Debt Contracts in the Presence of Performance Manipulation

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Debt Contracts in the Presence of Performance Manipulation"

Transcription

1 Debt Contracts in the Presence of Performance Manipulation Ilan Guttman Stern School of Business New York University Iván Marinovic Stanford Graduate School of Business Stanford University August 10, 2017 Abstract Empirical and survey evidence suggests that firms often manipulate reported numbers to avoid debt covenant violations. The theoretical literature on debt contracting, by and large, has ignored the borrower ability to manipulate financial reports. Building upon a standard debt financing setting with continuation decisions based on reported signals, we study the effect of the borrower s ability to manipulate his report on the design of debt contracts and the resulting investment continuation and manipulation decisions. The model generates an array of novel empirical predictions regarding the covenant, the interest rate (face value), the efficiency of the continuation/liquidation decisions, and the likelihood of covenant violations. For example, the model predicts that firms with stronger corporate governance may set tighter covenants and, as a result, violate their covenants more often. It also shows that firms with stronger governance may face higher interest rates. We should expect covenants to be more prevalent in environments in which the cost of manipulation is relatively high and the firm s private information is more precise. Keywords: Asymmetric Information, Debt Contracts, Earnings Management JEL codes: D82, D86, G3, M12 We would like to thank Cyrus Aghamolla, Anne Beyer, Jeremy Bertomeu, Robert Miller, Stephen Ryan, Paul Povel, Andy Skrzypacz, Felipe Varas, and Jeff Zwiebel for helpful comments and seminar participants at U.C Berkeley, New York University, Colorado Accounting Research Conference and the Accounting Research Workshop in Basel. 1

2 1 Introduction The finance and economics literature has studied debt contracts extensively, both theoretically and empirically. This literature has nonetheless overlooked an important friction: managers can, and often do, manipulate financial reports to avoid debt covenant violations. 1 In this paper, we study the design of debt contracts in the presence of manager s ability to manipulate reports. Given the vast evidence of performance manipulation to avoid covenant violation, it is important to understand its effect on the design of debt contracting, the resulting likelihood of covenant violation and the expected amount performance manipulation. Absent theory that considers the ability to manipulate reports, it is hard to understand some features of debt contracts and interpret the evidence relating debt contracts to firms information systems. 2 For example, it seems intuitive that when the firm s information system is less reliable - namely, when it is less costly for the manager to manipulate reported numbers - the interest rate should be higher in order to compensate the lender for the expected loss of control rights caused by the manager s potential manipulation. On the other hand, one might think that a less reliable information system should lead to tighter covenants, i.e., greater control rights assigned to the lender, in order to offset the manager s reduced cost of misreporting. Both hypotheses are intuitive when considered in isolation, however as our model demonstrates these hypotheses cannot hold at the same time. We study how a cash constrained firm/entrepreneur, who needs to raise debt financing to pursue a positive NPV project, optimally designs a debt contract. The main inovation in our model is that the manager has the ability to manipulate financial reports to avoid a covenant violation. Manipulating the report is assumed to be costly to the manager. We analyze how the various aspects of the optimal debt contract are affected by the firm s ability to manipulate the performance measure on which the covenant is written. 3 These aspects include: the level of the covenant, the interest rate (face 1 For evidence of misreporting to avoid covenant violations, see DeFond and Jiambalvo (1994); Sweeney (1994); Dichev and Skinner (2002), Graham et al. (2008) and Dyreng et al. (2011). 2 There is a large empirical literature in accounting documenting the impact of corporate governance and accounting quality on debt contracts. See Bharath et al. (2008); Ball et al. (2008), Costello and Wittenwerg-Moerman (2011). 3 In this paper we restrict attention to debt financing and derive the optimal debt contract. While pure debt financing is not the optimal financing method in our setting, in additional analysis of an extended setting that includes hidden effort we numerically characterize the optimal mix of 2

3 value), the efficiency of the investment continuation/termination decision, and the tightness of the covenant or the probability of covenant violation. To gain further insight, we study how these aspects vary with firms characteristics, including: (i) how costly it is for the manager to manipulate the report - which may capture the quality of the firm s corporate governance or the reliability of the accounting system; and (ii) the precision of the firm s private information about future cash flows - which may capture the relevance of the firm s private information. Our model demonstrates that the answer to these questions is subtle and often counter-intuitive. Our setting is a simple debt contracting model with three periods. In the first period, a cash constrained manager offers a debt contract to a lender in a competitive capital market to obtain financing for the firm s investment project. The debt contract is characterized by a covenant and a face value (or equivalently interest rate or spread). In the second period, the firm s manager privately observes a noisy signal of the profitability of the investment project and reports it to the lender. The manager is not confined to truthfully report the signal and can potentially misreport it to avoid a covenant violation. However, manipulating the report is costly and the cost is increasing in the magnitude of manipulation. If the report is lower than the covenant, i.e., a covenant violation, the control rights are transferred to the lender, who may terminate the project. Termination of the project allows the lender to recover a fraction of the loan. If the project is continued, the firm s terminal cash flows are realized in the third period. Upon realization of the cash flow, in the third period, the lender receives the maximum of the face value and the realized cash flows, while the equity holders receive the residual cash flow. The overall quality of the reporting/accounting system is determined by the precision of the private signal obtained by the manager which represents the relevance of the firm s private information and the cost of manipulation which represents the reliability of the accounting system. Since termination of the project only partially recovers the initial investment, covenant violation is costly for the manager and existing shareholders. 4 As such, given the debt contract that was debt an equity. The optimal mix includes both debt and equity, and hence the trade-off we identify in the baseline model qualitatively holds even under the optimal mix of debt and equity. 4 While in the equilibrium of our model the manager s continuation value given termination is zero, the main results would qualitatively hold for any cost to the manager and existing shareholders from covenant violation. Beneish and Press (1993) document that, in their sample, following technical covenant violation firms experience increased interest costs ranging between 0.84 and 1.63 percent of the market value of firms equity and that costs of restructuring debt represent an average of 3.7% of the market value of equity. 3

4 signed in the first period, the manager always has an ex-post incentive to continue the project. Whenever the manager s private signal is higher than the debt covenant, there is no incentive to manipulate the report. When the private signal is lower than the debt covenant, the manager will manipulate the report upward to avoid violation of the covenant whenever the cost of the required level of manipulation to avoid covenant violation is lower than the manager s/equity holder s expected benefit from continuation of the project. As such, whenever a covenant is used as part of the debt contract, it entails a positive expected manipulation costs. In designing the debt contract, the manager considers the tension between investment efficiency (efficiency of the termination/continuation decision) and the expected cost of misreporting. As our model demonstrates, this tension is typically not resolved by setting a covenant that implements the first best termination/continuation decision. While a debt contract that implements the first best investment decision is feasible, it is almost always suboptimal because such a contract induces excessive expected manipulation costs. Interestingly, the model generates different qualitative predictions for different parameter values. In particular when the cost of manipulation is high (high quality of corporate governance) the optimal debt contract gives rise to over-continuation of the investment project. When the cost of manipulation is low and the precision of firm s private signal is intermediate the contract induces over-termination of the investment, which may initially seem counter intuitive, Finally, when both the manipulation costs and the level of precision of firm s private signal are low, implementing a covenant is costly and the quality of the signal is low, and hence the contract does not include a covenant. In addition to characterizing the optimal debt contract, the model also offers prediction of how cross sectional variation in firm s characteristics affects the optimal debt contract. One interesting parameter, that sometimes generates counter intuitive results, is the cost of manipulating the report. Cross sectional variation in the cost of manipulating the report whether it is via real manipulation which decreases the future cash flows, or accrual manipulation which are personally costly to the manager can arise due to differences in many firm characteristics, such as the quality of corporate governance; the reliability of the accounting system; the level of scrutiny by regulators, auditors, financial intermediaries and investors; regulatory enforcement; and litigation risk. The model predicts that an increase in the manipulation cost reduces the covenant but this does not necessarily imply a lower frequency of covenant violation. In equi- 4

5 librium, a decrease in the level of the covenant may be accompanied by an increase in face value. The increase in face value weakens the manager s misreporting incentives and the maximum manipulation cost that the manager is willing to bear in order to avoid covenant violation. If the effect of the increase in face value dominates, the likelihood of covenant violation decreases in the manipulation cost. We show that covenant violations are more likely when misreporting is more costly in environments characterized by relatively noisy private information. Note that changes in the cost of manipulation also affect the equilibrium efficiency of the investment. In particular, if the face value increases significantly, then an increase in the manipulation cost induces more termination of the investment project. If the effect of the decrease in covenant dominates then an increase in the manipulation cost induces more continuation of the project, even if conditional on the signal the project obtains a negative NPV. The (perhaps counter intuitive) phenomenon that the likelihood of covenant violation increases in the manipulation cost, or in the quality of corporate governance, arises when misreporting costs are relatively high, e.g., when corporate governance is relatively strong. This may explain why firms with stronger governance may violate their covenants more often: since their misreporting friction is weaker, they rely on tighter covenants, but they also violate them more often. The relation between the cost of manipulation and interest rates can also be counter-intuitive. The optimal debt contract resolves the misreporting friction by simultaneously adjusting the covenant and interest rate (face value). As we later show, these two levers must be substitutes in equilibrium. This means that a lower manipulation cost may lead to tighter covenants but at the same time a lower interest rate (face value). Thus, a more reliable firm which manipulates less on average, can face a higher interest rates than a less reliable one. This is the case when the precision of the firm s signal is high and the cost of manipulation is relatively low. One important implication of this result is that measuring a firm cost of debt by the observed interest rate is often misleading. This is because the interest rate does not take into account the total value promised to the lender, in particular in cases where the lender receives less than the face value following covenant violation. Moreover, a measure of the cost of debt should take into account the efficiency loss in investment caused by the possibility of misreporting. In summary, our model generates a rich set of empirical predictions, such as: In many industries we should expect a positive relation between the cost of manipula- 5

6 tion (which as mentioned above could be related to corporate governance, industry characteristic, country characteristic) and the likelihood of debt covenant violation; We should expect covenants to be more prevalent in environments in which the cost of manipulation is relatively high and the firm s private information is more precise. These predictions can be empirically tested either in an international setting (taking into account variations in regulations, enforcement, transparency, etc.), or in the US by dividing the sample to pre and post Sarbanes-Oxley, or across industries. 1.1 Related Literature We follow the Grossman-Hart-Moore property rights program by studying the optimal assignment of control rights given contractual incompleteness (see Grossman and Hart (1986); Hart (1995); Hart and Moore (1990)). The incomplete contracting literature (see Aghion and Bolton (1992)) considers the use of financial contracts to assign control rights across different states of the world. This literature takes the information structure as exogenous: information is public but non-contractible. In our setting, by contrast, information is contractible but potentially misreported by the firm, which sometimes results in information asymmetry. In addition, given that our model introduces the ability to manipulate the report, the likelihood and the extent of misreporting and the resulting information asymmetry depend on how control rights are assigned. There is a large literature in accounting studying the causes and consequences of earnings manipulation. This literature has followed two strands: the first strand takes the manager incentives as exogenous and focuses on the market reaction to earnings reports (see e.g. Dye (1988); Fischer and Verrecchia (2000); Guttman et al. (2006)). The second strand studies optimal contracts when managers have discretion to manipulate the reports (see e.g., Liang (2000),Beyer et al. (2014),Dutta and Fan (2014),Stein (1989)). We build on the second strand but restrict attention to debt contracts. Our paper is related to the costly state verification literature started by Townsend (1979), where debt contracts are optimal because they minimize verification costs. In our setting, lenders do not monitor, and the optimal debt contract seeks to minimize expected misreporting costs while maximizing investment efficiency. Unlike in Townsend (1979) the firm can obfuscate the information available to the lender via misreporting. Dessein (2005) studies the optimal allocation of control rights as a function of 6

7 the severity of information asymmetries. Garleanu and Zwiebel (2009) also study the design and renegotiation of covenants in a setting where the lender has private information at the contracting stage. In their settings, the informed party gives up control rights to the lender to signal congruent preferences. As Garleanu and Zwiebel (2009), we focus on debt contracts, and do not address the more general security design question. The optimality of debt contracts in moral hazard settings under limited liability was first established by Innes (1990). More recently Hebert (2015) proves the optimality of debt when managers effort and risk choices are unobservable. 5 Cornelli and Yosha (2003) study stage financing in a settings where managers can engage only in ex-ante window dressing that shifts the distribution of signals. The signal in their setting is non-contractible and they find that the optimal contract is a convertible debt contract which results in no window dressing. We consider a very different setting where signals are hard, privately observed by the firm, but manipulable at some cost. As such, firms reports about the signal are contractible. The empirical literature has provided ample evidence that managers take (costly) actions to avoid covenant violation. Some examples are DeFond and Jiambalvo (1994); Sweeney (1994) which finds that managers of firms approaching default respond with income-increasing accounting changes and that the default costs imposed by lenders and the accounting flexibility available to managers are important determinants of managers accounting responses. Dichev and Skinner 2002 and Dyreng et al. (2011) provide large-sample support to the debt covenant hypothesis. While companies try to avoid covenant violation, covenant violations are not rare. Dichev and Skinner document that covenant violations occur at some point to about 30 percent of the firms in their sample. Graham et al. (2005), on the other hand, focus on violations aimed at meeting earnings benchmarks, and find that the bond covenants hypothesis seems to be important primarily where there are binding constraints. Covenant violation is costly to the firm. The cost of covenant violation can vary substantially across firms in terms of the type of cost and its magnitude. For example, covenant violation costs can be due to: transfer of control rights; increased interest rate (that may lead to refinancing costs); lenders demand for partial or full 5 Sengupta (1998) notes that debt financing is the predominant form of external financing for publicly traded firms in the U.S. For example, during 1992, publicly traded companies raised approximately 2,764 billion through investment grade debt issue (which excludes mortgage and government-backed debt, convertible debt and junk bonds) in comparison to approximately 932 billion raised through common and nonconvertible preferred stock issue. 7

8 repayment (which may lead to restructuring costs and modification of operations); increased lender control and restrictions on assets sale, dividend payment and investment activities (see e.g., Beneish and Press (1993)). Note that our main results do not rely on the manager s payoff upon covenant violation being zero. As long as the manager has some personal cost from covenant violation, she will have an incentive to avoid violation of the covenant and our main results will qualitatively hold. 6 The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the model. Then section 3 develops the first best benchmark and Section 4 conducts preliminary analyses. In section 5 we analyze a contract without covenant, whereas Section 6 derives the optimal debt contract. Section 7 discusses the properties of the optimal debt contract. Sections 8 and 9 discuss empirical implications and theoretical underpinnings. Section 10 proposes several extension and Section 11 concludes. 2 Model We consider a debt contracting setting in which the borrower can misreport the firm s prospects to avoid the contractual consequences of a covenant violation. A liquidity constrained entrepreneur/firm has access to a project that requires an initial investment of I and pays out a stochastic future cash flow x F (x), if completed. In order to finance the investment opportunity, the firm needs to raise funds I through a debt contract. The debt contract specifies a covenant, z (as explained below), and a face value, K, which the borrower promises to pay the lender at the project s maturity. If the lender accepts the debt contract offered by the manager and the project is funded at t = 1, the sequence of events is the following. At t = 2, the manager privately observes the realization of a noisy signal of the project s future cash flows, s, which is the realization of the random variable s. Given the signal s, the manager issues a (potentially biased) report of his private signal, r. The manager is not confined to truthfully reporting his private signal, however, manipulating the report is costly. We assume the manager s misreporting cost equals c r s. 7 In the 6 In section 10.3 we study renegotiation following a covenant violation, which is an alternative way of introducing cost from covenant violation. 7 The specific cost function does not play an important role in the analysis. All the results qualitatively go through under any strictly increasing function of the magnitude of manipulation, e.g., quadratic cost function. 8

9 main analysis we assume, for simplicity, that the manipulation costs are personally born by the manager (as commonly assumed in the theoretical accrual management literature). In Section 10.4 we show that similar results hold when introducing the assumption that also the future cash flows are decreasing in the manipulation of the report, i.e., real earnings/performance management rather than just accrual manipulation. If at t = 2 the manager s report about his private signal is lower than the covenant, i.e., r < z, there is a covenant violation. When the covenant is violated the lender receives the project s control rights and can terminate the project. The termination/liquidation proceeds are assumed to be L, where L < I. If the project is not terminated, at t = 3 cash flow of the project is realized and payoffs are allocated. Upon realization of the cash flows (at the maturity of the project at t = 3) the lender receives min(k, x) and the borrower retains the residual cash, i.e., the manager gets max(0, x K). Figure 1 summarizes the timeline of our setting. Figure 1: Timeline t=1 The debt contract is signed, specifying {z, K}. t=2 The manager privately observes signal s and reports r. If the covenant is violated, the project is terminated. t=3 If continued, the project s cash flows x are realized and payments are made. Both the lender and borrower are risk neutral. For simplicity, and without loss of generality, we assume that future cash flows are not discounted. The debt market is competitive, so in expectation lenders break-even. Both the manager and lender maximize their expected payoff and obtain zero payoffs when the project is not financed. All the model s parameters, payoff functions, distributions of the signal and the cash flows are assumed to be common knowledge. 2.1 Information Structure The objective of this paper is to study the impact of misreporting on the design of debt contracts. We design a setting that focuses on this interaction, while trying to abstract from other potentially confounding effects. One such effect is the variation of the density of the distributions of cash flows and the manager s private signal (As indicated earlier, given a debt covenant, there will be an interval of signal realizations below the debt covenant, such that for all signals within this interval 9

10 the manager will manipulate his report upwards in order to meet the covenant. When designing the optimal contract in the first period, the manager considers the expected manipulation cost, which depends on the distributions of the private signal and the cash flows.) For simplicity, we assume cash flows are uniformly distributed. In Section 10.2 we demonstrate that our results hold under standard unbounded distributions, such as the Log-Normal distribution. 8 We assume that the manager s private signal, s, is a mixture: that is, with probability ρ the signal is equal to the cash flow x and with probability 1 ρ the signal is pure noise that is drawn from the same distribution as x. Thus, ρ can be thought of as the accounting system s precision. This is an important parameter impacting the design of debt contracts: Ball et al. (2008) documents that when a borrower s accounting information is more precise, this lowers the lender s monitoring cost. 9 In the sequel, we assume that both the cash flows x and the signal s are uniformly distributed over [0, 1], i.e., x U [0, 1] and s U [0, 1]. Hence, the conditional expectation of x given the signal s is linear in s and given by E( x s) = ρs + (1 ρ)e(x). 3 First Best: No-misreporting Case Before deriving the equilibrium, we provide as a benchmark the first best outcome. The first best (labelled F B) is achieved when misreporting is precluded, i.e., in the limit as misreporting becomes prohibitively costly (c ). Naturally, in the absence of misreporting, the optimal debt contract induces efficient continuation/termination. Since the expected cash flow given continuation increases in the signal s, the first best continuation strategy is a threshold strategy. We denote the threshold signal below which the project is terminated by τ F B. That is, for all s < τ F B the project is terminated, otherwise the project is continued. When the signal realization equals this threshold, the expected cash flow given termination, L, equals the expected cash flow given continuation, E ( x s = τ F B). 8 We verified that similar results hold also for truncated normal and exponential distributions, but for brevity we did not include these examples. 9 In particular, they hypothesize and document that when a borrower s accounting information possesses higher informativeness, information asymmetry between the lead arranger and other syndicate participants is lower, allowing lead arrangers to hold a smaller proportion of new loan deals. 10

11 The expected value of the firm when manipulation is prohibited, depends only on the efficiency of the firm s investment policy as captured by τ. Under the firstbest continuation policy, the expected value of the firm, which we denote by V (τ), equals V ( τ F B) = Pr ( s < τ F B) L + Pr ( s τ F B) E ( x s > τ F B). The first best continuation threshold, τ F B, is given by τ F B = 2L (1 ρ). (1) 2ρ Due to the option to terminate the project, the firm value is greater than E (x). Note that V ( τ F B) represents an upper bound for the firm value relative to the case where misreporting is feasible. Condition 1. Under an efficient continuation policy, the project has positive net present value, formally V ( τ F B) I. This assumption imposes an upper bound on I. As we shall argue, this assumption means that, no matter how small is c, the project can always be financed. Furthermore, for any c > 0 there is always a debt contract that implements the first best continuation policy and generates positive expected payoffs to the lender and the manager. To focus on the interesting case, we assume the signal is sufficiently informative such that termination is sometimes optimal. If the signal were not sufficiently informative the contract would not include a covenant and the project would never be terminated. Formally, a signal is sufficiently informative if there are realizations of s, such that E( x s) < L. Condition 2. Termination is sometimes optimal, or ρ > 1 2L. This assumption means the signal is precise enough, so in the absence of misreporting, the optimal debt contract always implements some termination. As we shall argue, misreporting may lead to a contract without covenants where the project is never terminated. 11

12 4 Preliminaries A debt contract can be defined as a pair {K, z} consisting of a face value K and a covenant z. The face value, K, determines the maximum amount the lender receives when the project s cash flows realize; the covenant, z, determines the report below which the covenant is violated and the lender is awarded control rights - following which the lender can terminate the project. Any contract {K, z} that is agreed upon results in an equilibrium termination cutoff τ (z, K). The cutoff τ defines the signal value below which the manager prefers to report truthfully and violate the covenant, transferring control rights to the lender who can terminate the project. An arbitrary contract {K, z} and the resulting termination cutoff τ (z, K) determine the enterprise s expected future cash flows (to the lender and the shareholders). We refer to this value as firm value and denote it by V (τ). Note that the firm value is independent of the expected manipulation cost, and hence, only depends on the efficiency of the continuation decision - which is determined by τ. The face value, on the other hand, only affects the allocation of surplus between the firm and the lender, and may affect the manager s misreporting behavior. The firm value is given by V (τ) = Pr (s < τ) L + Pr (s τ) E ( x s > τ) = τl + 1 τ E(x s)f(s)ds. For a contract {K, z} and the resulting termination cutoff τ (z, K), the expected cash flow to the lender, which we refer to as the value of debt and denote it by D(K, τ), is given by D (K, τ (z, K)) = τ (z, K) L + 1 τ E(min (x, K) s)f(s)ds. Naturally, for the lender to be willing to provide funding, the debt value must be no smaller than I, i.e., D (K, τ (z, K)) I. The termination cutoff τ (z, K) that results from a contact {K, z} must be incentive compatible from the manager s stand point when choosing the report. Hence, when s = τ (z, K) the manager must be indifferent between manipulating the report in order to meet the covenant and continue the project, and between saving the manipulation cost and violating the covenant. We currently implicitly assume that 12

13 when the covenant is violated the lender prefers to terminate the project. We later show that this indeed holds in equilibrium, so we can ignore incentive compatibility on the lender s part. Formally, the manager s reporting incentive compatibility constraint, which determines τ (z, K) is E [ (x K) + s = τ (z, K) ] = c (z τ (z, K)). (2) We refer to equation 2 as the misreporting IC constraint, but strictly speaking this is what the IC constraint reduces to given the fact that indifference at the threshold implies in this model no incentives to manipulate below. Given the above reporting incentive compatibility condition, the expected misreporting cost borne by the manager, which we denote by C (z, τ), is C (z, τ) z τ c (z s) ds. We can now define an optimal debt contract. Definition 3. An optimal debt contract {K, z } and the resulting termination threshold τ is given by the solution to Π max V (τ (z, K)) C (z, τ (z, K)) {K,z} subject to the lender s participation constraint D (K, τ) I (3) and the manager s misreporting incentive compatibility constraint given in equation 2. Intuitively, in equilibrium the lender s participation constraint binds. So for future reference, we define a function K (τ) representing the face value that exactly satisfies the lender s participation constraint given a termination cutoff τ, namely D (K, τ) = I. (4) In the remainder of this section, we derive and characterize the optimal debt contract. We start by analyzing the game backwards, in particular, we analyze the 13

14 manager s reporting strategy and expected manipulation cost for any given contract. We next derive the set of contracts that satisfy the lender s participation constraint as an intermediate step toward finding the optimal debt contract. 4.1 Expected Manipulation Costs A debt contract is designed to maximize investment efficiency while avoiding excessive misreporting costs. In this section, we study how the covenant and face value affect the manager s expected misreporting costs. As mentioned above, the covenant, z, in conjunction with the face value, K, determine a threshold signal τ (z, K) below which it is too costly to manipulate the report to meet the covenant. When the manager s signal equals that threshold, the manager is indifferent between meeting the covenant, by misreporting the true signal, and violating the covenant, thereby allowing the lender to terminate the project. In other words, for any given {z, K}, the threshold τ is such that the manipulation cost incurred by the manager to meet the covenant equals the manager s expected continuation payoff, as characterized by equation 2. Equation 2 characterizes the manager s reporting behavior, given an arbitrary contract {z, K}. The manager manipulates his report only if the signal belongs to s [τ, z], and over this interval the manager reports z and the bias in the report is z s. Otherwise, the manager truthfully reports his signal to the lender, even if this triggers liquidation. We can now consider the expected misreporting cost induced by the contract. We focus on the case τ K. (As it will turn out, this condition must be satisfied in equilibrium). For any given pair {z, K} equation 2 defines a termination threshold τ (z, K) = z (1 ρ) (1 K)2, (5) 2c such that managers with signals above τ = τ (z, K) will prefer to manipulate the report (if needed) to avoid a covenant violation. Notice that the distance between z and τ, hence the probability of manipulation, is independent of τ. This property holds for any cost function that increases in the magnitude of the manipulation. For simplicity, we assume a linear cost function Notice we do not restrict the covenant z to have the same support as the cash flows, i.e., z can be larger than one. This may seem unnatural, and is a limitation of using the Uniform distribution (or more generally of distributions that are bounded from above). We demonstrate the robustness of our results, with respect to distributional assumptions in Section

15 Given the characterization of the marginal type s misreporting cost, and the interval of types choosing to manipulate s [τ, min (z, 1)] (where the termination threshold τ is given by equation 5), we can now analyze the expected misreporting costs induced by an arbitrary contract {K, z}. Lemma 4. The expected misreporting cost for arbitrary {K, z} can be written as C (z, τ (z, K)) z τ c (z s) f(s)ds = { (1 ρ) 2 8c (1 ρ) 2 8c (1 K) 4 if z < 1 (1 K) 4 c(z 1)2 2 if z 1. (6) Consider the effect of increasing z when z < 1 (and keeping K constant). 11 Increasing z induces a one-to-one increase in τ, thus shifting to the right the location of the interval of manager types that manipulate the report but given the Uniform distribution it does not affect the probability of manipulation. Therefore, for a given face value, the probability of misreporting and expected misreporting cost is independent of the covenant level when z < 1. Now, let us consider the case of z > 1. Increasing z leads again to a one-toone increase in τ(z, K). However, now the probability of manipulation and the expected misreporting cost decreases because the upper bound of the interval of types who chose to misreport is fixed at one. Setting tighter (i.e., higher) covenants has the ability to reduce the likelihood of misreporting, ceteris paribus. The following corollary summarizes this result. Corollary 5. For a given face value K, a marginal increase in the contract s covenant z weakly reduces expected misreporting costs. dc (z, τ (K, z)) dz = { 0 if z < 1 < 0 if z 1 Also, for a fixed covenant z a marginal increase in the face value lowers expected misreporting costs, dc (z, τ (K, z)) < 0. dk 11 In general, the effect of z on expected misreporting costs is non-monotonic. This is intuitive: the contract can eliminate misreporting costs by setting z = 0. (Such a contract gives the manager all the control rights.) Alternatively, the contract can mitigate misreporting by setting a high covenant, so that misreporting is always unaffordable to the manager. (At the limit, such a contract awards all control rights to the lender.) 15

16 The effect of face value K is also intuitive. Increasing the face value, for a given z, reduces the manager s skin in the game, thus weakening his manipulation incentives and lowering expected misreporting costs. In the next section, we derive the face value that maximizes the manager s payoff when the contract implements a termination policy τ. 4.2 Lender s Participation In addition to the expected misreporting costs, a contract {K, z} determines the lender s expected payoff, which has two components. First, if the covenant is violated, the lender assumes control rights and can liquidate the project to recover L. Second, if the project is continued, the lender receives the maximum of the face value K and the cash flow x. The lender will accept the debt contract as long as his expected payoff is higher than the investment, I. Since the manager can always extract all the surplus from the lender, the optimal contract should offer a face value that keeps the lender s participation constraint binding, thus solving Pr (s τ) L + 1 τ E (min (x, K) s) f (s) ds = I (7) This equation represents the lender s participation constraint when debt markets are competitive. Lemma 6. The face value that satisfies the lender s participation constraint when the contract {K, z} induces termination threshold τ, denoted by K (τ), is given by K (τ) = (I Lτ) + ρτ 2. (8) 1 τ + ρτ For any τ [0, ˆτ] the face value K (τ) is a continuous U-shaped function with the following characteristics: K (τ) > I; K (0) = 1 1 2I; 16

17 and the unique minimum of K ( ) over the interval [0, ˆτ], denoted τ +, is given by τ + arg min s [0 ˆτ] K (s), where ˆτ = L+ L 2 +2ρ 4ρI 2ρ. The value of ˆτ is defined by K (ˆτ) = 1, and represents the termination threshold that makes the lender indifferent when he has 100% rights over the firm cash flows. The function K ( ) defines the face value that satisfies the lender s participation constraint when the project is terminated for signals s τ, in which case the lender receives L (notice that the function K (τ) ignores whether τ is incentive compatible from the lender standpoint) A contract is feasible for a given cutoff τ if K K(τ) Figure 4 shows the region of feasible contracts. Figure 2: The lender s participation constraint. Parameters: ρ =.95, I =.45, L =.4. The U-shape of K (τ) means that for low τ the face value and control rights are 17

18 substitute ways of paying the lender: the manager can increase the lender s payoff by either increasing the face value or by increasing the covenant. However, when τ is large, face value and control rights are complements. To gain some intuition for the U-shape of K (τ), note that a low value of τ (i.e., when the probability of continuation is high) means the lender is unlikely to get control rights. As such, for low values of τ the lender demands a large face value to break-even. As τ increases, the lender gets extra control rights: we add more signals under which the project is terminated which is consistent with the lender s ex-post incentive for s = τ and hence the lender is willing to accept a lower face value. This continues up to a certain value of τ for which the termination threshold, τ, is expost optimal from the lender s standpoint, that is, for s = τ the lender is indifferent between continuation and termination. As we further increase τ, the contract starts inducing excessive termination, even from the lenders s ex-post standpoint, and hence, the lender demands additional compensation in terms of face value (recall K ( ) is derived assuming the lender can commit to terminating the project when he acquires control rights). As such, the face value for which the lender breaks even is a U-shape function of τ. As mentioned above, the U-shape of K ( ) implies that, when keeping the lender s constraint binding, for values of τ such that τ < τ + the face value K and the termination threshold τ are substitutes. By contrast, for higher values of τ, an increase in τ requires a higher face value to satisfy the lender s participation constraint. Hence, for τ > τ + the termination threshold τ and the face value K (τ) are complements. In the next section we demonstrate that in any equilibrium the face value and the threshold must be substitutes. 4.3 Covenant and Face Value: Substitutes or Complements? Given any debt contract, the manager always has an ex-post incentive to continue the project. For any given face value, the lender has an interior optimal continuation threshold. Lemma 6 proves that the face value that keeps the lender s participation constraint binding is U-shaped in τ. The minimum of K (τ) is obtained at τ = τ + where the lender s ex-post optimal continuation threshold coincides with s = τ +. For τ < τ +, given s = τ the lender faces higher incentive to terminate the project (and requires increase in the face value) and hence, τ < τ + results in ex-post over continuation from the lender s standpoint. For τ > τ +, given s = τ the lender faces lower incentive to terminate the project (and requires increase in the face value) and 18

19 hence τ < τ + results in ex-post over termination from the lender s standpoint. The following lemma shows that the equilibrium threshold τ is lower than τ +. This implies that evaluated at the equilibrium threshold the face values decreases in the termination threshold and that for s = τ the lender wishes to terminate the project. Lemma 7. The equilibrium threshold signal, τ, satisfies dk(τ) dτ 0. τ=τ The reason why face value and covenant must be substitutes in equilibrium is easier to see in the case when z < 1 where for a fixed face value the expected misreporting costs are independent of the termination threshold τ. Assume by contradiction that dk(τ) dτ > 0. Then, by lowering the termination threshold τ=τ while keeping the same face value the lender s participation constraint would still be satisfied while the manager would be strictly better off - in contradiction to the original contract being optimal. The case where z > 1 is more subtle, and hence it is deferred to the proof in the appendix. The ex-ante benefit from having a covenant is that it enables to induce termination of the project for sufficiently low signals. However, a covenant always comes with a cost - positive expected misreporting costs. For some set of parameters, the cost exceeds the benefit, and hence the optimal contract will not include a covenant. The following section identify the conditions for such contract. In Section 6 we derive the optimal contract when having a covenant is optimal. 5 A Contract without Covenant The following lemma identifies a condition under which the optimal contract does not include a covenant and provides the general expression for the optimal contract, the lender s participation constraint, and the manager s incentive compatibility constraint. We denote by τ, z, K the equilibrium termination threshold, covenant, and face value respectively, and by Π the manager s expected payoff. Lemma 8. If ρ is sufficiently low, then the project is never terminated and the contract does not induce misreporting. Hence τ = 0, z = 0, the face value K is given by 1 0 E (min (x, K ) s) ds = I, 19

20 or, equivalently, K = 1 1 2I. This contract generates manager payoff Π = E (x) I (note that the only relevant solution is 0 < K 1 and that 0 < I < E (x) = 0.5). In general, the debt contract maximizes the firm s expected cash flows net of expected misreporting costs, subject to the lender s participation constraint, and the manager s (misreporting) incentive compatibility constraint. If ρ is small, namely the signal is not very informative, the benefit of implementing a covenant to terminate the project under bad news is very low and the misreporting cost triggered by the presence of a covenant outweighs the expected benefit. In contrast, when ρ is high, the real option to terminate the project has high value, and the benefit of implementing a covenant outweighs the associated misreporting costs. 6 The Optimal Debt Contract Without the possibility of misreporting, an optimal contract induces efficient termination, no negative NP V projects are ever continued, hence τ = τ F B. However, when misreporting is possible, efficient termination policy can generate excessive misreporting costs. To balance this trade-off, the debt contract must optimize over two dimensions, control rights, z and interest rate, K. By controlling these aspects of the contract, the firm effectively determines the termination threshold, τ. It is convenient to formulate the contract as a single variable optimization program that depends only on the termination threshold τ. For this purpose we define the expected misreporting costs induced by threshold τ as χ (τ) C (ζ (K (τ), τ), τ), where ζ is the covenant value z = ζ (K, τ) such that ζ solves the misreporting incentive compatibility constraint: E [ (x K) + s = τ ] = c (ζ τ). χ (τ) thus represents the expected misreporting cost when the contract induces termination threshold τ and the face value is such that the lender breaks even. 20

21 An optimal contract can be represented as follows: Π = max {V (τ) χ(τ), E (x)} I. (9) τ [0,ˆτ] The existence of a maximum is immediate, given the bounded support and continuity of Π ( ). Uniqueness is not obvious because in principle one could think of multiple thresholds as being optimal, some of which implement relatively inefficient investments but, in return, induce lower expected misreporting costs. In the next section, we shall derive the optimal debt contract and show that it implements excessive continuation for some parameter values and excessive termination for others. The following proposition summarizes some of these results. Proposition 9. There exists a unique optimal debt contract characterized as follows. (i) If c is large, the equilibrium always entails over-continuation. Furthermore, the likelihood of covenant violation increases in c, and the face value decreases in c. (ii) If c is small, the optimal contract can have one of the following patterns: it may include no covenant, i.e., z = τ = 0 (for small ρ); or may entail overtermination (for intermediate ρ) ; or may entail over-continuation (for high ρ). When the contract entails over termination, the likelihood of covenant violation decreases in c, and the face value increases in c. Figure 3 illustrates the proposition. Note that the manager would like to increase his cost of manipulation. In fact, in this model, the entrepreneur wants (ex ante) to be unable to manipulate the signal. So we can think of this problem as a commitment problem, i.e. the manager cannot commit to being always truthful. In the following section, we formally derive the statements in Proposition 9 and develop the intuition for these results. 7 Properties of the Optimal Debt Contract We now turn to the efficiency of the contract s termination policy. This aspect is tied to the (endogenous) expected misreporting as is apparent from the first order condition V (τ ) = χ (τ ). (10) This equation underscores the main trade-off facing the optimal contract: investment efficiency versus misreporting costs. The left hand side, captures the marginal 21

22 Figure 3: The effect of misreporting costs c. Parameters: ρ =.8, L =.36, I =.4. The upper panels depict the effect of reliability on the contract s termination threshold (τ ) and face value (K ). The bottom panels depict the effect of c on the covenant (zˆ*) and manager s payoff (Π ). effect of the termination cutoff on the firm s expected cash flows. V ( ) is a hillshaped function of τ, that attains a maximum at τ F B > 0. The right hand side captures the marginal effect of the termination threshold on the expected misreporting costs. Evaluated at the first best we have V ( τ F B) = 0. Hence, if V (τ ) = χ (τ ) > 0, the equilibrium entails excessive continuation and excessive termination otherwise. We next study whether χ (τ ) is positive in equilibrium. 7.1 Overinvestment or Underinvestment? We first note that if a debt contract optimally implements some termination (i.e., τ > 0) it must necessarily induce misreporting. However, the presence of misreport- 22

23 0.95 τ = τ F B Π(τ ) = E(x) Precision ρ over-termination over-continuation no covenant Reliability c Figure 4: Accounting properties and investment efficiency. The blue line is defined as the set of c, ρ such that τ = τ F B. The red line is defined as the set of c, ρ such that max τ {V (τ) χ (τ) E (x)} = 0. Parameters: I =.45, L =.4. Notice that the over termination area is very small. This is due to our parametric assumption that x is uniformly distributed over [0, 1]. ing on the equilibrium path does not imply termination decisions will be distorted. 12 Generically, though, (namely for almost all parameter values) the possibility of misreporting distorts termination choices away from first best. It is however not clear whether the possibility of misreporting will induce excessive continuation or excessive termination. To address this question we first prove two useful lemmas. Lemma 10. (i) For sufficiently high values of c, the optimal contract includes a covenant 0 < z 1 and τ > 0. (ii) By contrast, for lower values of c, either there is no covenant (τ = 0 and z = 0) or the covenant is z > 1 and τ > 0. The above result indicates that for c sufficiently large, both termination and misreporting take place in equilibrium. Similarly for c sufficiently small both ter- 12 As we show, continuation decisions can be efficient in equilibrium (τ = τ F B ) even in the presence of equilibrium misreporting. 23

24 mination and misreporting happen in equilibrium, unless the signal is sufficiently imprecise (ρ is sufficiently low) that the misreporting cost outweighs the benefit from termination, and hence it becomes optimal to remove any covenant by setting τ = z = 0. For a given contract, it s clear that introducing the possibility to misreport would increase continuation. However, the contract s covenant depends on how costly it is for the manager to manipulate performance. When the endogeneity of contracts is taken into account, the ability to manipulate performance could lead in equilibrium to tighter covenants - making termination even more likely than under first best. To understand whether the equilibrium entails excessive continuation or excessive termination, we need to study the behavior of the expected misreporting costs. Specifically, we next ask whether more termination (i.e., a higher τ) increases expected misreporting costs C (τ) or not. The answer depends on whether z < 1, hence it depends on the level of the cost coefficient c. Indeed, when z < 1 the expected misreporting cost depends only indirectly on τ. Inspection of equation (6) shows that χ (τ) (1 K (τ)) 4. Furthermore, we have established that in equilibrium the face value and the threshold must be substitutes, i.e., K (τ) < 0. This means, that an increase in the continuation threshold will enable to decrease the face value without violating the lender s participation constraint. As a result, the manager retains a larger part of the realized cash flow, which increases the manager s incentive to manipulation the report in order to continue the project. As such, the expected misreporting cost increase in τ for all z 1. When c is sufficiently high z 1. Starting from the covenant that implements the first best continuation, an increase in the termination threshold will increase the expected manipulation cost and will also decrease the efficiency of termination (moving away from first best). As such, for sufficiently high c the the termination threshold is lower than the first best threshold, so the equilibrium entails excessive continuation. The following Lemma formalizes this result. Lemma 11. When c is large the equilibrium entails excessive continuation. Formally τ < τ F B. The converse is not true: a low reliability c does not necessarily lead to excessive termination relative to first best and may even lead to efficient termination. 24

Debt Contracts in the Presence of Performance Manipulation

Debt Contracts in the Presence of Performance Manipulation Debt Contracts in the Presence of Performance Manipulation Ilan Guttman Stern School of Business New York University Iván Marinovic Stanford Graduate School of Business Stanford University October 4, 2017

More information

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Online Appendix for Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing Giacomo Rodano Bank of Italy Nicolas Serrano-Velarde Bocconi University December 23, 2014 Emanuele Tarantino University of Mannheim 1 1 Reorganization,

More information

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited Shingo Ishiguro Graduate School of Economics, Osaka University 1-7 Machikaneyama, Toyonaka, Osaka 560-0043, Japan August 2002

More information

On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation

On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation On the use of leverage caps in bank regulation Afrasiab Mirza Department of Economics University of Birmingham a.mirza@bham.ac.uk Frank Strobel Department of Economics University of Birmingham f.strobel@bham.ac.uk

More information

Incomplete Draft. Accounting Rules in Debt Covenants. Moritz Hiemann * Stanford University. January 2011

Incomplete Draft. Accounting Rules in Debt Covenants. Moritz Hiemann * Stanford University. January 2011 Accounting Rules in Debt Covenants Moritz Hiemann * Stanford University January 2011 * I would like to thank Stefan Reichelstein and participants at the joint accounting and finance student seminar at

More information

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011 There are two questions on the exam, representing Macroeconomic Finance (234A) and Corporate Finance (234C). Please answer both questions to the best of your

More information

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Economic Theory 14, 247±253 (1999) Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w Christopher M. Snyder Department of Economics, George Washington University, 2201 G Street

More information

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion Davit Khantadze September 30, 017 Abstract We are interested in optimal signals for the sender when the decision maker (receiver) has to make two separate decisions.

More information

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser.

University of Konstanz Department of Economics. Maria Breitwieser. University of Konstanz Department of Economics Optimal Contracting with Reciprocal Agents in a Competitive Search Model Maria Breitwieser Working Paper Series 2015-16 http://www.wiwi.uni-konstanz.de/econdoc/working-paper-series/

More information

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium Online Appendix to Partnerships versus Corporations: Moral Hazard, Sorting and Ownership Structure Ayca Kaya and Galina Vereshchagina Appendix A formally defines an equilibrium in our model, Appendix B

More information

Auditing in the Presence of Outside Sources of Information

Auditing in the Presence of Outside Sources of Information Journal of Accounting Research Vol. 39 No. 3 December 2001 Printed in U.S.A. Auditing in the Presence of Outside Sources of Information MARK BAGNOLI, MARK PENNO, AND SUSAN G. WATTS Received 29 December

More information

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Evaluating Strategic Forecasters Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017 Motivation Forecasters are sought after in a variety of

More information

Optimal Penalty Level, Manipulation, and Investment Efficiency

Optimal Penalty Level, Manipulation, and Investment Efficiency Optimal Penalty Level, Manipulation, and Investment Efficiency Lin Nan Purdue University Xiaoyan Wen Texas Christian University October 24, 2016 Abstract In this study we examine whether it is efficient

More information

Misallocation and the Distribution of Global Volatility: Online Appendix on Alternative Microfoundations

Misallocation and the Distribution of Global Volatility: Online Appendix on Alternative Microfoundations Misallocation and the Distribution of Global Volatility: Online Appendix on Alternative Microfoundations Maya Eden World Bank August 17, 2016 This online appendix discusses alternative microfoundations

More information

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Fragility and Coordination Failures What makes financial systems fragile? What causes crises

More information

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem Jin Yong Jung We analyze how the wealth of an agent and its distribution affect the profit of the principal by considering the simple

More information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions 1. (45 points) Consider the following normal form game played by Bruce and Sheila: L Sheila R T 1, 0 3, 3 Bruce M 1, x 0, 0 B 0, 0 4, 1 (a) Suppose

More information

Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma

Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma RESEARCH ARTICLE A MODEL OF COMPETITION BETWEEN PERPETUAL SOFTWARE AND SOFTWARE AS A SERVICE Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma School of Information Systems, Singapore Management University, 80 Stanford Road, Singapore

More information

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation Christopher Phelan Working Paper 676 December 2009 Phelan: University of Minnesota and Federal Reserve

More information

Design and Renegotiation of Debt Covenants

Design and Renegotiation of Debt Covenants Design and Renegotiation of Debt Covenants Nicolae Garleanu Jeffrey Zwiebel October, 2003 Abstract We analyze the design and renegotiation of covenants in debt contracts as a particular example of the

More information

Rural Financial Intermediaries

Rural Financial Intermediaries Rural Financial Intermediaries 1. Limited Liability, Collateral and Its Substitutes 1 A striking empirical fact about the operation of rural financial markets is how markedly the conditions of access can

More information

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński Decision Making in Manufacturing and Services Vol. 9 2015 No. 1 pp. 79 88 Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment Andrzej Paliński Abstract. This paper presents a model of bank-loan repayment as

More information

Optimal Ownership of Public Goods in the Presence of Transaction Costs

Optimal Ownership of Public Goods in the Presence of Transaction Costs MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Optimal Ownership of Public Goods in the Presence of Transaction Costs Daniel Müller and Patrick W. Schmitz 207 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/90784/ MPRA

More information

Economics and Finance,

Economics and Finance, Economics and Finance, 2014-15 Lecture 5 - Corporate finance under asymmetric information: Moral hazard and access to external finance Luca Deidda UNISS, DiSEA, CRENoS October 2014 Luca Deidda (UNISS,

More information

Where do securities come from

Where do securities come from Where do securities come from We view it as natural to trade common stocks WHY? Coase s policemen Pricing Assumptions on market trading? Predictions? Partial Equilibrium or GE economies (risk spanning)

More information

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A.

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A. THE INVISIBLE HAND OF PIRACY: AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE INFORMATION-GOODS SUPPLY CHAIN Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A. {antino@iu.edu}

More information

Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations

Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations Rent Shifting and the Order of Negotiations Leslie M. Marx Duke University Greg Shaffer University of Rochester December 2006 Abstract When two sellers negotiate terms of trade with a common buyer, the

More information

(Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance

(Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance (Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha Department of Economics UC Davis Part 6. Lending Relationships and Investor Activism V. F. Martins-da-Rocha (UC Davis) Corporate

More information

Directed Search and the Futility of Cheap Talk

Directed Search and the Futility of Cheap Talk Directed Search and the Futility of Cheap Talk Kenneth Mirkin and Marek Pycia June 2015. Preliminary Draft. Abstract We study directed search in a frictional two-sided matching market in which each seller

More information

Settlement and the Strict Liability-Negligence Comparison

Settlement and the Strict Liability-Negligence Comparison Settlement and the Strict Liability-Negligence Comparison Abraham L. Wickelgren UniversityofTexasatAustinSchoolofLaw Abstract Because injurers typically have better information about their level of care

More information

Liability, Insurance and the Incentive to Obtain Information About Risk. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University

Liability, Insurance and the Incentive to Obtain Information About Risk. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University \ins\liab\liabinfo.v3d 12-05-08 Liability, Insurance and the Incentive to Obtain Information About Risk Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University Paul Thistle University of Nevada Las Vegas December

More information

Online Appendix to Managerial Beliefs and Corporate Financial Policies

Online Appendix to Managerial Beliefs and Corporate Financial Policies Online Appendix to Managerial Beliefs and Corporate Financial Policies Ulrike Malmendier UC Berkeley and NBER ulrike@econ.berkeley.edu Jon Yan Stanford jonathan.yan@stanford.edu January 7, 2010 Geoffrey

More information

Transactions with Hidden Action: Part 1. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Transactions with Hidden Action: Part 1. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Transactions with Hidden Action: Part 1 Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2015 Transactions with hidden action A risk-neutral principal (P) delegates performance of a task to an agent (A) Key features

More information

Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin. The allocation of authority under limited liability

Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin. The allocation of authority under limited liability Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin Nr. 2005/25 VOLKSWIRTSCHAFTLICHE REIHE The allocation of authority under limited liability Kerstin Puschke ISBN

More information

Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency. Problem

Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency. Problem Motivation versus Human Capital Investment in an Agency Problem Anthony M. Marino Marshall School of Business University of Southern California Los Angeles, CA 90089-1422 E-mail: amarino@usc.edu May 8,

More information

Basic Assumptions (1)

Basic Assumptions (1) Basic Assumptions (1) An entrepreneur (borrower). An investment project requiring fixed investment I. The entrepreneur has cash on hand (or liquid securities) A < I. To implement the project the entrepreneur

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH http://www.kier.kyoto-u.ac.jp/index.html Discussion Paper No. 657 The Buy Price in Auctions with Discrete Type Distributions Yusuke Inami

More information

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress Stephen D. Williamson Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis May 14, 015 1 Introduction When a central bank operates under a floor

More information

Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening

Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening NMI Workshop, ISI Delhi August 3, 2015 Motivation A seller wants to sell an object to a prospective buyer(s). Buyer has imperfect private information θ about

More information

Aggressive Corporate Tax Behavior versus Decreasing Probability of Fiscal Control (Preliminary and incomplete)

Aggressive Corporate Tax Behavior versus Decreasing Probability of Fiscal Control (Preliminary and incomplete) Aggressive Corporate Tax Behavior versus Decreasing Probability of Fiscal Control (Preliminary and incomplete) Cristian M. Litan Sorina C. Vâju October 29, 2007 Abstract We provide a model of strategic

More information

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade Jesse A. Schwartz Kennesaw State University Quan Wen Vanderbilt University May 2012 Abstract In a bilateral bargaining problem with private

More information

This short article examines the

This short article examines the WEIDONG TIAN is a professor of finance and distinguished professor in risk management and insurance the University of North Carolina at Charlotte in Charlotte, NC. wtian1@uncc.edu Contingent Capital as

More information

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights? Leonardo Felli 15 January, 2002 Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5 Property Rights Theory The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights? For an answer we need to distinguish

More information

Moral Hazard Example. 1. The Agent s Problem. contract C = (w, w) that offers the same wage w regardless of the project s outcome.

Moral Hazard Example. 1. The Agent s Problem. contract C = (w, w) that offers the same wage w regardless of the project s outcome. Moral Hazard Example Well, then says I, what s the use you learning to do right when it s troublesome to do right and ain t no trouble to do wrong, and the wages is just the same? I was stuck. I couldn

More information

Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright

Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals. Donald J. Wright Soft Budget Constraints in Public Hospitals Donald J. Wright January 2014 VERY PRELIMINARY DRAFT School of Economics, Faculty of Arts and Social Sciences, University of Sydney, NSW, 2006, Australia, Ph:

More information

Liquidity saving mechanisms

Liquidity saving mechanisms Liquidity saving mechanisms Antoine Martin and James McAndrews Federal Reserve Bank of New York September 2006 Abstract We study the incentives of participants in a real-time gross settlement with and

More information

Expectations Management

Expectations Management Expectations Management Tsahi Versano Brett Trueman August, 2013 Abstract Empirical evidence suggests the existence of a market premium for rms whose earnings exceed analysts' forecasts and that rms respond

More information

Asymmetric Information, Debt Capacity, And Capital Structure *

Asymmetric Information, Debt Capacity, And Capital Structure * Asymmetric Information, Debt Capacity, And Capital Structure Michael. emmon University of Utah Jaime F. Zender University of Colorado Boulder Current Draft: September 20, 2011 Preliminary and Incomplete

More information

Capital Structure, Compensation Contracts and Managerial Incentives. Alan V. S. Douglas

Capital Structure, Compensation Contracts and Managerial Incentives. Alan V. S. Douglas Capital Structure, Compensation Contracts and Managerial Incentives by Alan V. S. Douglas JEL classification codes: G3, D82. Keywords: Capital structure, Optimal Compensation, Manager-Owner and Shareholder-

More information

Dynamic Lending under Adverse Selection and Limited Borrower Commitment: Can it Outperform Group Lending?

Dynamic Lending under Adverse Selection and Limited Borrower Commitment: Can it Outperform Group Lending? Dynamic Lending under Adverse Selection and Limited Borrower Commitment: Can it Outperform Group Lending? Christian Ahlin Michigan State University Brian Waters UCLA Anderson Minn Fed/BREAD, October 2012

More information

Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment

Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment Suehyun Kwon CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 6280 CATEGORY 12: EMPIRICAL AND THEORETICAL METHODS DECEMBER 2016 An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded

More information

Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts. Oliver Hart and John Moore*

Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts. Oliver Hart and John Moore* Incomplete Contracts and Ownership: Some New Thoughts by Oliver Hart and John Moore* Since Ronald Coase s famous 1937 article (Coase (1937)), economists have grappled with the question of what characterizes

More information

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Definition of Incomplete Contracts Definition of Incomplete Contracts Susheng Wang 1 2 nd edition 2 July 2016 This note defines incomplete contracts and explains simple contracts. Although widely used in practice, incomplete contracts have

More information

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard December 5, 2012 Question 1 (Comparative Performance Evaluation) Consider the same normal linear model as in Question 1 of Homework 1. This time the principal employs

More information

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants April 2008 Abstract In this paper, we determine the optimal exercise strategy for corporate warrants if investors suffer from

More information

Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty

Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty Optimal Procurement Contracts with Private Knowledge of Cost Uncertainty Chifeng Dai Department of Economics Southern Illinois University Carbondale, IL 62901, USA August 2014 Abstract We study optimal

More information

OWNERSHIP AND RESIDUAL RIGHTS OF CONTROL Ownership is usually considered the best way to incentivize economic agents:

OWNERSHIP AND RESIDUAL RIGHTS OF CONTROL Ownership is usually considered the best way to incentivize economic agents: OWNERSHIP AND RESIDUAL RIGHTS OF CONTROL Ownership is usually considered the best way to incentivize economic agents: To create To protect To increase The value of their own assets 1 How can ownership

More information

ADVERSE SELECTION PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE. 1. Introduction

ADVERSE SELECTION PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE. 1. Introduction PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE LECTURE 2 LECTURER: DR. KUMAR ANIKET Abstract. We explore adverse selection models in the microfinance literature. The traditional market failure of under and over investment

More information

How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems?

How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems? How Effectively Can Debt Covenants Alleviate Financial Agency Problems? Andrea Gamba Alexander J. Triantis Corporate Finance Symposium Cambridge Judge Business School September 20, 2014 What do we know

More information

(1 p)(1 ε)+pε p(1 ε)+(1 p)ε. ε ((1 p)(1 ε) + pε). This is indeed the case since 1 ε > ε (in turn, since ε < 1/2). QED

(1 p)(1 ε)+pε p(1 ε)+(1 p)ε. ε ((1 p)(1 ε) + pε). This is indeed the case since 1 ε > ε (in turn, since ε < 1/2). QED July 2008 Philip Bond, David Musto, Bilge Yılmaz Supplement to Predatory mortgage lending The key assumption in our model is that the incumbent lender has an informational advantage over the borrower.

More information

Bernanke and Gertler [1989]

Bernanke and Gertler [1989] Bernanke and Gertler [1989] Econ 235, Spring 2013 1 Background: Townsend [1979] An entrepreneur requires x to produce output y f with Ey > x but does not have money, so he needs a lender Once y is realized,

More information

Voluntary Disclosure with Evolving News

Voluntary Disclosure with Evolving News Voluntary Disclosure with Evolving News Cyrus Aghamolla Byeong-Je An February 18, 2018 We study a dynamic voluntary disclosure setting where the manager s information and the firm s value evolve over time.

More information

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure Corporate Financial Management Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure As we discussed in previous lectures, two extreme results, namely the irrelevance of capital structure and 100 percent

More information

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation May 1, 1997 On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation Yoshitsugu Kanemoto 1 Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo 7-3-1 Hongo, Bunkyo-ku, Tokyo 113 Japan Abstract The most important drawback

More information

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems a Note by John Hassler * and Assar Lindbeck * Institute for International Economic Studies This revision: April 2, 1996 Preliminary Abstract A rationale for

More information

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009. Do not turn the page until instructed to. Do not forget to write Problems 1 and 2 in the first Blue Book and Problems 3 and 4 in the second Blue Book. 1 Econ 101A

More information

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Corporate Control Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Managerial Discipline and Takeovers Managers often don t maximize the value of the firm; either because they are not capable

More information

Haiyang Feng College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin , CHINA

Haiyang Feng College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin , CHINA RESEARCH ARTICLE QUALITY, PRICING, AND RELEASE TIME: OPTIMAL MARKET ENTRY STRATEGY FOR SOFTWARE-AS-A-SERVICE VENDORS Haiyang Feng College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin 300072,

More information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information - preliminary and incomplete, please do not cite - Working Paper R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information Andreas Frick Heidrun C. Hoppe-Wewetzer Georgios Katsenos June 28, 2016 Abstract

More information

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Those taking the FINAL have THREE hours Part A (Glaeser): 55

More information

Asymmetric Information, Debt Capacity, And Capital Structure *

Asymmetric Information, Debt Capacity, And Capital Structure * Asymmetric Information, Debt Capacity, And Capital Structure * Michael. emmon Blackrock Jaime F. Zender niversity of Colorado Boulder Current Draft: June, 016 * emmon: (801)585-510 finmll@business.utah.edu;

More information

Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective

Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective Olivier Compte and Philippe Jehiel November 2003 Abstract A principal has to choose among several agents to fulfill a task and then provide

More information

Information Processing and Limited Liability

Information Processing and Limited Liability Information Processing and Limited Liability Bartosz Maćkowiak European Central Bank and CEPR Mirko Wiederholt Northwestern University January 2012 Abstract Decision-makers often face limited liability

More information

Lecture 1: Introduction, Optimal financing contracts, Debt

Lecture 1: Introduction, Optimal financing contracts, Debt Corporate finance theory studies how firms are financed (public and private debt, equity, retained earnings); Jensen and Meckling (1976) introduced agency costs in corporate finance theory (not only the

More information

Auctions in the wild: Bidding with securities. Abhay Aneja & Laura Boudreau PHDBA 279B 1/30/14

Auctions in the wild: Bidding with securities. Abhay Aneja & Laura Boudreau PHDBA 279B 1/30/14 Auctions in the wild: Bidding with securities Abhay Aneja & Laura Boudreau PHDBA 279B 1/30/14 Structure of presentation Brief introduction to auction theory First- and second-price auctions Revenue Equivalence

More information

CONSUMPTION AND INVESTMENT DECISION: AN ANALYSIS OF AGGREGATE AND TIME-ADDITIVE MODELS

CONSUMPTION AND INVESTMENT DECISION: AN ANALYSIS OF AGGREGATE AND TIME-ADDITIVE MODELS CONSUMPTION AND INVESTMENT DECISION: AN ANALYSIS OF AGGREGATE AND TIME-ADDITIVE MODELS By LIANG FU A DISSERTATION PRESENTED TO THE GRADUATE SCHOOL OF THE UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF

More information

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3 EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3 Leonardo Felli 32L.G.06 26 January 2015 Failure of the Coase Theorem Recall that the Coase Theorem implies that two parties, when faced with a potential

More information

THEORIES OF BEHAVIOR IN PRINCIPAL-AGENT RELATIONSHIPS WITH HIDDEN ACTION*

THEORIES OF BEHAVIOR IN PRINCIPAL-AGENT RELATIONSHIPS WITH HIDDEN ACTION* 1 THEORIES OF BEHAVIOR IN PRINCIPAL-AGENT RELATIONSHIPS WITH HIDDEN ACTION* Claudia Keser a and Marc Willinger b a IBM T.J. Watson Research Center and CIRANO, Montreal b BETA, Université Louis Pasteur,

More information

Incentives for Innovation and Delegated versus Centralized Capital Budgeting

Incentives for Innovation and Delegated versus Centralized Capital Budgeting Incentives for Innovation and Delegated versus Centralized Capital Budgeting Sunil Dutta Qintao Fan Abstract This paper investigates how the allocation of investment decision authority affects managers

More information

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring Harold L. Cole and Narayana Kocherlakota Working Paper 604 September 2000 Cole: U.C.L.A. and Federal Reserve

More information

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION Szabolcs Sebestyén szabolcs.sebestyen@iscte.pt Master in Finance INVESTMENTS Sebestyén (ISCTE-IUL) Choice Theory Investments 1 / 65 Outline 1 An Introduction

More information

Counterparty Risk in the Over-the-Counter Derivatives Market: Heterogeneous Insurers with Non-commitment

Counterparty Risk in the Over-the-Counter Derivatives Market: Heterogeneous Insurers with Non-commitment Counterparty Risk in the Over-the-Counter Derivatives Market: Heterogeneous Insurers with Non-commitment Hao Sun November 16, 2017 Abstract I study risk-taking and optimal contracting in the over-the-counter

More information

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Feedback Effect and Capital Structure Minh Vo Metropolitan State University Abstract This paper develops a model of financing with informational feedback effect that jointly determines a firm s capital

More information

Optimal Labor Contracts with Asymmetric Information and More than Two Types of Agent

Optimal Labor Contracts with Asymmetric Information and More than Two Types of Agent Theoretical and Applied Economics Volume XIX (2012), No. 5(570), pp. 5-18 Optimal Labor Contracts with Asymmetric Information and ore than Two Types of Agent Daniela Elena ARINESCU ucharest Academy of

More information

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models IEOR E4707: Foundations of Financial Engineering c 206 by Martin Haugh Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models These notes develop the theory of martingale pricing in a discrete-time,

More information

Yao s Minimax Principle

Yao s Minimax Principle Complexity of algorithms The complexity of an algorithm is usually measured with respect to the size of the input, where size may for example refer to the length of a binary word describing the input,

More information

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay Juyan Zhang and Yi Zhang February 20, 2011 Abstract We investigate hold-up in the case of both simultaneous and sequential investment. We show that if

More information

Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information. Appendix

Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information. Appendix Optimal Long-Term Supply Contracts with Asymmetric Demand Information Ilan Lobel Appendix Wenqiang iao {ilobel, wxiao}@stern.nyu.edu Stern School of Business, New York University Appendix A: Proofs Proof

More information

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Partial privatization as a source of trade gains Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University April 12, 2008 Abstract A model of mixed oligopoly is constructed in which a Home public firm

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren October, 2013 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

research paper series

research paper series research paper series Research Paper 00/9 Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market by A. Mukherjee The Centre acknowledges financial support from The

More information

Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items

Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items Nir Shabbat - 05305311 December 5, 2012 Introduction The paper I read is called Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items by Sergiu Hart

More information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV GAME THEORY SOLUTION SET 1 WINTER 018 PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV Introduction For suggested solution to problem 4, last year s suggested solutions by Tsz-Ning Wong were used who I think used suggested

More information

Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types

Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types Dilip Mookherjee Boston University Ec 703b Lecture 1 (text: FT Ch 7, 243-257) DM (BU) Mech Design 703b.1 2019 1 / 1 Introduction Introduction to Mechanism

More information

SAVING-INVESTMENT CORRELATION. Introduction. Even though financial markets today show a high degree of integration, with large amounts

SAVING-INVESTMENT CORRELATION. Introduction. Even though financial markets today show a high degree of integration, with large amounts 138 CHAPTER 9: FOREIGN PORTFOLIO EQUITY INVESTMENT AND THE SAVING-INVESTMENT CORRELATION Introduction Even though financial markets today show a high degree of integration, with large amounts of capital

More information

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems

Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Online Appendix for Military Mobilization and Commitment Problems Ahmer Tarar Department of Political Science Texas A&M University 4348 TAMU College Station, TX 77843-4348 email: ahmertarar@pols.tamu.edu

More information

Adverse Selection When Agents Envy Their Principal. KANGSIK CHOI June 7, 2004

Adverse Selection When Agents Envy Their Principal. KANGSIK CHOI June 7, 2004 THE INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Working Paper Series No. 92 Adverse Selection When Agents Envy Their Principal KANGSIK CHOI June 7, 2004 KAGAWA UNIVERSITY Takamatsu, Kagawa 760-8523 JAPAN Adverse Selection

More information

Public-private Partnerships in Micro-finance: Should NGO Involvement be Restricted?

Public-private Partnerships in Micro-finance: Should NGO Involvement be Restricted? MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Public-private Partnerships in Micro-finance: Should NGO Involvement be Restricted? Prabal Roy Chowdhury and Jaideep Roy Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi Center and

More information

Peer monitoring and moral hazard in underdeveloped credit markets. Shubhashis Gangopadhyay* and Robert Lensink**

Peer monitoring and moral hazard in underdeveloped credit markets. Shubhashis Gangopadhyay* and Robert Lensink** eer monitoring and moral hazard in underdeveloped credit markets. Shubhashis angopadhyay* and Robert ensink** *ndia Development Foundation, ndia. **Faculty of Economics, University of roningen, The Netherlands.

More information

A Solution to Two Paradoxes of International Capital Flows. Jiandong Ju and Shang-Jin Wei. Discussion by Fabio Ghironi

A Solution to Two Paradoxes of International Capital Flows. Jiandong Ju and Shang-Jin Wei. Discussion by Fabio Ghironi A Solution to Two Paradoxes of International Capital Flows Jiandong Ju and Shang-Jin Wei Discussion by Fabio Ghironi NBER Summer Institute International Finance and Macroeconomics Program July 10-14, 2006

More information