and Vuolteenaho (2003), which is closely related, apply the same B/M decomposition to both a panel of U.S. rms and a panel of international rms and nd that the cross-sectional variation in B/M is dominated by the variation in expected protability. In a recent paper, Lochstoer and Tetlock (2016) extend Vuolteenaho's (2002) VAR approach and also nd B/M information is mostly about long-term protability. This is consistent with my nding that controlling for the variation in B/M associated with expected protability can drastically improve our ability to forecast long-term returns. The present-value relation underlying Vuolteenaho's B/M decomposition is also widely used to study the association between returns, cash ows, and the valuation ratio (e.g., see Fama and French (2006, 2015), Hou, Xue, Zhang (2014), and Novy-Marx (2013)). Apart from the important distinction of the long-term focus, my approach is unusual in that I use B/M as the left-hand variable in the rst stage regression and my predictor for returns is orthogonalized to variables related to expected protability. In contrast, B/M and protability measures are often used together in the right-hand side of a regression to predict returns. In such regressions, a positive relation between protability measures and subsequent returns leads to two possible interpretations. The more often cited is that high protability is asso- 5

6 ciated with high risk and thus high expected returns. 6 The other is that these protability measures can have nothing to do with expected returns but nevertheless show up as a significant regressor, because they serve as a control variable for the variation in B/M associated with expected protability. My empirical results highlight the relevance of the second case. 7 The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 lays out the theoretical motivation of my new approach. Section 3 describes the two empirical steps used to compute the new predictor for long-term returns. Section 4 tests the long-term predictive power of various expected-return estimates. Section 5 discusses the implication for cost of equity estimates. Section 6 presents a battery of robustness tests that address the questions regarding the control for expected protability, diminishing predictive power over long horizons, and the comparison to a VAR model. Section 7 presents the spanning test of monthly portfolio returns sorted on the IDR. Section 8 provides a conclusion. 2 Theoretical motivation 2.1 Theoretical framework My approach builds on the decomposition of B/M of Vuolteenaho (2002) ( ) ( ) bm t E t ρ τ 1 r t+τ E t ρ τ 1 e t+τ. (1) τ=1 In equation (1), bm t is the log B/M at time t, r t+τ is the log return, e t+τ is the log returnon-equity (hereafter ROE), ρ is a discount coecient related to the average payout ratio, which is often set to be around 0.96 in the literature. Equation (1) shows that the variation in B/M is not only driven by variation in expected returns but also variation in expected protability. It highlights the signal-extraction 6 Fama and French (2015) and Hou, Xue, Zhang (2014) thus include protability as one risk factor in their factor models. Nevertheless, Novy-Marx (2013) comments that the positive relation is inconsistent with explanations based on the distress risk, operating leverage risk, and duration risk. 7 This possibility is not a new theoretical prediction. It is consistent with both the dividend discount model and the q-theory. 6 τ=1

7 problem faced by researchers. To extract variations regarding expected returns from B/M, researchers will need to control for variations associated with expected protability. Without loss of generality, I assume X r t and X e t are time t vectors of state variables that are associated with long-term expected returns (E t ( τ=1 ρ τ 1 r t+τ )) and long-term expected protability (E t ( τ=1 ρ τ 1 e t+τ )), respectively. 8 E t ( τ=1 ρ τ 1 r t+τ ) E t ( τ=1 ρ τ 1 e t+τ ) bm t = 1 α r,e α e,r 1 θ r θ e X r t X e t, (2) where θ r = 1 α e,r and θ e = 1 α r,e due to the present value relation in Eq (1). The regression coecient of long-term expected returns on X r t and the coecent of long-term expected protability on X e t are normalized to be 1. I assume that state variables in X r t are independent of state variables in X e t. This assumption is not restrictive because expected returns and expected protability can have an arbitrary correlation through their loadings on X r t and X e t. For illustration purpose, in the following discussion X r t and X e t are treated as scalars. The derivation for the case in which X r t and X e t are vectors is similar and available upon request. 2.2 B/M as a noisy signal for long-term expected returns One common approach to capture long-term expected returns is to regress them on B/M. ( ) E t ρ τ 1 r t+τ τ=1 = a bm + b bm bm t + η bm t (3) b bm = θ rv X r α r,e θ e V X e, (4) θrv 2 X r + θev 2 X e in which V X r and V X e are the variances of X r t and X e t, respectively. We can evaluate the 8 Since this study focuses on the cross-sectional predictability, variance and covariance of variables refer to those of the cross-sectional demeaned variables. 7

8 forecast accuracy of this model via the mean squared forecast errors (MSFE) MSF E bm = E ( ) ηt bm 2 = [1 b bm θ r ] 2 V X r + [α r,e + b bm θ e ] 2 V X e (5) It is useful to illustrate the intuition of Eqs (4) and (5) through a polar case in which α e,r = 0 and α r,e = 0. That is, all useful information about expected returns is in X r t and all useful information about expected protability is in X e t. In this case, Eq (4) becomes b bm = V X r, (6) V X r + V X e The regression coecient b bm is smaller than 1 because the regression model in Eq (3) extracts signals about expected returns from bm t, which contains both the signal X r t and the noise X e t. 9 When the variance of the noise increases relative to the variance of the signal, that is signal-to-noise ratio V X r V X e decreases, the regression coecient b bm will decrease towards 0 and bm t becomes a bad predictor for expected returns. This eect can been seen more directly from the MSFE. Under this simplifying assumption, MSF E bm = V X r V X r + 1 (7) V X e If much of variation in B/M comes from variation in expected protability, that is, the signal to noise ratio V X r V X e is low, the forecast accuracy of the model in Eq (3) is poor. Cohen, Polk, and Vuolteenaho (2003) nd that expected protability causes about 75% to 80% of the B/M variance and a recent paper by Lochstoer and Tetlock (2016) nd similar results. I now discuss my new approach that aims to derive a purer signal about expected returns by controlling the B/M variation associated with expected protability. 9 The categorization of signal versus noise is dictated by the objective of forecasting returns. 8

9 2.3 Noise reduction I control for the B/M variation due to expected protability by regressing bm t on X e t in the rst stage regression: bm t = c + βx e t + ɛ bm t (8) According to Eq (2), the residual ɛ bm t with expected returns. I name ɛ bm t is a proxy for X r t, the state variable associated the implied discount rate (IDR) because it is not a direct estimate of the discount rate but rather a predictor implied by the B/M. I posit that the IDR can be a better predictor for long-term returns than the original B/M. To investigate the forecast accuracy of this model, I regress long-term expected returns on the IDR and compute the associated MSFE: ( ) E t ρ τ 1 r t+τ τ=1 = a IDR + b IDR IDR t + η IDR t (9) From Eq (2), IDR = θ r X r t and b IDR = 1 θ r (10) MSF E IDR = E ( ) ηt IDR 2 = α 2 r,e V X e (11) The intuition from Eq (11) is straightforward. The rst stage regression in Eq (8) eliminates the variation in bm t associated with Xt e, a variable associated with expected profitability, and the resulting IDR is a purer signal about expected returns. However, if Xt e is also correlated with the expected returns (i.e., α r,e is not zero), then the IDR misses the useful information about expected returns contained in X e t and the forecasting model in Eq (9) suers a loss of α 2 r,ev X e in forecast accuracy. Therefore, my new approach involves a trade-o between noise reduction and the use of limited information. My approach operates under the premise that it is challenging to directly model expected returns. Therefore, we 9

10 only know state variables X e t that are associated with expected protability and we are agnostic about X r t. The use of limited information can be overcome if I instead assume that we know X r t. Then a VAR model can be used to jointly model dynamics of expected returns and expected protability. 10 However, since protability can more reliably forecasted than returns, operating under the constraint that X r t is not observable can yield predictors with potentially more robust out-of-sample predictive power. To guide the empirical analysis, I take the dierence between the MSFEs under the two forecasting models (Eqs (5) and (11)) to gauge the relative forecast accuracy, MSF E bm MSF E IDR = [1 b bm θ r ] 2 V X r + ( [α r,e + b bm θ e ] 2 α 2 r,e) VX e (12) Therefore, as long as α r,e + b bm θ e > α r,e, my new approach will have better forecast accuracy. Given the consensus in the literature that b bm > 0 (see, e.g., Cohen, Polk, Vuolteenaho (2003) and Cochrane (2011)), my new approach will have higher forecast accuracy if α r,e θ e > 0. That is, the correlation between Xt e and expected returns and the correlation between Xt e and B/M have opposite signs (See Eq (2)). 11 This condition is further simplied if the potential correlation between X e t and expected returns is positive. In this case, we have θ e = 1 α r,e > 0 and thus α r,e θ e > 0 as long as X e t predominately captures the B/M information about expected protability. 3 Empirical implementation 3.1 The cross-sectional model I use the following model to control for the variation in B/M associated with expected protability. I keep my benchmark model parsimonious on purpose and leave extensions of 10 I explore this in Section A similar condition can be derived under the more complicated case in which X r and X g are vectors. 10

11 the model to future research. bm i,t = b 1,t roe i,t + b 2,t D i,t + b 3,t (D i,t roe i,t ) + b 4,t op i,t + b 5,t rnd i,t + ɛ i,t. (13) Variables are natural logarithmic to be consistent with Eq (1). bm is the log of B/M; roe is the log of (1+ROE); D is the decile ranking of the deviation of a rm's ROE from its median non-zero ROE over the past three years; 12 op is the log of (1+operating protability); and rnd is the log of (1+R&D intensity). A detailed description of variables is provided in the Data Appendix. These variables are associated with future protability on both theoretical and empirical grounds. Current ROE is a natural choice for predicting future protability because ROE is persistent. Fama and French (2000) nd strong evidence of a faster rate of mean reversion for extreme protability. To allow for this possibility, I add an interaction term of current ROE and its deviation from the average ROE. The next variable, operating protability (hereafter OP) measures current revenue relative to current expenses (e.g., Novy-Marx 2013; Ball, Gerakos, Linnainmaa, and Nikolaev 2015). It has incremental forecasting power for future protability because, unlike ROE, operating protability is not contaminated by accruals. Finally, R&D expenditures, like investments, have the potential to generate future earnings, even though they are treated as current expenses under the GAAP accounting rule. Holding ROEs the same, evidence suggests that rms with high R&D expenditures have high future protability (e.g., Lev and Sougiannis, 1996; Resutek, 2015). Hence, it is important to account for this eect in the cross-sectional regression. I eliminate B/M information about expected protability by removing the tted value in Eq (13) from bm, and call the resulting estimate the implied discount rate (IDR): IDR t = bm t bm t X e t. (14) 12 The median non-zero ROE serves as a proxy for the equilibrium ROE. Using the industry median ROE instead of the rm historical median ROE as a proxy for the equilibrium ROE also yields similar results. 11

12 where bm t X e t is the tted value from the cross-sectional model in Eq (13). 3.2 Data Accounting data are collected from the COMPUSTAT Industrial Annual le and price related data are collected from the CRSP monthly stock le, including all common stocks traded in NYSE, Amex, and NASDAQ. The COMPUSTAT and CRSP data are merged using the CRSP-COMPUSTAT linking table. To avoid look-ahead bias, I follow Fama and French (1993) and assume that accounting data for scal years ending in year t-1 are known at the end of June of year t. I use CRSP delisting returns if available. Otherwise, I impute the delisting return following Beaver, McNichols, and Price (2007). 13 Detailed descriptions of the variables are in the Data Appendix. I estimate the cross-sectional model in Eq (13) starting from 1971 because fewer than 500 rms have non-missing COMPUSTAT value for R&D expenditures prior to To avoid the inuential observation problems, prior research imposes data lters that exclude rms with extreme observations (e.g., Fama and French (2006), Vuolteenaho (2002)). I follow this approach and exclude rms with ROE and OP smaller (larger) than NYSE 1st (99th) percentile or with R&D intensity larger than its NYSE 99th percentile in the same year. There are on average 3,510 rms per year in my sample. Panel A of Table 1 presents the summary statistics for the main variables used in my cross-sectional model (observations with missing R&D value are excluded when calculating R&D summary statistics). The average rm has a market equity larger than its book equity, with both ROE and OP being positive. ROE has substantial negative skewness, while R&D intensity has substantial positive skewness because R&D expenditures are non-negative. 13 Alternatively, I impute the delisting return following Shumway (1997) when CRSP delisting returns are unavailable. Results are almost identical since the frequency of missing CRSP delisting returns upon delisting is about 0.004% in my sample. 14 After that, on average, approximately 48% of the rms have non-missing COMPUSTAT value for R&D expenditures. I follow the standard treatment of missing data by setting missing R&D expenditures to zero and add a dummy variable to indicate a missing value. This approach is equivalent to ignoring these missing values in multiple regressions. See William H. Greene, Econometric Analysis, 5th Edition for more detail. 12

13 Panel B of Table 1 shows the time-series average of the cross-sectional correlations between B/M and the three explanatory variables. Consistent with the economic intuition that rms with high protability and high R&D intensity have high market valuation, I nd high ROE, OP, and R&D intensity to be associated with low B/M. 3.3 Fama-MacBeth full sample estimation results for the crosssectional model Table 2 reports the full sample mean (across years) of cross-sectional slope estimates of the rst stage regression model in Eq (13). The associated t-statistics are computed using Newey-West standard errors with 5 lags to take account of serial correlations. I run separate regressions with and without microcap stocks. Fama and French (2008) nd that the microcap stocks (dened as stocks smaller than 20th percentile of NYSE size distribution) on average account for 60% of the total number of stocks but only 3% of the market cap. Running separate regressions helps to detect whether including microcap stocks skews the estimation results. The column labeled All presents the regressions including all stocks. The average slope for ROE is negative and highly signicant (-7.26 with a t-stat of -12.4). The slope for the interaction term of ROE and the ROE deviation ranking (D) is positive and also highly signicant (0.61 with a t-stat of 17.3). These two slopes imply that the overall slope for ROE is about -3.9 for rms with the mean ROE deviation ranking (i.e., D=5.5). A negative overall slope for ROE indicates that a high ROE is associated with high market valuation (low B/M). This negative overall slope is consistent with the extant evidence that high current protability is associated with high future protability (e.g. Fama and French, 2000) and thus leads to higher valuation and lower B/M. Furthermore, a back-of-the-envelope calculation shows that if the ρ in Eq (1) is 0.967, as proposed by Vuolteenaho (2002), then the overall slope for ROE of -3.9 implies a rst-order autoregressive (AR(1)) coecient of

14 for ROE. 15 This number is not too far from the one estimated by predictive regressions of one-year ahead protability in Fama and French (2000, Table 1). 16 While my new approach allows for more complicated dynamics of protability than AR(1) process, nding a similar level of rst-order autocorrelation of protability lends credibility to the new approach. The positive slope for the interaction term of ROE and the ROE deviation ranking indicates that B/M responds less strongly to extreme ROE. This is also consistent with the nding in Fama and French (2000, Table 1) in which they nd extreme protability reverts faster and thus would have weaker eect on B/M. Slopes for OP and R&D intensity are both negative and signicant. Like the negative slopes for ROE, these negative slopes are consistent with the working hypothesis that OP and R&D intensity are positively correlated with expected protability and thus are associated with lower B/M. The column labeled Non-microcap in Table 2 presents the regressions for the sample excluding microcap stocks. The slopes for ROE and the interaction term in this non-microcap sample change only slightly. The slopes for OP and R&D intensity have more noticeable changes. The slope for OP becomes more negative, from to -2.06, indicating larger impact on valuation from OP in the non-microcap sample. This can explained by a more persistent operating protability for larger rms, which tend to have more stable business revenue. The slope for R&D intensity becomes less negative, from to -3.30, indicating smaller impact on valuation from R&D intensity in the non-microcap sample. Lastly, the time-series average of R 2 is 31.3% for the full sample and 40.0% for the non-microcap sample, suggesting that my baseline cross-sectional model in Eq (13) describes the expected protability of larger rms more accurately. 17 The literature suggests several reasons why a possible positive correlation can exist be- 15 The 0.82 number is computed under the simplifying assumption that ROE follows AR(1) process. 16 Fama and French (2000) deate the earnings by total asset. Their specications in Panel B of Table 1 imply an AR(1) coecient of protability around When I augment the baseline model with an interaction term of OP (R&D intensity) and size, the resulting IDR shows noticeable improved predictive power for subsequent returns. 14

15 tween the regressors in my cross-sectional model and expected returns. 18 Barring any cash ow eect, this positive correlation predicts positive coecients of B/M on ROE, OP, and R&D intensity, opposite to what we nd in the data. Together with the negative correlations between B/M and these regressors in Panel B of Table 1, empirical patterns are consistent with my working hypothesis that these regressors predominately capture B/M variation due to expected protability. Nevertheless, it is ultimately an empirical question whether the tted value from the cross-sectional model indeed controls for expected protability and the resulting IDR has superior predictive power for long-term returns. I now turn to investigate this question. 4 Testing long-term predictive power I rst use the portfolio sorts approach and use Fama-MacBeth regressions to examine the long-term predictive power of various expected-return estimates. Portfolio sorts and Fama- MacBeth regressions are complementary approaches. The portfolio approach requires few distributional assumptions. In contrast, the regression approach imposes parametric assumptions, and thus the estimation results are more sensitive to observations in the tails of the distributions. But if the assumptions are satised, regressions give us sharper results than those provided by the portfolio sorts. 4.1 Expected-return estimates I compute the IDR in two steps. In the rst step, I run the cross-sectional regression (Eq (13)) at the end of June every year t. I compute the mean (across years) of slope estimates up to year t (to avoid look-ahead bias) and multiply the average slopes by the year t value of explanatory variables to get the tted value in year t. In the second step, I subtract the 18 E.g., see Haugen and Baker (1996), Chan, Lakonishok, and Sougiannis (2001), Fama and French (2006), and Novy-Marx (2013) for a positive correlation between returns and ROE, R&D-to-sales, and operating protability, respectively.haugen and Baker (1996); Chan, Lakonishok, and Sougiannis (2001) 15

16 tted value from bm t to in order to arrive at the IDR, as dened according in Eq (14). I compare my IDR to expected-return estimates from three types of existing models: ICC models, factor models, and a characteristic-based model. I choose two recent ICC models (Hou, Dijk, and Zhang 2012, and Li, Ng, and Swaminathan 2013) from the large body of ICC literature because they represent the state-of-art ICC estimation techniques. Within the factor models, in addition to the commonly studied Fama-French three-factor model, I examine the expected-return estimates from the newly-proposed Fama-French ve-factor model (FF5) and the Hou, Xue, and Zhang four-factor model (HXZ4). Within the characteristic-based models, I examine the expected-return estimate from a seven-characteristic model (Lewellen, 2014) that includes size, B/M, OP, share issuance, momentum, and asset growth. I focus on the seven-characteristic model as Lewellen (2014) has also tested a three-characteristic model and a fteen-characteristic model and concludes that the seven-characteristic model outperforms the three-characteristic model while the fteen-characteristic model shows insignicant improvement over the seven-characteristic model. 19 I compute the expected-return estimates for all the models considered with the only exception of the ICC measure in Li, Ng, and Swaminathan (2013), which is provided by the authors. Appendix A provides a detailed description of the construction of these expectedreturn estimates. I use these expected-return estimates to predict returns for the period from July 1977 to June 2014 because the ICC measure from Li, Ng, and Swaminathan (2013) is not available before Hou, Dijk, and Zhang (2012) explore several versions of ICC models. I choose their Gordon growth version because it is one of the best performing one. Levi and Welch (2014) oer an extensive examination of numerous implementations of two factor models, CAPM and Fama-French three-factor model. They cannot reject the null that these models have no predictive power. Lyle and Wang (2015) proposes a characteristic-based model for returns with two characteristics, B/M and ROE. Their model exhibits weaker predictive power than the seven-characteristic model in most cases, which is not surprising given that the seven-characteristic model uses more characteristics. 20 Periods before 1977 will be used as a training period to compute expected return estimates. 16

17 4.2 Portfolio sorts based on expected-return estimates Forming portfolios minimizes the error-in-variables problem associated with the sorting variable (e.g., Black, Jensen, and Scholes, 1972; Fama and MacBeth, 1973). To minimize survivorship bias, I reinvest the proceeds of delisted stocks back into their original portfolios because delisted stocks and the remaining stocks in the same portfolio have similar expected-return estimates and thus should have similar expected returns if these estimates are accurate. 21 Lastly, I use the technique in Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) to examine the long-term predictive power. Every year, I form univariate sorted portfolios based on one expected-return estimate and hold the portfolios for 5 years. I compute the average return per annum over the 5-year holding period in the following way. Take the highest ranked portfolio as an example. I rst compute the year t + 1 return of a strategy that invests equal amount in the ve highest ranked portfolios that are formed on year t, year t 1,..., year t 4, respectively. The time-series average of the annual returns of this strategy is the estimate of the average return per annum over a 5-year holding period. Since annual returns have very low serial correlations, I can compute standard errors of this estimate without estimating autocorrelations. Unlike Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), I do not rebalance these portfolios (back to equal weights) in the holding period, making them comparable to illiquid corporate investments. 22 To balance the concern that the numerous tiny-cap stocks may have undue inuence in the equal-weighted portfolio results and the concern that the value-weighted portfolio results are dominated by mega-cap stocks, I sort stocks into three size groups. To make the number of stocks relatively the same across size groups, I dene three size groups, large-cap, small-cap, and tiny-cap using the NYSE 50th and 10th percentiles as breakpoints. 23 Within 21 Under the alternative assumption that the expected-return estimates are inaccurate, a proper reinvestment strategy is to invest delisting proceeds to the market portfolios. As a robustness check, I use this alternative reinvestment strategy in the regression approach. 22 This approach is in spirit similar to Hodrick (1992, Eq (11)), where he recommends avoiding the summation of autocovariances associated with regressions of long-term returns by regressing one-period return on a series of lagged regressors. 23 Large-cap, small-cap, and tiny-cap stocks on average account for approximately 92%, 7%, and less than 17

18 each size group, I further sort stocks into equal-weighted decile portfolios (P1 to P10) in the ascending order of an expected-return estimate. Table 3 presents the time-series means and the standard errors of P10-minus-P1 return spreads. Compared with the two ICC measures, the IDR is the most reliable predictor for cross-sectional dierences in long-term returns. For large-cap, small-cap, and tiny-cap stocks, respectively, the IDR generates an average P10-minus-P1 return spread of 5.1% (t=3.6), 9.2% (t=4.9), and 16.2% (t=5.2) per annum in the 5-year holding period. The return spread generated within the tiny-cap stocks is about three times as large as that in the large-cap, though the t-value is only about 65% higher. This suggests that the timeseries variability of return spreads in the tiny-cap sample is much larger. To put these return spreads into perspective, the corresponding P10-minus-P1 spreads generated by the ICC measure from Hou, Dijk, and Zhang (2012) are 1.6% (t=0.5), 4.6% (t=1.4), and 6.9% (t=2.8) for large-cap, small-cap, and tiny-cap stocks, respectively. Alternatively, when I sort on the ICC measure from Li, Ng, and Swaminathan (2013), the P10-minus-P1 spreads are 1.2% (t=0.8), -0.2% (t=-0.1), and 2.0% (t=0.5) for large-cap, small-cap, and tiny-cap stocks, respectively. Consistent with results in Hou, Dijk, and Zhang (2012), I nd that their ICC estimate predicts returns more strongly than the ICC estimate based on analyst forecasts, such as the one in Li, Ng, and Swaminathan (2013). 24 However, the improvement concentrates in the small-cap and tiny-cap samples, and only in the tiny-cap sample does the ICC estimate based on Hou, Dijk, and Zhang's (2012) approach generate a statistically signicant P10-minus-P1 return spread. In comparison, the IDR shows consistent predictive power across all size groups, generating P10-minus-P1 annual return spreads and associated t-statistics that are far larger than those of the other two ICC estimates across three size groups. The predictive power of the IDR relative to the two existing ICC measures particularly 1% of the market cap in my sample, respectively. 24 See Easton and Monahan (2005), Lewellen (2010) and Richardson, Tuna, and Wysocki (2010) for reviews of the forecasting performance of ICC measures. 18

19 stands out in large-cap stocks (P10-minus-P1 returns 3 times as large and t-statistics 4 times as large). This is interesting given the continual debate regarding why we observe the predictable cross-sectional dierences in returns. Arguments attributing predictability to behavioral biases typically predict that, due to the eect of arbitrage, the anomalies would be weaker in large-cap stocks as well as in the long run. In contrast, risk-based explanations do not predict a weaker risk-return relation for large-cap stocks or for the long run. Consequently, the evidence that the IDR can predict long-term returns among large-cap stocks makes it more likely to be related to risk characteristics as opposed to mispricing. This hypothesis is interesting but requires analysis beyond the scope of this study. Table 3 also compares the expected-return estimates from the IDR approach to those generated by FF3, FF5, and HXZ4 factor models. Results show that the factor models do not have signicant predictive power for long-term returns. P10-minus-P1 return spreads generated by sorting on their expected-return estimates yield t-values that are smaller than 1.3 across all three models and across all three size groups. My nding of weak predictive power from factor models is consistent with the ndings in Levi and Welch (2014) and Lyle and Wang (2015). Finally, Table 3 shows that the seven-characteristic model is the most successful one among existing models tested. This model performs on par with the IDR, generating a P10- minus-p1 return spread of 5.1% per annum (t=2.9), 12.8% (t=7.1), and 17.4% (t=7.1) in the large-cap, small-cap, and tiny-cap samples, respectively. This section shows that the IDR can reliably predict 5-year holding period returns consistently across three size groups. In terms of the statistical signicance of P10-minus- P1 returns spreads, the predictive power of the IDR can be matched only by the sevencharacteristic model among the three types of existing models tested. A characteristic-based model is dened as a regression model of returns based on characteristics. Researchers are still in the process of understanding why characteristics directly predict returns and the lack of a coherent explanation hinders the search of more characteristics that can enhance the 19

20 predictive power of the characteristic-based model. In contrast, the IDR approach is more intuitive. It comes from the present value formula and builds on the fact that at the rm level protability is far easier to forecast than returns. More earnings forecasting variables can be incorporated to extend my benchmark model, and the better we can control for expected protability, the better expected-return estimate we can get. 4.3 Univariate Fama-MacBeth regressions to predict 5-year returns This section examines an alternative approach to the portfolio sorts, I run Fama-MacBeth regressions of overlapping 5-year returns on various expected-return estimates across the three size groups. Time-series variations in the slopes from Fama-MacBeth regressions reect the overall sampling error consisting of both estimation errors of expected-return estimates and the usual error term. To calculate the 5-year cumulative return, I reinvest the delisted proceeds into the CRSP value-weighted market portfolio. This reinvestment assumption is dierent from that in the portfolio sorts approach and serves as a robustness check to conrm that inference of long-term predictive power is not driven by a particular reinvesting assumption. I use Newey-West standard errors with four lags to adjust for the autocorrelation generated by overlapping returns. To address the concern that Newey-West standard errors may not account for autocorrelations accurately in a nite sample, in Section 8 I propose an alternative approach to estimate the slope coecients in which autocorrelations are less of an issue. Fama (1976, Chapter 9) shows that slope coecients from Fama-MacBeth regressions are portfolio returns. Specically, the slope estimate of regressing 5-year return r t,5 on a cross-sectionally demeaned regressor X t is the following: β t,5 = ( X tx t ) 1 X tr t,5 (15) = w tr t,5. (16) 20

21 Therefore, the slope estimates can be interpreted as the 5-year holding period return of a long-short portfolio with the weights implied by the Fama-MacBeth regression. 25 For ease of comparing the regression coecients across tested models, I scale the slopes of Fama- MacBeth regressions in a way that the portfolio weights implied by the scaled slopes are one-dollar long and one-dollar short and the scaled slopes can be interpreted as returns to a one-dollar long-short position. 26 Table 4 presents Fama-MacBeth univariate regressions using each of the expected-return estimates. Explanatory variables are winsorized to the 1st and 99th percentiles. Consistent with the portfolio sorts results, the IDR strongly predicts 5-year returns across all three size groups (t=4.0, 4.8, and 5.0 for large-cap, small-cap, tiny-cap, respectively). The magnitude of the scaled predictive slopes is similar to the P10-minus-P1 return spread in the portfolio sorts approach. Also consistent with the portfolio sorts results, the ICC models and the factor models shows much weaker predictive power. Among fteen regressions across these ve models and three size groups, the 5% level signicance appears only three times, twice of the ICC measure Hou, Dijk, and Zhang (2012) in the small-cap and tiny-cap samples (t=2.0 and 2.9 respectively and once for FF3 in the large-cap sample (t=3.0). Finally, similar to the portfolio sorts results, Fama-MacBeth regressions show that the seven-characteristic model has long-term predictive power similar to that of the IDR. The predictive slopes are highly signicantly across all size groups, with t-statistics of 3.8 in the large-cap sample, 7.8 in the small-cap sample, and 7.1 in the tiny-cap sample. Overall, there are only two material dierences in statistical inference between the Fama- MacBeth regression approach and the portfolio sorts approach: Fama-MacBeth regressions nd the ICC measure from Hou, Dijk, and Zhang (2012) to be statistically signicant in the small-cap sample and the expected-return estimate from FF3 to be signicant in the 25 Back, Kapadia, and Ostdiek (2015) show that Fama-MacBeth regression slopes are returns of the maximally diversied portfolios that have a unit pure exposure to the explanatory variables. 26 The portfolio weights implied by the unscaled Fama-MacBeth regression slopes depend on the crosssectional variation in the expected-return estimates and thus the magnitude of these portfolio returns cannot be readily compared across tested models. 21

22 large-cap sample, while the portfolio sorts do not nd such signicance. One reason is that the Fama-MacBeth regressions might have better power because they use information from all stocks whereas portfolio sorts only use the two extreme deciles. Alternatively, the Newey- West standard errors may not be accurate because they require estimates of autocorrelations from a relatively short sample. In Appendix B, I take account of the second possibility by using an alternative approach to estimate Fama-MacBeth regression slopes. The alternative approach reconciles the difference in statistical inferences between portfolio sorts and Fama-MacBeth regressions. The IDR exhibits slightly stronger statistical signicance under the alternative approach. To be conservative, I continue to use Newey-West standard errors to adjust for autocorrelations generated by overlapping returns. But in the robustness section, I will report separate Fama- MacBeth regressions for annual returns 1- to 5-years ahead and in these regressions returns no longer overlap. 4.4 Bivariate Fama-MacBeth regressions to predict 5-year returns Fama-MacBeth regressions also allow a straightforward way to examine whether the IDR has incremental explanatory power over the expected-return estimates from the existing models. In particular, since the characteristic-based model performs quite well and the characteristics contain protability measures, I explore whether the estimate from the characteristic-based model and the IDR subsume one another. Table 5 presents the results for bivariate regressions using the IDR along with expectedreturn estimates from each of the existing models considered. I nd that the IDR retains its signicance in all twenty-one cases (three size groups and seven estimates from existing models). The column labeled C7-JL shows that the expected-return estimate generated by the seven-characteristic model in Lewellen (2014) and the IDR have independent explanatory power in describing the cross section of 5-year returns in the tiny-cap and small-cap samples, all with t-values above 3.5. Interestingly, in the large-cap sample, the IDR remains signi- 22

23 cant (t=2.7) whereas the estimate from the seven-characteristic model becomes insignicant (t=1.3). 5 Implications for cost of equity 5.1 Decile portfolios sorted on the IDR Results in the previous section have shown that the IDR is a robust and powerful predictor for subsequent long-term returns. I now investigate whether the predictive power only comes from rms with extreme IDR value. If the predictive power comes solely from the tail distribution, although we can still use the IDR to construct long-short positions that earn signicant excess returns, the IDR will have little impact on our estimate of long-term expected returns, or cost of capital, for majority of the rms. Table 6 nds that the average returns of the decile portfolios sorted on the IDR are generally increasing with the IDR ranking. 27 In the large-cap sample, the average return per annum in a 5-year holding period increases by 2.6% when the IDR ranking increases from 1 to 6, and by another 2.5% when the ranking increases to 10. This suggests that, among large-cap rms, there is a dierence about 2.5% per annum in the discount rate over a 5-year investment horizon between rms in the lowest IDR decile and rms in the median IDR decile (or between rms in the median IDR decile and rms in the highest IDR decile). Although a 2.5% dierence in cost of capital is quite substantial in economic terms, the sampling error of average returns is large enough to render the 2.5% return spread statistically insignicant (t=1.5). The return spread only becomes statistically signicant when the change in rankings is large. The return dierences among small-cap and tiny-cap stocks are are much larger. Among the small-cap stocks, the average annual return over a 5-year holding period increases by 5.6% when the IDR ranking increases from 1 to 6 (t=2.9) and by another 3.5% when the ranking 27 These portfolios are rst introduced in Section

24 increases to 10. These return spreads are about 50% to 100% larger than the corresponding numbers in the large-cap sample. The corresponding return spreads among the tiny-cap stocks are even larger, typically more than 50% larger compared to the small-cap sample and 2 times larger compared to the large-cap sample. There are two interpretations for these results. First, the dierences in long-term expected returns are small among large-cap rms. Second, the IDR has stronger predictive power among small-cap and tiny-cap stocks. To sum up, average 5-year returns increase gradually with the IDR across decile portfolios. The pattern suggests that the IDR can be useful for improving our cost of capital estimate for most rms. Among large-cap stocks, we nd that although the IDR is a statistically signicant predictor for 5-year returns when considering the whole cross section, the predicted return dierence only becomes signicant if the rms' IDRs are suciently dierent from each other. On the other hand, return spreads generated by sorting on the IDR are markedly larger among tiny-cap stocks. Tiny-cap stocks in the lowest (highest) IDR decile earn around 8% per annum less (more) than tiny-cap stocks in the median IDR decile. If one holds the view that all return predictability captured by the IDR is due to mispricing, the tiny-cap results here indicate the relative mispricing between the lowest and the highest IDR deciles is 80% 16% per year for ve years. 5.2 Fama-French industry portfolios In the following analysis, I investigate how the new IDR measure can help improve our estimates of long-term expected returns. Running pooled time-series and cross-sectional regressions of future realized returns on predicted returns is a good way to gauge the predictive power of a model. The regression slope tells how informative the predictor is and the R 2 indicates how much variations in returns a model can explain More specically, the regression slope b is equivalent to the optimal weight a shrinkage estimator F s i,t = sf i,t should put on F i,t to minimize the mean-squared-forecast-error (MSFE). That is, b = arg min {s} MSF E (F s 1 i,t). MSFE of predicted returns F i,t from a particular model is N T i,t (R i,t F i,t ) 2. Both R i,t and F i,t are cross-sectionally demeaned. So F i,t is a better predictor than 0 (the cross-sectional [ ] 1 mean of F i,t ) if N T i,t (R i,t F i,t ) 2 Ri,t 2 1 < 0. That is, N T i,t (F i,t) 2 (1 2b) < 0. b is the re- 24

Accruals, cash flows, and operating profitability in the. cross section of stock returns

Accruals, cash flows, and operating profitability in the. cross section of stock returns Accruals, cash flows, and operating profitability in the cross section of stock returns Ray Ball 1, Joseph Gerakos 1, Juhani T. Linnainmaa 1,2 and Valeri Nikolaev 1 1 University of Chicago Booth School

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information

Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information Critical Finance Review, 2016, 5: 165 175 Another Look at Market Responses to Tangible and Intangible Information Kent Daniel Sheridan Titman 1 Columbia Business School, Columbia University, New York,

More information

The cross section of expected stock returns

The cross section of expected stock returns The cross section of expected stock returns Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER This version: March 2013 First draft: October 2010 Tel: 603-646-8650; email: jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu. I am grateful

More information

Dissecting Anomalies. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French. Abstract

Dissecting Anomalies. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French. Abstract First draft: February 2006 This draft: June 2006 Please do not quote or circulate Dissecting Anomalies Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French Abstract Previous work finds that net stock issues, accruals,

More information

Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information Revisited

Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information Revisited Critical Finance Review, 2016, 5: 135 163 Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information Revisited Joseph Gerakos Juhani T. Linnainmaa 1 University of Chicago Booth School of Business, USA, joseph.gerakos@chicagobooth.edu

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

The Value Premium and the January Effect

The Value Premium and the January Effect The Value Premium and the January Effect Julia Chou, Praveen Kumar Das * Current Version: January 2010 * Chou is from College of Business Administration, Florida International University, Miami, FL 33199;

More information

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru i Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE 2012 ii Statistical Understanding of the Fama-French Factor model Chua Yan Ru (B.Sc National University

More information

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly Online Appendix Section I provides details of the calculation of the variables used in the paper. Section II examines the robustness of the beta anomaly.

More information

Cross Sectional Asset Pricing Tests: Ex Ante versus Ex Post Approaches

Cross Sectional Asset Pricing Tests: Ex Ante versus Ex Post Approaches Cross Sectional Asset Pricing Tests: Ex Ante versus Ex Post Approaches Mahmoud Botshekan Smurfit School of Business, University College Dublin, Ireland mahmoud.botshekan@ucd.ie, +353-1-716-8976 John Cotter

More information

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1 Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns Fatma Sonmez 1 Abstract This paper s aim is to revisit the relation between idiosyncratic volatility and future stock returns. There are three key

More information

What Drives Anomaly Returns?

What Drives Anomaly Returns? What Drives Anomaly Returns? Lars A. Lochstoer and Paul C. Tetlock UCLA and Columbia Q Group, April 2017 New factors contradict classic asset pricing theories E.g.: value, size, pro tability, issuance,

More information

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less?

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less? Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less? Jia Chen, Kewei Hou, and René M. Stulz* January 2015 Abstract Using theories from the behavioral finance literature to predict that investors are attracted to

More information

Deflating Gross Profitability

Deflating Gross Profitability Chicago Booth Paper No. 14-10 Deflating Gross Profitability Ray Ball University of Chicago Booth School of Business Joseph Gerakos University of Chicago Booth School of Business Juhani T. Linnainmaa University

More information

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios RESEARCH Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios March 2016 Wei Dai, PhD Research The predictability of expected stock returns is an old topic and an important one. While investors may increase expected returns

More information

Underreaction, Trading Volume, and Momentum Profits in Taiwan Stock Market

Underreaction, Trading Volume, and Momentum Profits in Taiwan Stock Market Underreaction, Trading Volume, and Momentum Profits in Taiwan Stock Market Mei-Chen Lin * Abstract This paper uses a very short period to reexamine the momentum effect in Taiwan stock market, focusing

More information

Core CFO and Future Performance. Abstract

Core CFO and Future Performance. Abstract Core CFO and Future Performance Rodrigo S. Verdi Sloan School of Management Massachusetts Institute of Technology 50 Memorial Drive E52-403A Cambridge, MA 02142 rverdi@mit.edu Abstract This paper investigates

More information

It is well known that equity returns are

It is well known that equity returns are DING LIU is an SVP and senior quantitative analyst at AllianceBernstein in New York, NY. ding.liu@bernstein.com Pure Quintile Portfolios DING LIU It is well known that equity returns are driven to a large

More information

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( ) Lecture 5 Predictability Traditional Views of Market Efficiency (1960-1970) CAPM is a good measure of risk Returns are close to unpredictable (a) Stock, bond and foreign exchange changes are not predictable

More information

The predictive power of investment and accruals

The predictive power of investment and accruals The predictive power of investment and accruals Jonathan Lewellen Dartmouth College and NBER jon.lewellen@dartmouth.edu Robert J. Resutek Dartmouth College robert.j.resutek@dartmouth.edu This version:

More information

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? Supplementary Online Appendix

What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? Supplementary Online Appendix What Does Risk-Neutral Skewness Tell Us About Future Stock Returns? Supplementary Online Appendix 1 Tercile Portfolios The main body of the paper presents results from quintile RNS-sorted portfolios. Here,

More information

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions Abdulrahman Alharbi 1 Abdullah Noman 2 Abstract: Bansal et al (2009) paper focus on measuring risk in consumption especially

More information

Predictability of aggregate and firm-level returns

Predictability of aggregate and firm-level returns Predictability of aggregate and firm-level returns Namho Kang Nov 07, 2012 Abstract Recent studies find that the aggregate implied cost of capital (ICC) can predict market returns. This paper shows, however,

More information

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LVI, NO. 6 DEC. 2001 Dividend Changes and Future Profitability DORON NISSIM and AMIR ZIV* ABSTRACT We investigate the relation between dividend changes and future profitability,

More information

There is a Growth Premium After All

There is a Growth Premium After All There is a Growth Premium After All Yuecheng Jia Shu Yan Haoxi Yang February 6, 2018 Abstract The conventional wisdom argues that the growth stocks are riskier to earn a higher premium. However, the empirical

More information

Asubstantial portion of the academic

Asubstantial portion of the academic The Decline of Informed Trading in the Equity and Options Markets Charles Cao, David Gempesaw, and Timothy Simin Charles Cao is the Smeal Chair Professor of Finance in the Smeal College of Business at

More information

in-depth Invesco Actively Managed Low Volatility Strategies The Case for

in-depth Invesco Actively Managed Low Volatility Strategies The Case for Invesco in-depth The Case for Actively Managed Low Volatility Strategies We believe that active LVPs offer the best opportunity to achieve a higher risk-adjusted return over the long term. Donna C. Wilson

More information

Can we replace CAPM and the Three-Factor model with Implied Cost of Capital?

Can we replace CAPM and the Three-Factor model with Implied Cost of Capital? Uppsala University Department of Business Studies Bachelor Thesis Fall 2013 Can we replace CAPM and the Three-Factor model with Implied Cost of Capital? Authors: Robert Löthman and Eric Pettersson Supervisor:

More information

Keywords: Equity firms, capital structure, debt free firms, debt and stocks.

Keywords: Equity firms, capital structure, debt free firms, debt and stocks. Working Paper 2009-WP-04 May 2009 Performance of Debt Free Firms Tarek Zaher Abstract: This paper compares the performance of portfolios of debt free firms to comparable portfolios of leveraged firms.

More information

Economic Review. Wenting Jiao * and Jean-Jacques Lilti

Economic Review. Wenting Jiao * and Jean-Jacques Lilti Jiao and Lilti China Finance and Economic Review (2017) 5:7 DOI 10.1186/s40589-017-0051-5 China Finance and Economic Review RESEARCH Open Access Whether profitability and investment factors have additional

More information

Applied Macro Finance

Applied Macro Finance Master in Money and Finance Goethe University Frankfurt Week 2: Factor models and the cross-section of stock returns Fall 2012/2013 Please note the disclaimer on the last page Announcements Next week (30

More information

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor In this online appendix, we provide a comparative static analysis of the theoretical model as well as further robustness checks on the trend factor.

More information

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings Abstract This paper empirically investigates the value shareholders place on excess cash

More information

The Implied Cost of Capital: A New Approach

The Implied Cost of Capital: A New Approach The Implied Cost of Capital: A New Approach Kewei Hou, Mathijs A. van Dijk, and Yinglei Zhang * May 2010 Abstract We propose a new approach to estimate the implied cost of capital (ICC). Our approach is

More information

Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection

Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection of Stock Returns Cameron Truong Monash University, Melbourne, Australia February 2015 Abstract We document a significant positive relation

More information

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1

Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Interpreting the Value Effect Through the Q-theory: An Empirical Investigation 1 Yuhang Xing Rice University This version: July 25, 2006 1 I thank Andrew Ang, Geert Bekaert, John Donaldson, and Maria Vassalou

More information

Discussion Paper No. DP 07/02

Discussion Paper No. DP 07/02 SCHOOL OF ACCOUNTING, FINANCE AND MANAGEMENT Essex Finance Centre Can the Cross-Section Variation in Expected Stock Returns Explain Momentum George Bulkley University of Exeter Vivekanand Nawosah University

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

University of California Berkeley

University of California Berkeley University of California Berkeley A Comment on The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns : The Statistical Significance of FVIX is Driven by a Single Outlier Robert M. Anderson Stephen W. Bianchi

More information

Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth

Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth Analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts and past firm growth Abstract Several previous studies show that consensus analysts long-term earnings growth forecasts are excessively influenced by past firm

More information

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2012 The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Abdullah Al Masud Utah State University

More information

The Tangible Risk of Intangible Capital. Abstract

The Tangible Risk of Intangible Capital. Abstract The Tangible Risk of Intangible Capital Nan Li Shanghai Jiao Tong University Weiqi Zhang University of Muenster, Finance Center Muenster Yanzhao Jiang Shanghai Jiao Tong University Abstract With the rise

More information

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009 Long Chen Washington University in St. Louis Fresh Momentum Engin Kose Washington University in St. Louis First version: October 2009 Ohad Kadan Washington University in St. Louis Abstract We demonstrate

More information

What Drives Anomaly Returns?

What Drives Anomaly Returns? What Drives Anomaly Returns? Lars A. Lochstoer and Paul C. Tetlock Columbia Business School May 2016 Abstract We provide novel evidence on which theories best explain stock return anomalies. Our estimates

More information

The Level, Slope and Curve Factor Model for Stocks

The Level, Slope and Curve Factor Model for Stocks The Level, Slope and Curve Factor Model for Stocks Charles Clarke March 2015 Abstract I develop a method to extract only the priced factors from stock returns. First, I use multiple regression on anomaly

More information

Economics of Behavioral Finance. Lecture 3

Economics of Behavioral Finance. Lecture 3 Economics of Behavioral Finance Lecture 3 Security Market Line CAPM predicts a linear relationship between a stock s Beta and its excess return. E[r i ] r f = β i E r m r f Practically, testing CAPM empirically

More information

A Tough Act to Follow: Contrast Effects in Financial Markets. Samuel Hartzmark University of Chicago. May 20, 2016

A Tough Act to Follow: Contrast Effects in Financial Markets. Samuel Hartzmark University of Chicago. May 20, 2016 A Tough Act to Follow: Contrast Effects in Financial Markets Samuel Hartzmark University of Chicago May 20, 2016 Contrast eects Contrast eects: Value of previously-observed signal inversely biases perception

More information

There is a Growth Premium After All

There is a Growth Premium After All There is a Growth Premium After All Yuecheng Jia Shu Yan Haoxi Yang January 16, 2018 Abstract The conventional wisdom argues that the growth stocks are more risky to earn higher premium. However the empirical

More information

BAM Intelligence. 1 of 7 11/6/2017, 12:02 PM

BAM Intelligence. 1 of 7 11/6/2017, 12:02 PM 1 of 7 11/6/2017, 12:02 PM BAM Intelligence Larry Swedroe, Director of Research, 6/22/2016 For about ree decades, e working asset pricing model was e capital asset pricing model (CAPM), wi beta specifically

More information

What Drives Anomaly Returns?

What Drives Anomaly Returns? What Drives Anomaly Returns? Lars A. Lochstoer UCLA Paul C. Tetlock Columbia Business School August 2016 Abstract We provide novel evidence on which theories best explain stock return anomalies. Our estimates

More information

Equity risk factors and the Intertemporal CAPM

Equity risk factors and the Intertemporal CAPM Equity risk factors and the Intertemporal CAPM Ilan Cooper 1 Paulo Maio 2 This version: February 2015 3 1 Norwegian Business School (BI), Department of Financial Economics. E-mail: ilan.cooper@bi.no Hanken

More information

Seasonal Reversals in Expected Stock Returns

Seasonal Reversals in Expected Stock Returns Seasonal Reversals in Expected Stock Returns Matti Keloharju Juhani T. Linnainmaa Peter Nyberg October 2018 Abstract Stocks tend to earn high or low returns relative to other stocks every year in the same

More information

Intangible Returns, Accruals, and Return Reversal: A Multiperiod Examination of the Accrual Anomaly

Intangible Returns, Accruals, and Return Reversal: A Multiperiod Examination of the Accrual Anomaly THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW Vol. 85, No. 4 2010 pp. 1347 1374 Intangible Returns, Accruals, and Return Reversal: A Multiperiod Examination of the Accrual Anomaly Robert J. Resutek Dartmouth College DOI: 10.2308/accr.2010.85.4.1347

More information

Dissecting Anomalies EUGENE F. FAMA AND KENNETH R. FRENCH ABSTRACT

Dissecting Anomalies EUGENE F. FAMA AND KENNETH R. FRENCH ABSTRACT Dissecting Anomalies EUGENE F. FAMA AND KENNETH R. FRENCH ABSTRACT The anomalous returns associated with net stock issues, accruals, and momentum are pervasive; they show up in all size groups (micro,

More information

Can book-to-market, size and momentum be risk factors that predict economic growth?

Can book-to-market, size and momentum be risk factors that predict economic growth? Journal of Financial Economics 57 (2000) 221}245 Can book-to-market, size and momentum be risk factors that predict economic growth? Jimmy Liew, Maria Vassalou * Morgan Stanley Dean Witter, 1585 Broadway,

More information

Properties of implied cost of capital using analysts forecasts

Properties of implied cost of capital using analysts forecasts Article Properties of implied cost of capital using analysts forecasts Australian Journal of Management 36(2) 125 149 The Author(s) 2011 Reprints and permission: sagepub. co.uk/journalspermissions.nav

More information

Betting Against Alpha

Betting Against Alpha Betting Against Alpha Alex R. Horenstein Department of Economics School of Business Administration University of Miami horenstein@bus.miami.edu December 11, 2017 Abstract. I sort stocks based on realized

More information

The Unpriced Side of Value

The Unpriced Side of Value Chicago Booth Paper No. 12-18 The Unpriced Side of Value Joseph Gerakos University of Chicago Booth School of Business Juhani T. Linnainmaa University of Chicago Booth School of Business Fama-Miller Center

More information

The History of the Cross Section of Stock Returns

The History of the Cross Section of Stock Returns The History of the Cross Section of Stock Returns Juhani T. Linnainmaa Michael Roberts February 2016 Abstract Using accounting data spanning the 20th century, we show that most accounting-based return

More information

Do Anomalies Exist Ex Ante?*

Do Anomalies Exist Ex Ante?* Review of Finance (2014) 18: pp. 843 875 doi:10.1093/rof/rft026 Advance Access publication: July 19, 2013 Do Anomalies Exist Ex Ante?* YUE TANG 1, JIN (GINGER) WU 2 and LU ZHANG 3 1 University of Florida;

More information

Gross Profit Surprises and Future Stock Returns. Peng-Chia Chiu The Chinese University of Hong Kong

Gross Profit Surprises and Future Stock Returns. Peng-Chia Chiu The Chinese University of Hong Kong Gross Profit Surprises and Future Stock Returns Peng-Chia Chiu The Chinese University of Hong Kong chiupc@cuhk.edu.hk Tim Haight Loyola Marymount University thaight@lmu.edu October 2014 Abstract We show

More information

What Makes Stock Prices Move? Fundamentals vs. Investor Recognition

What Makes Stock Prices Move? Fundamentals vs. Investor Recognition Volume 68 Number 2 2012 CFA Institute What Makes Stock Prices Move? Fundamentals vs. Investor Recognition Scott Richardson, Richard Sloan, and Haifeng You, CFA The authors synthesized and extended recent

More information

Style Timing with Insiders

Style Timing with Insiders Volume 66 Number 4 2010 CFA Institute Style Timing with Insiders Heather S. Knewtson, Richard W. Sias, and David A. Whidbee Aggregate demand by insiders predicts time-series variation in the value premium.

More information

INVESTING IN THE ASSET GROWTH ANOMALY ACROSS THE GLOBE

INVESTING IN THE ASSET GROWTH ANOMALY ACROSS THE GLOBE JOIM Journal Of Investment Management, Vol. 13, No. 4, (2015), pp. 87 107 JOIM 2015 www.joim.com INVESTING IN THE ASSET GROWTH ANOMALY ACROSS THE GLOBE Xi Li a and Rodney N. Sullivan b We document the

More information

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios

A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios A Note on Predicting Returns with Financial Ratios Amit Goyal Goizueta Business School Emory University Ivo Welch Yale School of Management Yale Economics Department NBER December 16, 2003 Abstract This

More information

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach Hossein Asgharian and Björn Hansson Department of Economics, Lund University Box 7082 S-22007 Lund, Sweden

More information

Optimal Debt-to-Equity Ratios and Stock Returns

Optimal Debt-to-Equity Ratios and Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2014 Optimal Debt-to-Equity Ratios and Stock Returns Courtney D. Winn Utah State University Follow this

More information

Adjusting for earnings volatility in earnings forecast models

Adjusting for earnings volatility in earnings forecast models Uppsala University Department of Business Studies Spring 14 Bachelor thesis Supervisor: Joachim Landström Authors: Sandy Samour & Fabian Söderdahl Adjusting for earnings volatility in earnings forecast

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n.

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n. Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n. 5/2014 April 2014 ISSN: 2239-2734 This Working Paper is published under

More information

The Rational Part of Momentum

The Rational Part of Momentum The Rational Part of Momentum Jim Scott George Murillo Heilbrunn Center for Graham and Dodd Investing Columbia Business School Value Investing Research Consortium 1 Outline The Momentum Effect A Rationality

More information

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect?

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? Yi Jiang Department of Finance, California State University, Fullerton SGMH 5160, Fullerton, CA 92831 (657)278-4363 yjiang@fullerton.edu Yiming Qian

More information

Long Run Stock Returns after Corporate Events Revisited. Hendrik Bessembinder. W.P. Carey School of Business. Arizona State University.

Long Run Stock Returns after Corporate Events Revisited. Hendrik Bessembinder. W.P. Carey School of Business. Arizona State University. Long Run Stock Returns after Corporate Events Revisited Hendrik Bessembinder W.P. Carey School of Business Arizona State University Feng Zhang David Eccles School of Business University of Utah May 2017

More information

Fund Manager Educational Networks and Portfolio Performance. Botong Shang. September Abstract

Fund Manager Educational Networks and Portfolio Performance. Botong Shang. September Abstract Fund Manager Educational Networks and Portfolio Performance Botong Shang September 2017 Abstract In this study, I investigate the relation between social connections among fund managers and portfolio performance.

More information

Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis

Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2015 Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis Seth E. Williams Utah State University

More information

Betting against Beta or Demand for Lottery

Betting against Beta or Demand for Lottery Turan G. Bali 1 Stephen J. Brown 2 Scott Murray 3 Yi Tang 4 1 McDonough School of Business, Georgetown University 2 Stern School of Business, New York University 3 College of Business Administration, University

More information

Investment-Based Underperformance Following Seasoned Equity Offering. Evgeny Lyandres. Lu Zhang University of Rochester and NBER

Investment-Based Underperformance Following Seasoned Equity Offering. Evgeny Lyandres. Lu Zhang University of Rochester and NBER Investment-Based Underperformance Following Seasoned Equity Offering Evgeny Lyandres Rice University Le Sun University of Rochester Lu Zhang University of Rochester and NBER University of Texas at Austin

More information

The Impact of Institutional Investors on the Monday Seasonal*

The Impact of Institutional Investors on the Monday Seasonal* Su Han Chan Department of Finance, California State University-Fullerton Wai-Kin Leung Faculty of Business Administration, Chinese University of Hong Kong Ko Wang Department of Finance, California State

More information

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility B Volatility Appendix The aggregate volatility risk explanation of the turnover effect relies on three empirical facts. First, the explanation assumes that firm-specific uncertainty comoves with aggregate

More information

Common Factors in Return Seasonalities

Common Factors in Return Seasonalities Common Factors in Return Seasonalities Matti Keloharju, Aalto University Juhani Linnainmaa, University of Chicago and NBER Peter Nyberg, Aalto University AQR Insight Award Presentation 1 / 36 Common factors

More information

BOOK TO MARKET RATIO AND EXPECTED STOCK RETURN: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY ON THE COLOMBO STOCK MARKET

BOOK TO MARKET RATIO AND EXPECTED STOCK RETURN: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY ON THE COLOMBO STOCK MARKET BOOK TO MARKET RATIO AND EXPECTED STOCK RETURN: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY ON THE COLOMBO STOCK MARKET Mohamed Ismail Mohamed Riyath Sri Lanka Institute of Advanced Technological Education (SLIATE), Sammanthurai,

More information

MULTI FACTOR PRICING MODEL: AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH TO CAPM

MULTI FACTOR PRICING MODEL: AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH TO CAPM MULTI FACTOR PRICING MODEL: AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH TO CAPM Samit Majumdar Virginia Commonwealth University majumdars@vcu.edu Frank W. Bacon Longwood University baconfw@longwood.edu ABSTRACT: This study

More information

Common Risk Factors in the Cross-Section of Corporate Bond Returns

Common Risk Factors in the Cross-Section of Corporate Bond Returns Common Risk Factors in the Cross-Section of Corporate Bond Returns Online Appendix Section A.1 discusses the results from orthogonalized risk characteristics. Section A.2 reports the results for the downside

More information

Pricing and Mispricing in the Cross-Section

Pricing and Mispricing in the Cross-Section Pricing and Mispricing in the Cross-Section D. Craig Nichols Whitman School of Management Syracuse University James M. Wahlen Kelley School of Business Indiana University Matthew M. Wieland Kelley School

More information

Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds. Kevin C.H. Chiang*

Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds. Kevin C.H. Chiang* Further Evidence on the Performance of Funds of Funds: The Case of Real Estate Mutual Funds Kevin C.H. Chiang* School of Management University of Alaska Fairbanks Fairbanks, AK 99775 Kirill Kozhevnikov

More information

The Cross Section of Expected Holding Period Returns and their Dynamics: A Present Value Approach

The Cross Section of Expected Holding Period Returns and their Dynamics: A Present Value Approach The Cross Section of Expected Holding Period Returns and their Dynamics: A Present Value Approach Matthew R. Lyle Charles C.Y. Wang Working Paper 13-050 June 19, 2014 Copyright 2012, 2013, 2014 by Matthew

More information

Unpublished Appendices to Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information. Market Reactions to Different Types of Information

Unpublished Appendices to Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information. Market Reactions to Different Types of Information Unpublished Appendices to Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information. This document contains the unpublished appendices for Daniel and Titman (006), Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible

More information

Pricing and Mispricing in the Cross Section

Pricing and Mispricing in the Cross Section Pricing and Mispricing in the Cross Section D. Craig Nichols Whitman School of Management Syracuse University James M. Wahlen Kelley School of Business Indiana University Matthew M. Wieland J.M. Tull School

More information

Aggregation, Capital Heterogeneity, and the Investment CAPM

Aggregation, Capital Heterogeneity, and the Investment CAPM Aggregation, Capital Heterogeneity, and the Investment CAPM Andrei S. Gonçalves 1 Chen Xue 2 Lu Zhang 3 1 UNC 2 University of Cincinnati 3 Ohio State and NBER PBCSF November 21, 218 Introduction Theme

More information

Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence

Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence Joshua Livnat Department of Accounting Stern School of Business Administration New York University 311 Tisch Hall

More information

Does R&D Influence Revisions in Earnings Forecasts as it does with Forecast Errors?: Evidence from the UK. Seraina C.

Does R&D Influence Revisions in Earnings Forecasts as it does with Forecast Errors?: Evidence from the UK. Seraina C. Does R&D Influence Revisions in Earnings Forecasts as it does with Forecast Errors?: Evidence from the UK Seraina C. Anagnostopoulou Athens University of Economics and Business Department of Accounting

More information

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables Huacheng Zhang * University of Arizona This draft: 8/31/2012 First draft: 2/28/2012 Abstract We

More information

The evaluation of the performance of UK American unit trusts

The evaluation of the performance of UK American unit trusts International Review of Economics and Finance 8 (1999) 455 466 The evaluation of the performance of UK American unit trusts Jonathan Fletcher* Department of Finance and Accounting, Glasgow Caledonian University,

More information

Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance: Analysis of Holdings Returns

Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance: Analysis of Holdings Returns Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance: Analysis of Holdings Returns Samuel Kruger * June 2007 Abstract: Do mutual funds that performed well in the past select stocks that perform well in the future? I

More information

Accruals and Value/Glamour Anomalies: The Same or Related Phenomena?

Accruals and Value/Glamour Anomalies: The Same or Related Phenomena? Accruals and Value/Glamour Anomalies: The Same or Related Phenomena? Gary Taylor Culverhouse School of Accountancy, University of Alabama, Tuscaloosa AL 35487, USA Tel: 1-205-348-4658 E-mail: gtaylor@cba.ua.edu

More information

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves issn 1936-5330 Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves Brent Bundick Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City First Version: October 2007 This Version: June 2008 RWP 07-08 Abstract Piazzesi and Swanson

More information

UNIVERSITY OF ROCHESTER. Home work Assignment #4 Due: May 24, 2012

UNIVERSITY OF ROCHESTER. Home work Assignment #4 Due: May 24, 2012 UNIVERSITY OF ROCHESTER William E. Simon Graduate School of Business Administration FIN 532 Advanced Topics in Capital Markets Home work Assignment #4 Due: May 24, 2012 The point of this assignment is

More information

Portfolio strategies based on stock

Portfolio strategies based on stock ERIK HJALMARSSON is a professor at Queen Mary, University of London, School of Economics and Finance in London, UK. e.hjalmarsson@qmul.ac.uk Portfolio Diversification Across Characteristics ERIK HJALMARSSON

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information