How Do Managerial Styles Differentiate Across Bank Reactions to Systemic Crises? *

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "How Do Managerial Styles Differentiate Across Bank Reactions to Systemic Crises? *"

Transcription

1 How Do Managerial Styles Differentiate Across Bank Reactions to Systemic Crises? * Yu Shan April 29th, 2018 Abstract In the face of systemic crises, some bank managers reduce credit risk in their loan portfolios, whereas others exploit potential government bailouts and increase their internal credit risk. I use a connectedness sample method to differentiate risk taking across managerial styles. I find that asset innovators most aggressively reduce within-bank credit risk during financial crises, whereas liability innovators increase internal bank credit risk. However, during non-crisis periods, a bank s credit risk is positively related to its systemic risk exposure, indicating a baseline risk-taking proclivity. Results are robust with regard to within-loan, dynamic generalized method of moments, and lead-lag analysis. JEL Classifications: G20, G21, G24, G28. Keywords: Systemic Risk, Credit Risk, Public Guarantee, Syndicated Bank Loans, Manager Style, Risk-taking, Bank Governance. * I m grateful to Linda Allen for her invaluable support and guidance over the course of this project. I would like to also thank Ayan Bhattacharya, Gayle Delong, Sonali Hazarika, Armen Hovakimian, Michael LaCour-Little, Rajarishi Nahata, Lin Peng, Yao Shen, Nancy Wallace, Jun Wang, Ayako Yasuda, Yildiray Yildirim, Dexin Zhou, and seminar/conference participants at the Baruch College Brownbag Seminar and Financial Management Association 2017 Annual Meeting for their insightful suggestions and comments. All errors are my own. Ph.D. candidate in finance, Bert W. Wasserman Department of Economics and Finance, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College, New York, NY 10010, yu.shan@baruch.cuny.edu.

2 1. Introduction What are the reactions of financial firms to potential systemic crises or changes in their systemic importance? What determines their reactions? These topics form a part of the broader discussion of management and regulation of systemically important financial institutions. When a systemically important bank fails, there would be significant disruption to financial markets and the overall economy, thereby justifying implicit or explicit government guarantees and subsidies. Previous research has discussed the effect of government guarantees on bank risk-taking behavior. Several researchers have argued that bailout expectations may increase banks risk-taking behavior. This, in turn, may imply a decline in market discipline (Flannery, 1998; Sironi, 2003; Gropp, Vesala, and Vulps, 2006; Acharya, Anginer, and Warburton, 2016) and increase in moral hazard (Kane, 1989; Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache, 2002; Diamond and Rajan, 2009; Farhi and Tirole, 2012). Other researchers have challenged these conclusions and have proposed a risk-reducing effect driven by higher charter values (Cordella and Levy-Yeyati, 2003), lower undiversifiable contagion risk across banks (Freixas, Parigi, and Rochet, 2000; Allen and Gale, 2001; Diamond and Rajan, 2005; Dell Ariccia and Ratnovski, 2013; Choi, 2014), and clawback provisions (Allen and Li, 2011). Although extant research focuses on establishing a connection between implicit government guarantees and banks risk-taking behavior, these studies do not explore the direct association between risks taken by individual financial institutions and their systemic risk contribution. Current systemic bank regulations, which include countercyclical capital buffers and total loss-absorbing capacity requirements, are considered to be add-ons and do not fully integrate established individual bank risk taking measures (such as risk-based capital regulations) into newer systemic risk regulations. Bank regulations would lead to suboptimal outcomes if an existing association between systemic risk and disaggregated risk exposure on an individual bank basis is ignored. For example, if banks consistently reduce their individual risk exposure during a rise of systemic risk, then systemic bank regulations can be milder due to this automatic stabilizer. Alternatively, if banks regularly aggravate their own risk exposure by exploiting potential moral hazard advantages, systemic risk regulation would not be enough to address system-wide crises. This paper aims to complement extant literature by determining a direct relation between systemic risk and each individual bank s risktaking behavior. In particular, the paper examines whether and how banks internally adjust the credit risk in their syndicated bank loan portfolios as their measure of systemic risk changes. This paper focuses on credit risk because of its dominance in the internal risk exposure of banks (estimated to be approximately 60% of a bank s total risk). Furthermore, this paper defines how banks adjust their credit risk exposure to systemic risk changes as the banks credit-risk sensitivity to systemic risk. 1

3 In this study, I develop and test an empirical measure of each bank s credit-risk sensitivity to systemic risk. I specifically focus on banks credit risk-taking behavior concerning the newly originated syndicated bank loans. Credit risk is a major source of idiosyncratic risk in bank portfolios, and syndicated loans expose syndicate members to a choice of credit risk levels by deciding on participation and the amount of allocation share to contribute in a loan. I use data on syndicated bank loans to examine whether financial institutions adjust their credit risk-taking in response to levels of systemic risks. I measure the credit risk using borrower distance-to-default during loan origination while controlling for several loan characteristics. During periods of no recession or low macro-level systemic risk, bank systemic risk is positively related to credit risk-taking. That is, the more the bank contributes to overall systemic risk, the higher the credit risk in the syndicated bank loan portfolio. This indicates that banks may develop a tendency to seek abnormal returns from risk-enhancing activities. The study provides a robust result that applies to several different specifications, which control for loan, borrower, and bank characteristics, lending relationships, macroeconomic conditions, in addition to a series of fixed effects and endogeneity controls. The study findings reveal that during economic recession or a heightened risk of systemic crisis, there is a weakening in the positive relation between systemic risk and credit risk-taking. Moreover, the banks with the highest systemic risk lower the credit risk in their loan portfolios the most. This implies that during times of economic volatility, the increased risk of insolvency with the potential loss of bank charter value induces banks to reduce their insolvency risk by reducing their credit risk exposure. This acts as an automatic risk-taking stabilizer in the banking system, linking systemic risk to credit risk on an individual bank basis. The study results indicate that during times of volatility, systemically important banks maintain high levels of systemic risk to benefit from government bailouts even while minimizing their credit risk exposure. This may alleviate some of the uncertainty about whether the federal government will support a particular distressed bank. That is, increased systemic risk and reduced loan portfolio credit risk together may improve the chances of government support. These results are consistent with the Baker, Bloom, and Davis (2016) policy uncertainty index, which hit a peak after Lehman Brothers failed, as well as the subsequent reforms codified in the Dodd Frank Act and the Consumer Protection Act, which explicitly aim to reduce expectations of government shield. However, there is much heterogeneity across different banks in their adjustment of credit-risk sensitivity to systemic risk during systemic crises. The most risk-averse banks (as measured by the lower ex-ante credit risk in their syndicated bank loan portfolios) usually retract their internal risk taking when systemic crises are imminent, thereby reducing their credit risk exposure much more than less risk-averse (higher credit risk) banks. On a portfolio basis, the overall sign of the measures of the credit-risk sensitivity to systemic risk flips from negative to positive. In other words, the higher the bank s systemic risk, the lower the bank s 2

4 credit risk in its syndicated bank loan portfolio. This suggests a bank-specific idiosyncratic component. In this paper, I empirically identify this heterogeneity in risk-taking proclivity across banks as managerial style. Extant banking literature mainly assesses the impact of systemic importance and implicit government guarantees on banks risk-taking from an organizational perspective. It ignores the influence of human factors in shaping a bank s responses to potential systemic crises and changes in their bank s systemic importance. Top managers are the main decision makers in a wide range of corporate decisions (Bertrand and Schoar, 2003). Banking studies have suggested that executive compensation, board characteristics, and ownership structure can significantly impact bank risk-taking and bank performance (Beltratti and Stulz, 2012; DeYoung et al., 2013; Erkens et al., 2012; Berger et al., 2014; Minton et al., 2014). However, literature on how idiosyncratic executive-specific effects help explain bank risk-taking behavior is scarce. This study examines the role of managerial styles in determining the variation in banks internal risk-taking responses to changes in systemic importance or potential systemic crisis. It complements the literature in that it investigates how executive attributes or styles, which are independent of observable compensation incentives (e.g., Delta, Vega, and Bonus) and biographical characteristics (age and gender), help explain a large variation in bank s credit risk-taking sensitivity to systemic risk. The paper further examines managerial attitudes toward risk-taking (i.e., managerial style) and finds that differences among different managers, not banks, explain the heterogeneous response of credit risk to heightened systemic risk exposure. This result is consistent with that of Hagendorff et al. (2017). They argued that extreme risk-taking and other unsustainable business models in banking could ultimately be a people problem rooted in the idiosyncratic preferences of individuals and are not easily restrained by regulators and investors. This paper analyzes how idiosyncratic executive-specific effects explain the variation in credit-risk sensitivity to bank-level systemic risk in order to identify the implications of managerial style for risk-taking. I find that banks credit-risk sensitivity to systemic risk is significantly affected by few idiosyncratic manager preferences, that is, managerial styles. Focusing on executives such as CEOs, CFOs, COOs, and executive directors and using the connectedness sample method of Abowd, Kramarz, and Margolis (1999) (AKM, thereafter), I run a series of three-way fixed effects regressions (bank, executives, and year) to estimate the bank and executive fixed effects. Furthermore, I conduct factor analyses for the executive (bank) fixed effects to find dominant factors in explaining patterns across the styles of individual executives (banks). The two dominant factors show two dimensions of innovations that executives and banks show as preferences: asset side and liability side. Executives asset- and liability-side innovation preferences significantly affect a bank s credit-risk sensitivity to systemic risk. 3

5 Based on the loadings of individual executives on the two main factors, I assign each executive into one of four types: (1) Asset innovator but liability traditionalist; (2) Asset and liability innovator; (3) Asset and liability traditionalist; (4) Asset traditionalist and liability innovator. Intuitively, asset innovators are more likely to diversify into mortgage-backed securities and derivatives, whereas traditionalists focus more on lending. Unlike liability traditionalists, liability innovators are more likely to access non-deposit sources of funds. Banks managed by different types of executives exhibit different credit risk-taking sensitivities to systemic risk. In particular, asset innovators restrain and reduce the bank s credit-risk sensitivity to systemic risk during financial crises, whereas liability innovators increase the bank s credit-risk sensitivity to systemic risk during crises. This effect is unique to a manager, rather than a bank, indicating that human attributes, not institutional reasons, may be the leading cause for the often-cited too-big-to-fail problem. In robustness checks, the result is not replicated for a placebo test. The endogenous lender borrower matching is a concern in relation to the baseline model of creditrisk sensitivity to systemic risk. Thus, the results are subject to possible borrower self-selection despite the use of controls and fixed effects in my analysis. A few unknown characteristics of borrowers might induce borrowing firms to choose certain banks, thereby introducing selection bias into the analysis. Borrowers may also respond to bank risk-taking. For example, risky borrowers may depend more on stable refinancing sources during economic downturns and systemic crises. Therefore, risky borrowers may request loans from systemically important banks protected by public guarantees; therefore, they are more likely to survive during economic turmoil. Thus, distinguishing the supply-side from demand-side effects is important. I adopt two methods in this study. First, I conduct a two-stage least-square analysis and employ the geographic distance and number of banks in the state of the borrower as instruments for observed lending relationships. Second, I employ a series of within-loan analyses to empirically control for the demand effects of lending at systemically important banks. I use a within-loan regression analysis that controls for borrower self-selection of lenders to test my findings of a direct relation between systemic risk and credit risk (following the methodology of Chu, Zhang and Zhao, 2017). Based on the fact that a syndicated loan often has multiple lenders, I examine how the systemic risks of banks that fund the same loan affect their contributions to the loan, that is, within-loan estimation, which eliminates any fluctuation on the demand side. I find that systemically risky banks contribute a larger (smaller) portion to risky (safe) loans. The results are more significant for loans with excessive risks compared with other loans originated in the same year. This finding suggests that the direct relationship between systemic risk 4

6 and internal bank credit risk taking during non-crisis periods is driven by supply factors, thereby indicating underlying bank risk-taking proclivities. Endogeneity may also arise from reverse causality such that prior credit risk-taking may affect the current values of bank systemic risk. In fact, current values of systemic risk may not be independent of the credit risk-taking on previous loans. Thus, ignoring the dynamic nature of the independent and dependent variable relation may yield biased and inconsistent estimates (Wintoki, Linck, and Netter, 2012). Two methods are adopted to alleviate the reverse causality concern. First, I use a set of leadlag regressions and find that the causality runs from systemic risk to credit risk and not vice versa. Second, the method by Wintoki, Linck, and Netter (2012) is adopted using a dynamic panel generalized method of moments (GMM) estimation, which confirms the baseline analysis. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 introduces the model development. Section 3 reports the variable construction. Section 4 discusses the data and sample construction. Section 5 presents the empirical results, including the baseline results, a two-stage least-squares analysis controlling for borrower self-selection, a lead-lag analysis, and within-loan estimations. Section 6 provides robustness checks, including a different version of within-loan regression and a dynamic panel GMM analysis. Section 7 focuses on how idiosyncratic executive-specific styles explain the variation in credit risk-taking sensitivity to bank-level systemic risk. Section 8 presents the conclusion. 2. Model Development 2.1. The Credit-Risk Sensitivity Model This paper is based on the broad literature on bank bailout and its effects on bank risk-taking. Banks systemic risk, or systemic importance, is directly related to the likelihood of government bailout when the banking firm is in distress, and government credit guarantees can reduce investors risk exposures. Accordingly, clear evidence of market discipline may be difficult to find (Flannery, 1998). Empirical literature has found supporting evidence that the implicit safety nets weaken the predictive power of bank equity and debt prices on bank fragility (Gropp, Vesala, and Vulps, 2006). Furthermore, debt spreads are insensitive to bank risk for debts issued by public sector banks (Sironi, 2003) or largest financial institutions (Acharya, Anginer, and Warburton, 2016). Therefore, banks find it profitable to adopt a risky balance sheet and correlate their risk exposures (Farhi and Tirole, 2012). Some studies have claimed that safety nets in the banking industry lead to additional risk-taking by protected banks (Dam and Koetter, 2012) as well as their competitors (Gropp, Hakenes, and Schnabel, 2011). At the macroeconomic level, Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache (2002) found that explicit government guarantees increase overall bank 5

7 fragility. In particular, with regard to the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) recipients, Black and Hazelwood (2013) found that large TARP banks initiate riskier loans, which suggests moral hazard due to government support. In contrast to this argument on moral hazard, some studies have proposed a charter value effect through which banks may decrease risk-taking in response to expected public guarantees (Cordella and Levy-Yeyati, 2003). Hakenes and Schnabel (2010) indicated that protected banks may take lower risks when transparency in the banking sector is low and the deposit supply is sufficiently elastic. This paper complements the extant research by investigating the direct relation between financial institutions risk-taking in isolation and their systemic risk contribution. It examines how banks endogenously change their credit risk in their loan portfolio in response to changes in the systemic risks, termed as banks credit risk-taking sensitivity to systemic risks. Two complementary measures of systemic risk are used in this paper. CATFIN (Allen, Bali and Tang, 2012), which is a cross-sectional measure that identifies the overall level of systemic risk in the financial system at each point in time, is used to measure the macro-level aggregate systemic risk. This helps examine whether high levels of aggregate systemic risk that are likely to lead to government bailouts or other interventions induce banks to adjust the credit risk in their loan portfolios upward or downward. ΔCoVaR is used to measure the microlevel systemic risk contribution of each bank (Adrian and Brunnermeier, 2016) to determine the impact of an individual bank s insolvency on systemic risk in the overall financial system. The greater the contribution of an individual bank s insolvency to market-wide systemic risk, the greater is its imposition of systemic risk onto the macroeconomy. I use borrower distance-to-default as the key dependent variable to investigate whether the bank s systemic risk exposure (CATFIN and ΔCoVaR) is related to its decision to lend to borrowers of differing risk levels. I employ an array of control variables such as loan, borrower, and bank characteristics, lending relationships, macroeconomic conditions, as well as a series of fixed effects. A possible concern about the baseline regressions is the endogenous lender borrower matching such that the tests are subject to borrower self-selection. Some unobservable borrower characteristics may induce borrowing firms to choose certain banks, thereby introducing selection bias into the analysis. Borrowers may also respond to bank risk-taking. For example, risky borrowers may depend more on stable refinancing sources, especially during economic downturns. Therefore, risky borrowers may request loans from systemically important banks, which may be protected by public guarantees; thus, they are more likely to survive during periods of economic turmoil. The focus of this study is to examine whether banks control the credit risk in their loan portfolios by adjusting their credit and underwriting standards. Therefore, it is important to separate the supply-side from demand-side effects. This is done using two methods: first, I 6

8 conduct a two-stage least-square analysis and employ the geographic distance and number of banks in the state of the borrower as instruments for observed lending relationships. In the first stage, I regress the lending relationship variable on geographic distance and number of banks and other independent variables. In the second stage, I rerun the baseline regression using fitted value of lending relationship in all specifications. This method allows controlling for the probability of originating a loan between a firm i and a bank j that is independent of the channel of systemically risky banks selecting borrower with certain default risks. Second, I use a series of within-loan analysis to empirically control for the demand effects of lending at systemically important banks. In other words, I use a within-loan regression analysis that controls for borrower self-selection of lenders to test the findings of a direct relation between systemic risk and credit risk (Chu, Zhang and Zhao, 2017). Exploiting the unique feature that a syndicated loan often has multiple lenders, I examine how the systemic risks of banks that fund the same loan affect their contributions to the loan, that is, within-loan estimation, which eliminates any fluctuation on the demand side. Endogeneity may also arise from reverse causality such that current values of bank systemic risk can be affected by credit risk-taking in previous periods. In fact, current values of systemic risk may not be independent of the credit risk-taking on previous loans, and ignoring the dynamic nature of the independent and dependent variable relation may yield biased and inconsistent estimates (Wintoki, Linck, and Netter, 2012). I employ two methods to alleviate the reverse causality concern. First, using contemporaneous borrower s distance-to-default (or lender s ΔCoVaR) as the dependent variables, I use a set of lead-lag regressions and test whether they are associated with lagged lender s ΔCoVaR (or lagged borrower s distance-to-default). Second, the method of Wintoki, Linck, and Netter (2012) is adopted using a dynamic panel GMM estimation. There are several advantages of using dynamic panel GMM method. First, it allows current explanatory variables to be influenced by previous realizations of dependent variable. Second, it eliminates unobservable heterogeneity by first differencing all dependent and independent variables. Third, it uses the combination of variables from the history as valid instruments to account for simultaneity. The dynamic panel GMM estimation confirms the earlier findings Managerial Style Model Extant literature on banking mainly assesses the impact of systemic importance and implicit government guarantees on banks risk-taking from an organizational perspective. It ignores the influence of human factors in shaping a bank s responses to potential systemic crises and changes in their bank s systemic importance. Top managers have a significant influence on a wide range of corporate decisions (Bertrand and Schoar, 2003). Recent banking studies have suggested that 7

9 executive demographic characteristics and compensation, board characteristics, and ownership structure can significantly impact bank risk-taking and bank performance (Beltratti and Stulz, 2012; DeYoung et al., 2013; Erkens et al., 2012; Berger et al., 2014; Minton et al., 2014; Nguyen, Hagendorff and Eshraghi, 2017). In particular, Berger, Kick and Schaeck (2014) indicated that demographic characteristics of executive teams influence corporate governance in banking. Faccio, Marchica, and Mura (2016) documented CEO gender differences in risk-taking and capital allocation efficiency. However, these studies have not examined the idiosyncratic executive-specific effects that explain the variation in banks responses to changes in systemic importance or potential systemic crisis. The study focuses on a time-invariant measure of each individual manager s attitude toward risktaking, termed as the manager s style, instead of focusing on time-varying observable characteristics such as compensation and demographic characteristics. It adopts the method proposed by Hagendorff et al. (2017). They suggested that compensation and various other observable executive characteristics can only describe a small amount of the variation in banks business models and risktaking preferences. They found that much of the variation in bank business policy can be explained by time-invariant executive factors ( styles ), which explain the risk-taking culture in some banks. Since bank credit risk-taking sensitivity to systemic risk is mostly related to bank business models and how banks are managed (aggressively or conservatively) by executives, its variation may also be explained by the unobservable, time-invariant executive fixed effects. This paper complements the literature by investigating how executive attributes or styles, which are independent of observable compensation incentives (delta, vega, and bonus) and biographical characteristics (age and gender), explain a large variation in bank s credit risk-taking sensitivity to systemic risk. 3. Variable Constructions 3.1. Systemic Risks Two complementary measures of systemic risk are used in this paper. CATFIN is used to measure the macro-level aggregate systemic risk (Allen, Bali and Tang, 2012). It is a cross-sectional measure that identifies the overall level of systemic risk in the financial system at each point in time. It examines whether high levels of aggregate systemic risk that are likely to lead to government bailouts or other interventions induce banks to adjust the credit risk in their loan portfolios upward or downward. ΔCoVaR is used to measure the micro-level systemic risk (Adrian and Brunnermeier, 2016). It determines the impact of an individual bank s insolvency on systemic risk in the overall financial system. The greater the contribution of an individual bank s insolvency to market-wide systemic risk, the greater the individual bank s 8

10 imposition of systemic risk on the macroeconomy. This measure determines whether the bank s systemic risk exposure impacts its decision to lend to borrowers of differing risk levels. To construct the macro-level systemic risk, CATFIN 1, the method proposed by Allen, Bali, and Tang (2012), is used and VaR at the 99% confidence level is estimated using three different methodologies: the generalized Pareto distribution (GPD), the skewed generalized error distribution (SGED), and the nonparametric estimation method based on the left tail of the actual empirical distribution without any assumptions about the underlying return distribution. CATFIN is defined as the arithmetic average of the GPD, SGED, and nonparametric VaR measures. Allen, Bali, and Tang (2012) suggested that the risk of macroeconomic slump increases when CATFIN is above some early warning level, which is determined using the Chicago Fed National Activity Index (CFNAI) as a benchmark. CFNAI is an index of 85 existing monthly economic indicators. The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago denotes the three-month moving average of CFNAI (CFNAI-MA3) value of 0.7 as a turning point indicating economic contraction. Allen, Bali, and Tang (2012) demonstrated that when CATFIN is above some early warning level, it can significantly predict lower economic activity (CFNAI-MA3) one to eight months in advance of the slump. Therefore, CATFIN offers an early warning to alert regulators regarding the risk of economic recessions. This paper also tests whether banks credit risk-taking is affected by whether CATFIN breaches the early warning level. Following Allen, Bali, and Tang (2012), I construct an early warning dummy, which is equal to 1 if CATFIN is above the early warning level and 0 otherwise. For each quarter t, the early warning level is calculated as the median CATFIN using all observations up to quarter t in which CFNAI-MA3 falls below 0.7. To address possible reverse causality, both contemporaneous and lagged measures of systemic risk are used to examine the following quarter s credit risk in the bank s loan portfolio. A historical monthly CATFIN, CFNAI-MA3, Early Warning Level, and Warning dummy are presented in the Online Appendix. The micro-level systemic risk is measured by following the methodology used by Adrian and Brunnermeier (2016) to generate time-varying ΔCoVaR 2. First, I run the following quantile regressions in the weekly data (where j is a financial institution): X j t = α j q + γ j q M t 1 + ε j q,t, (4) 1 I thank Linda Allen and Yi Tang for providing the data on CATFIN. 2 I thank Tobias Adrian and Markus Brunnermeier for sharing their code for computing CoVaR. 9

11 X system j t = α system j q M t 1 + β system j q M t 1 + β system j q X j t + ε system j q,t, (5) where X j system j t denotes the weekly return of institution j in week t, X t denotes the financial sector return in week t, and M t 1 denotes a vector of seven systematic state variables in week t, including three-month yield change, term spread change, TED spread, credit spread change, market return, real estate excess return, and equity volatility. Thereafter, I generate the predicted values from these regressions to obtain j VaR q,t = α q j + γ q j M t 1, (6) j CoVaR q,t = α q system j + r q system j M t 1 + β q system j VaR j q,t, (7) j Finally, I compute the ΔCoVaR q,t for each institution: j ΔCoVaR q,t j = CoVaR q,t j CoVaR 50,t = β system j j (VaR q,t j VaR 50,t ) (8) These regressions result in a panel of weekly ΔCoVaR j j q,t. A quarterly time series of ΔCoVaR q,t is obtained by averaging the weekly risk measures within each quarter. Throughout the paper, q equals 99%, but the results are robust to the 95% level Credit Risk-Taking This paper uses the Merton distance-to-default as a measure of borrower default risk. Since credit risk can also be affected by loan characteristics such as loan amount, maturity, and being secured or not, I control for an array of loan characteristics. The method followed by Bharath and Bharath and Shumway (2008) and Crosbie and Bohn (2003) is adopted in calculating Merton s distance-to-default. The market equity value of a company is modeled as a call option on the company s assets: V E = V A e dt N(d 1 ) Xe rt N(d 2 ) + (1 e dt )V A (1) d 1 = log(v A X )+(r+s A 2 2 )T s A ; d 2 = d 1 s A T (2) where V E denotes the market value of a firm s equity, which is calculated from the CRSP database as the product of share price at the end of the quarter and the number of shares outstanding. X denotes the face value of debt maturing at time T, which is calculated as debt in current liabilities (COMPUSTAT data item 45) plus one half of long-term debt (COMPUSTAT data item 51). V A denotes the value of the firm s assets; r denotes the risk-free rate, which is defined as the 1-year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate obtained from 10

12 the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. s A denotes the volatility of the value of assets. I simultaneously solve the above two equations to find the values of V A and s A. Quarterly Merton s distanceto-default is finally computed as Distance to Default = log (VA ) + (m s 2 A )T X 2 s A T (3) I also calculate quarterly distance-to-default as a robustness check by first calculating the monthly distanceto-default and then taking quarterly averages. Both measures generate similar results in the baseline regressions Bank Business Policy Variables Banks follow different business policies characterized by the selection of different profit-earning assets and funding sources. Based on bank balance sheet data, I follow Hagendorff et al. (2017) and utilize eight bank policy variables that reflect strategic management choices. First, I include noninterest income over the sum of interest and noninterest income (Noninterest income) as a bank s choice between lending-based and feebased activities. Similarly, I use the ratio of loans over total assets (Loans) to measure a bank s focus on interest-generating assets. On the liability side, I measure banks funding structures using loans over total deposits (Loans/Deposits) and the proportion of liabilities that are not financed via deposits (Nondeposit funding). To identify banks with more focus on the trading book and on the banking book, two variables are used: the ratio of mortgage-backed securities over total assets (MBS) and the logarithm of the ratio of the notional amount of derivative contracts held for trading to total assets (Derivatives). To describe banks efforts to reduce diversifiable risk, the term lending diversification is used, which is defined as 1 minus the Herfindahl Index of the shares of real estate, commercial and industrial, consumer, and other loans over total assets. Finally, a bank s funding liquidity risk-taking is measured using the difference between liabilities repricing or maturing within 12 months and assets repricing or maturing with 12 months, scaled by total assets. Detailed definitions for the bank business policy variables are defined in Appendix I Compensation Incentives Literature has shown that banks risk-taking behavior can be influenced by manager compensation incentives (Fahlenbrach and Stulz, 2011; DeYoung et al., 2013; Berger et al., 2014; Nguyen et al., 2017). Executive compensation influences managerial risk preferences through executives portfolio sensitivities to changes in stock prices (Delta) and stock return volatility (Vega). Delta is the sensitivity of manager wealth to bank performance. It is calculated as the dollar changes in manager wealth to stock price 11

13 performance. Vega measures the sensitivity of manager wealth to bank risk, and it is calculated as the dollar change in wealth associated with a 1% increase in stock return volatility. If riskier bank policy increases stock price and volatility, then managers with high Delta or Vega have more incentives to engage in riskier bank policies. Both Delta and Vega are scaled by cash compensation and transformed to natural logarithm. I also control for the log of cash bonus (Bonus) since it is distinct from equity-based compensation and might impact a manager s risk preferences Control Variables I use a set of control variables for loan, borrower, and lender characteristics. To ensure that outliers do not strongly influence statistical results, all observations are set higher than the 99th percentile of each variable to that value; all values lower than the 1 st percentile of each variable are similarly winsorized. All variables are defined in Appendix I. The first set of control variables include bank characteristics such as Bank Total Assets, Bank Capital Ratio, Return on Equity, Liquidity, Loan Charge-offs, Loan Loss Allowance, and Risk-Weighted Assets. Since ΔCoVaR is constructed using market data and most public banks are bank holding companies, bank financial information is measured at the bank holding company level. ln(bank Total Assets) is defined as the natural logarithm of bank total assets (in billions); Bank Capital Ratio is defined as the bank s total capital over bank s total assets; Bank ROE is defined as bank net income over book equity; Bank Liquidity is defined as the sum of cash and available-for-sale securities divided by bank total assets; Loan Chargeoffs is defined as the total charge-offs on loans and leases divided by bank total assets; Loan Loss Allowance is defined as the total allowance for loan and lease losses divided by bank total assets; Risk-Weighted Assets is defined as total risk weighted assets divided by bank total assets. Although I include both lead lenders and participants in all the regressions in the study, I add a lead bank dummy in the within-loan regressions to account for possible unobservable differences between lead and nonlead banks. A bank is defined as a lead lender if its lend arranger credit variable is Yes in Dealscan. The second set of control variables comprises borrower characteristics. ln(borrower Total Assets) is defined as the natural logarithm of total assets (in billions); Tangibility is defined as total property, plant, and equipment divided by total assets; Leverage is defined as the total debt divided by total assets. I also include a lending relationship measure, as in the study by Bharath et al. (2007), since the intensity of past lending relationships can influence the matching between borrowers and lenders. The lending relationship between borrower i and bank j is defined as the dollar amount of loans to borrower i by bank j in the past five years over the total dollar amount of loans by borrower i in the past five years. 12

14 Thereafter, I control for an array of loan characteristics. ln(package Amount) is defined as the natural log of the package amount, where package amount is measured in millions. ln(package Maturity) is defined as the natural log of the maturity of the deal in months. Package maturity is calculated as the value-weighted average of the facility maturities. ln(no. of Lead Banks) is the natural log of the number of lead lenders in the deal syndicate. Finally, I control for macroeconomic conditions. Quarterly GDP per capita growth rate is used to measure the macroeconomic performance. In addition, a recession dummy (Recession) is generated to test the differential effect of bank systemic risk on credit risk-taking in expansion and recession periods. The recession dummy equals 1 if the month of loan origination is designated to be a contraction month by NBER and 0 if it is designated to be an expansion month. 4. Data 4.1. Sample Construction The sample period of this study spans Q to Q Banks quarterly financial data are collected from the Consolidated Financial Statements for Holding Companies (FR Y-9C) available on the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago website. Market data are obtained from CRSP. Borrowing firms quarterly financial data are collected from Compustat. Syndicated loan data are obtained from Loan Pricing Corporation s (LPC) Dealscan loan database. The Dealscan database contains historical information on the terms and conditions of deals in the global syndicated bank loan market. Borrower financial data are linked to Dealscan using the Dealscan-Compustat linking data provided by Chava and Roberts (2008, updated in August 2012). To construct the sample, I first start with a sample of 219,023 deal packages newly originated between January 1995 and December 2013 from the LPC Dealscan database. Since I conduct my analysis at the bank holding company level, I need to first identify the lenders in my sample and their ultimate parent companies. I utilize the information provided by the Federal Reserve System via its National Information Center (NIC) database to identify financial institutions acting as lenders in the study sample. No identity variables are used for lender and ultimate owner in Dealscan because Dealscan overwrites the ultimate owner of the lenders after mergers and acquisitions, that is, the ultimate owner in Dealscan is the ultimate owner at the end of the merger chain. In this analysis, the ultimate bank holding company or lending parent at the time of the issuance of each loan is identified. The NIC database provides detailed information about financial institutions, including types of institutions, establishment time, ownership information, address changes, name changes, and merger and acquisition history. NIC also provides each financial institution s 13

15 RSSD ID, a unique identifier assigned to each financial institution by the Federal Reserve System. Based on the lender information provided by Dealscan, including name, location, and lending history, each lender s RSSD ID is searched manually. Using their RSSD ID (Item RSSD9001 in Call Report and Y-9C), the lender s ultimate owner at the time of loan origination is determined by cross-checking the information contained in Call Report items RSSD ID of Regulatory High Holder 1 (RSSD9348), Financial Higher Holder ID (RSSD9364), and Financial High Holder Percent of Equity (RSSD9365). The three items provide the RSSD ID of a lender s ultimate bank holding company when a lender has an RSSD ID. For a bank that was acquired by another bank and lost its RSSD ID but kept its lending activity, the acquirer s RSSD ID was applied to the acquired bank as its new RSSD ID, and the new ultimate owner of the acquirer can then be identified. The full bank and bank holding companies merger and acquisition history is obtained from the Federal Bank of Chicago. Using the RSSD ID, Dealscan is linked to the Y-9C to obtain bank financial data. Dealscan is also linked to CRSP to collect market data through the PERMCO-RSSD link table provided by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. The bank characteristics data at the bank holding company level is collected using Y-9C reports. Using the PERMCO-RSSD link, bank holding companies are merged with their systemic risk measure, ΔCoVaR. This process reduces the study sample to 80,193 packages (140,609 package-lender pairs). Next, borrower characteristics from Compustat are merged with the information on corporate loans in Dealscan using the linking table provided by Chava and Roberts (2008, updated in Aug. 2012). Furthermore, the loans originated between September 2012 and December 2013 are linked manually. Owing to differences in capital structures and financing strategies between financial and nonfinancial firms, loans to financial companies (SIC between 6000 and 6999) are excluded from the sample. The utility firms (SIC code falls between 4900 and 4999) are also excluded because they may have different operating and reporting environments. This leads to a sample of 10,915 packages (22,595 package-lender pairs), which include 3,603 unique borrowers and 214 unique banks owned by 66 unique publicly traded bank holding companies with ΔCoVaR data. Since systemic risk ΔCoVaR is mostly measured at the bank holding company level, in the subsequent analysis, all regressions are run at the loan-bank holding company level Summary Statistics for Baseline Regressions Table 1 presents the summary statistics. There are 22,595 lender-package observations in the baseline regressions. Only package-level data are used in the baseline regression. The key dependent variable is borrower s quarterly distance-to-default, which has a mean of 6.772, a median of 6.002, and a standard deviation of The key independent variables are ΔCoVaR, which has a mean of 5.216, a median of 14

16 4.351, and a standard deviation of 2.550, and CATFIN, which has a mean of 2.393, a median of 2.286, and a standard deviation of The average deal amount is US$878 million, with average maturity of 49 months. On average, there are lead lenders in each package. The Lending Relationship between borrower i and lender j, which is defined as the dollar amount of loans to borrower i by bank j in the past five years over the total dollar amount of loans by borrower i in the past five years, has a mean of This indicates that on average, each bank engaged in 47% of the total amount a typical firm borrowed in the five years preceding the loan origination. Borrowers have an average size of $6.752 billion, with a mean tangibility of and leverage of Banks have a mean size of $779 billion, with mean capital ratio of 8.5% and return on equity of 8.3%. Table 2 presents the Spearman correlation matrix for the variables included in the baseline regressions. As shown in Table 2, borrower distance-to-default is negatively correlated with both ΔCoVaR (the bank-specific measure of systemic risk) and CATFIN (the aggregate measure of systemic risk), with correlation coefficients of and 0.289, respectively. This provides preliminary evidence that banks with higher levels of systemic risk lend to borrowers with higher credit risk during periods of high aggregate systemic risk Sample Construction for Within-Loan Regressions To investigate whether the relation between systemic risks and borrower default risk is driven by the demand rather than supply effects, within-loan estimations methodology by Chu, Zhang and Zhao (2017) are applied. By adding package (facility) fixed effects, the impact of the demand-side factors from the supply-side factors can be eliminated. The sample of within-loan regressions is constructed differently from that used in the baseline regressions. First, since borrower, loan, and macroeconomic characteristics drop out in a package or facility fixed effects regression, only lender characteristics are relevant to the within-loan regressions. Second, to control for an array of lender characteristics, a broader set of lender variables is used, which includes bank size, capital ratio, return on equity, liquidity, loan charge-offs, loan loss allowance, and risk-weighted assets, to control for lender characteristics and avoid omitted variable bias. Third, since the bank allocation share variable in Dealscan is employed to measure bank lending at the individual facility/package level, a series of requirements on this variable is added to increase its validity. The sample is constructed as follows. The samples at both package level and facility level are constructed separately because the data are processed differently between the two levels. For the facility-level sample, an initial sample of 15

17 246,260 loan facilities originated between January 1995 and December 2013 is considered. Following Chu, Zhang, and Zhao (2017), I focus on 182,745 facilities that involve credit lines, term loans, or both in this analysis since they are the dominant types of bank loans borrowed by nonfinancial firms. I further require the facility to have at least two banks as lenders because the allocation share for a sole-lender loan is always 100%. This reduces the sample to 152,549 facilities. Based on lenders name, city, state, and dates of their earliest and latest lending activities, their RSSD ID is searched manually through the NIC, and all lenders who do not have an identifiable RSSD ID are excluded. Next, I identify the ultimate holding companies of those banks from the Consolidated Financial Statements for Holding Companies (FR Y-9C), following the same methodologies introduced in Section 4.2, and exclude lenders who do not have an identifiable ultimate holding company in quarter t-1, where t denotes the quarter of loan origination. This reduces the sample size to 80,041 facilities. DealScan reports a bank s allocation share in a facility for approximately 31.78% of all lender-facility pairs. For each bank in each facility, Dealscan reports the allocation share in percentages. Since a bank s allocation share is used to measure bank lending at the individual facility level, loans without bank allocation share information or with allocation share greater than 100% are excluded, which is apparently erroneous. Since ΔCoVaR is estimated at the bank holding company level, I also calculate the allocation share at the bank holding company level for consistency. For example, if both bank A and bank B belong to a same bank holding company C and if bank A and bank B participate in a same facility with allocation shares of 10% and 20%, respectively, then it is treated as bank holding company C contributing 30% to the facility. If the allocation share for A or B is missing or greater than 100%, then the observations of A, B, and C on this loan are excluded because they lead to erroneous allocation share at the level of bank holding company C. In addition, all facilities in which the sum of all lender shares exceeds 110% are excluded. I choose 110% to account for rounding and minor errors. The above treatments lead to a sample of 15,850 facilities. Thereafter, the sample is restricted to loans from banks with nonmissing market equity data, systemic risk data, and Y-9C financial data in quarter t and t-1. This leads to a sample of 10,800 facilities, which involve 148 unique banks. These 148 banks belong to 68 unique bank holding companies. I then identify the borrowing firms from Compustat using the DealScan-Compustat linking table provided by Chava and Roberts (2009, updated in August 2012). For loans originated after August 2012, the changes in the link are manually adjusted by comparing borrower companies names in the two databases. This requires the borrowing firms to have an SIC code and distance-to-default in quarter t-1 and t to be included in the sample. I exclude utility firms and financial firms (two-digit 16

18 SIC code equal to 49 or between 60 and 69). These procedures lead to a sample of 3,797 facilities, which involve 123 unique banks that correspond to 66 unique bank holding companies. The package-level samples are constructed following similar procedures. First, only the observations of a bank holding company j in a package k are retained if the bank allocation share data are nonmissing for all its subsidiaries in all facilities under this package. Otherwise, the bank holding company s observation in package k is entirely removed from the sample. For example, bank A and bank B belong to a same bank holding company C. A contributes 30% only to facility F1, and B precipitates only in facility F2; however, its contribution share data are missing. F1 and F2 are under the same package. In this case, the observation for C is removed entirely from this package because its total contribution will be biased downward due to the missing data. Second, the allocation share for bank holding company j in package k is defined as the total allocation shares of all banks that belong to j and participate in the package k. A bank s allocation share in a package is its allocation share multiplied by facility amount and then divided by package amount. Third, the lead lender dummy for bank holding company j in package k is 1 if at least one of its subsidiaries acts as a lead lender in at least one facility under the package k. The final package level sample includes 3,081 packages, which involve 123 unique banks that correspond to 66 bank holding companies. For both levels, the lending relationship measure (Bharath et al., 2007) is included to control for the intensity of past lending relationship. Observations in the within-loan regressions are by facility-bank holding company pairs, while lending relationship is a bank-borrower level measure. In many cases, two or more banks that belong to the same bank holding company may participate in a same loan. In these cases, their bank level lending relationship measure is added up to create a bank holding company level measure. The rationale behind is that the proprietary information obtained from past lending activities are shared among banks that belong to a same bank holding company. To account for possible unobservable differences between lead and nonlead banks, a lead bank dummy is added in the regressions, which is equal to 1 if a bank is the lead bank in the package/facility and 0 otherwise. A bank is defined as a lead lender if its lead lender credit variable is Yes in Dealscan. The lead lender credit variable is by facility-bank pairs, and two or more banks that belong to a same bank holding company may participate in a same facility; some of them may be lead lenders, while the others are not. To create a bank holding company level lead lender dummy, the dummy is assigned a value of 1 if at least one of its banks acted as a lead lender in the facility. 17

Systemic Risk and Credit Risk in Bank Loan Portfolios

Systemic Risk and Credit Risk in Bank Loan Portfolios Systemic Risk and Credit Risk in Bank Loan Portfolios Yu Shan 1 Department of Economics and Finance, Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College, New York, NY 10010, USA Aug 27, 2017 Abstract I investigate

More information

Systemic Risk and Credit Risk in Bank Loan Portfolios

Systemic Risk and Credit Risk in Bank Loan Portfolios Systemic Risk and Credit Risk in Bank Loan Portfolios Yu Shan Baruch College, City University of New York May 5, 2017 Abstract I investigate the link between systemic risk and credit risk in the bank s

More information

The End of Market Discipline? Investor Expectations of Implicit State Guarantees

The End of Market Discipline? Investor Expectations of Implicit State Guarantees The Investor Expectations of Implicit State Guarantees Viral Acharya New York University World Bank, Virginia Tech A. Joseph Warburton Syracuse University Motivation Federal Reserve Chairman Bernanke (2013):

More information

Banks Non-Interest Income and Systemic Risk

Banks Non-Interest Income and Systemic Risk Banks Non-Interest Income and Systemic Risk Markus Brunnermeier, Gang Dong, and Darius Palia CREDIT 2011 Motivation (1) Recent crisis showcase of large risk spillovers from one bank to another increasing

More information

Bank Contagion in Europe

Bank Contagion in Europe Bank Contagion in Europe Reint Gropp and Jukka Vesala Workshop on Banking, Financial Stability and the Business Cycle, Sveriges Riksbank, 26-28 August 2004 The views expressed in this paper are those of

More information

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Abstract The tradeoff theory of corporate cash holdings predicts that

More information

Does Uniqueness in Banking Matter?

Does Uniqueness in Banking Matter? Does Uniqueness in Banking Matter? Frank Hong Liu a, Lars Norden b, and Fabrizio Spargoli c a Adam Smith Business School, University of Glasgow, UK b Brazilian School of Public and Business Administration,

More information

How Does Deposit Insurance Affect Bank Risk?

How Does Deposit Insurance Affect Bank Risk? Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Policy Research Working Paper 6289 How Does Deposit Insurance Affect Bank Risk? Evidence

More information

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations by Lei Wang Applied Economics Bachelor, United International College (2013) and Yao Liu Bachelor of Business Administration,

More information

Impact of credit risk (NPLs) and capital on liquidity risk of Malaysian banks

Impact of credit risk (NPLs) and capital on liquidity risk of Malaysian banks Available online at www.icas.my International Conference on Accounting Studies (ICAS) 2015 Impact of credit risk (NPLs) and capital on liquidity risk of Malaysian banks Azlan Ali, Yaman Hajja *, Hafezali

More information

Stronger Risk Controls, Lower Risk: Evidence from U.S. Bank Holding Companies

Stronger Risk Controls, Lower Risk: Evidence from U.S. Bank Holding Companies Stronger Risk Controls, Lower Risk: Evidence from U.S. Bank Holding Companies Andrew Ellul 1 Vijay Yerramilli 2 1 Kelley School of Business, Indiana University 2 C. T. Bauer College of Business, University

More information

Bank Capital and Lending: Evidence from Syndicated Loans

Bank Capital and Lending: Evidence from Syndicated Loans Bank Capital and Lending: Evidence from Syndicated Loans Yongqiang Chu, Donghang Zhang, and Yijia Zhao This Version: June, 2014 Abstract Using a large sample of bank-loan-borrower matched dataset of individual

More information

Corporate Governance of Banks and Financial Stability: International Evidence 1

Corporate Governance of Banks and Financial Stability: International Evidence 1 Corporate Governance of Banks and Financial Stability: International Evidence 1 Deniz Anginer Virginia Tech, Pamplin College of Business Asli Demirguc-Kunt Word Bank Harry Huizinga Tilburg University and

More information

Citation for published version (APA): Shehzad, C. T. (2009). Panel studies on bank risks and crises Groningen: University of Groningen

Citation for published version (APA): Shehzad, C. T. (2009). Panel studies on bank risks and crises Groningen: University of Groningen University of Groningen Panel studies on bank risks and crises Shehzad, Choudhry Tanveer IMPORTANT NOTE: You are advised to consult the publisher's version (publisher's PDF) if you wish to cite from it.

More information

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva* The Role of Credit Ratings in the Dynamic Tradeoff Model Viktoriya Staneva* This study examines what costs and benefits of debt are most important to the determination of the optimal capital structure.

More information

Stronger Risk Controls, Lower Risk: Evidence from U.S. Bank Holding Companies

Stronger Risk Controls, Lower Risk: Evidence from U.S. Bank Holding Companies Stronger Risk Controls, Lower Risk: Evidence from U.S. Bank Holding Companies Andrew Ellul 1 Vijay Yerramilli 2 1 Kelley School of Business, Indiana University 2 C. T. Bauer College of Business, University

More information

Rating Efficiency in the Indian Commercial Paper Market. Anand Srinivasan 1

Rating Efficiency in the Indian Commercial Paper Market. Anand Srinivasan 1 Rating Efficiency in the Indian Commercial Paper Market Anand Srinivasan 1 Abstract: This memo examines the efficiency of the rating system for commercial paper (CP) issues in India, for issues rated A1+

More information

Systemic risk and the U.S. financial system The role of banking activity

Systemic risk and the U.S. financial system The role of banking activity Systemic risk and the U.S. financial system The role of banking activity Denefa Bostandzic Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaft, Ruhr-Universität Bochum 30th June 2014 Abstract We demonstrate that U.S.

More information

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland The International Journal of Business and Finance Research Volume 6 Number 2 2012 AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University

More information

DOES COMPENSATION AFFECT BANK PROFITABILITY? EVIDENCE FROM US BANKS

DOES COMPENSATION AFFECT BANK PROFITABILITY? EVIDENCE FROM US BANKS DOES COMPENSATION AFFECT BANK PROFITABILITY? EVIDENCE FROM US BANKS by PENGRU DONG Bachelor of Management and Organizational Studies University of Western Ontario, 2017 and NANXI ZHAO Bachelor of Commerce

More information

Loan Partnerships with Intervention of Regulatory Bailouts: Evidence of TARP effect on Syndicated Loan Structure. Abstract

Loan Partnerships with Intervention of Regulatory Bailouts: Evidence of TARP effect on Syndicated Loan Structure. Abstract Loan Partnerships with Intervention of Regulatory Bailouts: Evidence of TARP effect on Syndicated Loan Structure Bolortuya Enkhtaivan * Texas A&M International University Siddharth Shankar Texas A&M International

More information

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking? October 19, 2009 Ulrike Malmendier, UC Berkeley (joint work with Stefan Nagel, Stanford) 1 The Tale of Depression Babies I don t know

More information

Government interventions - restoring or destructing financial stability in the long-run?

Government interventions - restoring or destructing financial stability in the long-run? Government interventions - restoring or destructing financial stability in the long-run? Aneta Hryckiewicz* University of Frankfurt and Kozminski University January 2, 2012 Abstract: Recent government

More information

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Capital allocation in Indian business groups Capital allocation in Indian business groups Remco van der Molen Department of Finance University of Groningen The Netherlands This version: June 2004 Abstract The within-group reallocation of capital

More information

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As Zhenxu Tong * University of Exeter Jian Liu ** University of Exeter This draft: August 2016 Abstract We examine

More information

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers By Pranit Chowhan Bachelor of Business Administration, University of Mumbai, 2014 And Vishal Bane Bachelor of Commerce, University of Mumbai, 2006 PROJECT

More information

Liquidity skewness premium

Liquidity skewness premium Liquidity skewness premium Giho Jeong, Jangkoo Kang, and Kyung Yoon Kwon * Abstract Risk-averse investors may dislike decrease of liquidity rather than increase of liquidity, and thus there can be asymmetric

More information

Does Competition in Banking explains Systemic Banking Crises?

Does Competition in Banking explains Systemic Banking Crises? Does Competition in Banking explains Systemic Banking Crises? Abstract: This paper examines the relation between competition in the banking sector and the financial stability on country level. Compared

More information

May 19, Abstract

May 19, Abstract LIQUIDITY RISK AND SYNDICATE STRUCTURE Evan Gatev Boston College gatev@bc.edu Philip E. Strahan Boston College, Wharton Financial Institutions Center & NBER philip.strahan@bc.edu May 19, 2008 Abstract

More information

Competition, Risk-Shifting, and Public Bail-out Policies

Competition, Risk-Shifting, and Public Bail-out Policies Competition, Risk-Shifting, and Public Bail-out Policies Reint Gropp European Business School, CFS and ZEW Hendrik Hakenes University of Hannover and MPI Bonn Isabel Schnabel University of Mainz, MPI Bonn,

More information

Asset Price Bubbles and Systemic Risk

Asset Price Bubbles and Systemic Risk Asset Price Bubbles and Systemic Risk Markus Brunnermeier, Simon Rother, Isabel Schnabel AFA 2018 Annual Meeting Philadelphia; January 7, 2018 Simon Rother (University of Bonn) Asset Price Bubbles and

More information

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage Jin-Chuan Duan * and Yun Li (First draft: April 12, 2006) (This version: May 16, 2006) Abstract This paper identifies a key cause for the documented diversification

More information

Debt Maturity and the Cost of Bank Loans

Debt Maturity and the Cost of Bank Loans Debt Maturity and the Cost of Bank Loans Chih-Wei Wang a, Wan-Chien Chiu b*, and Tao-Hsien Dolly King c June 2016 Abstract We examine the extent to which a firm s debt maturity structure affects borrowing

More information

MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM

MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM ) MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: THE ROLE OF GENDER IN EUROPE AND THE UNITED KINGDOM Ersin Güner 559370 Master Finance Supervisor: dr. P.C. (Peter) de Goeij December 2013 Abstract Evidence from the US shows

More information

Corporate Governance and Bank Insolvency Risk Anginer, D.; Demirguc-Kunt, A.; Huizinga, Harry; Ma, Kebin

Corporate Governance and Bank Insolvency Risk Anginer, D.; Demirguc-Kunt, A.; Huizinga, Harry; Ma, Kebin Tilburg University Corporate Governance and Bank Insolvency Risk Anginer, D.; Demirguc-Kunt, A.; Huizinga, Harry; Ma, Kebin Document version: Early version, also known as pre-print Publication date: 2014

More information

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance.

RESEARCH STATEMENT. Heather Tookes, May My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. RESEARCH STATEMENT Heather Tookes, May 2013 OVERVIEW My research lies at the intersection of capital markets and corporate finance. Much of my work focuses on understanding the ways in which capital market

More information

Economic Watch Deleveraging after the burst of a credit-bubble Alfonso Ugarte / Akshaya Sharma / Rodolfo Méndez

Economic Watch Deleveraging after the burst of a credit-bubble Alfonso Ugarte / Akshaya Sharma / Rodolfo Méndez Economic Watch Deleveraging after the burst of a credit-bubble Alfonso Ugarte / Akshaya Sharma / Rodolfo Méndez (Global Modeling & Long-term Analysis Unit) Madrid, December 5, 2017 Index 1. Introduction

More information

Bank Leverage and Monetary Policy s Risk-Taking Channel: Evidence from the United States

Bank Leverage and Monetary Policy s Risk-Taking Channel: Evidence from the United States Bank Leverage and Monetary Policy s Risk-Taking Channel: Evidence from the United States by Giovanni Dell Ariccia (IMF and CEPR) Luc Laeven (IMF and CEPR) Gustavo Suarez (Federal Reserve Board) CSEF Unicredit

More information

Factors in the returns on stock : inspiration from Fama and French asset pricing model

Factors in the returns on stock : inspiration from Fama and French asset pricing model Lingnan Journal of Banking, Finance and Economics Volume 5 2014/2015 Academic Year Issue Article 1 January 2015 Factors in the returns on stock : inspiration from Fama and French asset pricing model Yuanzhen

More information

Debt Maturity and the Cost of Bank Loans

Debt Maturity and the Cost of Bank Loans Debt Maturity and the Cost of Bank Loans Chih-Wei Wang a, Wan-Chien Chiu b,*, and Tao-Hsien Dolly King c September 2016 Abstract We study the extent to which a firm s debt maturity structure affects its

More information

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Plan B and other Reports Graduate Studies 5-2012 The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns Abdullah Al Masud Utah State University

More information

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure International Journal of Education and Research Vol. 1 No. 3 March 2013 Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure David Oima* David Sande** Benjamin Ombok*** Abstract Negative relationship

More information

Journal of Banking & Finance

Journal of Banking & Finance Journal of Banking & Finance 48 (2014) 312 321 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Banking & Finance journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf How does deposit insurance affect bank

More information

Capital structure and profitability of firms in the corporate sector of Pakistan

Capital structure and profitability of firms in the corporate sector of Pakistan Business Review: (2017) 12(1):50-58 Original Paper Capital structure and profitability of firms in the corporate sector of Pakistan Sana Tauseef Heman D. Lohano Abstract We examine the impact of debt ratios

More information

Local Culture and Dividends

Local Culture and Dividends Local Culture and Dividends Erdem Ucar I empirically investigate whether geographical variations in local culture, as proxied by local religion, affect dividend demand and corporate dividend policy for

More information

Discussion of: Banks Incentives and Quality of Internal Risk Models

Discussion of: Banks Incentives and Quality of Internal Risk Models Discussion of: Banks Incentives and Quality of Internal Risk Models by Matthew C. Plosser and Joao A. C. Santos Philipp Schnabl 1 1 NYU Stern, NBER and CEPR Chicago University October 2, 2015 Motivation

More information

The relation between bank losses & loan supply an analysis using panel data

The relation between bank losses & loan supply an analysis using panel data The relation between bank losses & loan supply an analysis using panel data Monika Turyna & Thomas Hrdina Department of Economics, University of Vienna June 2009 Topic IMF Working Paper 232 (2008) by Erlend

More information

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism Mehmet E. Akbulut 1 Department of Finance College of Business and Economics California State University Fullerton Abstract This paper examines whether managers

More information

Firm Debt Outcomes in Crises: The Role of Lending and. Underwriting Relationships

Firm Debt Outcomes in Crises: The Role of Lending and. Underwriting Relationships Firm Debt Outcomes in Crises: The Role of Lending and Underwriting Relationships Manisha Goel Michelle Zemel Pomona College Very Preliminary See https://research.pomona.edu/michelle-zemel/research/ for

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LIQUIDITY RISK AND SYNDICATE STRUCTURE. Evan Gatev Philip Strahan. Working Paper

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LIQUIDITY RISK AND SYNDICATE STRUCTURE. Evan Gatev Philip Strahan. Working Paper NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LIQUIDITY RISK AND SYNDICATE STRUCTURE Evan Gatev Philip Strahan Working Paper 13802 http://www.nber.org/papers/w13802 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

The impact of CDS trading on the bond market: Evidence from Asia

The impact of CDS trading on the bond market: Evidence from Asia Capital Market Research Forum 9/2554 By Dr. Ilhyock Shim Senior Economist Representative Office for Asia and the Pacific Bank for International Settlements 7 September 2011 The impact of CDS trading on

More information

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts Online Appendix to The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts This online appendix tabulates and discusses the results of robustness checks and supplementary analyses mentioned in the paper. A1. Estimating

More information

Supply Chain Characteristics and Bank Lending Decisions

Supply Chain Characteristics and Bank Lending Decisions Supply Chain Characteristics and Bank Lending Decisions Iftekhar Hasan Fordham University and Bank of Finland 45 Columbus Circle, 5 th floor New York, NY 100123 Phone: 646 312 8278 E-mail: ihasan@fordham.edu

More information

Credit Default Swaps and Bank Loan Sales: Evidence from Bank Syndicated Lending. November 2015

Credit Default Swaps and Bank Loan Sales: Evidence from Bank Syndicated Lending. November 2015 Credit Default Swaps and Bank Loan Sales: Evidence from Bank Syndicated Lending November 2015 Credit Default Swaps and Bank Loan Sales: Evidence from Bank Syndicated Lending Abstract Do banks use credit

More information

Creditor rights and information sharing: the increase in nonbank debt during banking crises

Creditor rights and information sharing: the increase in nonbank debt during banking crises Creditor rights and information sharing: the increase in nonbank debt during banking crises Abstract We analyze how the protection of creditor rights and information sharing among creditors affect the

More information

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS JOHANNES KEPLER UNIVERSITY LINZ Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison by Burkhard Raunig and Johann Scharler* Working Paper

More information

Bank Profitability, Capital, and Interest Rate Spreads in the Context of Gramm-Leach-Bliley. and Dodd-Frank Acts. This Draft Version: January 15, 2018

Bank Profitability, Capital, and Interest Rate Spreads in the Context of Gramm-Leach-Bliley. and Dodd-Frank Acts. This Draft Version: January 15, 2018 Bank Profitability, Capital, and Interest Rate Spreads in the Context of Gramm-Leach-Bliley and Dodd-Frank Acts MUJTBA ZIA a,* AND MICHAEL IMPSON b a Assistant Professor of Finance, Rankin College of Business,

More information

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings Abstract This paper empirically investigates the value shareholders place on excess cash

More information

Pornchai Chunhachinda, Li Li. Income Structure, Competitiveness, Profitability and Risk: Evidence from Asian Banks

Pornchai Chunhachinda, Li Li. Income Structure, Competitiveness, Profitability and Risk: Evidence from Asian Banks Pornchai Chunhachinda, Li Li Thammasat University (Chunhachinda), University of the Thai Chamber of Commerce (Li), Bangkok, Thailand Income Structure, Competitiveness, Profitability and Risk: Evidence

More information

Managerial Risk-Taking Incentive and Firm Innovation: Evidence from FAS 123R *

Managerial Risk-Taking Incentive and Firm Innovation: Evidence from FAS 123R * Managerial Risk-Taking Incentive and Firm Innovation: Evidence from FAS 123R * Connie Mao Temple University Chi Zhang Temple University This version: December, 2015 * Connie X. Mao, Department of Finance,

More information

Safer Ratios, Riskier Portfolios: Banks Response to Government Aid. Ran Duchin Denis Sosyura. University of Michigan

Safer Ratios, Riskier Portfolios: Banks Response to Government Aid. Ran Duchin Denis Sosyura. University of Michigan Safer Ratios, Riskier Portfolios: Banks Response to Government Aid Ran Duchin Denis Sosyura University of Michigan Motivation Key economic features of the past few years: Increased government regulation

More information

Working Paper October Book Review of

Working Paper October Book Review of Working Paper 04-06 October 2004 Book Review of Credit Risk: Pricing, Measurement, and Management by Darrell Duffie and Kenneth J. Singleton 2003, Princeton University Press, 396 pages Reviewer: Georges

More information

Conservatism and stock return skewness

Conservatism and stock return skewness Conservatism and stock return skewness DEVENDRA KALE*, SURESH RADHAKRISHNAN, and FENG ZHAO Naveen Jindal School of Management, University of Texas at Dallas, 800 West Campbell Road, Richardson, Texas 75080

More information

Bank Profitability and Risk-Taking in a Low Interest Rate Environment: The Case of Thailand

Bank Profitability and Risk-Taking in a Low Interest Rate Environment: The Case of Thailand Bank Profitability and Risk-Taking in a Low Interest Rate Environment: The Case of Thailand Lathaporn Ratanavararak and Nasha Ananchotikul First Draft (Do not quote) June 2018 Abstract This paper studies

More information

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect?

R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? R&D and Stock Returns: Is There a Spill-Over Effect? Yi Jiang Department of Finance, California State University, Fullerton SGMH 5160, Fullerton, CA 92831 (657)278-4363 yjiang@fullerton.edu Yiming Qian

More information

Shadow Banking and Financial Stability

Shadow Banking and Financial Stability Shadow Banking and Financial Stability Professor Dr. Claudia M. Buch Magdeburg University Institute for Economic Research Halle (IWH) German Council of Economic Experts Symposium Financial Stability and

More information

Securities Class Actions, Debt Financing and Firm Relationships with Lenders

Securities Class Actions, Debt Financing and Firm Relationships with Lenders Securities Class Actions, Debt Financing and Firm Relationships with Lenders Alternative title: Securities Class Actions, Banking Relationships and Lender Reputation Matthew McCarten 1 University of Otago

More information

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1 Devraj Basu Alexander Stremme Warwick Business School, University of Warwick November 2005 address for correspondence: Alexander Stremme Warwick Business

More information

How do business groups evolve? Evidence from new project announcements.

How do business groups evolve? Evidence from new project announcements. How do business groups evolve? Evidence from new project announcements. Meghana Ayyagari, Radhakrishnan Gopalan, and Vijay Yerramilli June, 2009 Abstract Using a unique data set of investment projects

More information

Leverage Across Firms, Banks and Countries

Leverage Across Firms, Banks and Countries Şebnem Kalemli-Özcan, Bent E. Sørensen and Sevcan Yeşiltaş University of Houston and NBER, University of Houston and CEPR, and Johns Hopkins University Dallas Fed Conference on Financial Frictions and

More information

Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion. Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b

Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion. Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b a Department of Finance, Spears School of Business, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater, OK

More information

ECCE Research Note 06-01: CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND THE COST OF EQUITY CAPITAL: EVIDENCE FROM GMI S GOVERNANCE RATING

ECCE Research Note 06-01: CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND THE COST OF EQUITY CAPITAL: EVIDENCE FROM GMI S GOVERNANCE RATING ECCE Research Note 06-01: CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND THE COST OF EQUITY CAPITAL: EVIDENCE FROM GMI S GOVERNANCE RATING by Jeroen Derwall and Patrick Verwijmeren Corporate Governance and the Cost of Equity

More information

CEO Incentives and Bank Risk over the Business Cycle. Steven Ongena, Tanseli Savaser, Elif Şişli-Ciamarra * January 8, 2018.

CEO Incentives and Bank Risk over the Business Cycle. Steven Ongena, Tanseli Savaser, Elif Şişli-Ciamarra * January 8, 2018. CEO Incentives and Bank Risk over the Business Cycle Steven Ongena, Tanseli Savaser, Elif Şişli-Ciamarra * January 8, 2018 Abstract Due to government guarantees provided to financial firms, bank shareholders

More information

Bank Bailouts, Bail-ins, or No Regulatory Intervention? A Dynamic Model and Empirical Tests of Optimal Regulation

Bank Bailouts, Bail-ins, or No Regulatory Intervention? A Dynamic Model and Empirical Tests of Optimal Regulation Bank Bailouts, Bail-ins, or No Regulatory Intervention? A Dynamic Model and Empirical Tests of Optimal Regulation Allen N. Berger University of South Carolina Wharton Financial Institutions Center European

More information

Does Financial Openness Lead to Deeper Domestic Financial Markets?

Does Financial Openness Lead to Deeper Domestic Financial Markets? Does Financial Openness Lead to Deeper Domestic Financial Markets? FPD Academy Award Seminar The World Bank July 28, 2010 César Calderón (The World Bank) Megumi Kubota (University of York) Motivation Salient

More information

On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty

On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty On the Investment Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty Christopher F Baum Department of Economics, Boston College and DIW Berlin Mustafa Caglayan Department of Economics, University of Sheffield Oleksandr

More information

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation

Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation ECONOMIC BULLETIN 3/218 ANALYTICAL ARTICLES Creditor countries and debtor countries: some asymmetries in the dynamics of external wealth accumulation Ángel Estrada and Francesca Viani 6 September 218 Following

More information

Success in Global Venture Capital Investing: Do Institutional and Cultural Differences Matter?

Success in Global Venture Capital Investing: Do Institutional and Cultural Differences Matter? Success in Global Venture Capital Investing: Do Institutional and Cultural Differences Matter? Sonali Hazarika, Raj Nahata, Kishore Tandon Conference on Entrepreneurship and Growth 2009 Importance and

More information

Contrarian Trades and Disposition Effect: Evidence from Online Trade Data. Abstract

Contrarian Trades and Disposition Effect: Evidence from Online Trade Data. Abstract Contrarian Trades and Disposition Effect: Evidence from Online Trade Data Hayato Komai a Ryota Koyano b Daisuke Miyakawa c Abstract Using online stock trading records in Japan for 461 individual investors

More information

Keywords: Equity firms, capital structure, debt free firms, debt and stocks.

Keywords: Equity firms, capital structure, debt free firms, debt and stocks. Working Paper 2009-WP-04 May 2009 Performance of Debt Free Firms Tarek Zaher Abstract: This paper compares the performance of portfolios of debt free firms to comparable portfolios of leveraged firms.

More information

Banks Incentives and the Quality of Internal Risk Models

Banks Incentives and the Quality of Internal Risk Models Banks Incentives and the Quality of Internal Risk Models Matthew Plosser Federal Reserve Bank of New York and João Santos Federal Reserve Bank of New York & Nova School of Business and Economics The views

More information

Topic 2. Productivity, technological change, and policy: macro-level analysis

Topic 2. Productivity, technological change, and policy: macro-level analysis Topic 2. Productivity, technological change, and policy: macro-level analysis Lecture 3 Growth econometrics Read Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992, QJE); Durlauf et al. (2004, section 3-7) ; or Temple, J. (1999,

More information

Are International Banks Different?

Are International Banks Different? Policy Research Working Paper 8286 WPS8286 Are International Banks Different? Evidence on Bank Performance and Strategy Ata Can Bertay Asli Demirgüç-Kunt Harry Huizinga Public Disclosure Authorized Public

More information

Do Peer Firms Affect Corporate Financial Policy?

Do Peer Firms Affect Corporate Financial Policy? 1 / 23 Do Peer Firms Affect Corporate Financial Policy? Journal of Finance, 2014 Mark T. Leary 1 and Michael R. Roberts 2 1 Olin Business School Washington University 2 The Wharton School University of

More information

What Drives Global Syndication of Bank Loans? Effects of Bank Regulations*

What Drives Global Syndication of Bank Loans? Effects of Bank Regulations* What Drives Global Syndication of Bank Loans? Effects of Bank Regulations* Janet Gao Indiana University janetgao@indiana.edu Yeejin Jang Purdue University jang67@purdue.edu December 12, 2017 Abstract The

More information

Bank Geographic Diversification and Systemic Risk: A Gravity-Deregulation Approach. (Abstract)

Bank Geographic Diversification and Systemic Risk: A Gravity-Deregulation Approach. (Abstract) Bank Geographic Diversification and Systemic Risk: A Gravity-Deregulation Approach (Abstract) Using the gravity-deregulation model to construct the time-varying and bankspecific exogenous instrument of

More information

CEOs Personal Portfolio and Corporate Policies

CEOs Personal Portfolio and Corporate Policies CEOs Personal Portfolio and Corporate Policies Hamid Boustanifar Dan Zhang October, 2016 Abstract Using a unique data set of personal wealth and sociodemographic characteristics for all Norwegian CEOs,

More information

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information? Yongsik Kim * Abstract This paper provides empirical evidence that analysts generate firm-specific

More information

Cascading Defaults and Systemic Risk of a Banking Network. Jin-Chuan DUAN & Changhao ZHANG

Cascading Defaults and Systemic Risk of a Banking Network. Jin-Chuan DUAN & Changhao ZHANG Cascading Defaults and Systemic Risk of a Banking Network Jin-Chuan DUAN & Changhao ZHANG Risk Management Institute & NUS Business School National University of Singapore (June 2015) Key Contributions

More information

Credit-Induced Boom and Bust

Credit-Induced Boom and Bust Credit-Induced Boom and Bust Marco Di Maggio (Columbia) and Amir Kermani (UC Berkeley) 10th CSEF-IGIER Symposium on Economics and Institutions June 25, 2014 Prof. Marco Di Maggio 1 Motivation The Great

More information

Macroeconomic Factors in Private Bank Debt Renegotiation

Macroeconomic Factors in Private Bank Debt Renegotiation University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Wharton Research Scholars Wharton School 4-2011 Macroeconomic Factors in Private Bank Debt Renegotiation Peter Maa University of Pennsylvania Follow this and

More information

Capital structure and the financial crisis

Capital structure and the financial crisis Capital structure and the financial crisis Richard H. Fosberg William Paterson University Journal of Finance and Accountancy Abstract The financial crisis on the late 2000s had a major impact on the financial

More information

Online Appendices for

Online Appendices for Online Appendices for From Made in China to Innovated in China : Necessity, Prospect, and Challenges Shang-Jin Wei, Zhuan Xie, and Xiaobo Zhang Journal of Economic Perspectives, (31)1, Winter 2017 Online

More information

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin June 15, 2008 Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin Abstract The trade effect of the euro is typically

More information

Debt Overhang, Rollover Risk, and Investment in Europe

Debt Overhang, Rollover Risk, and Investment in Europe Debt Overhang, Rollover Risk, and Investment in Europe Ṣebnem Kalemli-Özcan, University of Maryland, CEPR and NBER Luc Laeven, ECB and CEPR David Moreno, University of Maryland September 2015, EC Post

More information

Title. The relation between bank ownership concentration and financial stability. Wilbert van Rossum Tilburg University

Title. The relation between bank ownership concentration and financial stability. Wilbert van Rossum Tilburg University Title The relation between bank ownership concentration and financial stability. Wilbert van Rossum Tilburg University Department of Finance PO Box 90153, NL 5000 LE Tilburg, The Netherlands Supervisor:

More information

Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson

Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options. Joshua D. Anderson Managerial incentives to increase firm volatility provided by debt, stock, and options Joshua D. Anderson jdanders@mit.edu (617) 253-7974 John E. Core* jcore@mit.edu (617) 715-4819 Abstract We measure

More information

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract

Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation. Abstract Financial Constraints and the Risk-Return Relation Tao Wang Queens College and the Graduate Center of the City University of New York Abstract Stock return volatilities are related to firms' financial

More information

Bank Characteristics and Payout Policy

Bank Characteristics and Payout Policy Asian Social Science; Vol. 10, No. 1; 2014 ISSN 1911-2017 E-ISSN 1911-2025 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education Bank Characteristics and Payout Policy Seok Weon Lee 1 1 Division of International

More information

1. Logit and Linear Probability Models

1. Logit and Linear Probability Models INTERNET APPENDIX 1. Logit and Linear Probability Models Table 1 Leverage and the Likelihood of a Union Strike (Logit Models) This table presents estimation results of logit models of union strikes during

More information