DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS"

Transcription

1 DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS Working Paper No The Importance of Agenda and Willingness to Pay Nicholas E. Flores Department of Economics, University of Colorado at Boulder Boulder, Colorado December 1999 Center for Economic Analysis Department of Economics University of Colorado at Boulder Boulder, Colorado Nicholas E. Flores

2 The Importance of Agenda and Willingness to Pay Abstract This paper links the spatial model of voters preferences to the willingness to pay model of public goods provision. The willingness to pay approach, which is commonly used in benefit-cost analysis, is free from a specific cost provision schedule. Freedom from a specific cost schedule facilitates a wide range of choices for a monopoly agenda setter, including budget maximization and profit maximization, within a single model. Like the spatial model, the willingness to pay model allows for a clear graphical analysis. Interdependence of multiple good preferences is analyzed using substitute/complement relationships. These relationships can be used to predict how goods may be bundled to ensure passage or defeat.

3 Introduction The importance of the agenda is a well-studied phenomenon in the public choice literature. Much of our understanding of agenda effects has resulted from the application of spatial models to different formulations of the collective choice problem. This paper departs from the spatial approach and instead uses the willingness to pay framework to analyze the importance of agenda. 1 Both the willingness to pay framework and spatial models formulate the choice problem as that of a utility-maximizing agent facing an income constraint and a collective goods constraint. 2 While both generate the same individual decisions in the same circumstances, the analytical structure of the two approaches differ. The spatial approach considers what public goods choice would be made if the individual were able to select the level of public goods subject to an individual provision cost schedule. 3 The willingness to pay approach considers what individual price would be charged to induce the consumer to choose the constrained level of provision if the individual were able to freely choose the level of public goods. In the first case, a set of private levels of public goods is used as a point of reference and in the second case a set of private prices is used as a reference point. Using the willingness to pay framework in a one-dimensional public goods setting, the paper analyzes the monopoly agenda setter problem of Romer and Rosenthal (1978), Romer and Rosenthal (1979) and revisits the utility-maximizing bureaucrat discussed in Niskanen (1975). The paper then considers the two extremes of the utility-maximizing agenda setter, budget maximizing and profit maximizing, and characterizes the agenda setter's optimal profit maximizing solution. The willingness to pay framework allows a clear graphical analysis of the choices facing a utility-maximizing agenda setter. In a multi-dimensional setting, the paper uses the willingness to pay framework to 1 The willingness to pay framework is the standard approach used in benefit-cost analysis. 2 Still earlier applications of the same type of utility maximizing model can be found in the rationed goods literature. An early summary of this literature can be found in Tobin (1952). 3 Other variations include selecting the mix of public goods given an already determined budget or selecting the budget given an already determined mix of public goods. 1

4 decompose multi-dimensional bundles into sequences of single-dimensional changes. This allows the multi-dimensional properties of willingness to pay to be more carefully examined and related to unconstrained, utility-constant demands for the public goods. Using results from Carson, Flores and Hanemann (1998), the paper shows that expenditure approval with bundling is less likely if the unconstrained demands for public goods are Hicksian substitutes and more likely if they are Hicksian complements. Thus qualitative predictions of individual voter behavior are available without imposing separability. Moreover, the issue of surplus trading across dimensions is placed in an easily interpretable framework. Public goods with different magnitudes of willingness to pay relative to costs may be combined to assist in the passage of some measures and the failure of others. Finally, the paper provides a multi-dimensional analog of the choices facing the utility-maximizing agenda setter who has knowledge of voters' preferences. An Economic Model of Individual Choice Suppose that individual agents have non-satiable, strictly convex preferences over n market goods and k public goods and that these preferences are differentiable. The k-dimensional vector of public goods will be denoted Q and the n-dimensional vector of market goods will be denoted X. Equivalently, individual agent preferences can be represented by a strictly increasing, strictly quasi-concave utility function U(X,Q). The levels of private goods are individually chosen while the levels of public goods are collectively provided. Let y denote current disposable income which is simply income less payments for the current public goods level, Q 0, and p denote the vector of prices for the n market goods. The choice problem is to maximize utility subject to market prices, disposable income and the current level of public goods. 4 X m (p,q 0,y) is the vector that solves the maximization problem, or ordinary Marshallian demands, and U 0 = U(X(p,Q 0,y),Q 0 ) is the maximum obtainable utility. Of primary interest is the characterization of the optimal choice when deciding whether to vote yes or no for a change from the status quo level of public goods and the choice of agenda is 4 It will be assumed throughout this paper that the alternative to the proposed change is the current level of public goods provision/expenditures. Relaxing this assumption and allowing a different reversion level shifts the decision to an analysis centered around the reversion level. 2

5 outside of the agent's control. 5 One can think of the agenda coming from a variety of sources such as a monopoly agenda setter, a committee, or a group petitioning for a referendum. In any case, the agent has no input into what goes onto the agenda. The decision rule is passage by majority support of voters. Given that agents are maximizing utility and have no incentive to act strategically, the optimal decision rule is to vote for any proposition that results in a utility gain and vote against any proposition that results in a utility loss. Agents are indifferent between propositions that leave utility unchanged which makes either voting for the proposition or against the proposition optimal. It is assumed that in the situation of indifference, the decision rule is to vote for the proposition. Spatial analyses found in the public choice literature are centered around the concept of voters' ideal or preferred points of provision. The agent's preferred point of provision can be obtained by carrying out the mental exercise of deriving what level would be chosen by the agent if the choice of both the market and public goods were at his or her disposal. The preferred point is simply the mix of private and public goods chosen when the consumer is maximizing utility subject to before-tax income, market prices, and individual costs for each public good. 6 With a known provision schedule that yields a convex budget set for market and public goods, the class of preferences considered here provides a unique preferred point. With the preferred point in mind, the constrained utility analysis can be transformed into a spatial analysis whereby the utility ordering of possible combinations is equivalently represented by a function that is decreasing in movement away from the preferred point. In the case of a single market and public good, this concept is represented in the following two graphs. The first graph is the typical indifference curve graph showing that the utility-maximizing choice is (X *,Q * ). The second graph shows the relationship between the level of Q chosen and the maximum 5 The vote is a take-it or leave-it proposition and the analysis is a one-shot situation. Hence there is no incentive to vote strategically, leaving agents to vote sincerely. 6 There are other variations such as the preferred point obtained after a budget has been set and the individual chooses the mix of public goods. In these cases, the constraint is different in that the allocation between market goods and public goods has already been made. 3

6 obtainable utility for each Q. This relationship can be equivalently rewritten as a function of distance from the ideal point, Q *. U * U 0 As Figure 1.b. shows, the space of possibilities is partitioned into an acceptance region and a rejection region. The acceptance region consists of those alternatives located between the points of indifference, Q 0 and Q 0 +, or all of those points that would constitute a utility gain; the rejection region consists of those points located beyond the indifference points in the respective directions or those points that would constitute a utility loss. The decision rule is a simple spatial rule: vote yes when the proposition is located in the acceptance region and no if the proposition is located in the rejection region. An alternative individual decision rule is the comparison of willingness to pay for the 4

7 specified change with the individual cost of provision. 7 Willingness to pay is the amount of income foregone that would hold utility at the status quo level with the increased level of public goods, U 0 = U(X(p,Q 1,y-WTP),Q 1 ). Here the decision rule is to vote yes for the proposed change if the individual cost is less than or equal to willingness to pay and vote no if the individual cost exceeds willingness to pay. As in a spatial analysis, the acceptance region signals a utility gain relative to U 0 and the rejection region signals a utility loss. Figure 2 shows willingness to pay for a typical individual. The class of preferences under consideration guarantees that individual willingness to pay is strictly concave for increases in Q. At Q', the voter would agree to the provision increase if the increase cost less than P * and vote no if the cost were any greater. From an analytical perspective using a willingness to pay analysis is different from the spatial analysis. Knowledge of the distribution of voters' willingness to pay imparts knowledge of what price could be charged for a specified change while attaining majority approval whereas the spatial analysis imparts information that is relative to a price schedule. The Monopoly Agenda Setter and Willingness to Pay Building on work by [Niskanen (1971), Niskanen (1975)], [Romer and Rosenthal (1978), Romer and Rosenthal (1979)] provided a spatial analysis in the situation of a budget-maximizing agenda setter who presents a budget for consideration to voters who have different ideal points. 7 For simplicity, only increases from the status quo will be considered. The analysis is easily generalized in order to include decreases by using a willingness to accept compensation criterion along with the willingness to pay criterion for increases. 5

8 The agenda setter knows the voters' preferences which imparts knowledge of voters' preferred points (as well as willingness to pay). The setter also knows the cost of provision. 8 The Romer and Rosenthal analysis showed that the optimal agenda setting choice is either the reversion level (status quo level) or the highest provision level that would engender majority support. The choice depends upon the status quo provision level and voters' preferences. In the latter case, the decisive voter is left indifferent between the status quo level and the proposed agenda. Figures 3 and 4 provide graphs of the preference functions of three voters in two different situations. Q BM is the equilibrium point chosen by the agenda setter. In Figure 3, voter B is decisive and in Figure 4, voter A is decisive. 8 Given the budget maximizing assumption, voters' knowing or not knowing the cost provision is unimportant. 6

9 Niskanen (1975) discussed the plausibility of his 1971 budget-maximizing model and provided an alternative model of a utility-maximizing bureaucrat who provides some singledimensional output to the government and is subject to review by a government board. In the alternative model, the bureaucrat knows the relationship between the quantity demanded and the cost of provision, but the review board members necessarily do not know the minimum cost of provision. Niskanen provided a specific utility function with arguments of the bureaucrat's income and non-monetary perquisites. In the model, both income and non-monetary perquisites are functions of Q and the bureaucrat's discretionary budget, B-C, where B is the maximum budget that would be passed and C is the minimum cost of providing Q. Niskanen's discussion of the qualitative effects of changing the model's parameters was essentially an analysis of the tradeoffs between higher output and discretionary budget. However, his analysis explicitly excluded the possibility of a monopoly supplier and therefore total surplus extraction was not a possibility. By using the willingness to pay framework, the choices facing a utility-maximizing agenda setter can be graphically analyzed. Suppose that voters' preferences as well as provision costs, are known by the setter. Voters do not know the minimum cost of provision and vote their preferences. As noted above, the agenda setter's complete knowledge of voters' preferences can be translated into knowledge of the median willingness to pay distribution for every alternative 7

10 level of Q. Figure 5 shows willingness to pay for three voters and the cost of provision per individual which is assumed to be convex in costs. 9 Median willingness to pay is given by voter B's willingness to pay curve from Q 0 to Q' and by voter A's willingness to pay curve from Q' to Q BM. Costs Q 0 Q' Q BM From the Romer and Rosenthal analysis, the median willingness to pay will equal the cost of provision in the budget-maximizing case which is given by Q BM in Figure 5. This follows since at the equilibrium allocation derived in their analysis, the decisive voter is left indifferent. However for those points where median willingness to pay exceeds provision costs, the monopoly agenda setter has the option of charging more than provision costs and up to the median willingness to pay. 10 While total revenues will still be greater at Q BM (and hence the budgetmaximizing agenda setter would still choose this point), the possibility of enjoying discretionary budget adds an interesting dimension. As an extreme case, suppose that the agenda setter is a profit maximizer, i.e. the agenda setter is concerned only with maximizing discretionary budget. 11 In this case, the agenda setter 9 For simplicity, it is assumed that the cost is shared equally by each individual. 10 Throughout my analysis, it is assumed that at least the median voter's willingness to pay for small changes exceeds provision costs. A voter who finds provision too high at the status quo level would have a willingness to pay curve that is still concave in Q, but lies below the cost curve at all points greater than Q 0. Without any subsidization, such a voter would only vote for decreases and then the trade-off would be between the reduction in taxes and the reduction in Q. 11 Like the decision made by the consumer, the agenda-setter also must face the status quo. Therefore when refering to profit maximization, it is in reference to the status quo level of profits; the setter is deciding on maximum profits in addition to the level of profits at the status quo. 8

11 will choose Q to maximize the difference between median willingness to pay and the cost of provision. That is to say, the setter's objective is to choose Q in order to maximize WTP m (Q) - C(Q) where WTP m (Q) is the median willingness to pay function. The characterization of the point the agenda setter presents voters will depend upon the median willingness to pay function. First consider the case of a single voter having median willingness to pay for every alternative Q. In this case, the median willingness to pay function is differentiable and concave in Q. Therefore the optimal solution can be characterized by tangency conditions. The profitmaximizing agenda setter will produce at the level where marginal willingness to pay equals the marginal cost of provision. In Figure 6, this point is given by Q PM. Q 0 Q BM Assuming that Q is a normal good, the profit maximizing outcome will be less than the median willingness to pay voter's ideal point. This follows since at both the profit maximizing outcome and the ideal point, the ratio of marginal utility of the market good to marginal utility of the public good equals the ratio of the market good's price to the marginal provision cost. In both cases, the move represents a decrease in the shadow price relative to the initial point since there is an increase in Q. 12 The reduction in the shadow price implies a positive income effect that is realized in the income-constant, ideal point analysis, but is unrealized in the utility-constant 12 The shadow price p * is the price of Q that would induce consumption of the constrained\market bundle (X,Q) if both were chosen by the consumer. 9

12 analysis. 13 Figure 7 shows the ideal point, Q *, and the profit maximizing point, Q PM, for the median voter. In situations where the median voter changes with Q, median willingness to pay is still continuous, but no longer differentiable. Therefore all local interior optima and non-differentiable points must be evaluated. As the example shown in Figure 8 demonstrates, the profit maximizing point can occur at the intersection of two voters' willingness to pay curve. Q 0 Q BM Realistically, most bureaucrats will fall in between the extremes of budget-maximizing and profit maximizing. This leaves us with some utility-weighting scheme similar to the one found in 13 Recall that the willingness to pay analysis is utility-constant and therefore changes in consumption are along the same indifference curve. The ideal point analysis is income-constant and changes in consumption generally imply changes in utility. 10

13 Niskanen's analysis whereby the agenda setter trades off the level of provision with discretionary budget. Depending upon the setter's preferences, which may in turn depend upon the rules imposed on the setter, the optimal choice will occur somewhere between the extremes of budget maximizing and profit maximizing. The equivalence of the spatial approach and the willingness to pay framework implies that the two approaches are complementary. As in the case of the spatial analysis, the willingness to pay framework also lends itself to a nice graphical analysis. However, the willingness to pay framework has the advantage of not being subject to a provision schedule. Therefore the case of a utility-maximizing agenda setter is easily handled. The next section provides a multidimensional analysis of willingness to pay and show that simple information regarding substitution and complementarity between public goods gives the agenda setter still more options to obtain a more preferred outcome, from the agenda setter s perspective, by using agenda power. Multi-dimensional Bundling In a multi-dimensional public choice setting, predictions as clear as those from the singledimensional agenda setter models are much more difficult to obtain. Much of the research on agenda control in a multi-dimensional setting can be attributed to MacKay and Weaver (1981), MacKay and Weaver (1983). By imposing sufficient structure, the multi-dimensional analysis becomes more tractable. 14 Rather than imposing structure on the rules of the decision process to demonstrate the importance of the agenda, the focus is on individual preferences. By imposing a substitute or complement condition on the public goods under consideration, bundling affects willingness to pay and in turn influences the voter's decision. Returning to the willingness to pay framework, recall that willingness to pay satisfies the condition U 0 = U(X(p,Q 1,y-WTP),Q 1 ). Willingness to pay can also be represented as the difference in minimal expenditures necessary to obtain utility level U 0 when Q 0 and Q 1 are the respective public goods provision levels: WTP = e(p,q 0,U 0 ) - e(p,q 1,U 0 ). 14 MacKay and Weaver (1981), MacKay and Weaver (1983) provide a sequential analysis where the mix of public goods is selected subject to a budget or the budget is selected subject to a given mix of public goods. 11

14 This representation has proven invaluable in the public goods valuation research because this difference can be rewritten into a sequence of changes that provides valuable insight. 15 For example, suppose there are three public goods, Q = [q 1,q 2,q 3 ] t where t denotes the transpose. By adding and subtracting the two terms e(p,q 1 1,q 0 2,q 0 3,U 0 ) and e(p,q 1 1,q 1 2,q 0 3,U 0 ), willingness to pay for the multi-dimensional change can be rewritten into a sequence of singledimensional changes: WTP = [e(p,q 0 1,q 0 2,q 0 3,U 0 ) - e(p,q 1 1,q 0 2,q 0 3,U 0 )] + [e(p,q 1 1,q 0 2,q 0 3,U 0 ) - e(p,q 1 1,q 1 2,q 0 3,U 0 )] + [e(p,q 1 1,q 1 2,q 0 3,U 0 ) - e(p,q 1 1,q 1 2,q 1 3,U 0 )]. The first term in brackets is the willingness to pay for an increase in q 1 given the other goods are at the status quo level. The second term is willingness to pay for the increase in the second public good with the higher level of the first good and the status quo level of the third good. The last term is the willingness to pay for the increase in q 3 given the other public goods are at the higher level. For any of the single-dimensional changes, willingness to pay can be rewritten using the fundamental theorem of calculus. Using the first term as an example, e(p, q 0 1, q 0 2, q 0 3, U 0 ) & e(p, q 1 1, q 0 2, q 0 3, U Me(p, s, q ) ', q 0 3, U 0 ) ds. m Ms q 0 1 q 1 1 Willingness to pay is simply the integral over the marginal change in expenditures with respect to q 1. The assumed convexity of preferences yields a unique set of shadow prices for each public good for any point in the interior of the (X,Q) space. As shown by Maler (1974), the shadow price for each public good is the negative of the derivative of the expenditure function with respect to the good. The set of shadow prices at the status quo public goods level can be interpreted as the set of prices that would induce consumption of the same market goods/public goods bundle when both market and public goods are in the consumer's choice set. The first term 15 The sequence may be written in public goods or prices. Contemporary discussions of non-user values in the environmental goods literature decompose willingness to pay into first a price change and then a quantity change. This decomposition facilitates the use of the weak complementary condition (Maler (1974)). 12

15 can be rewritten using the shadow price relationship: q 0 1 Me(p, s, q 0 2, q 0 3, U 0 ) ds ' &p ( m Ms m 1 (p, s, q 0 2, q 0 3, U 0 )ds ' p ( m 1 (p, s, q 0 2, q 0 3, U 0 )ds. q 1 1 q 1 1 q 0 1 Willingness to pay for a one-dimensional change is simply the integral over the public good's inverse demand function or equivalently the integral over the good s shadow value. The set of inverse demand functions are functions of market goods prices and other public goods levels and therefore willingness to pay is also a function of these variables. In the cost-benefit literature, much attention has been focused on the relationship between a single public good and market goods while less emphasis has been placed on the relationship between public goods. Carson, Flores and Hanemann (1998) proved several propositions relating conditions from the unconstrained utility-maximization problem to the collective choice problem under consideration here. The propositions referred to below will be stated without proof. The proofs may be found in Carson, Flores and Hanemann (1998). q 1 1 q 0 1 Proposition 4 (CFH): Assume that all rationed goods are (strict) Hicksian substitutes. Then willingness to pay for an increase in q 1 is a nonincreasing (decreasing) function in the levels of q j, j = 1,2,.. k. 16 Proposition 9 (CFH): Suppose there are only two rationed (public) goods, k = 2, and these rationed goods are (strict) Hicksian complements, then willingness to pay for an increase in q i, i = 1, 2 is a nondecreasing (increasing) funnction in the levels of q j, j i. In the case where only two goods are under consideration, k=2, if the public goods are (strict) Hicksian complements, then willingness to pay for an increase in q i is a non-decreasing (increasing) function in the levels of q j, j i. When k > 2 and the goods are Hicksian complements, willingness to pay for an increase in q i may be either increasing or decreasing in the levels of q j, j i. 16 h Two goods (q i, q j ) are (strict) Hicksian substitutes if Mq h where q i is the Hicksian compensated demand. 13 i /Mp ( j (>) $ 0

16 These two propositions are important in understanding the effect of multi-dimensional bundling at the individual level because they allow for predictions in cases when preferences are not separable. When the goods are unconstrained Hicksian substitutes at the status quo level (subject to facing the individual shadow price), willingness to pay is decreasing in the levels of other public goods. In the case of unconstrained Hicksian complements and k=2, willingness to pay is increasing in the level of the other public good. Given these results, the agenda setter's knowledge of preferences or even just the Hicksian substitute/complement relationship allows for setter gains from the power of the agenda. Suppose that a bureaucrat/agenda setter is considering k distinct projects that can be 0 represented as changes in the levels of Q, [(q 1 6q ),...,(q k 6q 1 k )]. If one considers each change from the status quo in isolation, then there are k independent valuations for a given voter. 17 A question of interest for the agenda setter is how informative would independent valuations be when proposing multi-dimensional bundles for voters' approval? First assume that the setter only knows each voter's sum of independent valuations and that the cost of provision equals the median voter's sum of independent valuations. If the goods are unrestricted Hicksian substitutes, then the bundle would be turned down by voters. This result follows since willingness to pay for the bundle can be decomposed into the sequence of single-dimensional changes such as the example given above where k=3: WTP = [e(p,q 0 1,q 0 2,q 0 3,U 0 ) - e(p,q 1 1,q 0 2,q 0 3,U 0 )] + [e(p,q 1 1,q 0 2,q 0 3,U 0 ) - e(p,q 1 1,q 1 2,q 0 3,U 0 )] + [e(p,q 1 1,q 1 2,q 0 3,U 0 ) - e(p,q 1 1,q 1 2,q 1 3,U 0 )]. The first term is equivalent to an independent valuation. The second term is willingness to pay for the change in q 2, but with a higher level of q 1 ; the third term is willingness to pay for the change in q 3, but with higher levels of both q 1 and q 2. By Proposition 4 (CFH), willingness to pay for the bundle will be less than the sum of the independent valuations since the second two terms are less than their independently valued counterparts. Therefore, provided that voters' preferences goods. 17 That is to say, one can consider the willingness to pay for each good alone before increasing any of the other 14

17 are such that the k goods are Hicksian substitutes, the proposed bundle will fail. 18 If the k goods are Hicksian complements and k = 2, then passage is assured since willingness to pay for the bundle will exceed the sum of the independent valuations. However if k $ 3, then the bundling result is ambiguous in that willingness to pay for the bundle may be either greater or less than the sum of independent valuations. By using the results from Carson, Flores and Hanemann (1998), several generalizations are possible. In the case where all public goods under consideration are strict Hicksian substitutes, approval is less likely with bundling. In the case where a pair of public goods under consideration are strict Hicksian complements, approval is more likely with bundling. Therefore with as little information of preferences as whether or not goods are Hicksian substitutes or complements, the agenda setter is able to bundle goods in a manner to influence the outcome in his or her favor. For example, assume that the bureaucrat/agenda setter knows which goods are Hicksian substitutes and which goods are Hicksian complements as well as the distribution of independent willingness to pay for all projects that he may propose. The bureaucrat/agenda setter also has a single preferred project that if proposed alone would fail by a single vote. 19 There are several available options. The most obvious is for the setter to look toward complements that would pass if presented in isolation. Bundling with one or more goods from this set would increase the chance of passage of his preferred project. Another option elucidated by the willingness framework is to trade surplus within substitutes. There may be substitutes that are so highly valued relative to costs that even when bundled with the setter's preferred bundle (that alone would fail), the bundle will engender majority support A good example of what appears to be observable substitution-bundling effects is the California Proposition 128 (Big Green) ballot initiative that went down to defeat in Some contended that because the initiative simultaneously addressed so many issues, voters were unprepared for so much action at once. 19 Here it is assumed that only the minimal cost of provision is charged subject to a known individual payment schedule. 20 For the sake of simplicity, the possibility of reducing provision in one or more dimensions, which is certainly a possibility if some voters feel provision level is too high for some goods is not analyzed. Adding this dimension does not significantly alter the analysis, but does increase the setter's options. 15

18 The bureaucrat/agenda setter's knowledge of preferences provides all of the information necessary for manipulating the agenda. First note that the entire space of increases in Q can be partitioned into a majority acceptance region and majority rejection region. This is accomplished by considering the median voter willingness to pay function for any increase in Q and the cost of provision. As in the one-dimensional case, these functions will be denoted WTP m (Q) and C(Q). 21 The partition is given as follows: A = {Q: WTP m (Q) - C(Q) $ 0} R = {Q: WTP m (Q) - C(Q) < 0}, where A is the acceptance region and R is the rejection region. 22 Since the bureaucrat/agenda setter knows voter preferences, he also knows all increases in Q that will pass. Provided that C(Q) is continuous, A is a compact, but not necessarily convex set. 23 Therefore for any continuous function used to define the bureaucrat/setter's preferences, a maximum will exist, although it need not be unique. Again the extremes of budget-maximizing behavior and profitmaximizing behavior can be characterized. A budget maximizer would choose any element in the set M = {Q 0 A: TC(Q) $ TC(Q') œ Q' 0 A} where TC(Q) is the total cost of the additional provision and the profit maximizer would choose any element from the set P = {Q 0 A: WTP(Q) - TC(Q) $ WTP(Q') - TC(Q') œ Q' 0 A}. Because of possible non-convexities, M and P may contain multiple points between which the budget maximizer and profit maximizer respectively would be indifferent. Conclusion Spatial models have broad appeal because of their ability to transform complex choices 21 In the class of preferences considered here, individual willingness to pay is continuous in Q. WTP m (Q) will also be continuous in Q (although not differentiable) because those Q where the median voter changes are intersections of continuous functions. 22 If costs are not uniform across voters, the partition would be defined by the median net willingness to pay function rather than the median willingness to pay function. This follows since different payment schedules may alter the median voter for a particular Q. 23 As noted above, the function WTP(Q) m - C(Q) is continuous. The image of A is closed by definition and bounded above by the maximum of voter incomes. Therefore the image of A is compact and by continuity of WTP m (Q) - C m, (Q), A is compact. 16

19 into an easily interpretable framework which lends itself to a graphical representation. This paper uses a different, although equivalent, approach to analyze agenda effects by using the willingness to pay framework. In addition to sharing the same underlying utility-maximizing structure, the spatial approach and willingness to pay framework both employ the mental exercise of considering what would happen if the consumer were able to freely choose the levels of public goods. The spatial analysis results in a set of private levels (ideal points) of public goods while the willingness to pay analysis results in a set of private prices for public goods. The willingness to pay framework facilitates a clear analysis of the agenda setter's options and is a nice complement to the spatial approach. In the one-dimensional case, the paper provides an alternative analysis of Niskanen's (1975) utility-maximizing bureaucrat/agenda setter. The willingness to pay framework permits a graphical analysis that allows reference to the extremes of Romer and Rosenthal's (1978,1979) budget-maximizing agenda setter and a profit-maximizing version of Niskanen's (1975) utility-maximizing setter on the same graph. Juxtaposing these two extremes is useful because they bound the choices facing the utility-maximizing setter who is concerned with both the size of the budget and discretionary budget. Using results from Carson, Flores and Hanemann (1998), the paper shows how preference structure can influence voters' decisions in a multi-dimensional setting. Goods that are Hicksian substitutes result in less value for bundled goods than the sum of their independent values and pairs of goods that are Hicksian complements result in more value when bundled than the sum of independent valuations. Thus the agenda setter's knowledge of voters' substitute/complement relationships can provide the margin of victory for the setter's preferred project. Finally, the paper provides a multi-dimensional analog of the choices facing a utilitymaximizing setter. The willingness to pay framework allows a characterization of the setter's choice set which is compact under the condition of a continuous cost function. Therefore if the setter's preferences over the choice set are continuous, a maximum will exist. 17

20 References Carson, R. T., N. E. Flores and W. M. Hanemann (1998). Sequencing and Valuing Public Goods. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 36(3): MacKay, R. J. and C. Weaver (1981). Agenda Control by Budget Maximizers in a Multi-Bureau Setting. Public Choice 37(3): MacKay, R. J. and C. L. Weaver (1983). Commodity Bundling and Agenda Control in the Public Sector. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98(4): Maler, K.-G. (1974). Environmental Economics: A Theoretical Inquiry. Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University Press. Niskanen, W. A. (1971). Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Chicago, Aldine-Atherton Press. Niskanen, W. A. (1975). Bureaucrats and Politicians. Journal of Law and Economics 18(3): Romer, T. and H. Rosenthal (1978). Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas, and the Status Quo. Public Choice 33(4): Romer, T. and H. Rosenthal (1979). Bureaucrats versus Voters: On the Political Economy of Resource Allocation by Direct Democracy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 93(4): Tobin, J. (1952). A Survey of the Theory of Rationing. Econometrica 20(4):

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory Chapter Microeconomics of Consumer Theory The two broad categories of decision-makers in an economy are consumers and firms. Each individual in each of these groups makes its decisions in order to achieve

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Marshall and Hicks Understanding the Ordinary and Compensated Demand

Marshall and Hicks Understanding the Ordinary and Compensated Demand Marshall and Hicks Understanding the Ordinary and Compensated Demand K.J. Wainwright March 3, 213 UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND THE DEMAND FUNCTIONS Consider a consumer with the utility function =, who faces

More information

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1 Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak Lecture 1 Syllabus Mathematical Theory of Demand Utility Maximization Problem Expenditure Minimization Problem Mathematical Theory of Production Profit Maximization

More information

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations 19.1: Introduction This chapter is interesting and important. It also helps to answer a question you may well have been asking ever since we studied quasi-linear

More information

Taxation and Efficiency : (a) : The Expenditure Function

Taxation and Efficiency : (a) : The Expenditure Function Taxation and Efficiency : (a) : The Expenditure Function The expenditure function is a mathematical tool used to analyze the cost of living of a consumer. This function indicates how much it costs in dollars

More information

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies Geo rey Heal and Bengt Kristrom May 24, 2004 Abstract In a nite-horizon general equilibrium model national

More information

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals. Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals. We will deal with a particular set of assumptions, but we can modify

More information

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2013 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality Lecture 5 Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H Summary of Lectures, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality 2 Summary of Lecture 4: Consumption theory 2. Preference orders 2.2 The utility function

More information

Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C

Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C Monday 11.15 am 1.15 pm wnowak@prawo.uni.wroc.pl http://prawo.uni.wroc.pl/user/12141/students-resources Syllabus Mathematical Theory of Demand Utility

More information

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences Problem Set Answer Key I. Short Problems. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences u (q ; q ) = q = + q = u (q ; q ) = q + q u (q ; q ) = ln q + ln q All three

More information

ECON Micro Foundations

ECON Micro Foundations ECON 302 - Micro Foundations Michael Bar September 13, 2016 Contents 1 Consumer s Choice 2 1.1 Preferences.................................... 2 1.2 Budget Constraint................................ 3

More information

max x + y s.t. y + px = m

max x + y s.t. y + px = m 1 Consumer s surplus Consider a household that consumes power, denoted by x, and money, denoted by y. A given bundle (x, y), provides the household with a level of happiness, or utility given by U(x, y)

More information

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction By: Stephen P. Holland Holland, Stephen P. (2003) Extraction Capacity and the Optimal Order of Extraction, Journal of Environmental Economics and

More information

Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics

Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics Group I Suppose a representative firm in a perfectly competitive, constant-cost industry has a cost function: T C(q) = 2q 2 + 100q + 100 (a) If market demand

More information

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1. Choice 34 Choice A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1. Optimal choice x* 2 x* x 1 1 Figure 5.1 2. note that tangency occurs at optimal

More information

Project Evaluation and the Folk Principle when the Private Sector Lacks Perfect Foresight

Project Evaluation and the Folk Principle when the Private Sector Lacks Perfect Foresight Project Evaluation and the Folk Principle when the Private Sector Lacks Perfect Foresight David F. Burgess Professor Emeritus Department of Economics University of Western Ontario June 21, 2013 ABSTRACT

More information

The objectives of the producer

The objectives of the producer The objectives of the producer Laurent Simula October 19, 2017 Dr Laurent Simula (Institute) The objectives of the producer October 19, 2017 1 / 47 1 MINIMIZING COSTS Long-Run Cost Minimization Graphical

More information

I. More Fundamental Concepts and Definitions from Mathematics

I. More Fundamental Concepts and Definitions from Mathematics An Introduction to Optimization The core of modern economics is the notion that individuals optimize. That is to say, individuals use the resources available to them to advance their own personal objectives

More information

Bureaucratic Efficiency and Democratic Choice

Bureaucratic Efficiency and Democratic Choice Bureaucratic Efficiency and Democratic Choice Randy Cragun December 12, 2012 Results from comparisons of inequality databases (including the UN-WIDER data) and red tape and corruption indices (such as

More information

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS 5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS We studied how individual consumers and rms behave in Part I of the book. In Part II of the book, we studied how individual economic agents make decisions when there are strategic

More information

Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior

Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior CHAPTER 3 CONSUMER THEORY Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior Premises of the model: 1.Individual tastes or preferences determine the amount of pleasure people derive from the goods and services they

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

Endogenous choice of decision variables

Endogenous choice of decision variables Endogenous choice of decision variables Attila Tasnádi MTA-BCE Lendület Strategic Interactions Research Group, Department of Mathematics, Corvinus University of Budapest June 4, 2012 Abstract In this paper

More information

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS 2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS JEL Classification: H21,H3,H41,H43 Keywords: Second best, excess burden, public input. Remarks 1. A version of this chapter has been accepted

More information

Econ205 Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus Chapter 1

Econ205 Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus Chapter 1 Econ205 Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus Chapter 1 Margaux Luflade May 1st, 2016 Contents I Basic consumer theory 3 1 Overview 3 1.1 What?................................................. 3 1.1.1

More information

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand Economics 101 Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand 1 Intro First, a note on wealth and endowment. Varian generally uses wealth (m) instead of endowment. Ultimately, these two are equivalent. Given prices p, if

More information

Chapter 3. A Consumer s Constrained Choice

Chapter 3. A Consumer s Constrained Choice Chapter 3 A Consumer s Constrained Choice If this is coffee, please bring me some tea; but if this is tea, please bring me some coffee. Abraham Lincoln Chapter 3 Outline 3.1 Preferences 3.2 Utility 3.3

More information

Journal of College Teaching & Learning February 2007 Volume 4, Number 2 ABSTRACT

Journal of College Teaching & Learning February 2007 Volume 4, Number 2 ABSTRACT How To Teach Hicksian Compensation And Duality Using A Spreadsheet Optimizer Satyajit Ghosh, (Email: ghoshs1@scranton.edu), University of Scranton Sarah Ghosh, University of Scranton ABSTRACT Principle

More information

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

1 Two Period Exchange Economy University of British Columbia Department of Economics, Macroeconomics (Econ 502) Prof. Amartya Lahiri Handout # 2 1 Two Period Exchange Economy We shall start our exploration of dynamic economies with

More information

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) Was The New Deal Contractionary? Gauti B. Eggertsson Web Appendix VIII. Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication) ProofofProposition3:The social planner s problem at date is X min

More information

14.03 Fall 2004 Problem Set 2 Solutions

14.03 Fall 2004 Problem Set 2 Solutions 14.0 Fall 004 Problem Set Solutions October, 004 1 Indirect utility function and expenditure function Let U = x 1 y be the utility function where x and y are two goods. Denote p x and p y as respectively

More information

Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency. Problem

Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency. Problem Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency Problem Anthony M. Marino Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Los Angeles, CA 90089-1422 E-mail: amarino@usc.edu May 8,

More information

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik (http://www.sumonbhaumik.net) December 29, 2008

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik (http://www.sumonbhaumik.net) December 29, 2008 DUOPOLY MODELS Dr. Sumon Bhaumik (http://www.sumonbhaumik.net) December 29, 2008 Contents 1. Collusion in Duopoly 2. Cournot Competition 3. Cournot Competition when One Firm is Subsidized 4. Stackelberg

More information

Intro to Economic analysis

Intro to Economic analysis Intro to Economic analysis Alberto Bisin - NYU 1 The Consumer Problem Consider an agent choosing her consumption of goods 1 and 2 for a given budget. This is the workhorse of microeconomic theory. (Notice

More information

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium Online Appendix to Partnerships versus Corporations: Moral Hazard, Sorting and Ownership Structure Ayca Kaya and Galina Vereshchagina Appendix A formally defines an equilibrium in our model, Appendix B

More information

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES Structure 1.0 Objectives 1.1 Introduction 1.2 The Basic Themes 1.3 Consumer Choice Concerning Utility 1.3.1 Cardinal Theory 1.3.2 Ordinal Theory 1.3.2.1

More information

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes James E. Anderson February 6, 2009 These notes derive the useful concepts of trade expenditure functions, the closely related trade indirect utility

More information

MODULE No. : 9 : Ordinal Utility Approach

MODULE No. : 9 : Ordinal Utility Approach Subject Paper No and Title Module No and Title Module Tag 2 :Managerial Economics 9 : Ordinal Utility Approach COM_P2_M9 TABLE OF CONTENTS 1. Learning Outcomes: Ordinal Utility approach 2. Introduction:

More information

ECON 5113 Advanced Microeconomics

ECON 5113 Advanced Microeconomics Test 1 February 1, 008 carefully and provide answers to what you are asked only. Do not spend time on what you are not asked to do. Remember to put your name on the front page. 1. Let be a preference relation

More information

INDIVIDUAL AND HOUSEHOLD WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR PUBLIC GOODS JOHN QUIGGIN

INDIVIDUAL AND HOUSEHOLD WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR PUBLIC GOODS JOHN QUIGGIN This version 3 July 997 IDIVIDUAL AD HOUSEHOLD WILLIGESS TO PAY FOR PUBLIC GOODS JOH QUIGGI American Journal of Agricultural Economics, forthcoming I would like to thank ancy Wallace and two anonymous

More information

Lecture Note 7 Linking Compensated and Uncompensated Demand: Theory and Evidence. David Autor, MIT Department of Economics

Lecture Note 7 Linking Compensated and Uncompensated Demand: Theory and Evidence. David Autor, MIT Department of Economics Lecture Note 7 Linking Compensated and Uncompensated Demand: Theory and Evidence David Autor, MIT Department of Economics 1 1 Normal, Inferior and Giffen Goods The fact that the substitution effect is

More information

Comparative statics of monopoly pricing

Comparative statics of monopoly pricing Economic Theory 16, 465 469 (2) Comparative statics of monopoly pricing Tim Baldenius 1 Stefan Reichelstein 2 1 Graduate School of Business, Columbia University, New York, NY 127, USA (e-mail: tb171@columbia.edu)

More information

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics Ram Singh October 4, 015 This Write-up is available at photocopy shop. Not for circulation. In this write-up we provide intuition behind the two fundamental theorems

More information

Chapter URL:

Chapter URL: This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Effect of Education on Efficiency in Consumption Volume Author/Editor: Robert T. Michael

More information

HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTION AND WELFARE EVALUATION WITH NON-CONSTANT RETURNS TO SCALE. DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS CALIFORNIA STATE UNIVERSITY, LONG BEACH

HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTION AND WELFARE EVALUATION WITH NON-CONSTANT RETURNS TO SCALE. DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS CALIFORNIA STATE UNIVERSITY, LONG BEACH HOUSEHOLD PRODUCTION AND WELFARE EVALUATION WITH NON-CONSTANT RETURNS TO SCALE. J. F. SCOGGINS DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS CALIFORNIA STATE UNIVERSITY, LONG BEACH January 1986 The views expressed here belong

More information

Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage

Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage 1 Introduction Central questions: What determines the pattern of trade? Who trades what with whom and at what prices? The pattern of trade is based on comparative

More information

UTILITY THEORY AND WELFARE ECONOMICS

UTILITY THEORY AND WELFARE ECONOMICS UTILITY THEORY AND WELFARE ECONOMICS Learning Outcomes At the end of the presentation, participants should be able to: 1. Explain the concept of utility and welfare economics 2. Describe the measurement

More information

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712 Prof. James Peck Fall 06 Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 87. (30 points) A decision maker (DM) is a von Neumann-Morgenstern expected utility maximizer.

More information

Practice Problems: First-Year M. Phil Microeconomics, Consumer and Producer Theory Vincent P. Crawford, University of Oxford Michaelmas Term 2010

Practice Problems: First-Year M. Phil Microeconomics, Consumer and Producer Theory Vincent P. Crawford, University of Oxford Michaelmas Term 2010 Practice Problems: First-Year M. Phil Microeconomics, Consumer and Producer Theory Vincent P. Crawford, University of Oxford Michaelmas Term 2010 Problems from Mas-Colell, Whinston, and Green, Microeconomic

More information

Consumption and Saving

Consumption and Saving Chapter 4 Consumption and Saving 4.1 Introduction Thus far, we have focussed primarily on what one might term intratemporal decisions and how such decisions determine the level of GDP and employment at

More information

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis The main goal of Chapter 8 was to describe business cycles by presenting the business cycle facts. This and the following three

More information

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

We will make several assumptions about these preferences: Lecture 5 Consumer Behavior PREFERENCES The Digital Economist In taking a closer at market behavior, we need to examine the underlying motivations and constraints affecting the consumer (or households).

More information

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 2

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 2 Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak Lecture 2 The Utility Function, Examples of Utility Functions: Normal Good, Perfect Substitutes, Perfect Complements, The Quasilinear and Homothetic Utility Functions,

More information

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University April 12, 2008 Abstract A model of mixed oligopoly is constructed in which a Home public firm

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017 The time limit for this exam is four hours. The exam has four sections. Each section includes two questions.

More information

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box Paolo Crosetto paolo.crosetto@unimi.it DEAS - University of Milan Exercises solved in class on March 15th, 2010 Recap: pure exchange The simplest model of a general equilibrium

More information

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley Theoretical Tools of Public Finance 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley 1 THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL TOOLS Theoretical tools: The set of tools designed to understand the mechanics

More information

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, 2016 1. In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) cost. To investigate the consequences of markup pricing,

More information

The Effects of Specific Commodity Taxes on Output and Location of Free Entry Oligopoly

The Effects of Specific Commodity Taxes on Output and Location of Free Entry Oligopoly San Jose State University SJSU ScholarWorks Faculty Publications Economics 1-1-009 The Effects of Specific Commodity Taxes on Output and Location of Free Entry Oligopoly Yeung-Nan Shieh San Jose State

More information

Take Home Exam #2 - Answer Key. ECON 500 Summer 2004.

Take Home Exam #2 - Answer Key. ECON 500 Summer 2004. Take Home Exam # - Answer Key. ECO 500 Summer 004. ) While standing in line at your favourite movie theatre, you hear someone behind you say: like popcorn, but m not buying any because it isn t worth the

More information

Math: Deriving supply and demand curves

Math: Deriving supply and demand curves Chapter 0 Math: Deriving supply and demand curves At a basic level, individual supply and demand curves come from individual optimization: if at price p an individual or firm is willing to buy or sell

More information

Do Not Write Below Question Maximum Possible Points Score Total Points = 100

Do Not Write Below Question Maximum Possible Points Score Total Points = 100 University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2012 Ajaz Hussain TEST 2 SOLUTIONS TIME: 1 HOUR AND 50 MINUTES YOU CANNOT LEAVE THE EXAM ROOM DURING THE LAST 10 MINUTES OF THE TEST. PLEASE

More information

Homework # 2 EconS501 [Due on Sepetember 7th, 2018] Instructor: Ana Espinola-Arredondo

Homework # 2 EconS501 [Due on Sepetember 7th, 2018] Instructor: Ana Espinola-Arredondo Homework # 2 EconS501 [Due on Sepetember 7th, 2018] Instructor: Ana Espinola-Arredondo 1 Consuming organic food Consider an individual with utility function ux 1, x 2 = ln x 1 + x 2, where x 1 and x 2

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

Income and Efficiency in Incomplete Markets

Income and Efficiency in Incomplete Markets Income and Efficiency in Incomplete Markets by Anil Arya John Fellingham Jonathan Glover Doug Schroeder Richard Young April 1996 Ohio State University Carnegie Mellon University Income and Efficiency in

More information

A simple proof of the efficiency of the poll tax

A simple proof of the efficiency of the poll tax A simple proof of the efficiency of the poll tax Michael Smart Department of Economics University of Toronto June 30, 1998 Abstract This note reviews the problems inherent in using the sum of compensating

More information

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts

Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Trade Agreements as Endogenously Incomplete Contracts Henrik Horn (Research Institute of Industrial Economics, Stockholm) Giovanni Maggi (Princeton University) Robert W. Staiger (Stanford University and

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation May 1, 1997 On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation Yoshitsugu Kanemoto 1 Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo 7-3-1 Hongo, Bunkyo-ku, Tokyo 113 Japan Abstract The most important drawback

More information

Expenditure minimization

Expenditure minimization These notes are rough; this is mostly in order to get them out before the homework is due. If you would like things polished/clarified, please let me know. Ependiture minimization Until this point we have

More information

Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises

Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises C H A P T E R 0 Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises 0A Answers for Section A: Graphical Preliminaries Exercise 0A.1 Consider the set [0,1) which includes the point 0, all the

More information

Chapter 3 Dynamic Consumption-Savings Framework

Chapter 3 Dynamic Consumption-Savings Framework Chapter 3 Dynamic Consumption-Savings Framework We just studied the consumption-leisure model as a one-shot model in which individuals had no regard for the future: they simply worked to earn income, all

More information

Marginal Utility, Utils Total Utility, Utils

Marginal Utility, Utils Total Utility, Utils Mr Sydney Armstrong ECN 1100 Introduction to Microeconomics Lecture Note (5) Consumer Behaviour Evidence indicated that consumers can fulfill specific wants with succeeding units of a commodity but that

More information

CONSUMPTION THEORY - first part (Varian, chapters 2-7)

CONSUMPTION THEORY - first part (Varian, chapters 2-7) QUESTIONS for written exam in microeconomics. Only one answer is correct. CONSUMPTION THEORY - first part (Varian, chapters 2-7) 1. Antonio buys only two goods, cigarettes and bananas. The cost of 1 packet

More information

1 Excess burden of taxation

1 Excess burden of taxation 1 Excess burden of taxation 1. In a competitive economy without externalities (and with convex preferences and production technologies) we know from the 1. Welfare Theorem that there exists a decentralized

More information

Price Changes and Consumer Welfare

Price Changes and Consumer Welfare Price Changes and Consumer Welfare While the basic theory previously considered is extremely useful as a tool for analysis, it is also somewhat restrictive. The theory of consumer choice is often referred

More information

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK! University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS TIME: 1 HOUR AND 50 MINUTES DO NOT HAVE A CELL PHONE ON YOUR DESK OR ON YOUR PERSON. ONLY AID ALLOWED: A

More information

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Static Games and Cournot. Competition Static Games and Cournot Competition Lecture 3: Static Games and Cournot Competition 1 Introduction In the majority of markets firms interact with few competitors oligopoly market Each firm has to consider

More information

Oligopoly Games and Voting Games. Cournot s Model of Quantity Competition:

Oligopoly Games and Voting Games. Cournot s Model of Quantity Competition: Oligopoly Games and Voting Games Cournot s Model of Quantity Competition: Supposetherearetwofirms, producing an identical good. (In his 1838 book, Cournot thought of firms filling bottles with mineral

More information

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Transport Costs and North-South Trade Transport Costs and North-South Trade Didier Laussel a and Raymond Riezman b a GREQAM, University of Aix-Marseille II b Department of Economics, University of Iowa Abstract We develop a simple two country

More information

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations? Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 7, 0. Consider an individual faced with two job choices: she can either accept a position with a fixed annual salary of x > 0 which requires L x units of labor

More information

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A.

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A. THE INVISIBLE HAND OF PIRACY: AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE INFORMATION-GOODS SUPPLY CHAIN Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A. {antino@iu.edu}

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

Economics II - Exercise Session # 3, October 8, Suggested Solution

Economics II - Exercise Session # 3, October 8, Suggested Solution Economics II - Exercise Session # 3, October 8, 2008 - Suggested Solution Problem 1: Assume a person has a utility function U = XY, and money income of $10,000, facing an initial price of X of $10 and

More information

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section -2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply Matteo Paradisi September 3, 206 In today s section, we will briefly review the

More information

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions Journal of Economics and Management, 2018, Vol. 14, No. 1, 1-31 License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions Masahiko Hattori Faculty

More information

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20135 Theory of Finance, Part I (Sept. October) Fall 2014 Outline and objectives The backward, three-step solution

More information

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE Solutions and Activities for CHAPTER 2 THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE Questions and Problems 1. The price of a bus trip is $1 and the price of a gallon of gas (at the time of this writing!) is $3.

More information

PRODUCTION COSTS. Econ 311 Microeconomics 1 Lecture Material Prepared by Dr. Emmanuel Codjoe

PRODUCTION COSTS. Econ 311 Microeconomics 1 Lecture Material Prepared by Dr. Emmanuel Codjoe PRODUCTION COSTS In this section we introduce production costs into the analysis of the firm. So far, our emphasis has been on the production process without any consideration of costs. However, production

More information

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis EC 202 Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I George Symeonidis Oligopoly When only a small number of firms compete in the same market, each firm has some market power. Moreover, their interactions cannot be ignored.

More information

Solutions to Assignment #2

Solutions to Assignment #2 ECON 20 (Fall 207) Department of Economics, SFU Prof. Christoph Lülfesmann exam). Solutions to Assignment #2 (My suggested solutions are usually more detailed than required in an I. Short Problems. The

More information

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries

Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries BACKGROUND PAPER FOR THE WORLD DEVELOPMENT REPORT 2008 Income distribution and the allocation of public agricultural investment in developing countries Larry Karp The findings, interpretations, and conclusions

More information

A Course in Environmental Economics: Theory, Policy, and Practice. Daniel J. Phaneuf and Till Requate

A Course in Environmental Economics: Theory, Policy, and Practice. Daniel J. Phaneuf and Till Requate 1 A Course in Environmental Economics: Theory, Policy, and Practice PART I: ECONOMICS AND THE ENVIRONMENT Daniel J. Phaneuf and Till Requate 1. Introduction to the Theory of Externalities 1.1 Market failure

More information

Lecture Demand Functions

Lecture Demand Functions Lecture 6.1 - Demand Functions 14.03 Spring 2003 1 The effect of price changes on Marshallian demand A simple change in the consumer s budget (i.e., an increase or decrease or I) involves a parallel shift

More information

cahier n Two -part pricing, public discriminating monopoly and redistribution: a note par Philippe Bernard & Jérôme Wittwer Octobre 2001

cahier n Two -part pricing, public discriminating monopoly and redistribution: a note par Philippe Bernard & Jérôme Wittwer Octobre 2001 cahier n 2001-06 Two -part pricing, public discriminating monopoly and redistribution: a note par Philippe Bernard & Jérôme Wittwer EURIsCO Université Paris Dauphine Octobre 2001 LEO Univérsité d Orléans

More information

Forward Contracts and Generator Market Power: How Externalities Reduce Benefits in Equilibrium

Forward Contracts and Generator Market Power: How Externalities Reduce Benefits in Equilibrium Forward Contracts and Generator Market Power: How Externalities Reduce Benefits in Equilibrium Ian Schneider, Audun Botterud, and Mardavij Roozbehani November 9, 2017 Abstract Research has shown that forward

More information

AAEC 6524: Environmental Economic Theory and Policy Analysis. Outline. Introduction to Non-Market Valuation Part A. Klaus Moeltner Spring 2017

AAEC 6524: Environmental Economic Theory and Policy Analysis. Outline. Introduction to Non-Market Valuation Part A. Klaus Moeltner Spring 2017 AAEC 6524: Environmental Economic Theory and Policy Analysis to Non-Market Valuation Part A Klaus Moeltner Spring 207 March 4, 207 / 38 Outline 2 / 38 Methods to estimate damage and cost functions needed

More information