Direct elicitation of credit constraints: Conceptual and practical issues with an empirical application to Peruvian agriculture

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Direct elicitation of credit constraints: Conceptual and practical issues with an empirical application to Peruvian agriculture"

Transcription

1 Direct elicitation of credit constraints: Conceptual and practical issues with an empirical application to Peruvian agriculture Steve Boucher Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of California Davis One Shields Avenue, Davis, CA Catherine Guirkinger University of California Davis Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of California Davis One Shields Avenue, Davis, CA Carolina Trivelli Instituto de Estudios Peruanos Horacio Arteaga 694, Jesús María, Lima, Peru Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the American Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, Providence, Rhode Island, July 24-27, 2005 Copyright 2005 by Steve Boucher, Catherine Guirkinger and Carolina Trivelli. All rights reserved. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that this copyright notice appears on such copies.

2 1. Introduction Credit market imperfections are frequently cited as a primary impediment to efficient resource allocation in developing economies. As described by Petrick (2005) and Diagne, Zeller and Sharma (2000), two broad methods have been employed to empirically identify the importance of credit rationing. In the indirect method, researchers use assets or some other measured variable to divide the sample into groups that are more and less likely to be rationed. An Euler equation is then estimated. The dependence of consumption patterns on transitory income shocks is taken as evidence of imperfect access to (consumption) credit (Zeldes 1989). Thus in this indirect method, consumption and resource allocation decisions are used to backout the incidence of credit rationing. The direct method, in a sense, reverses the order of analysis. Researchers first attempt to directly measure whether or not a household is credit rationed and then evaluate the impact of the constraint by estimating a second stage equation (for example restricted profit or yield) that provides a household specific measure of the shadow value of capital (Feder et. al. 1990, Petrick 2004). While this method is perhaps more attractive because a broad range of impact questions can be addressed via the second stage estimation, its validity is crucially dependent upon both the conceptual definition of the credit constraint and the accuracy with which constrained households are identified in the first stage. In addition, data requirements are steep as both traditional survey data on consumption, production, and costs as well as non-traditional data on individuals perceptions of credit markets must be collected. Currently, there is little agreement in the literature regarding either how credit rationing should be defined or how to empirically identify rationed households. 1

3 The primary contribution of this paper is methodological. The specific goals of this paper are three-fold. First, we provide a general discussion of the concept of credit rationing. This discussion is important because differences in empirical strategies for measuring credit constraints can originate in definitional differences. To facilitate this discussion we develop a simple model to demonstrate that asymmetric information can give rise to three different mechanisms of non-price rationing quantity, transaction costs, and risk. Most empirical studies limit their definition of constrained households to those facing quantity rationing which is essentially a binding supply-side constraint. We argue, however, that this definition is incomplete as the consequences of asymmetric information may take the form of demand-side constraints associated with transaction costs and risk rationing. Second, we describe and suggest strategies for dealing with the empirical challenges associated with identifying an individual s, a household s, or a firm s rationing mechanism and constraint status. Third, we use a unique data set from Peru to estimate the determinants of credit rationing. The data set allows us to use different methods for classifying households as rationed and thus allows us to test the sensitivity of parameter estimates to choice of classification method. 2. Non-price Rationing: A Conceptual Framework In this section we develop a simple model of a credit market and activity choice. The goal is not to develop any new theoretical result, but instead to introduce and motivate the conceptual categories of non-price rationing we use in the empirical sections that follow. 1 Consider the following stylized model of credit demand and activity choice. A farmer owns T acres of land and produces with a Leontief style technology requiring a fixed investment 1 For recent reviews of the theoretical literature on quantity rationing see Ghatak, Mookherjee, and Ray (2002) and Udry and Conning (2005). 2

4 per-acre which, for simplicity, we will assume is $1. The farmer has no liquidity and thus requires a loan to finance production. The value of the farmer s non-liquid assets, including land and machinery, is A. To introduce uncertainty, we assume there are two possible states of nature success and failure that occur with probabilities p and 1-p respectively. Revenue per unit land under success is Y and under failure is 0. The farmer s reservation activity is to rent out the land and earn a certain rent of w per unit land. Risk neutral lenders operate in a perfectly competitive market and have an opportunity cost of capital equal to 1+γ. Assume that py > 1 +! + w so that, in a first-best world, the farmer would always seek a loan and undertake production. 2.1 Symmetric Information and the First-Best We begin by assuming that lenders can costlessly observe all relevant borrower characteristics and actions i.e., they do not confront moral hazard or adverse selection. A credit contract then specifies the borrower s repayment obligation under each state. Letting i denote the interest rate and k the per-unit land collateral requirement, the borrower repays (1+i)T under success and Tk under failure. The borrower s consumption in state j, C j, is thus: (1) # A + T[ Y $ (1 + i)] C j = "! A $ Tk if if j = success j = failure In turn, the lender s return per-hectare, R j, is: (2) R # i $ % = j "! k $ (1 + % ) if if j = success j = failure 3

5 In a world of symmetric information the optimal contract (1+i *, k * ) solves the following program: (3) Max 1+ i, k EU ( C ) Subject to : (3a) 1+ $ 1" p 1+ i # " k p p (3b) kt! A j where the first constraint ensures that the lender earns non-negative profits and the second constraint acknowledges that, at most, the borrower can post collateral worth A. Using equation (1) in the above program, it is easy to show that the optimal contract in a first-best world would allow the borrower to earn the entire surplus (constraint (3a) binds) and allow the borrower to equate marginal utility and thus consumption across states of nature. This simple model highlights the dual functions of the credit market as both provider of liquidity and, potentially, insurance. In this first best world, risk neutral lenders are willing to trade higher interest rates for a reduction in a collateral at a constant rate of (1-p)/p. Efficient risk sharing is thus achieved with the borrower paying a relatively high interest rate while fully insuring his consumption against production risk. Thus even in the absence of a well functioning insurance market, all socially desirable investments will be made if credit markets are perfect. We denote the farmer s credit demand in this first-best world as his notional demand. 2.2 Asymmetric Information and Non-Price Rationing As is well established in the theory literature, the presence of asymmetric information between borrower and lender may significantly alter our vision of the credit market. We 4

6 incorporate asymmetric information into our stylized model by assuming that lenders require that borrowers post a minimum of k units of collateral per-unit land. In addition, we assume that posting any amount of collateral implies a fixed cost of F to the borrower. 2 As discussed elsewhere, collateral provides incentives for borrowers to take costly actions that reduce the probability of failure and thereby addresses moral hazard (Hoff and Stiglitz, 1990). Collateral may also serve as a mechanism for sorting borrowers of unobservable types (say project riskiness) and thereby may also address adverse selection (Bester, 1985). While a complete model would endogenize k, that is beyond the scope of this paper. Instead, we simply assume k exists and is the same for all borrowers. 3 The presence of asymmetric information has immediate implications for the performance of our stylized credit market. In terms of our optimization program, we must add an additional constraint: k! k. 4 While the lender is still willing to trade interest rate reductions for collateral increases at a rate of (1-p)/p, he is only willing to do so over a restricted range of contracts with sufficiently high collateral. This restriction of the feasible contract set gives rise to the first form of non-price rationing namely quantity rationing. Farmers who cannot post the minimum required collateral (A < tk) are involuntarily excluded from the credit market. Quantity rationing occurs when a farmer has a profitable project, and thus positive notional demand for credit, but faces zero supply. As pointed out by several studies (Mushinski 1999, Japelli 1990) the availability of credit is necessary but not sufficient for a farmer with positive notional demand to have positive 2 Posting collateral typically requires verification of property deeds, verification that the property is not mortgaged to another party, and the actual registration of the mortgage itself. Each of these transactions implies a trip to the property registry and a fee. 3 See Boucher and Carter (2002) for an example of a model that endogenizes the collateral requirement in a model of moral hazard. 4 Note that this constraint is essentially an incentive compatibility constraint in a model of moral hazard. 5

7 effective demand, defined as the demand for contracts available in the actually existing or asymmetric information world. First, transaction costs reduce the expected income associated with a credit contract by F. As a result, a contract yields greater expected income than the reservation activity if py > 1 +! + w + F / T. Since transaction costs are assumed fixed, the expected income per unit land earned by the borrower from a given contract is increasing in farm size. Thus holding constant productivity and risk preferences small farmers will be more likely to voluntarily withdraw from the credit market due to transaction costs. A farmer who has positive notional demand but zero effective demand because of the size of transaction costs is called transaction cost rationed. Finally, even if transaction costs were negligible, the existence of an expected income enhancing contract is still not sufficient to guarantee a positive effective demand. To see this, return to the minimum collateral requirement. Another way to think about the collateral requirement is that it forces the borrower to bear a minimum amount of risk. 5 Thus even though available contracts raise the borrower s expected consumption (compared to the reservation activity), they may lower the borrower s expected utility because they force the borrower to bear too much risk. In this case the borrower is risk rationed he has access to an expected income enhancing contract but chooses to voluntarily withdraw from the credit market to instead undertake the lower return but certain reservation activity. If we assume zero transaction costs, then there will exist an agent with assets A * (T) who for a given farm size -- is indifferent between his credit contract and the reservation activity. Let r(a * ) denote this borrower s risk premium (per unit land) associated with the minimum 5 Indeed this is the intuition behind incentive compatibility under moral hazard. By requiring collateral, a lender forces borrowers to internalize the consequences of actions they take that influence the probability distribution of project returns. 6

8 collateral contract. Then, by definition, * r ( A ) = py! (1 + " )! w. Any farmer with a lower risk premium would strictly prefer the minimum collateral contract while those with a higher risk premium would instead prefer the reservation activity. Thus if we assume farmers risk preferences are described by decreasing absolute risk aversion, we conclude that, holding farm size constant, poorer borrowers those with A < A * -- will be more likely to be risk rationed. 6 To summarize, we have seen that asymmetric information can give rise to three types of non-price rationing. The first, quantity rationing, is perhaps the most obvious and has been emphasized in both the theory and empirical literature. Quantity rationing is solely a supply side phenomenon. In our simple model of fixed investment, it is defined by an empty feasible contract set. In general, quantity rationing occurs when a borrower s effective demand exceeds supply. In contrast, both transaction cost and risk rationing, which are defined conditional on a non-empty contract set, bring in the demand side. Any evaluation of the performance of credit markets should thus attempt to account for all three forms of non-price rationing. How to classify households into the appropriate rationing category is the task to which we now turn. 3. Measuring Credit Constraints a Practical Approach In this section we discuss the issues involved in classifying households as unconstrained (price rationed) versus constrained (non-price rationed) and, how we can further distinguish between supply-side (quantity) versus demand-side (risk or transaction costs) rationing mechanisms among constrained households. The discussion here essentially outlines variants of the strategy used in several household surveys, including the survey in Peru which will be the basis for the empirical analysis of section 4. 6 Note that if we allow for full endogeneity of contract terms to borrower wealth, this need not occur. As shown by Newman (1995) and Thiele and Wambagh (1999), the relatively wealthy may be more likely to be risk rationed. 7

9 3.1 Defining Constraint Categories Let E Di and N Di denote, respectively, the effective and notional demands for credit of household i. Similarly, let S i denote the maximum amount of credit a formal lender is willing to supply to the same household. The conceptual discussion from section 2 implies that a household (or individual or firm) will fall into one of three mutually exclusive categories: unconstrained, supply-side constrained, and demand-side constrained. We describe each in turn. Unconstrained, or price-rationed, households are unaffected by asymmetric information in credit markets. The following relationship holds for unconstrained households: ( C 1) D = D! S E i N i i While asymmetric information may imply that lenders impose a credit limit, this limit will not be binding for unconstrained households. Depending on their endowments and opportunities, E unconstrained households may be either borrowers ( D > 0 ) or non-borrowers. Resource allocation decisions of unconstrained households are unaffected by information asymmetries. Supply-side constrained, or quantity rationed, households face a binding credit limit and are characterized by the following relationship: i ( C 2) S < D! D i E i N i Note that while asymmetric information may reduce these households effective demand relative to their notional demand, the limiting constraint comes from the supply side. As such, we expect these households to demonstrate an expression of excess demand in the real world. We will deal with the question of how to capture this expression in the next section. 8

10 Finally, demand-side constrained households do not face a binding credit limit and thus do not express any excess demand for credit. They are described by the following two relationships: ( C 3) D < D and D! S E i N i E i i The risk sharing rules of the contract or the transaction costs associated with loan application drive a wedge between their notional and effective demand so that they are demand-side rationed. The primary empirical challenge is thus to distinguish demand-side constrained from unconstrained households. Neither expresses any excess demand, yet the former group s effective demand and thus also their resource allocation is adversely affected by asymmetric information in credit markets. 3.2 Operationalization of Constraint Categories Our overall goal is to identify whether or not a given household is constrained in the credit market. The discussion above indicates that the binding constraint may derive either from the supply or the demand side. In either case, the mechanism by which the household is rationed in the credit market is not price. In the case of a supply-side constraint, the rationing mechanism is quantity while in the case of a demand-side constraint the mechanism is either transaction costs or risk. We now turn to operationalizing the classification scheme described above. We begin with supply-side constrained households. Essentially, condition (C2) will hold if a household received less than its desired amount of credit given the available contract terms. In identifying these supply-side constrained households from survey data, it is useful to distinguish three separate groups. The first supply-side constrained group is unsatisfied borrowers, who apply for 9

11 and receive a loan, however the loan amount is less than their effective demand. The second group is rejected applicants, who have positive effective demand but a zero credit limit. The final supply-side constrained group is certainly-rejected non-applicants, who have positive effective demand but do not apply for a loan because based on past experience or their perceptions of lenders supply rules they are certain their loan application would be rejcted. Although each of these three groups is supply-constrained, given the typical structure of household surveys, their identification relies on different sets of questions. Figures 1 and 2 provide examples of the types of questions required to identify these three groups. Figure 1 shows several questions from the loan characteristics table. Note that the unit of observation (i.e. the row) is the received loan itself. The response to question 5 allows us to identify unsatisfied borrowers. There are two details to note in the formulation of this question. First, the borrower is asked to compare the amount received to the amount that he/she wanted. While it might seem intuitive to compare the amount received with the amount applied for, this would be problematic since the borrower may know the lender s supply rule and thus only ask for the amount they qualify for, even though this amount is less than their effective demand. The second thing to note is that the question must emphasize that the desired amount is conditional upon the interest rate available. Finally, although not essential for our present purpose of binary categorization of constraint status, question 5 can be followed by a question that asks the desired loan size. This would then identify a point on the borrower s demand curve and is thus useful for answering a different set of question such as the shadow value of liquidity. Since neither rejected applicants nor certainly-rejected non-applicants received a loan, the information from the loan characteristics table (Figure 1) provides no information about their constraint status. Instead, we turn to Figure 2, which describes non-borrowers experience in and 10

12 perceptions of the loan market of interest. After completing the loan characteristics table, enumerators determine whether or not the household had any loans from the sector of interest and, if not, the enumerator would apply the survey module depicted in Figure 2. The primary objective of this module is to sort all non-borrowers into their constraint category. Question 2 differentiates rejected applicants from non-applicants. Our second group of supply-side constrained households is thus identified by their response to this question. A specific issue is the time frame specified in this question. If a household s credit limit were time invariant, then the appropriate question would be whether or not the household has ever been rejected. If, as is more likely, the credit limit changes over time then a shorter recall period is preferable. Questions 3, 4, and 5 are again not necessary for the binary constraint classification, however they provide quantitative information on loan demand as well as qualitative information on perceived reasons for loan rejection. The third supply-side constrained group was the certainly rejected non-applicants. As these are non-borrowers, we again use this module to classify these households constraint status. To do so, the enumerator first asks question 6 to see if the household believes it could get a loan. If yes, then we know that the household is not supply-side constrained. If no, the enumerator continues with the hypothetical question 9: If you were certain that a lender would approve your application, would you apply? If yes, then the household is classified as constrained. One specific issue to be aware of is the wording of question 9. Notice that we do not ask would you accept a loan if you were offered one? The reason is that the word offered may imply that the respondent need not incur the costs of application. We now turn to identifying demand-side constrained households. We begin by noting that, as in the case of supply-side constraints, demand-side constrained households can be either 11

13 borrowers or non-borrowers. In line with the conceptual discussion of section 2, there are two main reasons why a borrower s effective demand may be less than his or her notional demand, namely transaction costs and contractual risk. Since transaction costs associated with loan application tend to have an important fixed component, we expect that, among borrowers, risk is likely to be more important than transaction costs in impacting effective demand. In practice, it is very difficult to distinguish risk rationed (demand-constrained) borrowers from unconstrained borrowers. To do so requires capturing how the amount demanded would be affected by changes in risk sharing rules while holding constant the borrower s expected monetary return from the contract. Essentially, this would require asking if loan demand would increase if collateral were reduced as interest rate was increased. This approach is problematic since collateral is difficult, if not impossible, to adjust at the margin (i.e. it is not feasible to put up only nine-tenths of a farm parcel). As a result, this then requires asking about demand under a contract with zero collateral and a relatively high interest rate. Our experience has shown that responses to this type of approach do not capture the desired information. Farmers were highly skeptical (and rightly so!) about banks that might offer a zero-collateral loan. One respondent summed up this problem as follows: I d be crazy to take a loan from a bank that doesn t ask for my land that would not be a serious institution so who knows what problems I might get into? In our judgement, then, attempting to identify the group of risk rationed borrowers may not be worthwhile. While the cost of doing so is high, the benefit is likely to be low in the sense that the resource allocation of risk rationed borrowers is likely to differ little compared to unconstrained borrowers. On one hand, as pointed out by several theoretical models, when contract terms are endogenous to borrower characteristics, smaller, less risky loans are not made available by lenders because lenders require the borrower to bear a certain amount of risk to 12

14 overcome moral hazard in borrower effort or project choice (Newman 1995). In addition, and as mentioned above, collateral assets are typically very lumpy and cannot be marginally adjusted. Thus by taking a slightly smaller loan, the borrower cannot reduce their loss under default. Finally, in practice, there may be little scope for varying loan size as many agricultural lenders offer boilerplate, or formulaic, loan contracts in which loan size is a fixed multiple of area cultivated. The second type of demand-side constrained households, and the ones we focus on here, is demand-side constrained non-applicants. Again Figure 2 provides information to classify these non-applicant households. Non-applicants are first divided into those who believe they would be offered a loan if they applied (answer Yes to question 6) and those who would not be offered a loan (answer No to question 6). We classify this first group into demand-side constrained versus unconstrained by following up with question 7 which asks why given that they could get a loan they did not apply for one. Table 1 provides a sample of the most common responses to this question and their subsequent classification as constrained or unconstrained. Households are classified as unconstrained if their response indicates that the expected rate of return to their investment or use of funds is less than the expected monetary costs of the loan. Households are classified as constrained if their response indicates that either risk or transaction costs were the primary reason that dissuaded them from borrowing. The second group, those who believe the lender would not approve their application, are then asked in question 9 whether they would want a loan if they were certain the lender would approve their application. As discussed above, those who say yes are the certainly-rejected non-applicants who are classified as supply-side rationed. Those who say no are then asked why. The same 13

15 types of responses as are outlined in Table 1 are then used to classify them as constrained or unconstrained. 3.3 Issues and Challenges in Classification via Direct Elicitation As suggested above, use of the direct elicitation approach requires a significant amount of information not typically collected in multi-purpose household surveys. Thus the time and resources required to successfully implement the approach are non-trivial. In this section we raise and discuss three general issues that arise in utilizing the method. Issue 1: Definition of Loan Sectors There are two main reasons to define distinct sectors or segments of the credit market and to then cast the language of the qualitative questions in Figure 2 with respect to these sectors. First, if the terms of credit contracts differ systematically across types of lenders, then households may have a clear preference ordering with respect to loan source. A household could then be constrained with respect to their preferred loan source but unconstrained with respect to less preferred sources. To classify this household as constrained, we need to dinstinguish between the two loan sources. In general, if there exists a clear hierarchy across lender types, at a minimum we should apply the classification methodology to determine constraint status with respect to the most preferred sector. For example, in a study of rural credit markets in India, Bell, Udry and Srinivasan (1997) assume that loans from the formal sector (agricultural cooperatives) are, if available, strictly preferred to informal loans from traders. As such, any household observed with an informal loan can be classified as constrained with respect to the formal sector. 14

16 The second, and perhaps more obvious, reason to define and refer to loan sectors is that the researcher may have sector (or even institution) specific hypotheses. For example, we might be interested in evaluating a policy that affects a certain type of institution. Mushinsky (1999) evaluates the impact of market oriented reforms implemented by credit unions in Guatemala on the prevalence of non-price rationing in the credit unions. We also might be interested in testing the existence of a preference hierarchy across loan sectors. Kochar (1997), for example, questions the assumption that the formal loan sector is the most preferred sector. A sector specific application of this method would be useful in this case. The most common sectoral definition are formal and informal. The distinction between formal versus informal sectors may be based on many alternative lender characteristics. Common criteria include: Is the lender regulated? Does the lender lend for profit? Is the lender specialized in financial intermediation? Of course the classification need not be binary. In our study of credit markets in rural Peru, we distinguish amongst four types of regulated lending institutions: commercial banks, municipal banks, rural banks, and finance companies. While each of these institutions is regulated by the central bank, there are differences in the specific rules and regulations that apply to each type. No matter what sectoral definition is chosen, the researcher needs to formulate clear rules so that the enumerators consistently assign lenders into the appropriate sector, enabling them to correctly apply the sequence of questions described above (for example, see question 3 of Figure 1). Issue 2: Use of Hypothetical Questions As described above, the classification of non-applicants constraint status relies upon hypothetical questions. All non-applicants are asked if a lender would approve their loan 15

17 application if they were to apply. This question is potentially problematic for several reasons. First, this question introduces a change in the tone of the survey. Until this point in the survey, the respondent is likely to have been bombarded with factual recall questions. The enumerator now asks the respondent to change gears and think about the outcome of a loan application that was not made. Clearly communicating the idea behind this question is thus a non-trivial exercise. Beyond a clear phrasing of the question itself, effective use of this type of hypothetical question requires careful selection and training of enumerators, who may need to step outside of the literal question in order to convey the idea. Assuming the question is clearly conveyed and understood, we face an additional issue. We want to establish whether or not the household has a strictly positive credit limit. Since we rely on the respondent s perception of the lender s decision, error is introduced into the data. The consequences of this error regarding hypothetical supply are less problematic, however, than might first appear. There are two types of potential errors. Consider first overly-pessimistic non-applicants who incorrectly believe they would be rejected. If they have no effective demand, they will not be incorrectly classifies as supply-side constrained. On the other hand, if they have positive effective demand, they will appear as supply-side constrained even though a lender would approve their application. However, we do not consider this a mis-classification because the household s behavior is indeed determined by the perception of the constraint and not the actual constraint. Overly optimistic non-applicants, who incorrectly believe the lender in question would offer a loan, have no effective demand and thus would never be classified as supply-side constrained. A related issue is that in order to classify non-applicants as constrained or unconstrained we need to know whether or not they have positive effective demand which, in turn, depends 16

18 upon the household s perception of contracts available in the market. Since these non-applicant households are not participating in the credit market, they may be unfamiliar with existing terms. In pre-liberalization Peru, for example, the primary formal lender was the state development bank (Banco Agrario) which offered loan contracts with subsidized, and sometimes negative, real interest rates and did not require collateral. Many farmers have not borrowed from the formal sector since the state bank shut down in Consequently, the market conditions that these farmers have in mind when answering the question about their willingness to accept a formal loan may still be those of these highly subsidized loans. In the phrasing of the questionnaire it is essential to precisely define which institutions are included in the formal sector. The researcher may also use auxiliary information to gauge the accuracy of the respondent s perceptions. The quality of data analysis may be raised by controlling for the household s integration into the formal financial market. Useful controls include: the coverage of the formal sector in the zone, individual farmer/household credit history, general access to information at the household level, and whether or not the household has friends or family with a formal loan. A potential strategy which does not require making the assumption that farmer have strong familiarity with relevant market conditions is to add precision about a given credit product in the hypothetical questions. This solution has a fundamental drawback, however, as credit terms may differ both across borrowers and lenders so that the given contract may not reflect the contracts available to the household. Issue 3: Household versus Individual Constraint? The final issue we take up is whether the credit constraint classification should be made at the household or individual level. Up until now, we have couched the discussion at the 17

19 household level. This approach is consistent if we believe the household behaves in line with a unitary household model in which endowments and income are pooled amongst household members. Under this assumption, we would direct the qualitative questions of Table 2 to the household head, who would respond for the overall household. We implicitly assume that the head can, given the endowments and opportunities available to the household, assess the effective and notional demand of -- as well as the supply available to -- the entire household. If, in contrast, resources are not pooled within the household or information is not shared, then individual characteristics including whether or not individuals are credit constrained may impact the household s resource allocation. In this case, we would need to elicit the constraint status at the individual level. This individual approach, while costly, is useful for testing hypotheses related to gender bias in credit access and intra-household resource allocation processes. In sum, while there are many potential pitfalls in implementing the direct approach, we feel that with sufficient training and fieldwork preparation, the approach can yield reasonable classification of households (or individuals ) constraint status. In the next section we demonstrate the importance of the means used to directly elicit constraint status by carrying out an econometric exercise that examines two hypotheses regarding the determinants of credit rationing. 4. Empirical Application: Determinants of Non-Price Rationing in Piura, Peru In this section we use a data set that used the direct elicitation approach to analyze how the inclusion of demand-side constraints impacts our evaluation of the determinants of credit rationing. We will explore two particular determinants of constraint status that have been the 18

20 focus of much of the empirical literature, namely the household s wealth and the possession of a land title. Our empirical exercise compares the determinants of credit constraints across our two alternative definitions of credit constraint. The first definition which we will call the restrictive definition classifies as credit constrained only those households that are supply-side constrained. According to this restrictive definition, a household is classified as constrained if and only if condition C2 holds (i.e. the household s effective demand exceeds available supply). The second and we feel more appropriate definition classifies a household as constrained if it is constrained either from the supply or demand side. This definition, which we call the comprehensive definition, classifies a household as constrained if either condition C2 or C3 holds. Our objective is not to separate the impact of explanatory variables on credit supply and on credit demand, but instead to evaluate their effect on the probability that a household is credit constrained under the alternative constraint definitions. Therefore, we estimate a reduced form logit equation with the binary credit constraint status as the dependent variable. We carry out the estimation twice first constructing the households constraint status using the restrictive definition and then using the comprehensive definition. The analysis of the determinants of credit constraints answers important questions in and of itself. It also corresponds to the first stage of many studies aimed at evaluating the impact of credit constraints on household-specific outcomes. Indeed, in order to control for potential selection bias in the estimation of the impact equation, a selection model needs to be estimated. Feder et. al. (1992), Carter and Olinto (2003) and Foltz (2004) provide examples of this general approach in studies analyzing impacts of credit constraint on investment or 19

21 productivity. We focus on two determinants of credit constraints that have been the focus of the empirical literature: household wealth and the possession of a land title. 4.1 Title, Wealth, and Credit Constraints We first examine the relationship between the probability of being credit constrained and the possession of a land title. As summarized by Besley (1995), there are two main mechanisms by which gaining access to a title may affect a household s credit market participation. First, titled land may be offered as collateral and thus may loosen a binding supply-side constraint. Second, by enhancing tenure security and reducing the transaction costs of land transactions, a title may increase a household s investment demand. A household that was previously discouraged from borrowing by risk or transaction costs, may upon receipt of a title -- seek a loan so that their constraint status may change. In our context of northern Peru, land tenure is secure and independent of title. We anticipate, then, that at least in our context the primary mechanism by which title may affect a household s credit constraint status is via relaxing supplyconstraints. As such, we expect that while possession of a land title will reduce the probability of being credit constrained under both the restrictive and comprehensive constraint definitions, the impact will be larger using the restrictive (supply-side) definition. The second explanatory variable we focus on is household wealth. As in the case of title, there are multiple mechanisms by which a household s wealth (holding title constant) may impact its constraint status. If household wealth is observable to lenders, it may be taken as a positive signal of capacity to repay both because high current wealth is likely to be positively correlated with the household s ability and the quality of their investment projects. Wealthier households are also likely to be less affected by demand-side constraints. If total wealth is 20

22 positively correlated with the size or scale of a household s productive activities as is certainly the case in rural areas where farmland is the most important asset then fixed transaction costs are less likely to deter wealthier households from applying for loans than poor households. Under the assumption of decreasing absolute risk aversion, wealthier households would, holding constant the risk-sharing rules of credit contracts, be less likely to be risk rationed than poorer households. 7 Given that lower wealth households are more likely to be demand-side constrained, this discussion suggests that the impact of using the restrictive instead of comprehensive constraint definition on the estimated probability of credit rationing is likely to be decreasing in household wealth. 4.2 Econometric model We examine the relationships discussed above by estimating a reduced form logit model. Let C i indicate the credit constraint status of household i, taking value 1 if the household is constrained and 0 otherwise. The probability that a household is constrained is:! ' X i e ( 4) Pr( C i = 1) =! ' 1+ e where: X i ; ( 5) ' $ 0 + $ 1 * TITLEi + $ 2 % X = * WEALTH + # ' H + "' Z +! i i i i TITLE i is a dummy variable that takes the value one if the household owns at least one parcel with a registered property title. WEALTH i is the value of household s wealth and includes the value of residential land, farm and business assets, household durables, and financial assets. H i 7 If, however, contract terms are endogenous to borrower wealth, then it is possible that wealthier households are more likely to be risk rationed than poor households. This general theoretical point is made by Thiele and Wambaugh (1999). Boucher and Carter (2003) show this result in the case of credit contracts. 21

23 is a vector of household characteristics including the area of owned farm land, household size, education of the household head, and the dependency ratio. Z i is a vector of geographic and year variables. Finally, α 0, α 1, α 2, γ, and λ, are parameters to be estimated. As will be described shortly, the data used for estimation come from a panel of household surveys. This allows us to estimate the model in two ways: a logit on the pooled sample with cluster robust standard errors; and a conditional or fixed effects -- logit. The main advantages of the pooled estimation are that it: uses information from the full sample; allows the estimation of the coefficients associated with time invariant variables; permits the estimation of predicted probabilities and marginal impacts of the regressors. The pooled estimation, however, does not fully address the potential endogeneity problems that arise in our context. In particular, we are concerned about a potential bias in our estimates of α 1 and α 2 the coefficients associated with title and wealth that may arise if unobserved characteristics such as land quality, past credit history or the aptitude to deal with loan paperwork impact both the probability of being constrained and the household s wealth. While we partially address this issue by including regressors that capture some aspects of credit history (one dummy to indicate whether the household ever used formal credit and another to indicate if the household ever defaulted) and farmer ability (education and farm experience), unobserved heterogeneity remains a concern as we do not have controls for land quality. The fixed-effect logit estimation produces parameter estimates that are robust to biases introduced by time invariant unobserved factors and therefore addresses the issue of the endogeneity of title and wealth as long as the source of this endogeneity is time-invariant. The fixed-effect logit, however, has two drawbacks. First, since parameter estimates are identified by the subset of households that change rationing status over time, the sample size is reduced. If the cross- 22

24 sectional sample size is small as in our case the inability to use the full sample information may be costly. Second, because consistent estimates of the household fixed effect cannot be computed, neither marginal effects nor predicted probabilities of being constrained can be calculated. 4.3 Data and context The data come from a survey administered to farm households in 1997 and again in 2003 in the department of Piura, on Peru s north coast. The sample was drawn from the comprehensive lists maintained by the irrigation commissions (comisiones de regantes) and is representative of irrigated, commercial agriculture in the department. 8 Of the original 547 households surveyed in 1997, 499 were resurveyed in The empirical analysis in this paper is based on these 499 households. In addition to conventional demographic and production modules, the survey contains a section, similar to the one described in Section 3, that explores in-depth borrowers and non-borrowers experiences in and perceptions of the credit market. The survey thus permits the classification of households as constrained or unconstrained according to both the restrictive and comprehensive definitions of credit constraint. Table 2 provides descriptive characteristics of sample households. The mean farm size is just over 4 hectares. This reflects the unique agrarian structure of Peru. As a result of the agrarian reform of the 1960 s and 1970 s, the large landholding class was eliminated so that the vast majority of high quality, irrigated farm land is controlled by small-holders. Farmers in Piura produce a variety of annual and perennial crops. While historically, cotton has dominated the local economy, falling cotton prices and rising input costs have led to a large-scale substitution 8 Boucher (2000) provides a detailed description of the sample design. 23

25 away from cotton and into rice and corn in recent years. Piura s tropical climate and relatively good port access also favor the production of perennial exports such as bananas and mango. Until 1992, the state s agricultural development bank Banco Agrario held a monopoly over formal credit delivery to the agricultural sector in Peru. This changed dramatically when the government of Alberto Fujimori ( ) implemented a financial liberalization program that shut down the Banco Agrario in 1992 and eliminated interest rate controls. The banking law was also rewritten in order to create a secure environment for commercial banks to lend and to promote rural and municipal banks (Cajas Rurales and Cajas Municipales). These latter two institutions were expected to attend to the needs of the sector of small commercial producers that would likely by neglected by commercial banks. In the post-liberalization period, growth of formal lending to agriculture was truncated by a series of crises in the late 1990 s. In 1998, Peru and particularly Piura experienced a severe El Niño occurrence and the lagged impacts of the Mexican Peso crisis. This was followed by a serious political crisis culminating in the fleeing of Fujimori to Japan in With the agricultural sector severely depressed, the re-establishment of an agricultural development bank was placed back on the political agenda in the presidential election of Indeed in 2003, current president Alejandro Toledo made good on his campaign promise by opening Agrobanco a new state bank operating primarily as a second-tier institution. As of 2003 the year of the second survey Agrobanco was not yet an important source of loans. Table 3 describes credit market participation of sample households in the two survey years. Consistent with the formal sector crisis, the fraction of sample households borrowing from the formal sector fell slightly from 26% in 1997 to 24% in Borrowing from informal sources 24

26 decreased more, with the percentage of sample households with an informal loan decreasing from 49% to 39%. Table 4 compares the percentage of households that are classified as constrained when using the restrictive versus comprehensive definitions. Two results merit comment. First, use of the restrictive constraint definition leads to a significant underestimate of the prevalence of credit constraints. In 1997, 20 percent of the sample was demand-side constrained (of which 11% was accounted for by transaction costs and 9% by risk) while in 2003 this percentage increased to 36 percent (of which 13% was accounted for by transaction costs and 23% by risk). Second, there is a marked decrease in the overall frequency of credit constraints, and this result holds independently of the constraint definition. While the decrease in constraint frequency could result from households accumulating wealth, experience and perhaps a credit history, this view is overly optimistic. As mentioned above, the frequency of formal loan receipt actually declined from 1997 to This decrease in formal loan use appears to have been accompanied by a decrease in both notional and effective demand. A more likely explanation for this decrease is the general crisis of the agricultural sector and the lower profitability of the agricultural sector. 4.4 Econometric Results Table 5 presents parameter estimates from the pooled and fixed-effect logits. 9 As mentioned earlier, since the fixed effect estimation does not generate estimates of the household fixed effect, marginal effects of the independent variables on the probability of being non-price rationed cannot be computed. However the magnitude of the coefficients can be interpreted by converting them to odds ratios. To enable a comparison of coefficient magnitudes across 9 We also estimated a random effect logit. The results are virtually identical to those of the pooled logit and are thus not reported here. 25

27 estimations we report all coefficients in this form. 10 Note that for both definitions of credit constraint, the pooled and the fixed effect estimations yield similar results in terms of the coefficient significance and their size. We begin by examining the role of title on the constraint probability. Under both constraint definitions, the coefficient on the title variable is significant and the odds ratio is smaller than one so that, in line with our expectation, the possession of a title decreases the probability of being credit constrained. Furthermore, the odds ratio is smaller when the restrictive definition is used. The coefficient estimates under restricted and comprehensive definitions are 0.38 and 0.58 respectively. This suggests that, owning a title reduces the odds of being constrained by more than 60% when the restrictive constraint definition is used but only by about 40% when the comprehensive definition is used. Even if the point estimates are outside of each other s confidence intervals, those confidence intervals overlap so that there is weak statistical evidence that the point estimates are different. In conclusion, owning a title significantly reduces the odds of being constrained under both definitions of credit constraint, and the point estimates suggest that the effect is stronger when the restrictive definition is used. We now turn to the role of household wealth. While we have no prior about the relative size of the coefficient on wealth across definitions, we do expect that the difference in the predicted probability of being constrained -- Pr(C=1 Restricted Definition)-Pr(C=1 Comprehensive Definition) -- is decreasing in wealth. As we already mentioned, we cannot generate these probabilities using the fixed effect logit estimation. We will therefore rely on the parameters generated by the pooled logit estimation 10 The odds ratio represents the estimated factor by which the independent variable impacts the odds of the outcome. The odds ratio equals e^{β} so that the absence of effect corresponds an odds ratio of 1 (e =1). Odds ratios greater than one indicate a positive effect of the independent variable on the response while odds ratios smaller than one are equivalent to negative impacts. 26

Direct Elicitation of Credit Constraints: Conceptual and Practical Issues with an Empirical Application to Peruvian Agriculture

Direct Elicitation of Credit Constraints: Conceptual and Practical Issues with an Empirical Application to Peruvian Agriculture Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of California, Davis Direct Elicitation of Credit Constraints: Conceptual and Practical Issues with an Empirical Application to Peruvian Agriculture

More information

Direct Elicitation of Credit Constraints: Conceptual and Practical Issues with an Application to Peruvian Agriculture

Direct Elicitation of Credit Constraints: Conceptual and Practical Issues with an Application to Peruvian Agriculture Direct Elicitation of Credit Constraints: Conceptual and Practical Issues with an Application to Peruvian Agriculture stephen r. boucher University of California, Davis, and Giannini Foundation of Agricultural

More information

Rural Financial Intermediaries

Rural Financial Intermediaries Rural Financial Intermediaries 1. Limited Liability, Collateral and Its Substitutes 1 A striking empirical fact about the operation of rural financial markets is how markedly the conditions of access can

More information

Credit Constraints and Productivity in Peruvian Agriculture

Credit Constraints and Productivity in Peruvian Agriculture Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of California, Davis Credit Constraints and Productivity in Peruvian Agriculture by Catherine Guirkinger and Steve Boucher Working Paper No.

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Understanding the Coexistence of Formal and Informal Credit Markets in Piura, Peru

Understanding the Coexistence of Formal and Informal Credit Markets in Piura, Peru World Development Vol. 36, No. 8, pp. 1436 1452, 2008 Ó 2008 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved 0305-750X/$ - see front matter www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2007.07.002 Understanding

More information

DETERMINANTS OF AGRICULTURAL CREDIT SUPPLY TO FARMERS IN THE NIGER DELTA AREA OF NIGERIA

DETERMINANTS OF AGRICULTURAL CREDIT SUPPLY TO FARMERS IN THE NIGER DELTA AREA OF NIGERIA DETERMINANTS OF AGRICULTURAL CREDIT SUPPLY TO FARMERS IN THE NIGER DELTA AREA OF NIGERIA Okerenta, S.I. and Orebiyi, J. S ABSTRACT For effective administration of agricultural credit, financial institutions

More information

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS 5 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS The present study has analysed the financing choice and determinants of investment of the private corporate manufacturing sector in India in the context of financial liberalization.

More information

Adverse Selection in the Market for Crop Insurance

Adverse Selection in the Market for Crop Insurance 1998 AAEA Selected Paper Adverse Selection in the Market for Crop Insurance Agapi Somwaru Economic Research Service, USDA Shiva S. Makki ERS/USDA and The Ohio State University Keith Coble Mississippi State

More information

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress Stephen D. Williamson Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis May 14, 015 1 Introduction When a central bank operates under a floor

More information

Exploring the Effect of Wealth Distribution on Efficiency Using a Model of Land Tenancy with Limited Liability. Nicholas Reynolds

Exploring the Effect of Wealth Distribution on Efficiency Using a Model of Land Tenancy with Limited Liability. Nicholas Reynolds Exploring the Effect of Wealth Distribution on Efficiency Using a Model of Land Tenancy with Limited Liability Nicholas Reynolds Senior Thesis in Economics Haverford College Advisor Richard Ball Spring

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Online Appendix for Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Giacomo Rodano Bank of Italy Nicolas Serrano-Velarde Bocconi University December 23, 2014 Emanuele Tarantino University of Mannheim 1 1 Reorganization,

More information

Insurance Markets When Firms Are Asymmetrically

Insurance Markets When Firms Are Asymmetrically Insurance Markets When Firms Are Asymmetrically Informed: A Note Jason Strauss 1 Department of Risk Management and Insurance, Georgia State University Aidan ollis Department of Economics, University of

More information

Causes and Implications of Credit Rationing in Rural Ethiopia

Causes and Implications of Credit Rationing in Rural Ethiopia Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Policy Research Working Paper 6096 Causes and Implications of Credit Rationing in Rural

More information

Chapter 8 Liquidity and Financial Intermediation

Chapter 8 Liquidity and Financial Intermediation Chapter 8 Liquidity and Financial Intermediation Main Aims: 1. Study money as a liquid asset. 2. Develop an OLG model in which individuals live for three periods. 3. Analyze two roles of banks: (1.) correcting

More information

Theory of the rate of return

Theory of the rate of return Macroeconomics 2 Short Note 2 06.10.2011. Christian Groth Theory of the rate of return Thisshortnotegivesasummaryofdifferent circumstances that give rise to differences intherateofreturnondifferent assets.

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Chapter 3 Dynamic Consumption-Savings Framework

Chapter 3 Dynamic Consumption-Savings Framework Chapter 3 Dynamic Consumption-Savings Framework We just studied the consumption-leisure model as a one-shot model in which individuals had no regard for the future: they simply worked to earn income, all

More information

Characterization of the Optimum

Characterization of the Optimum ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 5. Portfolio Allocation with One Riskless, One Risky Asset Characterization of the Optimum Consider a risk-averse, expected-utility-maximizing

More information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Topic 5: Information Economics 21, Summer 2002 Andreas Bentz Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02 Introduction

More information

Development Economics 455 Prof. Karaivanov

Development Economics 455 Prof. Karaivanov Development Economics 455 Prof. Karaivanov Notes on Credit Markets in Developing Countries Introduction ------------------ credit markets intermediation between savers and borrowers: o many economic activities

More information

Risk Rationing and Activity Choice in. Moral Hazard Constrained Credit Markets

Risk Rationing and Activity Choice in. Moral Hazard Constrained Credit Markets September 2005 Risk Rationing and Activity Choice in Moral Hazard Constrained Credit Markets Abstract By shrinking the available menu of loan contracts, asymmetric information can result in two types of

More information

Determinants of Credit Rationing for Corporate Farms in Russia. Alexander Subbotin

Determinants of Credit Rationing for Corporate Farms in Russia. Alexander Subbotin Determinants of Credit Rationing for Corporate Farms in Russia Alexander Subbotin Paper prepared for presentation at the XIth Congress of the EAAE (European Association of Agricultural Economists), 'The

More information

9. Assessing the impact of the credit guarantee fund for SMEs in the field of agriculture - The case of Hungary

9. Assessing the impact of the credit guarantee fund for SMEs in the field of agriculture - The case of Hungary Lengyel I. Vas Zs. (eds) 2016: Economics and Management of Global Value Chains. University of Szeged, Doctoral School in Economics, Szeged, pp. 143 154. 9. Assessing the impact of the credit guarantee

More information

Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default

Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default Trends and Issues October 2018 Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default Chester S. Spatt, Carnegie Mellon University and TIAA Institute Fellow 1. Introduction An

More information

Development Economics Part II Lecture 7

Development Economics Part II Lecture 7 Development Economics Part II Lecture 7 Risk and Insurance Theory: How do households cope with large income shocks? What are testable implications of different models? Empirics: Can households insure themselves

More information

Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada Operating Cash Flows: Sales $682,500 $771,750 $868,219 $972,405 $957,211 less expenses $477,750 $540,225 $607,753 $680,684 $670,048 Difference $204,750 $231,525 $260,466 $291,722 $287,163 After-tax (1

More information

Development Economics 855 Lecture Notes 7

Development Economics 855 Lecture Notes 7 Development Economics 855 Lecture Notes 7 Financial Markets in Developing Countries Introduction ------------------ financial (credit) markets important to be able to save and borrow: o many economic activities

More information

ADVERSE SELECTION PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE. 1. Introduction

ADVERSE SELECTION PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE. 1. Introduction PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE LECTURE 2 LECTURER: DR. KUMAR ANIKET Abstract. We explore adverse selection models in the microfinance literature. The traditional market failure of under and over investment

More information

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory Chapter Microeconomics of Consumer Theory The two broad categories of decision-makers in an economy are consumers and firms. Each individual in each of these groups makes its decisions in order to achieve

More information

Portfolio Investment

Portfolio Investment Portfolio Investment Robert A. Miller Tepper School of Business CMU 45-871 Lecture 5 Miller (Tepper School of Business CMU) Portfolio Investment 45-871 Lecture 5 1 / 22 Simplifying the framework for analysis

More information

EU i (x i ) = p(s)u i (x i (s)),

EU i (x i ) = p(s)u i (x i (s)), Abstract. Agents increase their expected utility by using statecontingent transfers to share risk; many institutions seem to play an important role in permitting such transfers. If agents are suitably

More information

Population Economics Field Exam September 2010

Population Economics Field Exam September 2010 Population Economics Field Exam September 2010 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No materials are allowed. The exam consists of two parts each worth

More information

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments 6.1: Introduction This chapter and the next contain almost identical analyses concerning the supply and demand implied by different kinds

More information

Online Appendix for Liquidity Constraints and Consumer Bankruptcy: Evidence from Tax Rebates

Online Appendix for Liquidity Constraints and Consumer Bankruptcy: Evidence from Tax Rebates Online Appendix for Liquidity Constraints and Consumer Bankruptcy: Evidence from Tax Rebates Tal Gross Matthew J. Notowidigdo Jialan Wang January 2013 1 Alternative Standard Errors In this section we discuss

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Theory. 2.1 One Country Background

Theory. 2.1 One Country Background 2 Theory 2.1 One Country 2.1.1 Background The theory that has guided the specification of the US model was first presented in Fair (1974) and then in Chapter 3 in Fair (1984). This work stresses three

More information

The Effects of the Premium Subsidies in the U.S. Federal Crop Insurance Program on Crop Acreage

The Effects of the Premium Subsidies in the U.S. Federal Crop Insurance Program on Crop Acreage The Effects of the Premium Subsidies in the U.S. Federal Crop Insurance Program on Crop Acreage Jisang Yu Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of California, Davis jiyu@primal.ucdavis.edu

More information

Pisco Sour? Insights from an Area Yield Pilot program in Pisco, Peru

Pisco Sour? Insights from an Area Yield Pilot program in Pisco, Peru Pisco Sour? Insights from an Area Yield Pilot program in Pisco, Peru Steve Boucher University of California, Davis I-4/FAO Conference: Economics of Index Insurance Rome, January 15-16, 2010 Pilot Insurance

More information

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Title: Author: Address: E-Mail: Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate. Thomas W. Zuehlke Department of Economics Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida 32306 U.S.A. tzuehlke@mailer.fsu.edu

More information

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20135 Theory of Finance, Part I (Sept. October) Fall 2014 Outline and objectives The backward, three-step solution

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Staff Paper December 1991 USE OF CREDIT EVALUATION PROCEDURES AT AGRICULTURAL. Glenn D. Pederson. RM R Chellappan

Staff Paper December 1991 USE OF CREDIT EVALUATION PROCEDURES AT AGRICULTURAL. Glenn D. Pederson. RM R Chellappan Staff Papers Series Staff Paper 91-48 December 1991 USE OF CREDIT EVALUATION PROCEDURES AT AGRICULTURAL BANKS IN MINNESOTA: 1991 SURVEY RESULTS Glenn D. Pederson RM R Chellappan Department of Agricultural

More information

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY* Sónia Costa** Luísa Farinha** 133 Abstract The analysis of the Portuguese households

More information

International Macroeconomics

International Macroeconomics Slides for Chapter 3: Theory of Current Account Determination International Macroeconomics Schmitt-Grohé Uribe Woodford Columbia University May 1, 2016 1 Motivation Build a model of an open economy to

More information

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński Decision Making in Manufacturing and Services Vol. 9 2015 No. 1 pp. 79 88 Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment Andrzej Paliński Abstract. This paper presents a model of bank-loan repayment as

More information

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria and Rational Expectations Equilibria 1 Basic Setup Two periods: 0 and 1 One riskless asset with interest rate r One risky asset which pays a normally distributed

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Christopher Phelan Working Paper 676 December 2009 Phelan: University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve

More information

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS Bielefeld University phemelo.tamasiga@uni-bielefeld.de 01-July-2013 Agenda 1 Motivation 2 3 4 5 6 Motivation Samuelson (1939);there are gains from trade, consequently

More information

Global Financial Management

Global Financial Management Global Financial Management Valuation of Cash Flows Investment Decisions and Capital Budgeting Copyright 2004. All Worldwide Rights Reserved. See Credits for permissions. Latest Revision: August 23, 2004

More information

CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS

CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS This chapter presents the results of the study and its analysis in order to meet the objectives. These results confirm the presence and impact of the biases taken into consideration,

More information

Should Unconventional Monetary Policies Become Conventional?

Should Unconventional Monetary Policies Become Conventional? Should Unconventional Monetary Policies Become Conventional? Dominic Quint and Pau Rabanal Discussant: Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, University of California Berkeley and NBER Question: Should LSAPs be used

More information

Impact of the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR) on the access to finance for business and long-term investments Executive Summary

Impact of the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR) on the access to finance for business and long-term investments Executive Summary Impact of the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR) on the access to finance for business and long-term investments Executive Summary Prepared by The information and views set out in this study are those

More information

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality DORON NISSIM* Corporate disclosures are an important source of information for investors. Many studies have documented strong price

More information

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? October 19, 2009 Ulrike Malmendier, UC Berkeley (joint work with Stefan Nagel, Stanford) 1 The Tale of Depression Babies I don t know

More information

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index Marc Ivaldi Vicente Lagos Preliminary version, please do not quote without permission Abstract The Coordinate Price Pressure

More information

Credit Lecture 23. November 20, 2012

Credit Lecture 23. November 20, 2012 Credit Lecture 23 November 20, 2012 Operation of the Credit Market Credit may not function smoothly 1. Costly/impossible to monitor exactly what s done with loan. Consumption? Production? Risky investment?

More information

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan Optimal Credit Market Policy Matteo Iacoviello 1 Ricardo Nunes 2 Andrea Prestipino 1 1 Federal Reserve Board 2 University of Surrey CEF 218, Milan June 2, 218 Disclaimer: The views expressed are solely

More information

Empirical Evidence. Economics of Information and Contracts. Testing Contract Theory. Testing Contract Theory

Empirical Evidence. Economics of Information and Contracts. Testing Contract Theory. Testing Contract Theory Empirical Evidence Economics of Information and Contracts Empirical Evidence Levent Koçkesen Koç University Surveys: General: Chiappori and Salanie (2003) Incentives in Firms: Prendergast (1999) Theory

More information

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure Corporate Financial Management Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure As we discussed in previous lectures, two extreme results, namely the irrelevance of capital structure and 100 percent

More information

Modeling Credit Markets. Abhijit Banerjee Department of Economics, M.I.T.

Modeling Credit Markets. Abhijit Banerjee Department of Economics, M.I.T. Modeling Credit Markets Abhijit Banerjee Department of Economics, M.I.T. 1 1 The neo-classical model of the capital market Everyone faces the same interest rate, adjusted for risk. i.e. if there is a d%

More information

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California, CEPR and NBER February 11, 2006 VERY PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies the

More information

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment George Alogoskoufis, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory, 2015 Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment In this chapter we present the main neoclassical model of investment, under convex adjustment costs. This

More information

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Economic Theory 14, 247±253 (1999) Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Christopher M. Snyder Department of Economics, George Washington University, 2201 G Street

More information

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives Miguel Antón, Florian Ederer, Mireia Giné, and Martin Schmalz August 13, 2016 Abstract This internet appendix provides

More information

Conceptual Framework (Revised) Issued June Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting 2018

Conceptual Framework (Revised) Issued June Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting 2018 Conceptual Framework (Revised) Issued June 2018 Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting 2018 COPYRIGHT Copyright 2018 Hong Kong Institute of Certified Public Accountants This Framework contains the

More information

January 26,

January 26, January 26, 2015 Exercise 9 7.c.1, 7.d.1, 7.d.2, 8.b.1, 8.b.2, 8.b.3, 8.b.4,8.b.5, 8.d.1, 8.d.2 Example 10 There are two divisions of a firm (1 and 2) that would benefit from a research project conducted

More information

Optimization of a Real Estate Portfolio with Contingent Portfolio Programming

Optimization of a Real Estate Portfolio with Contingent Portfolio Programming Mat-2.108 Independent research projects in applied mathematics Optimization of a Real Estate Portfolio with Contingent Portfolio Programming 3 March, 2005 HELSINKI UNIVERSITY OF TECHNOLOGY System Analysis

More information

Collateral and Amplification

Collateral and Amplification Collateral and Amplification Macroeconomics IV Ricardo J. Caballero MIT Spring 2011 R.J. Caballero (MIT) Collateral and Amplification Spring 2011 1 / 23 References 1 2 Bernanke B. and M.Gertler, Agency

More information

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 17 Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1 Luísa Farinha Pedro Prego 2 Abstract The analysis of liquidity management decisions by firms has recently been used as a tool to investigate the

More information

Expected utility inequalities: theory and applications

Expected utility inequalities: theory and applications Economic Theory (2008) 36:147 158 DOI 10.1007/s00199-007-0272-1 RESEARCH ARTICLE Expected utility inequalities: theory and applications Eduardo Zambrano Received: 6 July 2006 / Accepted: 13 July 2007 /

More information

Chapter 11 International Trade and Economic Development

Chapter 11 International Trade and Economic Development Chapter 11 International Trade and Economic Development Plenty of good land, and liberty to manage their own affairs their own way, seem to be the two great causes of prosperity of all new colonies. Adam

More information

A Model of Simultaneous Borrowing and Saving. Under Catastrophic Risk

A Model of Simultaneous Borrowing and Saving. Under Catastrophic Risk A Model of Simultaneous Borrowing and Saving Under Catastrophic Risk Abstract This paper proposes a new model for individuals simultaneously borrowing and saving specifically when exposed to catastrophic

More information

Capital Gains Realizations of the Rich and Sophisticated

Capital Gains Realizations of the Rich and Sophisticated Capital Gains Realizations of the Rich and Sophisticated Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley and NBER Jonathan M. Siegel University of California, Berkeley and Congressional Budget Office

More information

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011 Instructions You have 4 hours to complete this exam. This is a closed book examination. No written materials are allowed. You can use a calculator. THE EXAM IS COMPOSED

More information

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, 2016 1. In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average) cost. To investigate the consequences of markup pricing,

More information

Professor Dr. Holger Strulik Open Economy Macro 1 / 34

Professor Dr. Holger Strulik Open Economy Macro 1 / 34 Professor Dr. Holger Strulik Open Economy Macro 1 / 34 13. Sovereign debt (public debt) governments borrow from international lenders or from supranational organizations (IMF, ESFS,...) problem of contract

More information

Appendix C An Added Note to Chapter 4 on the Intercepts in the Pooled Estimates

Appendix C An Added Note to Chapter 4 on the Intercepts in the Pooled Estimates Appendix C An Added Note to Chapter 4 on the Intercepts in the Pooled Estimates If one wishes to interpret the intercept terms for each year in our pooled time-series cross-section estimates, one should

More information

Durable Goods Price Cycles: Theory and Evidence from the Textbook Market. By Eric W. Bond and Toshiaki Iizuka

Durable Goods Price Cycles: Theory and Evidence from the Textbook Market. By Eric W. Bond and Toshiaki Iizuka Durable Goods Price Cycles: Theory and Evidence from the Textbook Market By Eric W. Bond and Toshiaki Iizuka June 2005 Abstract: We develop a model of the monopoly pricing of a durable good when there

More information

Economia Finanziaria e Monetaria

Economia Finanziaria e Monetaria Economia Finanziaria e Monetaria Lezione 11 Ruolo degli intermediari: aspetti micro delle crisi finanziarie (asimmetrie informative e modelli di business bancari/ finanziari) 1 0. Outline Scaletta della

More information

1 Modelling borrowing constraints in Bewley models

1 Modelling borrowing constraints in Bewley models 1 Modelling borrowing constraints in Bewley models Consider the problem of a household who faces idiosyncratic productivity shocks, supplies labor inelastically and can save/borrow only through a risk-free

More information

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium Online Appendix to Partnerships versus Corporations: Moral Hazard, Sorting and Ownership Structure Ayca Kaya and Galina Vereshchagina Appendix A formally defines an equilibrium in our model, Appendix B

More information

CHAPTER 2. Financial Reporting: Its Conceptual Framework CONTENT ANALYSIS OF END-OF-CHAPTER ASSIGNMENTS

CHAPTER 2. Financial Reporting: Its Conceptual Framework CONTENT ANALYSIS OF END-OF-CHAPTER ASSIGNMENTS 2-1 CONTENT ANALYSIS OF END-OF-CHAPTER ASSIGNMENTS NUMBER Q2-1 Conceptual Framework Q2-2 Conceptual Framework Q2-3 Conceptual Framework Q2-4 Conceptual Framework Q2-5 Objective of Financial Reporting Q2-6

More information

Credit II Lecture 25

Credit II Lecture 25 Credit II Lecture 25 November 27, 2012 Operation of the Credit Market Last Tuesday I began the discussion of the credit market (Chapter 14 in Development Economics. I presented material through Section

More information

Abstract. Crop insurance premium subsidies affect patterns of crop acreage for two

Abstract. Crop insurance premium subsidies affect patterns of crop acreage for two Abstract Crop insurance premium subsidies affect patterns of crop acreage for two reasons. First, holding insurance coverage constant, premium subsidies directly increase expected profit, which encourages

More information

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam Optimal Financial Education Avanidhar Subrahmanyam Motivation The notion that irrational investors may be prevalent in financial markets has taken on increased impetus in recent years. For example, Daniel

More information

Bank Risk Ratings and the Pricing of Agricultural Loans

Bank Risk Ratings and the Pricing of Agricultural Loans Bank Risk Ratings and the Pricing of Agricultural Loans Nick Walraven and Peter Barry Financing Agriculture and Rural America: Issues of Policy, Structure and Technical Change Proceedings of the NC-221

More information

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market Liran Einav 1 Amy Finkelstein 2 Paul Schrimpf 3 1 Stanford and NBER 2 MIT and NBER 3 MIT Cowles 75th Anniversary Conference

More information

CHAPTER 7 FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET EFFICIENCY

CHAPTER 7 FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET EFFICIENCY CHAPTER 7 FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET EFFICIENCY Chapter Overview This chapter has two major parts: the introduction to the principles of market efficiency and a review of the empirical evidence on efficiency

More information

A Balanced View of Storefront Payday Borrowing Patterns Results From a Longitudinal Random Sample Over 4.5 Years

A Balanced View of Storefront Payday Borrowing Patterns Results From a Longitudinal Random Sample Over 4.5 Years Report 7-C A Balanced View of Storefront Payday Borrowing Patterns Results From a Longitudinal Random Sample Over 4.5 Years A Balanced View of Storefront Payday Borrowing Patterns Results From a Longitudinal

More information

Note on Assessment and Improvement of Tool Accuracy

Note on Assessment and Improvement of Tool Accuracy Developing Poverty Assessment Tools Project Note on Assessment and Improvement of Tool Accuracy The IRIS Center June 2, 2005 At the workshop organized by the project on January 30, 2004, practitioners

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008 Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008 There are two questions on the exam, representing Asset Pricing (236D = 234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings Upjohn Institute Policy Papers Upjohn Research home page 2011 The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings Leslie A. Muller Hope College

More information

Ricardo. The Model. Ricardo s model has several assumptions:

Ricardo. The Model. Ricardo s model has several assumptions: Ricardo Ricardo as you will have read was a very smart man. He developed the first model of trade that affected the discussion of international trade from 1820 to the present day. Crucial predictions of

More information

LECTURE 1 : THE INFINITE HORIZON REPRESENTATIVE AGENT. In the IS-LM model consumption is assumed to be a

LECTURE 1 : THE INFINITE HORIZON REPRESENTATIVE AGENT. In the IS-LM model consumption is assumed to be a LECTURE 1 : THE INFINITE HORIZON REPRESENTATIVE AGENT MODEL In the IS-LM model consumption is assumed to be a static function of current income. It is assumed that consumption is greater than income at

More information

Development Economics

Development Economics Development Economics Development Microeconomics (by) Bardhan and Udry Chapter 7 Rural credit markets [1] Importance Smoothing consumption in an environment where production is risky and insurance markets

More information

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy We now proceed to study optimal fiscal policy. We should make clear at the outset what we mean by this. In general, fiscal policy entails the government choosing its spending

More information

IFRS Conceptual Framework Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting

IFRS Conceptual Framework Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting March 2018 IFRS Conceptual Framework Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting is issued by the International

More information